A Service of

Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics

Maag, Thomas

Working Paper On the accuracy of the probability method for quantifying beliefs about inflation

KOF Working Papers, No. 230

Provided in Cooperation with: KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich

Suggested Citation: Maag, Thomas (2009) : On the accuracy of the probability method for quantifying beliefs about inflation, KOF Working Papers, No. 230, ETH Zurich, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, Zurich, http://dx.doi.org/10.3929/ethz-a-005859391

This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/50407

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu KOF Working Papers

On the Accuracy of the Probability Method for Quantifying Beliefs about Inflation

Thomas Maag

No. 230 July 2009 ETH Zurich KOF Swiss Economic Institute WEH D 4 Weinbergstrasse 35 8092 Zurich Switzerland

Phone +41 44 632 42 39 Fax +41 44 632 12 18 www.kof.ethz.ch [email protected] On the Accuracy of the Probability Method for Quantifying Beliefs About Inflation∗

Thomas Maag†

KOF Working Paper No. 230, July 2009 This Version: April 2010

Abstract

This paper assesses the probability method for quantifying EU consumer survey data on perceived and expected inflation. Based on household level data from the Swedish consumer survey that asks for both qualitative and quantitative responses, it is found that the theoretical assumptions of the method do not hold. In particular, estimates of unrestricted response schemes indicate that response intervals are asymmetric and that qualitative inflation expectations are formed relative to perceptions of current inflation. Nevertheless, the probability method generates series that are highly correlated with the mean of actual quantitative beliefs. For quantifying the cross-sectional dispersion of beliefs, however, an index of qualitative variation is most accurate.

JEL classification: C53, D84, E31. Keywords: quantification, inflation expectations, inflation perceptions, qualitative response data, belief formation.

∗I thank Simone Elmer, Sarah M. Lein, Christoph Moser, Rolf Schenker and seminar participants at the KOF Swiss Economic Institute for helpful comments and suggestions. I am grateful to the Swedish National Institute of Economic Research for providing access to the Consumer Tendency Survey data. Financial support by the Swiss National Science Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. †KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich, CH-8092 Zurich, Switzerland, E-mail: [email protected]

1 1 Introduction

Surveys of households and firms are often qualitative. Rather than giving a quantitative estimate of a particular variable, respondents are asked to indicate their beliefs on qualitative scales. In the European Union (EU), beliefs of households about inflation are surveyed as part of the Joint Harmonized EU Consumer Survey programme. Within this framework, har- monized qualitative surveys are conducted in all member states, covering a national sample size of roughly 1,500 households on a monthly basis. The EU consumer survey thus provides an extensive and consistent dataset on beliefs about inflation.1 In particular, the EU con- sumer survey both asks for perceptions about current inflation and expectations about future inflation. Consequently, the response data has been investigated by a large literature. Only recently, the euro cash changeover and its effects on inflation perceptions of households has given rise to a new strand of research.2 Since the EU consumer survey is qualitative, most empirical applications rely on a method to quantify the qualitative response data in the first place. This paper assesses the validity of one particular method, the probability method for 5-category scales, and compares its accuracy to other quantification approaches. Possibly the most widely used quantification method is the balance statistic proposed by Anderson (1952). It is originally defined as the difference between the share of respondents that perceive or expect positive inflation rates and the share of respondents that perceive or expect negative inflation rates. Theil (1952) rationalizes the balance statistic, demonstrating that it is an appropriate measure of the population mean if quantitative beliefs are uniformly distributed. Furthermore, Theil (1952) suggests that the distributional assumption may be relaxed by imposing a instead. Combined with the assumption that re- spondents perceive or expect prices to be constant in qualitative terms if their quantitative

1Currently, the Joint Harmonized EU Consumer Survey covers a monthly sample of roughly 40,000 con- sumers in 27 member states. The consumer survey consists of 15 qualitative questions pertaining to the household’s financial situation, perceived economic conditions and planned savings and spending. The ques- tionnaire is translated into national languages and may include additional country specific questions, see European Commission (2007). 2This literature centers on the rise in perceived inflation coinciding with the euro cash changeover, as doc- umented in ECB (2005). Several explanations are being discussed, including increased information processing requirements due to conversion rates, overreaction to prices of frequently bought items and anchoring of per- ceptions to prior expectations. See, e.g., Ehrmann (2006), Aucremanne, Collin, and Stragier (2007), Doehring and Mordonu (2007), Dziuda and Mastrobuoni (2006), Aalto-Set¨al¨a(2006) and Fluch and Stix (2007). Ab- stracting from the euro cash changeover, other contributions use the EU consumer survey data to investigate belief formation in general, see, e.g., D¨opke, Dovern, Fritsche, and Slacalek (2008), Forsells and Kenny (2004), Lamla and Lein (2008) and Lein and Maag (2008).

2 belief is within an indifference interval around 0%, the mean and of the imposed distribution can be identified. The model of Theil (1952) has been rediscovered by Carl- son and Parkin (1975) and is known today as the Carlson-Parkin method or the 3-category probability method.3 Batchelor and Orr (1988) extend the probability method to response data on 5-category scales as it is available from the EU consumer survey. Taking into ac- count the particular wording of the EU consumer survey, Berk (1999) additionally suggests an identification scheme that links inflation expectations to inflation perceptions. The goal of this paper is to assesses the 5-category probability method and to derive lessons for applied research. The analysis relies on joining qualitative and quantitative response data on household-level, taken from the Swedish Consumer Tendency Survey. To the best of my knowledge, only two studies have investigated surveys that ask for both qualitative and quantitative responses. Defris and Williams (1979) consider a 5-year sample from an Australian consumer survey. They document that the balance statistic as well as the 3- category probability method generate series that are only weakly correlated with quantitative survey responses. Batchelor (1986) investigates micro-data from the University of Michigan Survey of Consumers. In line with Defris and Williams (1979), Batchelor (1986) finds that both the balance statistic and quantified expectations generated with the probability method are inaccurate, in particular in the short term. This result is in contrast to my findings for Sweden. This paper extends the literature in several respects. First, it provides a detailed as- sessment of the theoretical assumptions underlying the 5-category probability method. Ex- isting research focuses on the 3-category probability method and on testing distributional assumptions. Joining quantitative and qualitative responses on household-level allows to es- timate unrestricted response schemes. The restrictions imposed by the 5-category probability method can then be tested using likelihood theory. Second, the accuracy of the 5-category probability method relative to the mean and cross-sectional of quantitative responses is assessed in a long sample of 154 monthly surveys spanning 01/1996–10/2008. The discussion centers on comparing correlation coefficients relying on the Fisher z-transformation and double block bootstrap confidence intervals. Accuracy is compared to a set of alternative

3A less common quantification method is the regression approach of Pesaran (1987). The regression method extends the balance statistic, allowing for a non-linear relation between response shares and quantitative beliefs. The method is outlined in Section 4. Pesaran (1987) discusses the three-category probability method and the regression approach in detail. Nardo (2003) provides a recent survey of quantification methods.

3 quantification methods, including the 3-category probability method, the balance statistic and the regression approach. For quantifying the cross-sectional heterogeneity of beliefs, the set of alternatives includes the 3-category probability method, an index of qualitative variation, an index of ordinal variation and the disconformity index. Third, the probability method is assessed for quantifying both perceptions and expectations of inflation. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the data and highlights important statistical properties. Section 3 assesses the assumptions of the 5-category probability method. Section 4 investigates the accuracy of the method and contrasts it with alternative approaches. Section 5 draws lessons for applied research. Section 6 concludes.

2 Data

Inflation opinions of Swedish households are being surveyed on a monthly basis since 1973. This paper uses monthly household-level response data which is available for the period 01/1996–10/2008.4 Unlike most surveys in other countries, the Swedish Consumer Tendency Survey jointly asks for qualitative and quantitative beliefs about inflation. The questionnaire captures beliefs in two steps.5 In a first step, households are asked to report perceived inflation on a five-category ordinal scale. This qualitative question is in line with the questionnaire of the Joint Harmonized EU Consumer Survey. The question reads:

“Compared with 12 months ago, do you find that prices in general are. . . ?” “Lower

(S1), about the same (S2), a little higher (S3), somewhat higher (S4), a lot higher (S5), don’t know”.

In the following, S1 through S5 denote the qualitative response categories and s1 through s5 are the fractions of households that opt for the respective category.6 In a second step, house- holds are asked for a direct quantitative estimate of the current annual inflation rate. The question reads: “How much higher/lower in percent do you think prices are now? (In other

4During this period, the survey comprises a monthly sample of roughly 1,500 households which are inter- viewed by telephone. The sample horizon is limited by data availability. Before 1996, qualitative responses were only recorded on a 3-option ordinal scale and quantitative beliefs were only surveyed on a quarterly basis. 5The exact procedure is outlined in the GfK (2002) survey manual. A schematic of the questioning can be found in Palmqvist and Str¨omberg (2004). Note that the English description of the response categories provided by GfK (2002) differs from the official terminology in European Commission (2007). In particular, European Commission (2007) labels the category S4 in the question on perceived inflation “moderately higher”. 6 Response shares are computed excluding the “don’t know” category, i.e. s1 through s5 sum up to 100%.

4 words, the present rate of inflation)”. As a result and in contrast to the Joint Harmonized EU Consumer Survey, households report both qualitative and quantitative beliefs about inflation. In a similar manner, expected inflation is captured in a first step by asking:

“Compared to the situation today, do you think that in the next 12 months prices in

general will. . . ?” “Go down a little (S1), stay more or less the same (S2), go up more

slowly (S3), go up at the same rate (S4), go up faster (S5), don’t know”.

In a second step, quantitative beliefs are captured by asking: “Compared with today, how much in percent do you think prices will go up/down? (In other words, inflation/deflation 12 months from now)”. In line with the literature, the quantitative response data is adjusted for outliers. Responses outside the interval [−30%, 30%] are omitted which reduces the sample size by 0.3%.7 More- over, only observations that contain non-missing responses to the qualitative and quantitative questions are considered. Regarding inflation perceptions, 13% of observations only include a qualitative but no quantitative response. Regarding inflation expectations, 15% of observa- tions only include a qualitative but no quantitative response. As will be discussed in the next section, a theoretical assumption of quantification methods is that households form quantita- tive beliefs. The high shares of missing quantitative responses can therefore be considered as evidence against this assumption. However, an alternative interpretation is that qualitative responses with missing quantitative responses are uninformed and should be attributed to the “don’t know” category.8 As Table 1 shows, the resulting sample includes almost 200,000 observations from 154 monthly surveys spanning 01/1996–10/2008. Throughout this paper, the discussion centers on this sample. The appendix additionally presents results for a shorter sample covering 01/2002–10/2008. I consider this subsample to account for a potential structural break due to a change in the surveying institution in 01/2002. As will be shown, results for both

7Over the entire sample period, 667 (443) observations contain quantitative inflation perceptions (expecta- tions) that are outliers. 8This view is supported by the distribution of missing quantitative answers by qualitative response category. For inflation perceptions, about 70% of missing quantitative answers are accounted for by respondents that opt for the qualitative category S3 (“a little higher”). For inflation expectations, 40% of missing quantita- tive answers are accounted for by respondents that opt for the qualitative category S4 (“go up at the same rate”). Note that 1.3% (2.2%) of all observations only contain a quantitative but no qualitative perception (expectation).

5 Table 1: Summary statistics for quantitative responses

Perceptions Expectations Overall Min Max Overall Min Max Observations 197,487 1,031 1,456 192,845 961 1,417 Number of months 154 154 Mean 1.81 0.47 5.91 2.10 0.59 4.66 Median 0.00 0.00 5.00 1.00 0.00 4.00 Standard deviation 4.06 2.68 5.37 3.73 2.68 4.94 Share of integer answers 0.94 0.86 0.98 0.92 0.82 0.98 Share of focal point answers 0.81 0.50 0.92 0.72 0.56 0.86 Share of zero responses 0.59 0.08 0.80 0.44 0.12 0.70 Mean response, given S1 -4.79 -20.00 -2.12 -3.89 -6.36 -2.53 Mean response, given S2 0.03 -0.05 0.46 0.02 -0.03 0.24 Mean response, given S3 4.72 3.98 5.95 4.06 3.04 5.55 Mean response, given S4 7.94 5.22 10.72 4.77 3.91 6.06 Mean response, given S5 9.58 4.25 16.00 3.98 3.12 6.14

Notes: The column overall presents results for the entire sample spanning 01/1996–10/2008. Min and Max are the monthly minimum and maximum of the respective statistic. All shares are relative to the overall number of observations. estimation periods are consistent, confirming the validity of the results for the full sample.9 As a measure of actual inflation I use the year-over-year percentage change in the Harmonized Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) as published by Eurostat.10 Figure 1a plots the cross-sectional mean of quantitative inflation perceptions, together with qualitative response shares and the actual inflation rate. The figure indicates that quantitative inflation perceptions closely track actual inflation. The correlation between the two series is 0.78. Moreover, the first panel of Table 1 shows that the overall mean of inflation perceptions is 1.81%, as opposed to an average HICP inflation rate of 1.61%. Hence, inflation perceptions of the Swedish public are roughly unbiased during 01/1996–10/2008. This finding is in line with earlier results of Jonung and Laidler (1988) for Sweden.11 Figure 1 further

9In 01/2002 the surveying institution has changed from Statistics Sweden to GfK Sweden. The change goes along with a decline in the share of missing quantitative responses. This might be partly due to differences in the questioning, as outlined by Palmqvist and Str¨omberg (2004). However, the share of missing observations rises again sharply in 2008 to levels before 2002. Hence, part of the initial decline in the share of missing quantitative responses appears to be coincidental. 10I have also considered the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and the Consumer Price Index excluding mortgage payments and indirect taxes (CPIX). Particularly at the beginning of the sample period, these indices might have obtained more attention by the Swedish public than the HICP. Employing these alternative indices does not alter the conclusions in qualitative terms. 11Inflation perceptions in Sweden seem relatively accurate compared to other countries. Relying on a monthly household survey conducted by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Bryan and Venkatu (2001a, 2001b) find that inflation perceptions (and expectations) exceed actual inflation by several percentage points. For the

6 indicates that inflation perceptions surge in 2008, exceeding actual inflation by roughly 2%.

Meanwhile, the share of qualitative responses in the lowest two categories S1 and S2 (“lower” and “about the same”) sharply declines. Figure 1b shows the cross-sectional mean of inflation expectations. Again, inflation ex- pectations exhibit pronounced comovement with actual inflation, the correlation between the two series being 0.70. Predictive power is relatively low, as the correlation with 12 months ahead inflation is only 0.28. Table 1 documents that inflation expectations average somewhat higher than perceptions at 2.05%. Moreover, the figures reveal a systematic difference be- tween qualitative perceptions and expectations of inflation. Qualitative inflation perceptions are concentrated in categories S2 and S3 (“about the same” and “a little higher”). During 1996–2008, 87% of respondents opt for these categories. In contrast, 70% of qualitative in-

flation expectations fall into categories S2 and S5 (“stay more or less the same” and “go up faster”). Table 1 highlights important properties of the quantitative response data. First, panel 1 shows that beliefs about inflation are highly heterogeneous. Despite the low cross-sectional means, inflation perceptions and expectations exhibit cross-sectional standard deviations of 4.06% and 3.73%, respectively. Second, panel 2 indicates that more than 90% of all quanti- tative answers are integers. Third, integer answers are concentrated at a few focal points.12 Both for perceptions and expectations, the most frequently mentioned focal points are -5%, -2%, 0%, 2%, 5%, 10%.13 As Table 1 indicates, the most important focal point is 0%, which accounts for more than half of all focal point responses. Towards the end of the sample period, the share of zero responses declines significantly. It attains a minimum of 8% for perceptions and 12% for expectations in 06/2008. The high share of zero responses also explains the low medians of quantitative beliefs. Fourth, the cross-sectional mean of quantitative inflation perceptions is generally rising in the qualitative response category. This is shown in panel 3 which summarizes the conditional means of quantitative responses depending on the quali- tative response. As opposed to inflation perceptions, qualitative inflation expectations are not ordered. For expectations, the mean response given S4 (“go up at the same rate”) is

U.K., Driver and Windram (2007) report a correlation of perceived inflation with actual inflation of roughly 0.5 in a similar sample period. 12In line with Bryan and Palmqvist (2006), focal points are defined as integers that are mentioned more often than their neighboring integers. I have not found any evidence for important non-integer focal points. 13Of the remaining integers, 1, 3 and 4 obtain the highest response shares. This set accounts for 9% of quantitative inflation perceptions and for 15% of expectations.

7 Notes: iesostecmltv hr fasesi categories in answers of share cumulative the shows line h oetge iesosteshare the shows line grey lowest The iue1 ulttv epnesae n enqatttv response quantitative mean and shares response Qualitative 1: Figure

Cumulative share Cumulative share

1996m1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 1996m1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 1998m1 1998m1 HICP inflationrate(rhs) Mean quantitativeresponse(rhs) Qualitative responseshares(s1lowest,s5highest) HICP inflationrate(rhs) Mean quantitativeresponse(rhs) Qualitative responseshares(s1lowest,s5highest) 2000m1 2000m1 s b Expectations (b) 1 a Perceptions (a) fqaiaieasesi category in answers qualitative of 2002m1 2002m1 8 S 1 2004m1 2004m1 and S 2 etc. , 2006m1 2006m1 2008m1 2008m1 S 1 h eodlws grey second-lowest the , 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 % % higher than the mean response given S5 (“go up faster”). Also, in comparison to inflation perceptions, the differences between the cross-sectional means given qualitative responses S3, 14 S4 and S5 are only minor. Fifth, the relation between quantitative and qualitative responses is time varying. The differences between overall, minimum and maximum conditional means are considerable for most categories. The only exception is S2 (“about the same”): Given this qualitative response, the mean quantitative response is always close to 0%. These initial results suggest that the relation between quantitative and qualitative beliefs about inflation is complex. The response scheme, i.e. the formal relation between quan- titative and qualitative responses, appears to be time varying. Moreover, the conditional mean of quantitative expectations is not monotonously rising in the order of the qualitative response categories. While the 5-category probability method allows for a time varying re- sponse scheme, it imposes a certain symmetry on the response scheme and requires ordered qualitative data. Regarding the distributional assumptions, the mean and median values in- dicate that quantitative beliefs are positively skewed and therefore not normally distributed. The concentration of answers at focal points, in particular at 0%, raises additional doubt whether any of the common parametric distributions adequately describes the quantitative response data. The next section thus discusses in detail whether the assumptions of the probability method are consistent with the data.

3 Validity of the Probability Method

3.1 Theoretical Assumptions

This section tests the main theoretical assumptions of the 5-category probability method for quantifying qualitative response data. Building on contributions of Theil (1952) and Carlson and Parkin (1975), the 5-category probability method has been proposed by Batchelor and Orr (1988). To begin with, the method is briefly outlined. Assume that previous to answering the consumer survey, respondent i forms a quantitative e 15 belief πt,i about inflation over the upcoming 12 months. Respondent i then answers the

14On a monthly basis, the mean of inflation perceptions is not always strictly rising too. This is indicated by the minima of monthly conditional means in panel 3 of Table 1. But the conditional means lack order only in 27 months, as opposed to 136 months for inflation expectations. 15 p The analogous approach for quantifying perceived inflation πt,i and detailed derivations can be found in Appendix A.1.

9 qualitative survey question on expected inflation according to the following response scheme:

e − πt,i < δt : prices in general will go down a little (S1) − ≤ e δt πt,i < δt : stay more or less the same (S2) ≤ e r − δt πt,i < πt ηt : go up more slowly (S3) r − ≤ e r πt ηt πt,i < πt + ηt : go up at the same rate (S4) e ≥ r πt,i πt + ηt : go up faster (S5) (1)

r r The response scheme is defined by the parameters δt, ηt and πt . In the following, πt is referred to as reference inflation. It is the inflation rate that people have in mind when opting

for answer S4 (“prices will go up at the same rate” and, for inflation perceptions, “prices are moderately higher”). The first key assumption of the probability method restricts the response scheme to be fully defined by these three parameters:

Assumption 1: r The response intervals are symmetric around 0% and around πt .

− r − r The corresponding intervals [ δt, δt) and [πt ηt, πt + ηt) correspond to qualitative responses

S2 and S4 respectively. A second assumption imposes structural homogeneity on the response scheme:

Assumption 2: r Threshold parameters δt and ηt and the reference inflation πt are identical across respondents.

e Quantitative inflation expectations πt,i will vary across respondents due to differences in information sets and information processing. To infer the mean quantitative inflation ex- pectation from qualitative response shares, the probability method imposes a distributional e assumption on πt,i. The standard assumption is that the cross-sectional distribution of quan- titative beliefs is normal:

Assumption 3: e ∼ The cross-sectional distribution of quantitative beliefs is normal, i.e. πt,i e e 2 N(πt , (σt ) ).

e e The parameters of interest are the cross-sectional mean πt and standard deviation σt of quantitative beliefs. As outlined in Appendix A.1, the above assumptions yield a system of e e r 4 linearly independent equations with 5 unknowns (πt σt , δt, ηt, πt ) which can be solved for e e r πt and σt . The solution for both parameters is equal to the product of reference inflation πt 1 5 and a function of the response shares st , ..., st .

10 r The usual identification scheme restricts reference inflation πt . For quantifying inflation r expectations two choices of πt are apparent. First, reference inflation can be set equal to some actual rate of inflation, assuming that the respondent knows the actual rate of inflation and answers the question relative to this value. Second, reference inflation can be set equal p to previously quantified perceived inflation πt as suggested by Berk (1999). This approach is supported by empirical evidence that households are not necessarily well informed about 16 r actual inflation. Identifying πt is less obvious for inflation perceptions. Following Carlson and Parkin (1975) it is commonly assumed that inflation perceptions are unbiased over the r 17 sample horizon. This assumption can be imposed by restricting πt to a constant accordingly. The last assumption thus reads:

Assumption 4: r The reference rate of inflation πt for quantifying inflation expectations is equal to actual inflation or quantified perceived inflation. The reference rate of inflation for quantifying inflation perceptions is time invariant.

3.2 Symmetry of the Response Scheme

r Assumption 1 restricts response intervals to be symmetric around 0% and around πt . To test the validity of this assumption I estimate an unrestricted response scheme defined by 4 threshold parameters. Assume that respondent i answers the qualitative question according to the following scheme:18

e 1 πt,i + εt,i < µt : prices in general will go down a little (S1) 1 ≤ e 2 µt πt,i + εt,i < µt : stay more or less the same (S2) 2 ≤ e 3 µt πt,i + εt,i < µt : go up more slowly (S3) 3 ≤ e 4 µt πt,i + εt,i < µt : go up at the same rate (S4) e ≥ 4 πt,i + εt,i µt : go up faster (S5) (2)

The idiosyncratic component εt,i allows the response scheme to shift between individuals. Under the assumption that the idiosyncratic component represents the sum of independent idiosyncratic factors it is reasonable to assume that εt,i is normally distributed. One thus

16See, e.g., Bryan and Venkatu (2001a, 2001b) who document that inflation perceptions of U.S. households are significantly biased. 17 r The solution for πt is given by Equation (A.7) in the Appendix. 18 e p The identical scheme applies to inflation perceptions, with πt,i being replaced by πt,i.

11 obtains an ordered probit model (Zavoina and McKelvey, 1975). In contrast to the usual e identification scheme, I restrict the coefficient on the quantitative belief πt,i to unity, whereas ∼ 2 the variance of εt,i remains unrestricted. Assuming that εt,i N(0, σt ), the following proba- bilities are obtained:

( ) −πe + µ1 | e t,i t P (S1 πt,i, µt, σt) = Φ σt ( ) ( ) −πe + µ2 −πe + µ1 | e t,i t − t,i t P (S2 πt,i, µt, σt) = Φ Φ σt σt ( ) ( ) −πe + µ3 −πe + µ2 | e t,i t − t,i t P (S3 πt,i, µt, σt) = Φ Φ σt σt ( ) ( ) −πe + µ4 −πe + µ3 | e t,i t − t,i t P (S4 πt,i, µt, σt) = Φ Φ σt σt ( ) −πe + µ4 | e − t,i t P (S5 πt,i, µt, σt) = 1 Φ σt

{ 1 4} 1 2 where µt = µt , ..., µt . Deviating from the assumptions of the probability method, µt , µt 3 4 and µt , µt are not required to be symmetric around 0% and the reference rate of inflation, respectively. Table 2 presents the maximum likelihood estimation results of the unrestricted response scheme. By construction, the threshold parameters are rising in the qualitative response category. The model is confirmed by highly significant parameter estimates which are stable 1 2 across subperiods. The width of the interval [µt , µt ) corresponding to qualitative response

S2 (“about the same”) exceeds 8% both for perceptions and expectations. The estimated parameters suggest that this interval is not symmetric around 0%. Relying on maximum 1 − 2 19 likelihood theory, I test the restriction that µt = µt with a likelihood ratio test. The second panel of Table 2 shows that this test clearly rejects the null hypothesis of symmetry. The estimates point to systematic differences between perceptions and expectations. While 1 − the threshold parameters for inflation perceptions are increasing from µt = 6.91% to 4 1 − µt = 13.89%, the thresholds for inflation expectations between µt = 7.04% and 4 µt = 5.61%. For inflation expectations, the threshold parameters that define the response

19 2 The test statistic is given by LR = −2 (logLr − logLi) → χ (q), where logLr is the log likelihood of the restricted model and logLi is the log likelihood of the unrestricted model. The number of restrictions is given by q = 1.

12 Table 2: Estimated response schemes for perceived and expected inflation

1996–2008 2002–2008 Perceptions Expectations Perceptions Expectations 1 µt -6.909*** -7.404*** -7.595*** -7.883*** (0.0300) (0.0367) (0.0457) (0.0556) 2 µt 3.194*** 1.739*** 2.526*** 0.617*** (0.0138) (0.0141) (0.0188) (0.0230) 3 µt 10.95*** 2.797*** 10.97*** 2.005*** (0.0267) (0.0141) (0.0362) (0.0212) 4 µt 13.89*** 5.609*** 14.04*** 5.682*** (0.0388) (0.0174) (0.0520) (0.0251) σt 3.782*** 4.427*** 4.260*** 5.083*** (0.0118) (0.0163) (0.0181) (0.0270)

N 197,487 192,845 110,071 109,782 Log L -138,263 -220,521 -88,738 -136,562 Likelihood ratio tests 1 2 − 1 H0 : Symmetry such that µt = µt (q = 1) LR statistic 20,978.94 35,749.40 17,427.61 25,138.60 P-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Notes: This table shows maximum likelihood estimates of the unrestricted response scheme (2). Monthly data, 01/1996–10/2008 and 01/2002–10/2008. N is the number of observations, log L is the log likelihood, standard errors in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

intervals for S3, S4, S5 are in a narrow range of 4 to 5 percent. This allows for two inter- pretations: Either, the response intervals are indeed narrower for inflation expectations than for inflation perceptions, or the ordered model does not adequately describe the formation of qualitative inflation expectations. The second interpretation is suggested by the lack of order in conditional means documented in Section 2. The unordered nature of qualitative responses seems to be caused by the relative wording of the response categories. The quali- tative response S4 (“prices will go up at the same rate”) anchors the qualitative expectation to the perception of current inflation. A respondent who gives consistent answers will always opt for qualitative response S4 if the quantitative expectation corresponds to the subjective quantitative perception of inflation, irrespective of the level of expected inflation. The second interpretation is also supported by the substantially lower log likelihood of the model for expectations, despite the lower number of observations. e I therefore estimate a scheme for positive inflation expectations πt,i that accounts for the p role of quantitative inflation perceptions πt,i at the household-level:

13 Table 3: Estimated relative response schemes for expected inflation

Expectations Income groups (1st quartile lowest) 1st quartile 2nd quartile 3rd quartile 4th quartile Overall 1 µt -7.172*** -6.014*** -5.056*** -3.928*** -5.316*** (0.184) (0.116) (0.0569) (0.0132) (0.0500) 2 µt 1.322*** 1.059*** 0.805*** 0.575*** 0.814*** (0.0839) (0.0550) (0.0445) (0.0104) (0.0242) σt 6.212*** 4.956*** 4.056*** 3.182*** 4.369*** (0.139) (0.0826) (0.0062) (0.0039) (0.0347)

N 10,046 15,133 15,584 19,618 60,381 Log L -8,759 -12,591 -12,436 -14,921 -49,217 Likelihood ratio tests LR statistic P-value 1 1 2 H0 : Identical threshold parameters µt , µt (q = 6) 746.60 0.00 2 H0 : Identical standard deviation σt (q = 3) 907.96 0.00 3 H0 : Identical thresholds and standard deviation (q = 9) 1,020.93 0.00

Notes: This table shows maximum likelihood estimates of the relative response scheme (3). Monthly data, 01/2002–10/2008. Standard errors in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

e p 1 πt,i + εt,i < πt,i + µt : prices in general will go up more slowly (S3) p 1 ≤ e p 2 πt,i + µt πt,i + εt,i < πt,i + µt : go up at the same rate (S4) e ≥ p 2 πt,i + εt,i πt,i + µt : go up faster (S5) (3)

∼ 2 e − p where εt,i N(0, σt ). This scheme assumes that the respondent will opt for S4 if πt,i πt,i 1 2 lies in the range [µt , µt ). Maximum likelihood estimation results can be found in the last column of Table 3. All parameters are highly significant, confirming that the qualitative response about expected inflation is linked to the quantitative inflation perception. Moreover, the response interval is highly asymmetric: Qualitative answers are more responsive to an increase of quantitative expectations over perceptions than to a decrease. The significance of the relative response scheme suggests that despite the lack of an unambiguous relation between quantitative and qualitative expectations, the 5-category survey contains more information

than a 3-category survey that does not distinguish between S3, S4 and S5. In sum, the results indicate that Assumption 1 is not satisfied. Under the normality assumption, the estimated response interval is not symmetric around 0%, both for inflation

14 perceptions and expectations.20 Furthermore, the response interval is not symmetric around r πt for inflation expectations. The estimations confirm that qualitative inflation expectations are formed relative to perceived inflation. This result suggests that the link between expec- tations and perceptions should be exploited in quantifying qualitative responses.

3.3 Homogeneity of the Response Scheme

r Assumption 2 imposes that threshold parameters δt and ηt and reference inflation πt are ho- mogeneous across respondents. Since the Swedish dataset only contains one observation per individual, this assumption is tested by estimating the response scheme for different income groups.21 Tables 4 and 5 summarize the estimation results for perceptions and expectations, respectively. The tables show that the absolute values of threshold parameters tend to decline in income. The lower panel of Tables 4 and 5 show likelihood ratio tests of three restrictions. 1 The null hypotheses state that threshold parameters are identical across income groups (H0 ), 2 that standard deviations are identical across income groups (H0 ) and that threshold param- 3 eters and standard deviations are identical across income groups (H0 ). All three hypotheses are clearly rejected. Table 3 presents estimation results for the relative response scheme (3) that links expected inflation to perceived inflation. Again, all three hypotheses are clearly rejected. The estimates show the same pattern as above: The absolute values of threshold parameters are declining in income. Overall, these results suggest that the response scheme systematically differs across income-groups, which implies that Assumption 2 is violated.22

20This finding is consistent with Henzel and Wollmersh¨auser(2005) who investigate data from a special edition of the ifo World Economic Survey that directly asks respondents to indicate the indifference interval. Henzel and Wollmersh¨auser(2005) report that the positive threshold parameter is larger in absolute terms than the negative parameter. As opposed to the Swedish survey, however, the ifo survey queries professional forecasters and answers are given on a 3-category ordinal scale. 21I have also considered educational groups, with unchanged qualitative results. 22Note that the mean of beliefs about inflation also depends on socioeconomic characteristics. The cross- sectional means of perceptions and expectations are declining in income. This pattern is consistent with the estimated response schemes that suggest that individuals in the highest income quartile experience deviations of inflation from zero as more relevant in qualitative terms than individuals in lower income quartiles.

15 Table 4: Estimated response schemes for perceived inflation by income groups

Perceptions Income groups (1st quartile lowest) 1st quartile 2nd quartile 3rd quartile 4th quartile Overall 1 µt -9.074*** -8.201*** -6.657*** -5.833*** -7.308*** (0.142) (0.105) (0.0821) (0.0627) (0.0459) 2 µt 2.411*** 2.487*** 2.405*** 2.366*** 2.479*** (0.0571) (0.0429) (0.0352) (0.0271) (0.0192) 3 µt 11.55*** 11.68*** 10.63*** 9.405*** 10.79*** (0.100) (0.0824) (0.0704) (0.0541) (0.0372) 4 µt 14.60*** 15.07*** 13.53*** 12.16*** 13.77*** (0.136) (0.119) (0.104) (0.0836) (0.0535) σt 5.232*** 4.682*** 3.759*** 3.179*** 4.120*** (0.0583) (0.0425) (0.0326) (0.0238) (0.0183)

N 17,092 24,845 25,482 32,614 100,033 Log L -15,584 -20,718 -19,346 -23,163 -79,851 Likelihood ratio tests LR statistic P-value 1 1 4 H0 : Identical threshold parameters µt ,...,µt (q = 12) 1,868.21 0.00 2 H0 : Identical standard deviation σt (q = 3) 1,115.68 0.00 3 H0 : Identical thresholds and standard deviation (q = 15) 2,080.00 0.00

Notes: This table shows maximum likelihood estimates of the unrestricted response scheme (2). Monthly data, 01/2002–10/2008. Standard errors in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

16 Table 5: Estimated response schemes for expected inflation by income groups

Expectations Income groups (1st quartile lowest) 1st quartile 2nd quartile 3rd quartile 4th quartile Overall 1 µt -9.229*** -8.303*** -7.031*** -5.968*** -7.598*** (0.165) (0.124) (0.102) (0.0747) (0.0561) 2 µt 0.703*** 0.440*** 0.591*** 0.783*** 0.600*** (0.0686) (0.0527) (0.0429) (0.0315) (0.0233) 3 µt 2.452*** 1.972*** 1.816*** 1.835*** 1.950*** (0.0633) (0.0480) (0.0394) (0.0294) (0.0215) 4 µt 7.075*** 6.164*** 5.136*** 4.407*** 5.502*** (0.0805) (0.0575) (0.0452) (0.0328) (0.0253) σt 6.089*** 5.448*** 4.488*** 3.789*** 4.905*** (0.0827) (0.0614) (0.0484) (0.0344) (0.0271)

N 17,232 24,757 25,384 32,528 99,901 Log L -21,816 -31,163 -31,206 -39,092 -124,179 Likelihood ratio tests LR statistic P-value 1 1 4 H0 : Identical threshold parameters µt ,...,µt (q = 12) 1,102.84 0.00 2 H0 : Identical standard deviation σt (q = 3) 1,689.36 0.00 3 H0 : Identical thresholds and standard deviation (q = 15) 1,804.00 0.00

Notes: This table shows maximum likelihood estimates of the unrestricted response scheme (2). Monthly data, 01/2002–10/2008. Standard errors in parentheses. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively.

17 3.4 Normality of Quantitative Responses

Assumption 3 requires that the cross-sectional distribution of quantitative beliefs is normal. Normality has been tested and rejected for inflation expectations of consumers (Batchelor and Dua, 1987) and professional forecasters (Carlson, 1975, Lahiri and Teigland, 1987). These studies generally find that quantitative beliefs are positively skewed and leptokurtic. Both patterns can also be found in the Swedish survey data, as panel 1 of Table 6 indicates. Beliefs about inflation exhibit a pronounced positive skewness and are leptokurtic. Consequently, the Jarque-Bera test rejects the null hypothesis of normality in every single survey month, as panel 2 of Table 6 shows. More generally, the probability method requires that beliefs follow some identifiable para- metric distribution. Lahiri and Teigland (1987) suggest a noncentral t distribution as an alternative to the normal distribution. The noncentral t distribution allows for positive skew- ness and fat tails. I formally test whether quantitative responses follow this distribution using the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test.23 Results are summarized in panel 3 of Table 6 and show that this null hypothesis is also rejected in all months. These formal tests do not answer the question which parametric distribution produces the best quantification results. The answer will also depend on the time period. During 1996–2007, the high share of zero responses cannot be reconciled with both the normal and noncentral t distributions. With the rise in perceptions and expectations of inflation in 2008, the shape of the empirical distribution becomes somewhat smoother and less skewed, as the share of zero responses declines. Overall, the results indicate that differences in the relative fit of common parametric distributions are predominated by the high share of zero responses. This conjecture is consistent with Berk (1999), Dasgupta and Lahiri (1992) and Smith and McAleer (1995) who find that the accuracy of the quantified series does not significantly vary between any of the common parametric distributions.

23 | − | The Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic is given by Dn(F ) = supx Fn(x) F (x) , where Fn(.) is the empirical distribution function. Note that the noncentral t distribution is equal to the t distribution if the noncentrality parameter µ is zero.

18 Table 6: Tests for the distribution of quantitative responses

Perceptions Expectations Overall Min Max Overall Min Max Skewness 4.04 0.05 8.50 3.64 -0.31 9.31 Kurtosis 40.51 9.96 117.20 43.96 10.85 151.95 Jarque-Bera test for normal distribution J-B statistic 6,099.24 771.61 22,361.00 5,837.78 543.04 27,213.38 P-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Kolmogorov-Smirnov test for noncentral t distribution K-S statistic 0.31 0.12 0.41 0.24 0.14 0.37 P-value 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 µ 0.51 0.10 4.00 0.74 0.20 2.70 df 1.02 1 3 1.01 1 2

Notes: Monthly data, 01/1996–10/2008. Overall denotes the mean of monthly statistics, Min and Max are the 2 monthly minimum and maximum of the respective statistic. The Jarque-Bera statistic is asymptotically χ2 distributed. The approximate 1% critical values for the Kolmogorov-Smirnov are given by 1.52N −0.5, where N is the number of observations. The noncentral t distribution is defined by the noncentrality parameter µ and the degrees of freedom df. The table shows the parameters that minimize the Kolmogorov-Smirnov statistic.

3.5 Defined Reference Rate of Inflation

r Assumption 4 requires that reference inflation πt is equal to some defined value. This as- sumption is required to identify the system of equations that is generated by Assumptions 1 to 3. As outlined above, for identifying perceived inflation it is typically assumed that ref- erence inflation is a constant such that perceptions are unbiased. To assess this assumption, Figure 2a shows the mean of quantitative inflation perceptions given by households that opt

for qualitative response S4. The conditional mean of perceptions is highly volatile with a standard deviation of 1.15%. It averages at 7.93% but shows a declining tendency over time. The assumption that the reference rate of inflation is constant over time is clearly at odds with this pattern. For expected inflation, reference inflation is commonly assumed to be equal to actual in- flation or to (previously quantified) perceived inflation. Figure 2b shows that the conditional mean of inflation expectations given qualitative answer S4 is less volatile, with a standard deviation of only 0.53%. The figure plots three alternative measures of reference inflation: The conditional mean of quantitative inflation perceptions of respondents that expect prices 24 to “go up at the same rate” (S4), quantified inflation perceptions and actual HICP inflation.

24Inflation perceptions are quantified using the 5-category probability method with the unbiasedness as- sumption.

19 Clearly, the conditional mean of inflation perceptions closely follows the conditional mean of inflation expectations. The correlation coefficient of the two series is 0.94, the average level difference only 0.39%. The similarity of these series is in line with the finding that qualitative expectations are formed relative to quantitative perceptions. In contrast, the correlations of the conditional mean with quantified inflation perceptions and actual inflation are -0.15 and 0.06, respectively. In both cases, the level difference is substantial. Consequently, the as- sumption that reference inflation corresponds to quantified or actual inflation can be rejected. However, the correlations of the conditional mean with quantified inflation perceptions and actual inflation increase to 0.46 and 0.41 during 2002–2008. Notably, a comovement of these measures of moderate inflation with the conditional mean is apparent towards the end of the sample period, when actual inflation substantially increases. Alternatively, Assumption 4 can be assessed based on the implied level of reference in- flation. The implied level of reference inflation is obtained by combining the cross-sectional mean of quantitative responses with Assumptions 1 to 3.25 Assessing this series amounts to a joint test of Assumptions 1 to 3. Figure 2a indicates that implied reference inflation fluctuates around a similar level as the conditional mean of inflation perceptions. However, the correlation between the two series is 0.06. For inflation expectations shown in Figure 2b, the implied reference inflation averages 2% below the conditional mean. The correlation of the two series is 0.31. Provided that the true reference rate of inflation is equal to the condi-

tional mean given qualitative answer S4, these results suggests that Assumptions 1 to 3 can be jointly rejected. In light of this finding, the next section assesses the joint validity of all 4 hypotheses in more detail.

3.6 Joint Assessment

While all four hypotheses can be individually rejected, this section investigates the joint validity of the assumptions. The focus does not lie on rejection/non-rejection but rather on the degree of overall validity. I proceed by quantifying the qualitative survey data with the 26 5-category probability method. This yields the threshold parameters δt and ηt which can

25 e Given the cross-sectional mean πt of quantitative inflation expectations, implied reference inflation can be obtained by rearranging Equation (A.3). 26Inflation perceptions are quantified by imposing the unbiasedness condition. For inflation expectations it is assumed that reference inflation is equal to quantified inflation perceptions. Detailed derivations are provided in Appendix A.1.

20 n unie nainpretosaedrvduigte5ctgr rbblt ehd o quantifying For method. probability 5-category the imposed. using is derived condition unbiasedness are the perceptions perceptions inflation quantified for opt and that respondents of answer perception qualitative for opt that respondents Notes: hsfiuesosatraiemaue of measures alternative shows figure This

% %

1996m1 0 2 4 6 8 1996m1 0 2 4 6 8 10 iue2 esrso eeec inflation reference of Measures 2: Figure 1998m1 1998m1 mle e.ifainHICPinflation Conditionalmeanperception Quantified perception Implied ref.inflation Mean responseS4 S 4 2000m1 2000m1 nteqeto bu xetdiflto.Ipidrfrneinflation reference Implied inflation. expected about question the in S 4 . b Expectations (b) a Perceptions (a) odtoa enperception mean Conditional π 2002m1 2002m1 t r HICP inflation Implied ref.inflation Mean responseS4 21 . enrsos S4 response Mean 2004m1 2004m1 2006m1 2006m1 stema uniaieble of belief quantitative mean the is stema uniaieinflation quantitative mean the is π t r 2008m1 2008m1 be used to construct the implied response scheme on a monthly basis. Figure 3 shows box plots of the distribution of monthly response shares. For each answer category, the fraction of quantitative beliefs that lie within the implied response interval (“quant.”) is compared to the actual share of qualitative responses (“N”).27 For inflation perceptions, Figure 3a signals pronounced deviations of implied from actual response fractions in categories S3 and S5. The high share of quantitative responses in the implied range of S5 is consistent with the previous finding that the distribution of responses is positively skewed and leptokurtic. Moreover, the low fraction of quantitative responses in the implied range of

S3 appears to be a direct consequence of fitting the normal distribution to the high share of zero responses. A similar pattern is obtained for inflation expectations. Figure 3b illustrates that the deviation of the implied from the actual response share is highest for categories S3, S4 and

S5. Similar to perceptions, the fraction of quantitative responses in the implied range of S5 exceeds the actual share of qualitative responses. This pattern also relates to the finding of the previous section, according to which the mean quantitative answer of respondents opting

for qualitative answer S4 is significantly higher than actual inflation or quantified inflation perceptions. Consequently, a large fraction of these quantitative answers fall into the interval

of the qualitative answer S5. Further insights can be gained by looking at the fraction of quantitative responses that lie below or above the implied response interval. Figure A.1 in the Appendix shows these fractions relative to the number of responses in the respective qualitative response category. Both for perceptions and expectations, the figure reveals that the 5-category probability method best accommodates qualitative answer S2. On average, 99% of quantitative responses associated with qualitative answer S2 lie within the implied response interval. S2 is the most important qualitative response, accounting for roughly 59% of perceptions and 42% of expectations during 1996–2008. Regarding inflation perceptions shown in Figure A.1a, coverage for the second most important category S3, which obtains 30% of responses, is lower. Only about 30% of quantitative responses are within the implied response interval. A relatively large share of quantitative responses lies below the implied response interval, indicating that the interval around 0% is too wide. The worst coverage results for S4, but only 4% of respondents

27Note that by construction, the actual share of qualitative responses corresponds to the predicted share of quantitative responses under the normality assumption.

22 opt for this qualitative category. The pattern is different for inflation expectations. Figure A.1b indicates that only about

10% of quantitative beliefs fall into the implied response intervals for S3 and S4. Most quantitative responses are above the implied interval. This can be explained by the high

share of on average 27% of responses in category S5. Fitting this share leads to a downward shift of the lower response intervals. Moreover, the previous section has shown that quantified perceptions are significantly lower than reference inflation πr. Hence, the implied response intervals linked to quantified perceptions will be too low. The above findings also hold in the 01/2002–10/2008 subperiod, as Figures A.2 and A.3 in the Appendix confirm. In sum, the results suggest that Assumptions 1 through 4 are invalid. This leads to significant distortions primarily concerning the incorporation of information from positive categories S3, S4, S5, which seem more pronounced for inflation expectations than for inflation perceptions. The next section assesses the implications for the accuracy of the probability method.

23 fmnhyfatosadcnan einln.Upr(oe)ajcn ausaegvnb h ihs value range. highest interquartile the the by of given 3/2 percentile are with +(-) values 75th percentile adjacent method and (lower) (25th) 25th probability Upper 75th the 5-category the between line. than the median range greater a the using contains covers not quantified and box fractions are Each monthly inflation. Expectations of reference unbiased as method inflation. probability perceptions HICP 5-category quantified the to ( using respect quantified responses are with qualitative Perceptions of 01/1996–10/2008. period share Sample actual the and Notes: hs grsso h rcino uniaieaseswti h mle epneitra ( interval response implied the within answers quantitative of fraction the show figures These

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 excludes outsidevalues excludes outsidevalues 1qat 2qat 3qat 4qat 5qat N S5quant. N S4quant. N S3quant. N S2quant. N S1 quant. N S5quant. N S4quant. N S3quant. N S2quant. N S1 quant. iue3 culadtertclrsos fractions response theoretical and Actual 3: Figure b Expectations (b) a Perceptions (a) N ). S1 24 through S5 r h ulttv epnecategories. response qualitative the are quant. ) 4 Accuracy of the Probability Method

4.1 Level and Dynamics of Beliefs

This section assesses the accuracy of the 5-category probability method relative to the mean of actual quantitative survey responses. Perceptions and expectations of inflation are quantified by imposing the usual restrictions. Inflation perceptions are assumed to be unbiased with respect to HICP inflation. Inflation expectations are quantified by setting reference infla- tion equal to HICP inflation and alternatively, following Berk (1999), to quantified perceived inflation.28 The 5-category probability method is compared to a set of alternative quantifi- cation methods. The first alternative is the 3-category probability method of Carlson and Parkin (1975).29 The second alternative is the scaled balance statistic with mean and vari- ance of actual inflation. In line with the literature, the 5-category balance statistic is given by − − − p − n s5 + 0.5s4 0.5s2 s1. The 3-category balance statistic is given by s5 + s4 + s3 s1 = st st , p n where st and st are the fractions of respondents that report that prices are rising and falling, respectively. The third alternative is the Pesaran (1987) regression approach for 3-category response data.30 The primary measure of accuracy I consider is the (Pearson) correlation coefficient between the quantified series and the cross-sectional mean of quantitative responses. As opposed to the mean absolute error (MAE) or root mean squared error (RMSE), the correlation coefficient is robust to a constant scaling of the involved series. In particular, the correlation coefficient is unaffected by the average level of reference inflation πr. Another advantage of employing the correlation coefficient is that its distributional properties have been explored. The Fisher z-transformation of the correlation coefficient results in an approximately normal random variable, provided the underlying data follows a bivariate normal distribution. Relying on the Fisher z-transformation, the null hypothesis that two correlation coefficients are equal

28Perceived inflation is quantified using the 5-category probability method under the assumption of unbi- asedness with respect to HICP inflation. 29Answer categories are aggregated following Berk (1999), see Appendix A.2 for details. 30Unlike the early regression approaches suggested by Theil (1952) and Anderson (1952), the Pesaran (1987) approach allows for asymmetric response behavior in periods of rising and falling inflation. The Pesaran p− n β1st β2st approach is based on nonlinear least squares estimation of the model πt = − p + εt, where πt denotes 1 β3st actual HICP inflation. Expected inflation is generated in a second step as a prediction of this model based on answering fractions about inflation expectations (where coefficient estimates are obtained in the first step using perceptions data). A measure of perceived inflation is computed as the prediction of the model using the perceptions data it has been estimated with.

25 (ρ1 = ρ2) can be tested using the following statistic:

−1 −1 z = tanh (ρ1) − tanh (ρ2) (4) ( ) where tanh−1(ρ ) = 0.5ln 1+ρi . The z statistic is approximately normal with variance i 1−ρi 1 + 1 , where T and T are the sample sizes underlying correlation coefficients ρ and T1−3 T2−3 1 2 1

ρ2, respectively. However, the normal approximation may be inaccurate in the present case because |ρi| is high and the underlying series are serially dependent (Mudholkar, 2006). I therefore assess significance based on double block bootstrap confidence intervals for the z statistic.31 Table 7 summarizes the results. The underlying series are plotted in Figures A.4 and A.5 in the Appendix. All statistics are provided for levels and first differences. The last column in each panel shows the Fisher z statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the difference between the correlation coefficient in the first row of each panel (ρ1) and the correlation coeffi- cient in the respective row (ρ2) is zero. Since the quantified series and the mean quantitative beliefs are highly persistent, the discussion focuses on results for first differences.32 These results are not subject to spurious regression problems as the first differences are stationary. However, the results on the significance of correlation are mostly consistent for levels and first differences. Panel 1 of Table 7 indicates that in terms of correlation with the mean of quantitative perceptions, all quantification methods perform well. The correlation in first differences is 0.86 for the series generated with the 5-category probability method. The 3-category probability method generates virtually identical results. Interestingly, the 5-category and 3-category balance statistics are more accurate, with correlation coefficients of 0.91 and 0.89, respectively. The z-statistic indicates that the correlation coefficient for the 5-category balance statistic is significantly higher than the correlation coefficient for the 5-category probability method. Regarding expectations, panel 2 of Table 7 shows that the accuracy of the 5-category probability method depends on the imposed reference inflation. Employing quantified per-

31Matlab codes are available from the author. The double moving block bootstrap of the percentile confidence interval is based on 1,000 first level replications and 2,500 second level replications and a block size of 5. See Efron and Tibshirani (1993) for a description of the method. 32Employing an Augmented Dickey-Fuller test the null hypothesis of a unit root cannot be rejected on the 10% level for all actual and quantified mean series.

26 Table 7: Accuracy of quantified inflation perceptions and expectations

Perceptions Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z P.HICP (5 cat.) -0.17 0.22 0.32 0.97 0.00 0.12 0.15 0.86 P.HICP (3 cat.) -0.17 0.19 0.24 0.98 -0.24 0.00 0.11 0.15 0.83 0.09 Balance (5 cat.) -0.20 0.20 0.25 0.99 -0.51* 0.00 0.11 0.13 0.91 -0.22** Balance (3 cat.) -0.20 0.22 0.31 0.97 0.04 0.00 0.10 0.14 0.89 -0.12 Pesaran (3 cat.) -0.21 0.25 0.47 0.94 0.44 0.00 0.12 0.16 0.85 0.02

Expectations Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z

27 P.Perc. (5 cat.) -0.85 0.85 0.89 0.94 0.00 0.13 0.17 0.80 P.HICP (5 cat.) -0.87 0.87 0.96 0.86 0.47 0.00 0.23 0.30 0.50 0.55** P.HICP (3 cat.) -0.49 0.49 0.24 0.95 -0.06 0.00 0.13 0.15 0.82 -0.05 Balance (5 cat.) -0.49 0.56 0.25 0.89 0.35 0.00 0.17 0.13 0.82 -0.06 Balance (3 cat.) -0.49 0.51 0.31 0.96 -0.18 0.00 0.14 0.14 0.84 -0.13 Pesaran (3 cat.) 0.12 0.22 0.29 0.95 -0.08 0.00 0.13 0.18 0.81 -0.01

Notes: Accuracy is measured relative to the mean of quantitative responses, 01/1996–10/2008. For perceptions, P.HICP (5 cat.) and P.HICP (3 cat.) denote the 5-category and 3-category probability method under the assumption that perceptions are unbiased with respect to HICP inflation. For expectations, P.Perc. (5 cat.) and P.HICP (5 cat.) are the 5-category probability methods with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions and HICP inflation, respectively. P.HICP (3 cat.) is the 3-category probability method under the assumption that expectations are unbiased. Bias is defined as the difference between the mean of quantified beliefs and the mean of quantitative responses. ρ is the correlation coefficient with the mean of quantitative responses. z is the Fisher z statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the difference between the correlation coefficient in the first row of each panel and the correlation coefficient in the respective row is zero. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance of z at the 10%, 5% and 1% level based on double block bootstrap percentile confidence intervals. ceptions generates significantly better results than employing actual HICP inflation, as the z-statistic indicates. The correlation coefficients are 0.80 and 0.50, respectively. The most accurate method for quantifying inflation expectations is again a balance statistic. Moreover, the 3-category regression approach is slightly more accurate than the 5-category probability method. These differences are not statistically significant, however. Results for the sample 01/2002–10/2008 in Table A.1 confirm these findings. In sum, all quantification methods generate series that are highly correlated with the cross- sectional mean of quantitative inflation perceptions. The 5-category balance statistic tracks actual quantitative perceptions most accurately. For expectations, none of the alternative methods performs significantly better than the 5-category probability method with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions. The reasonable performance of the probability method is in contrast to findings of Batchelor (1986) for the U.S.33 However, the 5-category probability method may perform weakly to quantify expectations, depending on the chosen reference inflation. Moreover, the similar accuracy of the 5-category probability method and the 3-category methods signals that the 5-category probability method does not efficiently use information from positive response categories.

4.2 Heterogeneity of Beliefs

The cross-sectional heterogeneity of beliefs is subject to increasing research in macroeco- nomics. This section investigates how to best infer cross-sectional heterogeneity from qual- itative survey data. Cross-sectional heterogeneity is measured by the standard deviation of quantitative beliefs. The 5-category probability method not only allows to identify the mean but also the standard deviation of the fitted normal distribution given by Equation (A.4). In addition, I consider four alternative measures of heterogeneity. The first alternative is implied standard deviation from the 3-category probability method, given by Equation (A.9). The second

33Batchelor (1986) documents that the quantified series do not predict the direction of change in mean quan- titative responses. In the present case, a comparison of signs confirms the high correlation in first differences. For inflation perceptions, the balance statistic and the probability method indicate the correct direction of change of the mean quantitative response in 131 and 129 out of 153 months, for expectations in 121 and 120 months.

28 alternative is an index of qualitative variation (IQV) based on response shares s1 through s5: ( ) K ∑K IQV = 1 − s2 K − 1 i i=1 where K = 5 is the number of response categories and si the fraction of answers in category i. K ≤ ≤ The scaling factor K−1 ensures that 0 IQV 1. Unlike the probability method, the IQV does not account for the ordered nature of the data. The third alternative is the d2-index of ordinal variation proposed by Lacy (2006).34 This index is given by:

K∑−1 DSQ = Fi(1 − Fi) i=1 where K = 5 is the number of response categories and Fi the cumulative response share in category i, e.g., F3 = s1 + s2 + s3. As the IQV, the DSQ statistic attains its minimum of 0 if all answers lie in the same response category. But while the IQV is maximal when answers are uniformly distributed, the DSQ attains its maximum of 1 if the distribution is polarized,

i.e. if s1 = s5 = 0.5. The fourth alternative is the disconformity index of Theil (1955) defined 2 35 as DIS = sp + sn − (sp − sn) . Table 8 summarizes the results. Since the time series of heterogeneity are less persistent than the series of means, the discussion centers on results in levels.36 The alternative measures of heterogeneity are plotted in Figures A.6 and A.7. Table 8 shows that both the 5-category probability method and the 3-category probability method considerably underestimate actual heterogeneity of quantitative beliefs. The implied standard deviation lies 1.7% to 2.4% below the actual standard deviation of quantitative responses. This finding is consistent with earlier results of Defris and Williams (1979) and Batchelor (1986). Regarding inflation perceptions, the first panel of Table 8 shows that implied standard deviation from the 5-category probability method traces actual heterogeneity only weakly. The correlation coefficient is 0.30. The 3-category probability method performs significantly better, as the z statistic indicates. Qualitative measures of variation are even more highly

34Lacy (2006) builds on earlier work of Blair and Lacy (1996, 2000). 35The disconformity index relies on the same theoretical assumptions as the 3-category balance statistic, see Batchelor (1986). 36Both for perceptions and expectations, the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test rejects the null hypothesis of a unit root for the standard deviation of actual quantitative responses and for the quantified series using the 5-category probability method linked to HICP inflation.

29 Table 8: Accuracy of measures of cross-sectional heterogeneity

Perceptions Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) -1.76 1.76 1.83 0.30 0.00 0.29 0.36 0.31 Implied SD (P.HICP, 3 cat.) -1.83 1.83 1.88 0.68 -0.52* 0.00 0.28 0.36 0.36 -0.06 IQV (5 cat.) 0.83 -0.90** 0.48 -0.19** DSQ (5 cat.) 0.87 -1.01** 0.47 -0.19** DIS (3 cat.) 0.35 -0.05 0.30 0.01

Expectations Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Implied SD (P.Perc., 5 cat.) -2.42 2.42 2.45 0.67 0.00 0.27 0.33 0.40 30 Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) -2.44 2.44 2.50 0.52 0.24** 0.00 0.33 0.42 0.20 0.22** Implied SD (P.HICP, 3 cat.) -1.95 1.95 1.98 0.71 -0.07 0.00 0.28 0.34 0.33 0.07 IQV (5 cat.) 0.80 -0.29** 0.28 0.13 DSQ (5 cat.) 0.45 0.32 0.18 0.24** DIS (3 cat.) 0.30 0.49** 0.14 0.27**

Notes: Accuracy is measured relative to the cross-sectional standard deviation of quantitative responses, 01/1996–10/2008. For perceptions, Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) is the implied standard deviation from the 5-category probability method under the HICP unbiasedness condition. For expectations, Implied SD (P.Perc., 5 cat.) and Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) are implied standard deviations from the 5-category probability method with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions and actual HICP inflation, respectively. Both for perceptions and expectations, Implied SD (P.HICP, 3 cat.) is the implied standard deviation from the 3-category probability method under the HICP unbiasedness condition. IQV is the index of qualitative variation, DSQ is the d2-index of ordinal variation proposed by Lacy (2006) and DIS is the disconformity statistic. Bias is defined as the difference between the mean of quantified beliefs and the mean of quantitative responses. ρ is the correlation coefficient with the standard deviation of quantitative responses. z is the Fisher z statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the difference between the correlation coefficient in the first row of each panel and the correlation coefficient in the respective row is zero. *, ** and *** indicate statistical significance of z at the 10%, 5% and 1% level based on double block bootstrap percentile confidence intervals. correlated with the standard deviation of quantitative perceptions. The correlation coefficients of the IQV and the DSQ are 0.83 and 0.87, respectively. The performance of the 3-category disconformity index is substantially lower, its correlation with actual standard deviation of quantitative responses is similar to the 5-category probability method. The implied standard deviation from the 5-category probability method performs better for quantifying heterogeneity of inflation expectations, as the second panel of Table 8 indicates. Again, the correlation depends on the choice of reference inflation. Employing actual HICP inflation instead of quantified perceptions reduces the correlation coefficient significantly from 0.67 to 0.52. The implied standard deviation of the 3-category approach is about as accurate as the 5-category probability method with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions. The IQV most closely tracks actual heterogeneity of quantitative responses. Its correlation with actual standard deviation is 0.80, which is significantly higher than the correlation of the 5-category probability method. Unlike for perceptions, the DSQ statistic is only moderately correlated with actual heterogeneity. Even lower is the correlation for the disconformity index, which is in line with earlier findings of Batchelor (1986). Results for first differences are broadly consistent, with the exception that for quantifying expectations the IQV does not outperform other methods anymore. Results for the shorter sample spanning 01/2002– 10/2008 in Table A.2 confirm the relatively high accuracy of the IQV compared to other methods.37 In sum, these results suggest that while the probability method is relatively accurate in de- scribing the central tendency, it is considerably less accurate in capturing cross-sectional het- erogeneity. Moreover, the 3-category probability method performs better than the 5-category method, which is consistent with findings of the previous section.38 The IQV generally domi- nates the other methods in terms of correlation with the cross-sectional standard deviation of quantitative beliefs. The DSQ is only accurate for quantifying the heterogeneity of inflation perceptions. A possible interpretation of this result is that the IQV is less distorted by the lack of order in qualitative inflation expectations than the DSQ index.

37Note that in this sample the probability method gains relative accuracy for quantifying inflation expecta- tions. I have also assessed accuracy of the square root of the index of qualitative variation, the square root of the DSQ-statistic and the square root of the disconformity index. The correlations with actual standard deviation of survey responses do not significantly change, both in their absolute level and relative ordering. 38The reasonable performance of the 3-category probability method also reinforces the results of Dasgupta and Lahiri (1993) who show that implied dispersion from the 3-category method is useful for predicting business cycle turning points.

31 5 Which Quantification Method Should Be Used?

The assumptions of the 5-category probability method can be individually and jointly rejected. Moreover, the estimated response schemes indicate that qualitative inflation expectations are not strictly increasing in quantitative expectations since positive responses are given relative to perceived inflation. Both for perceptions and expectations of inflation, however, the response scheme estimates indicate that three separate positive categories S3, S4 and S5 contain additional information over just one positive category. Despite the violation of theoretical assumptions, the accuracy of the 5-category probability method for quantifying the cross-sectional mean of inflation perceptions is high. The relative performance of the 3-category probability method indicates, however, that the 5-category method does not efficiently use the additional information from three positive response cate- gories. The most accurate method is the 5-category balance statistic. For quantifying the cross-sectional mean of inflation expectations, the accuracy of the r 5-category probability method largely depends on the chosen reference inflation πt . Employ- ing quantified inflation perceptions yields significantly more accurate results than employing actual HICP inflation. At first sight this finding is inconsistent with the zero correlation of quantified perceptions and reference inflation during the full sample as documented in Section 3.5. But as Figure 2 indicates, the relation between quantified perceptions and reference in- flation becomes stronger towards the end of the sample period. The correlation coefficient of reference inflation and quantified perceptions increases to 0.46 during 2002–2008. In particu- lar, quantified perceptions surge in 2007 and 2008, while reference inflation increases to about 6%. This suggests that the 5-category probability method with quantified perceptions as reference inflation will gain relative accuracy once inflation perceptions substantially diverge from actual inflation.39 It remains the question why the simple balance statistic tends to trace mean beliefs even more closely than the 5-category probability method. Table 9 provides a possible expla- nation. The table shows the mean of quantitative responses conditional on the qualitative response. Conditional means of actual quantitative responses are compared to the imposed conditional means of the balance statistic and of the 5-category probability method. The imposed conditional means are scaled to match the mean and variance of actual conditional

39This is the case, e.g., around the euro cash changeover in 2002 (ECB, 2005).

32 Table 9: Actual and imposed conditional means

Perceptions Expectations Actual Balance P.HICP Actual Balance P.Perc. Mean response, given S1 -4.79 -3.96 -4.94 -3.89 -2.87 -3.60 Mean response, given S2 0.03 -0.23 0.37 0.02 -0.54 0.37 Mean response, given S3 4.72 3.50 4.62 4.06 1.79 2.40 Mean response, given S4 7.94 7.22 7.70 4.77 4.12 3.53 Mean response, given S5 9.58 10.95 9.75 3.98 6.45 6.25

Notes: The column Actual presents results for actual quantitative survey responses, 01/1996–10/2008. Balance shows the mean values that the balance statistic attributes to qualitative survey categories. P.HICP denotes implied conditional means of the 5-category probability method unbiased with respect to HICP inflation. P.Perc. are the implied conditional means of the 5-category probability method with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions. Conditional means are scaled to match the mean and standard deviation of actual conditional means. means.40 Table 9 reveals that both methods impose (scaled) conditional means that match actual conditional means quite well. In other words, the conditional means imposed by the balance statistic are roughly proportional to the actual conditional means in the data. Not surprisingly, the fit is better for perceptions than for expectations. This also suggests that the balance statistic, unlike the probability method, will loose relative accuracy once the ratio of conditional means changes. The accuracy of the 5-category probability method is low for quantifying the cross- sectional standard deviation of beliefs. Here, an index of qualitative variation is preferable. The index of qualitative variation also dominates the DSQ index of ordinal variation for quantifying the heterogeneity of expectations. In sum, these results are in favor of the 5-category probability method for quantifying the mean of beliefs. The index of qualitative variation is preferable for quantifying the cross- sectional standard deviation of beliefs. In particular, the IQV seems less distorted by a lack of order in qualitative inflation expectations than other quantification methods. The findings also indicate that the 5-category probability method with quantified perceptions as reference inflation might gain relative accuracy once inflation perceptions deviate from actual inflation. This also points to a general limitation of the results: Findings on the quantification of expectations might differ from other countries as Swedish consumers are relatively well

40The (unscaled) conditional means of the 5-category balance statistic are -1, 0.5, 0, 0.5, 1. The implied conditional means of the probability method are computed by numerical integration using the quantified e r parameters πt , σt, δt, ηt, πt . Perceptions are quantified employing the 5-category probability method unbiased with respect to HICP inflation. Expectations are quantified using the 5-category probability method with reference inflation given by quantified perceptions.

33 informed about actual HICP inflation.

6 Conclusion

This paper assesses the validity and accuracy of the 5-category probability method for quantifying household perceptions and expectations of inflation. The analysis capitalizes on jointly avail- able qualitative and quantitative response data from the Swedish Consumer Tendency Sur- vey. Relying on monthly household-level data covering 01/1996–10/2008, the theoretical assumptions of the 5-category probability method are individually and jointly tested and re- jected. Maximum likelihood estimations of unrestricted response schemes indicate that the actual response scheme is neither symmetric nor homogeneous across individuals. Moreover, it is found that qualitative inflation expectations are formed relative to inflation perceptions, which is a direct result of survey design. An important consequence is that the conditional mean of quantitative inflation expectations is not monotonously rising in qualitative response categories. Furthermore, quantitative beliefs are not normally distributed and cannot be rec- onciled with a noncentral t distribution either. The usual assumptions on the reference rate of inflation (the “moderate” rate of inflation) are shown to be at odds with the data. Nevertheless, the accuracy of the 5-category probability method in terms of correlation with the mean of actual quantitative beliefs is high. For quantifying inflation expectations the accuracy of the method strongly depends on the identifying restriction imposed by the choice of reference inflation. Relying on double block bootstrap confidence intervals for Fisher’s z statistic, it is shown that setting reference inflation equal to previously quantified inflation perceptions yields significantly better results than setting reference inflation equal to actual inflation. Nevertheless, the 5-category probability method is not more accurate than the balance statistic and the 3-category probability method. This suggests that the 5-category probability method does not efficiently use information from positive qualitative response categories. In sum, the results are still in favor of the 5-category probability method. In particular, the 5-category probability method with quantified perceptions as reference infla- tion might gain relative accuracy once inflation perceptions substantially deviate from actual inflation. The most accurate measure of the cross-sectional standard deviation of beliefs is the index of qualitative variation. The findings for Sweden suggest a number of avenues for further research. To exploit the

34 additional information from three positive response categories, research is needed on how to identify the reference rate of inflation. Moreover, a non-parametric analysis should generate further insights that will help to improve the imposed response scheme and distribution. Looking ahead, implications for survey design should also be discussed in more depth. The results for Sweden indicate that it is difficult to efficiently handle the relative nature of the positive qualitative responses about inflation expectations. Obvious alternative survey designs include to adopt the same response scheme for expectations as currently in use for perceptions or to directly ask for quantitative responses in the first place.

35 References

Aalto-Setal¨ a,¨ V. (2006): “Why Do Consumers Believe That the Euro Raised Prices?,” International Journal of Consumer Studies, 30(2), 202–206.

Anderson, O. (1952): “The Business Test of the IFO-Institute for Economic Research Munich, and Its Theoretical Model,” Revue de l’Institut International de Statistique, 20, 1–17.

Aucremanne, L., M. Collin, and T. Stragier (2007): “Assessing the Gap Between Observed and Perceived Inflation in the Euro Area: Is the Credibility of the HICP at Stake?,” National Bank of Belgium Working Paper 112.

Batchelor, R. A. (1982): “Aggregate Expectations Under the Stable Laws,” Journal of Econometrics, 16(2), 199–210.

(1986): “Quantitative v. Qualitative Measures of Inflation Expectations,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 48(2), 99–120.

Batchelor, R. A., and P. Dua (1987): “The Accuracy and Rationality of UK Inflation Expectations: Some Quantitative Evidence,” Applied Economics, 19(6), 819–828.

Batchelor, R. A., and A. B. Orr (1988): “Inflation Expectations Revisited,” Economica, 55(219), 317–331.

Berk, J. M. (1999): “Measuring Inflation Expectations: A Survey Data Approach,” Applied Economics, 31(11), 1467–1480.

Blair, J., and M. G. Lacy (1996): “Measures of Variation for Ordinal Data as Functions of the Cumulative Distribution,” Perceptual and Motor Skills, 82(2), 411–418.

(2000): “Statistics of Ordinal Variation,” Sociological Methods & Research, 28(3), 251–280.

Bryan, M. F., and S. Palmqvist (2006): “Testing Near-Rationality Using Detailed Survey Data,” Sveriges Riksbank Research Paper Series.

Bryan, M. F., and G. Venkatu (2001a): “The Curiously Different Inflation Perspectives of Men and Women,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary Series.

36 (2001b): “The Demographics of Inflation Opinion Surveys,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary Series.

Carlson, J. A. (1975): “Are Price Expectations Normally Distributed?,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 352, 749–754.

Carlson, J. A., and M. Parkin (1975): “Inflation Expectations,” Economica, 42(166), 123–138.

Dasgupta, S., and K. Lahiri (1992): “A Comparative Study of Alternative Methods of Quantifying Qualitative Survey Responses Using NAPM Data,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 10(4), 391–400.

(1993): “On the Use of Dispersion Measures From NAPM Surveys in Business Cycle Forecasting,” Journal of Forecasting, 12(3-4), 239–253.

Defris, L. V., and R. A. Williams (1979): “Quantitative Versus Qualitative Measures of Price Expectations: The Evidence From Australian Consumer Surveys,” Economics Letters, 2(2), 169–173.

Doehring, B., and A. Mordonu (2007): “What Drives Inflation Perceptions? A Dynamic Panel Data Analysis,” European Commission Economic Papers 284.

Dopke,¨ J., J. Dovern, U. Fritsche, and J. Slacalek (2008): “The Dynamics of Euro- pean Inflation Expectations,” B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 8(1).

Driver, R., and R. Windram (2007): “Public Attitudes to Inflation and Interest Rates,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 47(2), 208–223.

Dziuda, W., and G. Mastrobuoni (2006): “The Euro Changeover and Its Effects on Price Transparency and Inflation,” Working Paper 26, Collegio Carlo Alberto.

ECB (2005): “Consumers’ Inflation Perceptions: Still At Odds With Official Statistics?,” ECB Monthly Bulletin, (4), 30–32.

Efron, B., and R. J. Tibshirani (1993): An Introduction to the Bootstrap. Chapman & Hall.

37 Ehrmann, M. (2006): “Rational Inattention, Inflation Developments and Perceptions After the Euro Cash Changeover,” ECB Working Paper 588, European Central Bank.

European Commission (2007): The Joint Harmonised EU Programme of Business and Consumer Surveys: User Guide, European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs.

Fluch, M., and H. Stix (2007): “The Development of Euro Prices - Subjective Perception and Empirical Facts,” Monetary Policy and the Economy (OeNB), 07(1), 55–84.

Forsells, M., and G. Kenny (2004): “Survey Expectations, Rationality and the Dynamics of Euro Area Inflation,” Journal of Business Cycle Measurement and Analysis, 1(1), 13–41.

GfK (2002): Consumer Tendency Survey, GfK Sweden, Stockholm, Sweden.

Henzel, S., and T. Wollmershauser¨ (2005): “Quantifying Inflation Expectations With the Carlson-Parkin Method: A Survey-based Determination of the Just Noticeable Differ- ence,” Journal of Business Cycle Measurement and Analysis, 2(3).

Jonung, L., and D. Laidler (1988): “Are Perceptions of Inflation Rational? Some Evi- dence for Sweden,” American Economic Review, 78(5), 1080–1087.

Lacy, M. G. (2006): “An Explained Variation Measure for Ordinal Response Models With Comparisons to Other Ordinal R2 Measures,” Sociological Methods & Research, 34(4), 469– 520.

Lahiri, K., and C. Teigland (1987): “On the Normality of Probability Distributions of Inflation and GNP Forecasts,” International Journal of Forecasting, 3(2), 269–279.

Lamla, M. J., and S. M. Lein (2008): “The Role of Media for Consumers’ Inflation Expectation Formation,” KOF Working Papers 201, ETH Zurich.

Lein, S. M., and T. Maag (2008): “The Formation of Inflation Perceptions — Some Empirical Facts for European Countries,” KOF Working Papers 204, ETH Zurich.

Mudholkar, G. S. (2006): “Fisher’s z-Transformation,” in Encyclopedia of Statistical Sci-

ences, ed. by S. Kotz, C. B. Read, N. Balakrishnan, and B. Vidakovic. Wiley.

38 Nardo, M. (2003): “The Quantification of Qualitative Survey Data: A Critical Assessment,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 17, 645–668.

Palmqvist, S., and L. Stromberg¨ (2004): “Households’ Inflation Opinions - A Tale of Two Surveys,” Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review, 4, 23–42.

Pesaran, M. H. (1987): The Limits to Rational Expectations. Blackwell.

Smith, J., and M. McAleer (1995): “Alternative Procedures for Converting Qualitative Response Data to Quantitative Expectations: An Application to Australian Manufactur- ing,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10(2), 165–185.

Theil, H. (1952): “On the Shape of Microvariables and the Munich Business Test,” Revue de l’Institut International de Statistique, 20, 105–120.

(1955): “Recent Experiences With the Munich Business Test: An Expository Arti- cle,” Econometrica, 23(2), 184–192.

Zavoina, W., and R. D. McKelvey (1975): “A Statistical Model for the Analysis of Ordinal Level Dependent Variables,” Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 4, 103–120.

39 Appendix

A.1 Derivation of the 5-Category Probability Method

This section derives the 5 category probability method based on the assumptions introduced in Section 3. The method has been originally proposed by Batchelor and Orr (1988) and relies on earlier contributions of Theil (1952) and Carlson and Parkin (1975). All derivations e p equally hold for quantifying inflation perceptions, in which case πt is substituted with πt . The response scheme for inflation perceptions is given by:

p − πt,i < δt : prices in general are lower (S1) − ≤ p δt πt,i < δt : about the same (S2) ≤ p r − δt πt,i < πt ηt : a little higher (S3) r − ≤ p r πt ηt πt,i < πt + ηt : moderately higher (S4) p ≥ r πt,i πt + ηt : a lot higher (S5)

Under the assumptions introduced in Section 3, the relation between aggregate response e shares and expected inflation πt in period t is given by: ( ) − − e 1 e − δt πt st = P (πt,i < δt) = Φ (σt ) ( ) − e − − e 2 − ≤ e δt πt − δt πt st = P ( δt πt,i < δt) = Φ Φ (σt ) σt ( ) r − − e − e 3 ≤ e r − πt ηt πt − δt πt st = P (δt πt,i < πt ηt) = Φ Φ (σt ) σt( ) r − e r − − e 4 r − ≤ e r πt + ηt πt − πt ηt πt st = P (πt,i ηt πt,i < πt + ηt) = Φ Φ ( σ)t σt r − e 5 r ≤ e − πt + ηt πt st = P (πt,i + ηt πt,i) = 1 Φ (A.1) σt where Φ(.) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. The system of equations (A.1) can be rewritten to obtain a system of 4 linearly independent equations with 5 unknowns e r (πt , σt, δt, ηt, πt ):

40 ( ) − − e 1 −1 1 δt πt Gt = Φ st = σt ( ) − − e 2 −1 − 5 − 4 − 3 − 2 δt πt Gt = Φ 1 st st st st = σt ( ) − e 3 −1 − 5 − 4 − 3 δt πt Gt = Φ 1 st st st = σt ( ) r − − e 4 −1 − 5 − 4 πt ηt πt Gt = Φ 1 st st = σt ( ) r − e 5 −1 − 5 πt + ηt πt Gt = Φ 1 st = (A.2) σt

e System (A.2) can be solved for the mean πt of expected inflation:

G2 + G3 πe = πr t t (A.3) t t 2 3 − 4 − 5 Gt + Gt Gt Gt

e In the following, πt is referred to as “expected inflation” (rather than “mean of expected inflation”). The remaining unknowns are given by:

−2 σ = πr (A.4) t t 2 3 − 4 − 5 Gt + Gt Gt Gt G2 − G3 δ = πr t t (A.5) t t 2 3 − 4 − 5 Gt + Gt Gt Gt G4 − G5 η = πr t t (A.6) t t 2 3 − 4 − 5 Gt + Gt Gt Gt

r For quantifying inflation perceptions, πt is commonly identified by restricting inflation per- ceptions to be unbiased over the sample period. Rearranging Equation (A.3) and imposing unbiasedness yields:

r π πt = ∑ 2 3 (A.7) 1 T Gt +Gt t=1 2 3− 4− 5 T Gt +Gt Gt Gt where T is the number of periods and π the average actual rate of inflation.

A.2 Derivation of the 3-Category Probability Method

Theil (1952) and Carlson and Parkin (1975) have originally developed the probability method for three-option ordinal scales. In line with Berk (1999), the EU consumer survey responses

41 are aggregated to three categories by defining sn = s1, ss = s2 and sp = s3 + s4 + s5. The relation between response shares and expected inflation is given by: ( ) − − e n e − δ πt st = P (πt,i < δ) = Φ (σt ) ( ) − e − − e s − e δ πt − δ πt st = P ( δ < πt,i < δ) = Φ Φ ( σt ) σt − e p e − δ πt st = P (δ < πt,i) = 1 Φ σt where Φ(.) is a standard normal cumulative distribution function. At any t we have a system of 2 linearly independent equations with 3 unknowns (δ, µt, σt). Solving yields:

Φ−1 (sn) + Φ−1 (1 − sp) πe = δ t t (A.8) t −1 n − −1 − p Φ (st ) Φ (1 st ) 2 σ = δ (A.9) t −1 − p − −1 n Φ (1 st ) Φ (st )

p The identical equations hold for perceived inflation πt . In line with the existing literature, the system is identified by imposing unbiasedness of beliefs with respect to actual inflation during the sample period. The parameter δ is restricted accordingly:

π δ = [ ] ∑ −1 n −1 − p 1 T Φ (st )+Φ (1 st ) T t=1 −1 n − −1 − p Φ (st ) Φ (1 st )

42 A.3 Further Results

43 h ag ewe h 5had7t ecnieo otl rcin n otisamda line. median a covers contains are box and Each Expectations fractions monthly inflation. inflation. of reference HICP percentile as to 75th and perceptions respect 25th quantified with the perceptions unbiased with between Quantified method method range sum 01/1996–10/2008. the probability probability the category period the to Sample 5 using relative quantified the are category. Fractions on respective based response. the qualitative are in simultaneous responses the qualitative by of defined interval response implied Notes: hs grsso h rcin fqatttv epne htleblw( below lie that responses quantitative of fractions the show figures These iueA1 epnefatosblwadaoeteipidinterval implied the above and below fractions Response A.1: Figure

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 excludes outsidevalues excludes outsidevalues 1hg 2lwhg 3lwhg 4lwhg S5low high S4low high S3low high S2low S1 high S5low high S4low high S3low high S2low S1 high b Expectations (b) a Perceptions (a) 44 low n bv ( above and ) high the ) Notes: apepro 120–020.Sefont fFgr o ealddescription. detailed a for 3 Figure of footnote See 01/2002–10/2008. period Sample iueA2 culadtertclrsos rcin,2002–2008 fractions, response theoretical and Actual A.2: Figure

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 excludes outsidevalues excludes outsidevalues 1qat 2qat 3qat 4qat 5qat N S5quant. N S4quant. N S3 quant. N S2quant. N S1 quant. N S5quant. N S4quant. N S3quant. N S2quant. N S1 quant. b Expectations (b) a Perceptions (a) 45 Notes: iueA3 epnefatosblwadaoeteipiditra,2002–2008 interval, implied the above and below fractions Response A.3: Figure apepro 120–020.Sefont fFgr . o ealddescription. detailed a for A.1 Figure of footnote See 01/2002–10/2008. period Sample

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 excludes outsidevalues excludes outsidevalues 1hg 2lwhg 3lwhg 4lwhg S5low high S4low high S3low high S2low S1 high S5low high S4low high S3low high S2low S1 high b Expectations (b) a Perceptions (a) 46 % % iueA4 rs-etoa eno nainperceptions inflation of mean Cross-sectional A.4: Figure 1996m1 0 2 4 6 1996m1 0 2 4 6 1998m1 1998m1 b aac ttsisadrgeso method regression and statistics Balance (b) .IP( a. HICP inflationrate P.HICP(5cat.) P.HICP (3cat.) Mean quantitative aac 3ct)Pesaran Balance(5cat.) Balance (3cat.) Mean quantitative 2000m1 2000m1 a rbblt method Probability (a) 2002m1 2002m1 47 2004m1 2004m1 2006m1 2006m1 2008m1 2008m1 % % iueA5 rs-etoa eno nainexpectations inflation of mean Cross-sectional A.5: Figure

1996m1 0 2 4 6 1996m1 0 1 2 3 4 5 1998m1 1998m1 b aac ttsisadrgeso method regression and statistics Balance (b) aac 3ct)Pesaran Balance(5cat.) Balance (3cat.) Mean quantitative .IP( a. P.HICP (3cat.) P.Perc(5cat.) P.HICP (5cat.) Mean quantitative 2000m1 2000m1 a rbblt method Probability (a) 2002m1 2002m1 48 2004m1 2004m1 2006m1 2006m1 2008m1 2008m1 Table A.1: Accuracy of quantified inflation perceptions and expectations, 2002–2008

Perceptions Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z P.HICP (5 cat.) -0.26 0.27 0.40 0.97 0.00 0.12 0.15 0.85 P.HICP (3 cat.) -0.11 0.14 0.18 0.99 -0.56** 0.00 0.10 0.15 0.79 0.15 Balance (5 cat.) -0.20 0.20 0.25 0.99 -0.79 0.00 0.10 0.12 0.89 -0.22** Balance (3 cat.) -0.15 0.19 0.33 0.97 0.02 0.00 0.10 0.14 0.86 -0.08 Pesaran (3 cat.) -0.27 0.31 0.60 0.93 0.30 0.00 0.12 0.17 0.81 0.09 49 Expectations Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z P.Perc. (5 cat.) -0.76 0.76 0.80 0.97 0.00 0.15 0.20 0.79 P.HICP (5 cat.) -0.92 0.92 1.00 0.89 0.70** 0.00 0.26 0.35 0.51 0.50** P.HICP (3 cat.) -0.39 0.39 0.18 0.97 0.09 0.00 0.15 0.15 0.83 -0.08 Balance (5 cat.) -0.22 0.35 0.25 0.82 0.99 0.00 0.17 0.12 0.84 -0.13 Balance (3 cat.) -0.27 0.31 0.33 0.95 0.31 0.00 0.16 0.14 0.84 -0.13 Pesaran (3 cat.) 0.05 0.22 0.32 0.92 0.53 0.00 0.15 0.20 0.81 -0.03

Notes: Sample period 01/2002–10/2008. See Table 7 for a detailed description. rbblt ehdudrteHC nisdescondition. unbiasedness the HICP is the under method probability condition. unbiasedness cat.) 5 (P.HICP, quantitative SD Notes: d 2 idxo ria aito rpsdb ay(06 and (2006) Lacy by proposed variation ordinal of -index

steipidsadr eito rmte5ctgr rbblt ehdudrteHICP the under method probability 5-category the from deviation standard implied the is % % 1996m1 1996m1 2 3 4 5 6 2 3 4 5 6 stecosscinlsadr eito fqatttv uvyresponses. survey quantitative of deviation standard cross-sectional the is mle D(.IP cat.) 3 (P.HICP, SD Implied iueA6 eeoeet fiflto perceptions inflation of Heterogeneity A.6: Figure 1998m1 1998m1 Dqatttv ImpliedSD(P.HICP,5cat.) Implied SD(P.HICP,3cat.) SD quantitative 2000m1 2000m1 b ulttv measures Qualitative (b) S rs DC(rhs) IQV(rhs) DSQ (rhs) SD quantitative a rbblt method Probability (a) 2002m1 2002m1 50 steipidsadr eito rmte3-category the from deviation standard implied the is 2004m1 IQV 2004m1 DIS steidxo ulttv variation, qualitative of index the is 2006m1 stedsofriystatistic. disconformity the is 2006m1 2008m1 2008m1

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 Index mle SD Implied DSQ aito rpsdb ay(06 and (2006) Lacy by proposed respectively.variation condition. inflation, unbiasedness HICP actual HICP and cat.) the perceptions 3 quantified (P.HICP, by SD given Implied inflation reference with method ability cat.) 5 (P.Perc., quantitative SD Notes: and % % 1996m1 1996m1 mle D(.IP cat.) 5 (P.HICP, SD Implied 2.5 3 3.5 4 4.5 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 stecosscinlsadr eito fqatttv uvyresponses. survey quantitative of deviation standard cross-sectional the is iueA7 eeoeet fiflto expectations inflation of Heterogeneity A.7: Figure steipidsadr eito rmte3ctgr rbblt ehdunder method probability 3-category the from deviation standard implied the is 1998m1 1998m1 Dqatttv ImpliedSD(P.Perc.,5cat.) ImpliedSD(P.HICP,3cat.) Implied SD(P.HICP,5cat.) SD quantitative IQV DIS 2000m1 steidxo ulttv variation, qualitative of index the is 2000m1 b ulttv measures Qualitative (b) S rs DC(rhs) IQV(rhs) DSQ (rhs) SD quantitative a rbblt method Probability (a) stedsofriystatistic. disconformity the is 2002m1 r mle tnaddvain rmte5ctgr prob- 5-category the from deviations standard implied are 2002m1 51 2004m1 2004m1 2006m1 2006m1 2008m1 DSQ 2008m1 sthe is

.2 .4 .6 .8 1

d Index 2 idxo ordinal of -index mle SD Implied Table A.2: Accuracy of measures of cross-sectional heterogeneity, 2002–2008

Perceptions Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) -2.00 2.00 2.04 0.27 0.00 0.28 0.34 0.20 Implied SD (P.HICP, 3 cat.) -1.86 1.86 1.88 0.65 -0.51 0.00 0.24 0.31 0.45 -0.27* IQV (5 cat.) 0.80 -0.82* 0.47 -0.26** DSQ (5 cat.) 0.79 -0.82 0.33 -0.13 DC (3 cat.) -0.15 0.43 0.29 -0.09 52 Expectations Level First differences Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Bias MAE RMSE ρ z Implied SD (P.Perc, 5 cat.) -2.35 2.35 2.40 0.30 0.00 0.28 0.36 0.27 Implied SD (P.HICP, 5 cat.) -2.51 2.51 2.57 0.30 0.01 0.00 0.33 0.42 0.27 -0.01 Implied SD (P.HICP, 3 cat.) -1.88 1.88 1.90 0.42 -0.13 0.00 0.29 0.36 0.26 0.01 IQV (5 cat.) 0.33 -0.03 0.05 0.22 DSQ (5 cat.) -0.09 0.41 0.10 0.17 DC (3 cat.) 0.09 0.23 0.13 0.14

Notes: Sample period 01/2002–10/2008. See Table 8 for a detailed description.