On the Unequal Inequality of Poor Communities

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On the Unequal Inequality of Poor Communities On the Unequal Inequality of Poor Communities Chris Elbers, Peter F. Lanjouw, Johan A. Mistiaen, Berk O¨ zler, and Ken Simler Public Disclosure Authorized Communities differ in important ways in their needs, capacities, and circumstances. Because central governments are not able to discern these differences fully, they seek to achieve their policy objectives by relying on decentralized mechanisms that use local information. Household and individual characteristics within communities can also vary substantially. A growing body of theoretical literature suggests that inequality within communities can influence policy outcomes in ways that are either harmful or helpful, depending on the circumstances. Until recently, empirical investigations into the impact of inequality have been held back by a lack of systematic evidence on community-level inequality. This study uses household survey and population census data to estimate per capita consumption inequality within communities in three devel- oping economies. It finds that communities vary markedly in their degree of inequality. It also shows that there should be no presumption that inequality is less severe in poor communities. The kind of community-level inequality estimates generated here can be used in designing and evaluating decentralized antipoverty programs. Public Disclosure Authorized Governments commonly implement decentralized antipoverty programs that are designed to distribute assets or cash to individuals or households. Usually, the central government distributes antipoverty funds to communities, which then decide how to allocate the funds. One example is social fund projects, a type of community-based development initiative in which poor communities identify projects, apply for funding, and design, implement, and manage their projects (Mansuri and Rao 2004).1 These initiatives intend to improve poverty Chris Elbers is a professor at the Vrije (Free) University Amsterdam; his e-mail address is celbers@ feweb.vu.nl. Peter F. Lanjouw is a lead economist in the Development Research Group at the World Bank; his e-mail address is [email protected]. Johan A. Mistiaen is an economist/statistician in Public Disclosure Authorized the Development Data Group at the World Bank; his e-mail address is [email protected]. Berk O¨ zler is an economist in the Development Research Group at the World Bank; his e-mail address is [email protected]. Ken Simler is a research fellow at the International Food Policy Research Institute; his e-mail address is [email protected]. The authors are grateful to Francois Bourguignon, Francisco Ferreira, Emanuela Galasso, Ravi Kanbur, Jenny Lanjouw, Vijayendra Rao, and Martin Ravallion for comments and helpful discussions. They would also like to thank the journal editor and three anonymous referees for guidance. 1. Mansuri and Rao (2004) distinguish community-based development from community-driven development, popularized by the World Bank, which refers to projects in which communities have direct control over key decisions as well as management of investment funds. Community-based development can be thought of as a broader term that accommodates but is not restricted to the World Bank’s community-driven development concept. THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 18, NO. 3, Ó The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK 2004; all rights reserved. doi:10.1093/wber/lhh046 18:401–421 Public Disclosure Authorized 401 402 THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 18, NO. 3 targeting and project implementation by using local information and inviting local participation. In practice, however, these potential benefits of local involve- ment may be outweighed by the possibility of resources being captured by local elites.2 In a review of the community-based development approach, Mansuri and Rao (2003) argue that although potential gains are large, there are also important risks inherent in the basic precepts of the approach. Uncertainty about the ultimate impact of such programs implies that a blanket application of a given approach in all communities may not be approp- riate. Again, Mansuri and Rao (2004) caution against the wholesale scaling up of best practices identified in a few pilot settings, because the success of such pilot projects might depend crucially on local conditions that are not found elsewhere. Still, large projects such as a countrywide cash transfer or social fund program cannot take into account the full range of local characteristics that could possibly affect project performance. Hence, policymakers must confront the challenge of designing schemes that take critical local information into account but are not prohibitively costly to implement. Governments have traditionally dealt with this problem by categorizing communities by easily observable characteristics and adapting schemes for each group. Lacking local-level data on poverty, government programs may draw on proxy indicators—believed to be correlated with local poverty condi- tions—to determine the eligibility of communities for various projects. But despite emerging theoretical analysis and empirical evidence that local inequal- ity may also affect local development outcomes, such information has rarely made its way into program design. One reason is that estimates of local inequal- ity have not been widely available until recently.3 Another is that inequality may not be considered of primary importance when the target of an intervention is a small, poor community in a developing economy. The natural assumption is that where livelihoods are at the subsistence level there is little likelihood that well-being would vary much across households and individuals. This article addresses both these issues. Applying a newly developed metho- dology, it estimates local-level welfare outcomes using the detailed information available from household surveys and the large-scale representation of the population census for Ecuador, Madagascar, and Mozambique. These techni- ques can be used to derive meaningful estimates of income or expenditure inequality for small areas for many countries, using readily available data. The article examines the importance of local-level inequality by decomposing national inequality in each country into a within-community and between- community component. This decomposition exercise produces a summary sta- 2. A vivid illustration of elite capture problems in practice and a theoretical treatment of this issue are provided in Platteau and Gaspart (2003). 3. McKenzie (2003) provides a recent attempt to proxy local inequality on the basis of easily observed correlates of household income. Elbers and others 403 tistic that masks significant heterogeneity in inequality across communities. The article provides additional evidence that this heterogeneity in inequality is evident even among poor rural communities. It demonstrates that information on local inequality can help program implementers further categorize commu- nities after conditioning on local poverty and type of area. I. HOW C AN L OCAL I NEQUALITY A FFECT W ELFARE O UTCOMES? Mansuri and Rao (2004) present a comprehensive overview of the theoretical and empirical literature on the relationship between local inequality and devel- opment outcomes. Two critical issues emerge. How does inequality within a community influence the targeting impact of a particular project? How does local inequality affect collective action within communities? Recent theoretical analysis suggests that inequality may affect targeting out- comes of social fund projects or antipoverty transfer schemes by reducing the relative power of the intended beneficiaries (Galasso and Ravallion forthcom- ing; Bardhan and Mookherjee 1999). In such cases, the advantage of such decentralized approaches to make use of better community-level information about priorities and the characteristics of residents could be offset by the possibility that the local governing body is controlled by elites, who may have different objectives than the poor within their communities. Although the predictions from this theoretical work are ambiguous, limited empirical evidence shows that both the pros and the cons of decentralized decisionmaking are at work in various countries. Alderman (2002) finds that communities in Albania were able to improve targeting by using information unavailable to the central government. By contrast, Galasso and Ravallion (forthcoming) find that high levels of local inequality (as measured by land- holding) were associated with worse targeting performance under the Food for Education program in villages in Bangladesh. A detailed case study of the small north Indian village of Palanpur from the late 1950s through the early 1990s shows how local elites appropriated public resources and opportunities that were to be made available to the whole com- munity (Dre` ze and others 1998). The study documents the introduction of 18 types of government-provided programs into the village, including a public works road-building program, free schooling, free basic health care, old-age pensions, a fair-price shop, and a farmer cooperative. The sobering diagnosis is that most of these programs were nonfunctional, particularly programs that had a redistributive component. Dre` ze and others argue that a key explanation for this dispiriting record is that village institutions were dominated by privileged groups and that only programs that enjoyed their backing were allowed to succeed. Dre` ze and others (1998,
Recommended publications
  • Curriculum Vitae
    Curriculum Vitae of Yanis Varoufakis 1. Personal information Place and date of birth: Athens, 24 March 1961 Nationality: Greek and Australian E'mail: [email protected] and [email protected] 2. Educational Background Doctorate: University of Essex, Department of Economics, 1987, PhD in Economics; Title: Optimisation and Strikes; Description: A statistical investigation of competing time series, cross-section, econometric, parametric and game theoretical models of industrial strikes based on USA and UK data. The data sets used were of two forms: macroeconomic (aggregate). and panel data. Supervisor: Professor Monojit Chatterji (currently at Dundee University) Examiners: Professors David Ulph (University of Bristol) and Anthony Shorrocks (University of Essex). Masters: University of Birmingham, Department of Mathematical Statistics, 1982, MSc in Mathematical Statistics Specialisation: Time series, statistical inference, statistical theory, stochastic processes, limited dependent variable estimation, maximum likelihood estimation, non-parametric statistics. Bachelor: University of Essex, School of Mathematical Studies, 1981, BA(Hons) Mathematical Economics High School Moraitis School, Athens, Greece 1 3. Academic positions Primary position January 2013 – Visiting Professor, Lyndon B. Johnson Graduate School of Public Affairs, University of Texas, Austin, USA September 2006 – Professor of Economic Theory, Faculty of Economic Sciences, University of Athens, Athens, Greece September 2000 to September 2006 Associate Professor of Economic
    [Show full text]
  • Spatial Decomposition of Inequality
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Shorrocks, Anthony; Wan, Guanghua Working Paper Spatial decomposition of inequality WIDER Discussion Paper, No. 2004/01 Provided in Cooperation with: United Nations University (UNU), World Institute for Development Economics Research (WIDER) Suggested Citation: Shorrocks, Anthony; Wan, Guanghua (2004) : Spatial decomposition of inequality, WIDER Discussion Paper, No. 2004/01, The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER), Helsinki This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/52738 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Discussion Paper No. 2004/01 Spatial Decomposition of Inequality Anthony Shorrocks and Guanghua Wan* January 2004 Abstract This paper reviews the theory and application of decomposition techniques in the context of spatial inequality.
    [Show full text]
  • The Global Wealth Report 2019 in Mid-2019
    October 2019 Research Institute Global wealth report 2019 Color gradient or Image placeholder Thought leadership from Credit Suisse and the world's foremost experts Editorial Ten years ago, the Credit Suisse Research To mark its tenth anniversary, this year’s report Institute launched the first Global wealth report examines in more detail the underlying factors providing the most comprehensive and up-to- for the evolution of wealth levels and wealth dis- date survey of household wealth. Since then the tribution. The growth records of countries can be Global wealth report has become the standard quite different depending on whether wealth is reference point to monitor wealth growth across measured in US dollars or domestic currencies, countries and the extent to which wealth inequalities or in nominal or inflation-adjusted units. In the are widening or narrowing. longer term, the most successful countries are those that succeed in raising wealth as a multiple For the past decade, global wealth creation has of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) by addressing centered around China and the United States. institutional and financial-sector deficiencies. This year, the United States extended its un- This can result in a virtuous cycle in which broken spell of wealth gains, which began after higher wealth stimulates GDP growth, which in the global financial crisis in 2008. The United turn raises aggregate wealth. China, India and States also accounts for 40% of dollar million- Vietnam provide examples of this virtuous cycle aires worldwide and for 40% of those in the top in action. 1% of global wealth distribution. Wealth in China started the century from a lower base, but grew Second, the report looks at the evolution of at a much faster pace during the early years.
    [Show full text]
  • The World Distribution of Household Wealth
    The World Distribution of Household Wealth James B. Davies*, Susanna Sandstrom†, Anthony Shorrocks†, and Edward N. Wolff‡ July 2007 * Department of Economics University of Western Ontario London, Canada N6A 5C2 † UNU-WIDER Katajanokanlaituri 6 B 00160 Helsinki, Finland ‡ Department of Economics 19 West 4th Street 6th Floor New York University New York, NY 10003 USA Valuable comments and suggestions were received from participants at the WIDER project meeting on Personal Assets from a Global Perspective in May 2006 and at the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth Conference in Joensuu, Finland, in August 2006. Special thanks are due to Tony Atkinson, Brian Bucks, Markus Jäntti, and Branko Milanovic. Responsibility for all errors or omissions is our own. 1. Introduction Research on economic inequality – both within countries and between countries – is usually framed in terms of differences in income or consumption. In recent years a number of studies have extended this line of work to the global stage, by attempting to estimate the world distribution of income: see, for example Bourguignon and Morrison (2002), and Milanovic (2002, 2005). The findings document the very high disparity of living standards amongst the world’s citizens, but indicate that the rising inequality seen within many countries in recent decades has not led to a clear upward trend in global income inequality. The lack of trend is due to the rapid increase of incomes in certain developing countries, of which China is by far the most important. Alongside this work there has been growing recognition of the importance of other contributions to individual well-being, most especially health status, but also education, environment, personal security, and vulnerability to natural disasters.
    [Show full text]
  • When Aligned with Political Or Ethnic Divisions
    Unequal incomes in Asia a “particular worry” when aligned with political or ethnic divisions Income disparities undermine social and political stability, say experts Tokyo, 17 January 2006 – The unequal distribution of income, wealth, power and resources between peoples in different locations (“spatial disparities”) are a potential cause of conflict and can undermine social and political stability, according to forthcoming book published by United Nations University Press. “Spatial Disparities in Human Development” provides a series of perspectives from Asia – home to two thirds of the world’s poorest people – and describes how this crucial problem will impact on the Millennium Development Goals. The book is based on a research project launched by the World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University (UNU-WIDER). A worldwide group of experts analyzed evidence on the extent of spatial inequalities and the resulting book has been edited by Ravi Kanbur, an economics professor at Cornell University, New York, Anthony J. Venables, the Chief Economist in the UK Department for International Development (DFID) and a professor of Economics at the London School of Economics, and Guanghua Wan, a Senior Research Fellow at UNU-WIDER in Finland. The gaps in living standards within developing and transition economies are a growing source of concern. “The topic takes on added significance when spatial and regional divisions align with political and ethnic tensions to undermine social and political stability,” says Professor Anthony Shorrocks, the Director of UNU-WIDER, in the Foreword to the book. “Whatever the original source, there is a widespread perception that spatial disparities in human development have become more visible and that they are increasing over time,” he says.
    [Show full text]
  • The Global Wealth Report 2021
    June 2021 Research Institute Global wealth report 2021 Thought leadership from Credit Suisse and the world’s foremost experts Introduction Now in its twelfth year, I am proud to present to you the 2021 edition of the Credit Suisse Global Wealth Report. This report delivers a comprehensive analysis on available global household wealth, underpinned by unique insights from leading academics in the field, Anthony Shorrocks and James Davies. This year’s edition digs deeper into the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic and the response of policymakers on global wealth and its distribution. Mindful of the important wealth differences that have built over the last year, our report also offers perspectives and, indeed, encouraging prospects, for wealth accumulation throughout the global wealth pyramid as we look to a world beyond the pandemic. I hope you find the insights of this edition of the Global Wealth Report to be of particular value in what remain unprecedented times. António Horta-Osório Chairman of the Board of Directors Credit Suisse Group AG 2 02 Editorial 05 Global wealth levels 2020 17 Global wealth distribution 2020 27 Wealth outlook for 2020–25 35 Country experiences 36 Canada and the United States 38 China and India 40 France and the United Kingdom 42 Germany, Austria and Switzerland 44 Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden 46 Japan, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan (Chinese Taipei) 48 Australia and New Zealand 50 Nigeria and South Africa 52 Brazil, Chile and Mexico 54 Greece, Italy and Spain 56 About the authors 57 General disclaimer / important
    [Show full text]
  • Inequality and Injustice in Our Global Economy
    UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) WIDER Annual Lecture 9 The World is not Flat: Inequality and Injustice in our Global Economy Nancy Birdsall UNU-WIDER gratefully acknowledges sponsorship of the 2005 Annual Lecture by the Finnish Ministry for Foreign Affairs UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) A research and training centre of the United Nations University The Board of UNU-WIDER Francois Bourguignon Ronald Findlay Nora Lustig Ernest Aryeetey Deepak Nayyar, Chairperson Martti Hetemäki Vladimir Popov Ex Officio J. A. van Ginkel, Rector of UNU Anthony Shorrocks, Director of UNU-WIDER UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) was established by the United Nations University as its first research and training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland in 1985. The purpose of the Institute is to undertake applied research and policy analysis on structural changes affecting the developing and transitional economies, to provide a forum for the advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable and environmentally sustainable growth, and to promote capacity strengthening and training in the field of economic and social policy making. Its work is carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through networks of collaborating scholars and institutions around the world. UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) Katajanokanlaituri 6 B 00160 Helsinki, Finland Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2006 Camera-ready typescript prepared by Liisa Roponen at UNU-WIDER Printed at Hakapaino Oy, Helsinki, Finland: www.hakapaino.fi The views expressed in this publication are those of the author. Publication does not imply endorsement by the Institute or the United Nations University of any of the views expressed.
    [Show full text]
  • The Climate Change Challenge
    UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) WIDER Annual Lecture 11 The Climate Change Challenge Kemal Derviş In cooperation with the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). UNU-WIDER acknowledges the financial contributions to the research programme by the governments of Denmark (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Finland (Ministry for Foreign Affairs), Norway (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Sweden (Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency—Sida) and the United Kingdom (Department for International Development). UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) A research and training centre of the United Nations University The Board of UNU-WIDER Ernest Aryeetey François Bourguignon Ronald Findlay Ricardo Frenkel Martti Hetemäki Deepak Nayyar, Chairperson Vladimir Popov Ex Officio Konrad Osterwalder, Rector of UNU Anthony F. Shorrocks, Director of UNU-WIDER UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) was established by United Nations University as its first research and training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland in 1985. The purpose of UNU-WIDER is to undertake applied research and policy analysis on structural changes affecting the developing and transitional economies, to provide a forum for the advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable and environmentally sustainable growth, and to promote capacity strengthening and training in the field of economic and social policy making. Its work is carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through networks of collaborating scholars and institutions around the world. UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) Katajanokanlaituri 6 B 00160 Helsinki, Finland Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2008 Camera-ready typescript prepared by Lisa Winkler at UNU-WIDER Cover design by Ara Kazandjian at UNU-WIDER.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Wealth Report 2014 G 45 28 23 14 38 04 03 Contents
    October 2014 Research Institute Thought leadership from Credit Suisse Research and the world’s foremost experts Global Wealth Report 2014 GLOBAL WEALTH REPORT 2014_2 Contents 03 Introduction 04 Global wealth 2014: The year in review 14 Global trends in household wealth 23 The global wealth pyramid 28 Wealth inequality 38 Household wealth in 2019 45 Wealth of nations 46 United States: Land of fortunes 47 Japan: Shock therapy 48 China: Star of the east 49 India: Emerging wealth 50 France: Uncertain prospects 51 United Kingdom: Advancing again 52 Switzerland: View from the top 53 Russia: Little sign of growth 54 Singapore: Robust and stable growth 55 Taiwan: Asian tiger 56 Indonesia: Impressive growth 57 Australia: No worries 58 South Africa: Signs of growth 59 Chile: Sustained growth 60 Canada: Rising wealth 61 Brazil: Slumbering giant 62 Authors 63 Imprint / Disclaimer ILASYEUNG ILASYEUNG S For more information, please contact: Richard Kersley, Head of Global Securities Products and Themes, Credit Suisse Investment Banking, [email protected] Markus Stierli, Head of Fundamental Micro Themes Research, Credit Suisse Private Banking & Wealth Management, PHOTO: ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/PACOPINILLOS, ISTOCKPHOTO.COM/ [email protected] R COVE GLOBAL WEALTH REPORT 2014_3 Introduction The Credit Suisse Global Wealth Report provides the most comprehensive and up-to-date source of information on global household wealth. Since 2010, we have collaborated with Professors Anthony Shorrocks and Jim Davies, recognized authorities on this topic, and the principal authors of “Personal Wealth from a Global Perspective,” Oxford University Press, 2008. Unlike other studies, this report measures and analyzes trends in wealth across nations from the very base of the “wealth pyramid” to the ultra-high net worth individuals.
    [Show full text]
  • WIDER Special Issue: Inequality and Poverty in China
    World Institute for Development Economics Research No. 2/2007 Why the Poorest Countries four distinct traps that between them account for the problem, each requiring a distinct remedy. I also argue are Failing and What Can that globalization, though it has been benign for the be Done About it majority of the developing world, is not working for the bottom billion and is not likely to do so. On by Paul Collier the contrary, it is liable to make them increasingly marginalized. So what are the key policy issues? One is that Africa has failed to develop jobs in export manufactures, the strategy that has been transforming Asia. Bangladesh has generated nearly three million jobs by exporting garments. If Kenya could do the same, it would be transformed. But Asia’s success has made it harder for Africa to get started. It will help by granting Africa better access to developed country markets. At present most of the G8 countries impose tariffs on imports of garments from Africa. There is one exception: the US. The US allows Kenya to export shirts duty-free into its market. Europe does not. Even the few African countries that are allowed duty-free access into Europe get blocked by absurd technical © Friedrich Stark / Das Fotoarchiv. / Still Pictures / Still Fotoarchiv. / Das Stark Friedrich © requirements: Lesotho sells thousands of shirts to America, but they do not satisfy the regulations of the European Union. As a result, over the last five years Africa’s garments exports to Europe have declined while increasing sevenfold to the US. The G8 could easily adopt a common set of rules for these African exports that would generate jobs across the region.
    [Show full text]
  • WIDER Annual Lecture 10 Global Patterns of Income and Health
    UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) WIDER Annual Lecture 10 Global Patterns of Income and Health: Facts, Interpretations, and Policies Angus Deaton UNU-WIDER gratefully acknowledges the financial contributions to the research programme by the governments of Denmark (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Finland (Ministry for Foreign Affairs), Norway (Royal Ministry of Foreign Affairs), Sweden (Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency—Sida), and the United Kingdom (Department for International Development). UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) A research and training centre of the United Nations University The Board of UNU-WIDER Ernest Aryeetey Francois Bourguignon Ronald Findlay Roberto Frenkel Martti Hetemäki Deepak Nayyar, Chairperson Vladimir Popov Ex Officio Hans van Ginkel, Rector of UNU Anthony Shorrocks, Director of UNU-WIDER UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) was established by the United Nations University as its first research and training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland in 1985. The purpose of the Institute is to undertake applied research and policy analysis on structural changes affecting the developing and transitional economies, to provide a forum for the advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable and environmentally sustainable growth, and to promote capacity strengthening and training in the field of economic and social policy making. Its work is carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and through networks of collaborating scholars and institutions around the world. www.wider.unu.edu [email protected] UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) Katajanokanlaituri 6 B 00160 Helsinki, Finland Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2007 Camera-ready typescript prepared by Lorraine Telfer-Taivainen at UNU-WIDER Printed at Hakapaino Oy, Helsinki, Finland: www.hakapaino.fi The views expressed in this publication are those of the authors.
    [Show full text]
  • The Meaning of Economic Development
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Nafziger, E. Wayne Working Paper From Seers to Sen: The meaning of economic development WIDER Research Paper, No. 2006/20 Provided in Cooperation with: United Nations University (UNU), World Institute for Development Economics Research (WIDER) Suggested Citation: Nafziger, E. Wayne (2006) : From Seers to Sen: The meaning of economic development, WIDER Research Paper, No. 2006/20, ISBN 929190788X, The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER), Helsinki This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/63321 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Research Paper No. 2006/20 From Seers to Sen The Meaning of Economic Development E.
    [Show full text]