Monetary

Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one

Chris Edmond

2nd Semester 2014

1 This class

Monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one •

Fiscal policy and multipliers • Reading • Woodford “Simple analytics of the government expenditure ⇧ multiplier” AEJ: ,2011

Available from the LMS

2 This class

1- Benchmark fiscal multipliers

– long-run multiplier (neoclassical case) – short-run multiplier (for constant real rate)

2- Detailed new Keynesian example

– illustrates how multiplier depends on reaction, stickiness, etc

3 Neoclassical benchmark

Household function • U(C) V (N) • C + G = Y = F (N)

Standard optimality conditions •

V 0(N) W = = F 0(N) U 0(C) P Utility cost of producing Y output •

1 V 0(N) V˜ (Y ) V (F (Y )), V˜ 0(Y )= ⌘ F 0(N)

4 Neoclassical benchmark (cont)

Key optimality condition can then be written •

U 0(Y G)=V˜ 0(Y ) Implicitly differentiating and using U (C)=V˜ (Y ) gives • 0 0

U 00(C) dY U (C) U (C) Y = 00 = 0 ˜ U (C) V˜ (Y ) dG U 00(C) V 00(Y ) 00 00 U (C) Y + ˜ Y 0 V 0(Y )

⌘ = u (0, 1) ⌘u + ⌘v 2

where ⌘u > 0 and ⌘v > 0 are elasticities of U 0(C) and V˜ 0(Y ) with respect to Y

5 Imperfect

Not much changes with constant markup • W " P = , MF (N) M⌘" 1 0 Key condition can then be written •

U 0(Y G)= V˜ 0(Y ) M Again, implicitly differentiating and using U (C)= V˜ (Y ) gives • 0 M 0 dY ⌘ = u (0, 1) dG ⌘u + ⌘v 2 Constant markup reduces level of Y , but does not affect multiplier •

6 Aside: countercyclical markups?

Suppose markup depends on output, (Y ). Multiplier formula • M then generalises to dY ⌘ = u dG ⌘u + ⌘m + ⌘v

where ⌘m is of markup with respect to output

Multiplier > 1 if markups sufficiently countercyclical, ⌘ < ⌘ • m v Large literature provides microfoundations for countercyclical • markups. More generally, key is for endogenous decline in gap between real and household MRS

7 Short-run vs. long-run effects

This neoclassical benchmark determines long-run multiplier • dY¯ ⌘ = u (0, 1) dG¯ ⌘u + ⌘v ⌘ 2

[i.e., effects of permanent changes in government purchases]

Consider government purchases G with permanent G¯ • { t} What are the effects of transitory or short-run changes in G ? • t

8 Transitory change in Gt Multiplier effects depends on assumed monetary policy response.If • we want to “keep monetary policy unchanged”, what should we hold constant?

Suppose monetary policy seeks to maintain a constant real • rate r = ⇢ = log >0. Household consumption Euler equation t then implies

Ct = Ct+1 = C¯

for some level of consumption determined by the permanent level G¯

Hence for a purely transitory change • dYt Yt = C¯ + Gt, =1 dGt independent of details of wage or price stickiness! 9 Summary

Long-run/neoclassical multiplier • dY¯ ⌘ = u (0, 1) dG¯ ⌘u + ⌘v ⌘ 2 Short-run multiplier, holding real constant • dY t =1 dGt What if policy cannot maintain constant real rate? • – depends on details of monetary policy reaction, price stickiness etc – next, a simple new Keynesian example

10 Simple new Keynesian example

Intertemporal consumption Euler equation • 1 ct = (it Et[⇡t+1] ⇢)+Et[ct+1] Goods market, constant productivity • c + g = y = a +(1 ↵)n t t t t Labor supply • w p = c + 'n t t t t Static markup (with flexible ) • p = µ + w + n y log(1 ↵) t t t t

11 Flexible price equilibrium

Natural output, in log deviations • n yˆt =gˆt

If measure G relative to Y¯ ,thatisgˆ (G G¯)/Y¯ , then this • t t ⌘ t elasticity is the long-run multiplier, as above

⌘ = u = ⌘u + ⌘v '+↵ + 1 ↵ ⇣ ⌘

12 Flexible price equilibrium (cont).

Output gap • y˜ yˆ yˆn =ˆy gˆ =ˆc +(1 )ˆg t ⌘ t t t t t t Plug back into intertemporal consumption Euler equation to get dynamic IS curve

1 n y˜t = (it Et[⇡t+1] r )+Et[˜yt+1] t Natural real rate [assuming gˆ process is AR(1)] • { t} rn = ⇢ + (1 )(1 ⇢ )ˆg t g t

13 Simple new Keynesian example

Dynamic IS curve •

1 n y˜t = (it Et[⇡t+1] r )+Et[˜yt+1] t New Keynesian

⇡t = Et[⇡t+1]+y˜t

Interest rate rule •

it = ⇢ + ⇡⇡t + yy˜t

Natural real rate • rn = ⇢ + (1 )(1 ⇢ )ˆg t g t

14 Method of undetermined coefficients

Guess •

⇡t = '⇡ggˆt, and y˜t = 'yggˆt

for some coefficients '⇡g,'yg to be determined

As usual, new Keynesian Phillips curve immediately implies • proportional relationship  ' = ' ⇡g 1 ⇢ yg g And from dynamic IS curve • (1 )(1 ⇢ ) 1  ' = g , + ( ⇢ ) > 0 yg +1 ⇢ ⌘ y 1 ⇢ ⇡ g g  g

15 Effects of increases in government purchases

Output gap increases •

@y˜t = 'yg > 0 @gˆt Inflation increases • @⇡t = '⇡g > 0 @gˆt Monetary policy tightens •

@it = ⇡'⇡g + y'yg > 0 @gˆt

16 Multipliers redux

Output then given by • 1 ⇢ + yˆ =˜y +ˆyn =(' +)g ˆ = g gˆ t t t gy t 1 ⇢ + t g (hence output [and employment] also increase)

Since G is measured relative to Y¯ , this elasticity is also the new • t Keynesian multiplier

Observe that • 1 ⇢ + < g < 1 1 ⇢ + g

17 Discussion

Sticky prices imply a larger multiplier than classical benchmark •

But multiplier still less than one • [interest rate rule here allows rt to vary]

Size of multiplier increasing in degree of price stickiness • [high ✓ reduces  which reduces and increases multiplier]

Size of multiplier decreasing in monetary policy reactiveness • [high policy coefficients ⇡,y increase and reduce multiplier]

Size of multiplier decreasing in persistence of gˆ shock • t

18 Discussion

Larger multipliers obtain when monetary policy accommodates • fiscal expansion

Important special case is when monetary policy is constrained by • the zero-lower-bound (ZLB) on it

Can then have multipliers (substantially) larger than one •

19 Next class

Monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part two •

The zero lower bound. Implications for multipliers. • Main reading: • Woodford “Simple analytics of the government expenditure ⇧ multiplier” AEJ: Macroeconomics,2011

Further reading • Christiano, Eichenbaum and Rebelo “When is the government ⇧ spending multiplier large?” Journal of ,2011

Available from the LMS

20