Beyond Competition for Incorporation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Beyond Competition for Incorporation UC Berkeley Law and Economics Workshop Title Beyond Competition for Incorporation Permalink https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8dx735c2 Author Kamar, Ehud Publication Date 2005-10-01 eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library University of California BEYOND COMPETITION FOR INCORPORATIONS Ehud Kamar* October 2005 Forthcoming in the Georgetown Law Journal This Article documents and analyzes a powerful form of regulatory competi- tion — competition for investments — that has transformed national corpo- rate laws in the European Union in recent years. Unlike the competition for incorporations that shapes Delaware corporate law and, by some accounts, the corporate laws of other American states as well, competition for invest- ments sparks innovation in corporate law when firms cannot incorporate outside the jurisdiction in which they operate, and is designed to attract in- vestments in local businesses rather than incorporations by foreign busi- nesses. The high political payoffs that await successful participants in the competition for investments enable them to overcome opposition that could stifle competition for incorporations. And, together with the fact that no single jurisdiction in the European Union can dominate the market for in- vestments, these payoffs drive multiple jurisdictions, including large ones, to compete. Allowing firms to incorporate outside the jurisdiction in which they operate, as a recent series of European Court of Justice rulings re- quires, may or may not breed competition for incorporations. Either way, however, as long as the competition for investments does not lose its steam, the effect on firms will be quite the same. Judging from the reforms that the competition for investments has fueled so far, the effect will be positive. * Visiting Professor, New York University School of Law; Associate Professor, Uni- versity of Southern California Law School; [email protected]. I would like to thank Scott Altman, Jennifer Arlen, Oren Bar-Gill, Lily Batchelder, Stephen Choi, Guido Ferrarini, Ronald Garet, Elizabeth Garrett, Jeffrey Gordon, Gillian Hadfield, Ernst Hirsch Ballin, Marcel Kahan, Gregory Keating, Daniel Klerman, Marja Lutsep, Ruth Mason, Edward McCaffery, Arkadiusz Radwan, Brian Raphael, Nicolai Schwarz-Gondek, John Steines, Eric Talley, Mark Weinstein, and workshop participants at the Harvard Law School and Swiss Institute of Technology Conference on Corporate Lawmaking in the European Union held on October 29-30, 2004, the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Law and Economics Association, and the law schools of Fordham University, New York University, Southwest- ern University, University of Southern California, and University of Texas for helpful comments. TABLE OF CONTENTS Introduction .............................................................................................2 I. Competition for Investments.............................................................. 8 A. The Old Way: Tax Incentives .................................................. 8 B. The New Way: Corporate Law................................................ 11 II. The Incentives to Compete...............................................................27 A. Benefits .................................................................................. 28 1. Competition for Incorporations........................................ 28 2. Competition for Investments............................................. 31 B. Costs....................................................................................... 38 1. Competition for Incorporations........................................ 38 2. Competition for Investments.............................................45 III. Normative Implications................................................................. 49 A. Competition for Investments and Competition for Incorporations Compared..................................................... 50 1. Who Competes and How .................................................. 50 2. Firms Whose Costs of Incorporating Abroad Are Low .....53 3. Firms Whose Costs of Incorporating Abroad Are High ....54 B. The Effects of Firm Choice on the Competition for Investments ............................................................................57 1. The Incentives to Compete ................................................57 2. The Effects on Firms ......................................................... 62 3. Competition for Incorporations as a Complement............63 Conclusion............................................................................................. 64 INTRODUCTION The notion that jurisdictions may compete for incorporations by tailoring their corporate laws to the preferences of corporate decision- makers has long fascinated legal commentators. It is easy to see why. The competition paradigm provides a powerful analytical tool for evaluating the entire body of corporate law without needing to ponder the merits of every detail. All one needs to do is examine the prefer- ences of those who make incorporation decisions. As long as corporate decisionmakers prefer laws that maximize the value of the firm, jurisdictions will produce such laws. Nearly half a century of legal scholarship has produced scores of articles explaining state corporate laws in the United States as a 2 product of just such competition. The basic facts are undisputed. First, firms in the United States are free to incorporate in any one of fifty states and the District of Columbia regardless of where they conduct their business. Second, states introduce legal innovations and copy from each other. And third, the state that innovates and copies more than any other — Delaware — prospers by attracting the most incorporations. These facts leave no doubt that Delaware competes for incorporations. Commentators only disagree over whether other states also compete,1 and whether corporate decisionmakers push the compe- tition in a desirable direction.2 From here it is a small step to apply the same analysis to other parts of the world, with the European Union as a natural place to start.3 Only the European Union does not meet a necessary condition for a market of incorporations to evolve. Unlike American states, most member states in the European Union follow the so-called real-seat rule, which prevents companies operating in these member states from 1 Compare Marcel Kahan & Ehud Kamar, The Myth of State Competition in Corpo- rate Law, 55 Stan. L. Rev. 679 (2002) (arguing that no American state but Delaware is actively pursuing incorporations), Lucian Bebchuk & Assaf Hamdani, Vigorous Race or Leisurely Walk: Reconsidering the Debate on State Competition over Corporate Charter, 112 Yale L.J. 553 (2002) (same), Ronald Gilson, Presentation at the American Law Institute and the European Corporate Governance Institute Conference on Regulatory Competition and Subsidiarity in Corporate Governance in a Transatlantic Perspective, http://www.ecgi.org/ tcgd/launch/gilson_speech.php (Jul. 12, 2004) (same), Melvin Eisenberg, Presentation at the American Law Institute and the European Corporate Governance Institute Conference on Regulatory Competition and Subsidiarity in Corporate Governance in a Transatlantic Perspective, http://www.ecgi.org/tcgd/launch/eisenberg_speech.php (Jul. 12, 2004) (same), and Mark J. Roe, Delaware’s Competition, 117 Harv. L. Rev. 588 (2003) (arguing that Delaware’s real competition is the federal regulator), with Roberta Romano, Is Regulatory Competition a Problem or Irrelevant for Corporate Governance?, 21 Oxford Rev. Econ. Pol. 221 (2005) (arguing that all American states pursue incorporations). 2 Compare Roberta Romano, Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle, 1 J.L. Econ. & Org. 225 (1985) (arguing that competition produces efficient law), Daniel R. Fischel, The “Race to the Bottom” Revisited: Reflections on Recent Developments in Delaware’s Corporation Law, 76 Nw. U. L. Rev. 913 (1982) (same), Ralph K. Winter, Jr., Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation, 6 J. Legal Stud. 251 (1977) (same), with William L. Cary, Federalism and the Corporation: Reflections upon Delaware, 83 Yale L.J. 663 (1974), and Lucian Arye Bebchuk, Federalism and the Corporation: The Desirable Limits on State competition in Corporate Law, 105 Harv. L. Rev. 1435 (1992). 3 The theory of competition for incorporations has also been applied to Canadian provinces. See Jeffrey G. MacIntosh & Douglas Cumming, The Role of Interjurisdictional Competition in Shaping Canadian Corporate Law, 20 Int’l Rev. L. & Econ. 141 (2000); Ronald J. Daniels, Should Provinces Compete? The Case for a Competitive Corporate Law Market, 36 McGill L.J. 130 (1990). 3 incorporating abroad.4 If this rule were to change, commentators have argued, intense competition for incorporations would immediately follow.5 This moment of truth has arrived. In fact, it arrived several years ago, when the first in a series of decisions by the European Court of Justice required member states to recognize companies incorporated in other member states and to refrain from imposing local corporate law on them.6 Will the new freedom to choose where to incorporate unleash a fierce race among member states to win incorporations? Probably not. There is no reason to believe that European countries 4 See Eddy Wymeersch, The Transfer of the Company’s Seat in European Company Law, 40 Common Mkt. L. Rev. 661, 666-73 (2003) (reviewing legal barriers to incorporation abroad). 5 See Brian Cheffins,
Recommended publications
  • Public Plicy Brief 44
    PPB No.44 2/18/99 2:50 PM Page a1 The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Public Policy Brief The Asian Disease: Pl a u s i b l e Di a g n o s e s , Po s s i b l e Re m e d i e s Regulation of Cros s - B o r der Interbank Lending and Derivatives Tra d e Ma r tin Mayer No. 44, 1998 PPB No.44 2/18/99 2:50 PM Page 2 The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard Co l l e g e , founded in 1986, is an autonomous, inde- pendently endowed re s e a rch organization. It is n o n p a rtisan, open to the examination of diverse points of view, and dedicated to public servi c e . The Jerome Levy Economics Institute is publish - ing this proposal with the conviction that it rep r e - sents a constructive and positive contribution to the discussions and debates on the relevant policy issues. Neither the Institute’s Board of Governo r s nor its Advisory Board necessarily endorses the pr oposal in this issue. The Levy Institute believes in the potential for the study of economics to improve the human condi- tion. Through scholarship and economic forecast- ing it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. The present res e a r ch agenda includes such issues as financial instability, povert y, employment, pro b- lems associated with the distribution of income and wealth, and international trade and competitive- ness.
    [Show full text]
  • Tuesday July 30, 1996
    7±30±96 Tuesday Vol. 61 No. 147 July 30, 1996 Pages 39555±39838 federal register 1 II Federal Register / Vol. 61, No. 147 / Tuesday, July 30, 1996 SUBSCRIPTIONS AND COPIES PUBLIC Subscriptions: Paper or fiche 202±512±1800 FEDERAL REGISTER Published daily, Monday through Friday, Assistance with public subscriptions 512±1806 (not published on Saturdays, Sundays, or on official holidays), by General online information 202±512±1530 the Office of the Federal Register, National Archives and Records Administration, Washington, DC 20408, under the Federal Register Single copies/back copies: Act (49 Stat. 500, as amended; 44 U.S.C. Ch. 15) and the Paper or fiche 512±1800 regulations of the Administrative Committee of the Federal Register Assistance with public single copies 512±1803 (1 CFR Ch. I). Distribution is made only by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC FEDERAL AGENCIES 20402. Subscriptions: The Federal Register provides a uniform system for making Paper or fiche 523±5243 available to the public regulations and legal notices issued by Assistance with Federal agency subscriptions 523±5243 Federal agencies. These include Presidential proclamations and For other telephone numbers, see the Reader Aids section Executive Orders and Federal agency documents having general applicability and legal effect, documents required to be published at the end of this issue. by act of Congress and other Federal agency documents of public interest. Documents are on file for public inspection in the Office of the Federal Register the day before they are published, unless earlier filing is requested by the issuing agency.
    [Show full text]
  • The Reason Given for the UK's Decision to Float Sterling Was the Weight of International Short-Term Capital
    - Issue No. 181 No. 190, July 6, 1972 The Pound Afloat: The reason given for the U.K.'s decision to float sterling was the weight of international short-term capital movements which, despite concerted intervention from the Bank of England and European central banks, had necessitated massive sup­ port operations. The U.K. is anxious that the rate should quickly o.s move to a "realistic" level, at or around the old parity of %2. 40 - r,/, .• representing an effective 8% devaluation against the dollar. A w formal devaluation coupled with a wage freeze was urged by the :,I' Bank of England, but this would be politically embarrassing in the }t!IJ light of the U.K. Chancellor's repeated statements that the pound was "not at an unrealistic rate." The decision to float has been taken in spite of a danger that this may provoke an international or European monetary crisis. European markets tend to consider sterling as the dollar's first line of defense and, although the U.S. Treasury reaffirmed the Smithsonian Agreement, there are fears throughout Europe that pressure on the U.S. currency could disrupt the exchange rate re­ lationship established last December. On the Continent, the Dutch and Belgians have put forward a scheme for a joint float of Common Market currencies against the dollar. It will not easily be implemented, since speculation in the ex­ change markets has pushed the various EEC countries in different directions. The Germans have been under pressure to revalue, the Italians to devalue. Total opposition to a Community float is ex­ pected from France (this would sever the ties between the franc and gold), and the French also are adamant that Britain should re­ affirm its allegiance to the European monetary agreement and return to a fixed parity.
    [Show full text]
  • EUROPEAN BANICING INTEGRATION, TEN YEARS AFTER by 95/92/FIN * Professor of Banking and Finance, at INSEAD, Boulevard De Constanc
    EUROPEAN BANICING INTEGRATION, TEN YEARS AFTER by J. DERMINE 95/92/FIN * Professor of Banking and Finance, at INSEAD, Boulevard de Constance, 77305 Fontainebleau Codex, France. The author acknowledges financial support from INSEADs International Financial Services (IFS) programme. A working paper in the INSEAD Working Paper Series is intended as a means whereby a faculty researchers thoughts and findings may be communicated to interested readers. The paper should be considered preliminary in nature and may require revision. Printed at INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France EUROPEAN BANKING INTEGRATION, Ten Years After by Jean Dermine INSEAD F-77300 Fontainebleau, France October 1995 Revised and expanded version of a paper "Banking Industry in the ECs Internal Market" presented at a conference organized by the Sveriges Riksbank, Stockholm, November 1993. Forthcoming in European Financial Management. Abstract Ten year ago, the White Paper on the Completion of the Single Market announced the integration of European banking markets. The purpose of this essay is to identify four public issues that remain to be addressed. Home country control of international banks need to be complemented by host country control. The deposit guarantee schemes should be modified by rendering insured deposits "first order claim". A European authority is needed to ensure that banks do not exploit domestic rents to subsidize international activities. Finally, tax evasion is a fourth issue that remains to be addressed. At a meeting of the Council of Ministers held in Milan in 1985, the European Commission proposed a detailed timetable for the complete integration of European markets by January 1993. The aim was to dismantle the technological, regulatory and fiscal barriers which prevented the free flow of goods, capital and persons in the European Union.
    [Show full text]
  • The Real Scandal on Spain's Economic Scene
    Click here for Full Issue of EIR Volume 10, Number 10, March 15, 1983 ical environment of Spain today would appear to have other motivations than economic ones. A key to the apparent mystery may be the unusual serenity of the private banks. Indeed, it is now suspected that the entire operation against Rumasa was cooked up between the top private banks, in particular Banesto, Bilbao, Central, and Hispanoamericano, and Mariano Rubio, deputy governor of the Bank of Spain since 1965 and architect of the monetarist The real scandal on takeover of the country's finances. The profile of these top banks is highly interesting. Spain's economic scene Investments abroad-otherWise known as capital flight­ doubled in 1982 relative to 1981. Ninty-five percent of all overseas investment by banks was carried out by the top 10, by Katherine Kanter in Paris and after the United States-Miami, to be precise--Chile, Portugal, and Puerto Rico were the major recipients of Span­ When Spanish Finance Minister Miguel Boyer announced ish bankers' money. Investments increased most into Chile, Feb. 23, that due to non-cooperation on the part of the coun­ Puerto Rico, and Uruguary, and decreased in those countries try's largest private enterprise Rumasa S.A. (1.5 percent of struggling to industrialize in spite of their debt burden: Ar­ the GNP, 400 companies, 350,000 employees, 18 banks), gentina, Mexico, Brazil, and Peru. the government would probably have to send in auditors from Now, whatever one may think of the "ride' em cowboy" the central bank, the Bank of Spain, he provoked an imme­ entrepreneurial approach of Ruiz Mateus, the unescapable diate run on the Rumasa group's banks and a stir in the fact is that the Rumasa empire he controlled was the only :'1ternational financialpress demanding that Spain should be major economic and financial power in the country with some blacklisted on the credit markets.
    [Show full text]
  • A Map of the Financial Powers That Control P-2 Operations
    Click here for Full Issue of EIR Volume 8, Number 27, July 7, 1981 THE BANKING CONNECTIONS A map of the financial powers that control P-2 operations by David Goldman, Economics Editor Italian banking has been more international in character precedented opportunity to work through the Chinese than any other country's since the 14th century, and it is boxes of money-laundering fr om the inside outwards. not likely that a scandal implicating the board chairmen The most prominent financier of the Italian Socialist of every major Italian bank could fail to have worldwide Party, Calvi built the $6 billion Banco Ambrosiano as the ramifications. In fact, the publication of P-2 Grand core of a $20 billion international empire of merged and Master Licio Gelli's membership list sent shock waves associated companies. But Ambrosiano itself fits tightly out to Canada, Hong Kong, and the Caribbean. The into a larger series of boxes, a publicity-shy but powerful evidence now in the public domain comes very close to international syndicate known as "Inter-Alpha," among demonstrating the existence of a tightly coordinated the first. It includes West Germany's BHF-Bank, world network for dirty money transactions-a "Dope, France's Swiss-connected Credit Commercial, the Kre­ Inc.," as this publication first characterized it in an dietbank of Luxemburg, and the British combination of October 1978 feature. Williams and Glyns-Royal Bank of Scotland, the latter Not merely the major Italian banks, but Bank of about to merge with the Hongkong and Shanghai Bank. America and Chase Manhattan in the United States, the Ambrosiano is thoroughly Italian in character, but Hongkong and Shanghai Bank, and major institutions not in ownership.
    [Show full text]
  • Cross-Border Crime 1100
    Eumpooo Jour d ISSN 0928-1371 00 D0mó000 po0óoy o11 oooooreh v© _ 1 Ro 0 Cross-border crime 1100 MU9W puil M~ M° WY© European Journal ISSN 0928-137 on Criminal Policy and Research Volume 1 no 3 Cross-border crime 1993 Kugler Publications Amsterdam/New York RDC, The Hague Aims and scope Advisory board The European Journal on Criminal Policy dr. H.-J. Albrecht, Germany and Research is a platform for discussion Max Planck Institute and information exchange on the crime dr. A.E. Bottoms, Great Britain problem in Europe. Every issue University of Cambridge concentrates on one central topic in the prof. dr. N.E. Courakis, Greece criminal field, incorporating different University of Athens angles and perspectives. The editorial prof. dr. J.J.M. van Dijk, The Netherlands policy is on an invitational basis. The Ministry of Justice / University of Leiden journal is at the same time policy-based dr. C. Faugeron, France and scientific, it is both informative and Cesdip plural in its approach. The journal is of prof. K. Gdnczàl, Hungary interest to researchers, policy makers and Eótvós University other parties that are involved in the dr. M. Joutsen, Finland crime problem in Europe. Heuni The European Journal on Criminal prof. dr. H.-J. Kerner, Germany Policy and Research is published by University of Tubingen Kugler Publications in cooperation with prof. dr. M. Levi, Great Britain the Research and Documentation Centre University of Wales of the Ministry of Justice in The dr. P. Mayhew, Great Britain Netherlands. The RDC is, independently Home Office from the Ministry, responsible for the prof.
    [Show full text]
  • List of Articles
    List of Articles A Asbestos Boesky, Ivan A. H. Robins Asia Boland Amendment AAMCO AT&T Bond Fraud ABSCAM Australia Boycott Accounting Fraud Automobile Braithwaite, John Adelphia Communications Brazil Advance Fee Scam B Breast Implants Advertising Fraud Bad Checks Bre-X Africa Bait-and-Switch Bribery Age Discrimination Bakker, Jim and Tammy Brown Lung Agnew, Spiro T. Banco Ambrosiano Buffalo Creek Air Pollution Bank Fraud Bush, George H. W. Allied Chemical Bank of Credit and Commerce Bush, George W. Allied Irish Banks International Butcher Brothers American Civil War Bank Secrecy Act American Cyanamid Banker’s Trust C American Hospital Supply Bankruptcy Fraud Campaign Finance American Motors Barings Bank Canada American Revolution BASF Canadian Mining Scandals Ancient Mercantile Crime Baycol Capitalism Anderson, Jack Beech Aircraft Capone, Alphonse Anheuser-Busch Beech-Nut Nutrition Caribbean Islands Antitrust Bendectin Carl Karcher Enterprises Arab Nations Bendix Corporation Carnegie, Andrew Arbitrage Benson, Michael L. Carson, Rachel Archer Daniels Midland Better Business Bureaus Carter, James E. Argentina B. F. Goodrich Caveat Emptor Art Fraud Bid Rigging Celler-Kefauver Act Arthur Andersen Board of Directors Cendant xxv xxvi List of Articles Centennial Savings and Loan Cressey, Donald Federal Trade Commission Act Center for Science in the Public Crime Seriousness Felony Interest Criminal Facilitation Fertility Fraud Central America Critical Theory Fiduciary Fraud Challenger Disaster Cuba Film Recovery Systems Charity Fraud Cullen, Francis T. Financial Accounting Standards Check Kiting Currency Fraud Board Chem-Bio Cyberstalking Financial Crime Chevron Kingpin Statute China D Firestone Tires Cigarette Advertising Daisy Chains Fisher-Price Civil Forfeiture Daiwa Bank Fisse, Brent Class-Action Lawsuits Dalkon Shield Flaming Ferraris Clayton Antitrust Act Day Fines Food and Drug Administration Clean Air Act Debt Restructuring Fraud Ford Pinto Clean Water Act Defective Products Ford, Gerald R.
    [Show full text]
  • List of Marginable Otc Stocks1 List of Foreign
    LIST OF MARGINABLE OTC STOCKS 1 AND LIST OF FOREIGN MARGIN STOCKS 2 AS OF November 10, 1997 The List of Marginable OTC Stocks and the List of Foreign Margin Stocks are published quarterly by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (the Board). The List of Marginable OTC Stocks is composed of stocks traded in the United States over-the-counter (OTC) that have been determined by the Board to be subject to margin requirements as of November 10, 1997, pursuant to Section 207.6 of Federal Reserve Regulation G, ‘‘Securities Credit by Persons Other Than Banks, Brokers, or Dealers,’’ Section 220.17 of Regulation T, ‘‘Credit by Brokers and Dealers,’’ and Section 221.7 of Regulation U, ‘‘Credit by Banks for the Purpose of Purchasing or Carrying Margin Stocks.’’ It also includes all OTC stocks designated as National Market System (NMS) securities. Additional NMS securities may be added in the interim between Board quarterly publications; these securities are immediately marginable upon designation as NMS securities. The names of these securities are available at the National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc. and at the Securities and Exchange Commission. This List supersedes the previous List of Marginable OTC Stocks published effective August 11, 1997. The List of Foreign Margin Stocks is composed of foreign equity securities that have met the Board’s eligibility criteria, pursuant to Regulation T, Section 220.17. These foreign equity securities are eligible for margin treatment at broker–dealers on the same basis as domestic margin securities. This list supersedes the previous List of Foreign Margin Stocks published effective August 11, 1997.
    [Show full text]
  • Foreign Creditor Rights: Recognition of Foreign Bankruptcy Adjudications in the United States and the Republic of Singapore
    FOREIGN CREDITOR RIGHTS: RECOGNITION OF FOREIGN BANKRUPTCY ADJUDICATIONS IN THE UNITED STATES AND THE REPUBLIC OF SINGAPORE MARK GROSS* As United States businesses increase sales and investments in de- veloping nations such as Singapore, creditor claims are sure to follow.' Because of this expected rise in lender claims, it is increasingly impor- tant to comprehend the reliability of creditor claim enforcement. This paper is an attempt to respond to the increasing value of trade between Singapore and other nations by providing a review of creditor claim enforcement in Singapore. The following analysis is primarily limited to foreign creditor rights within the bankruptcy context. A discussion of the rights of foreign creditors in the United States is also presented to enhance the reader's understanding of foreign creditor rights in Singapore. There should be little question that Singapore is worthy of this attention. As one of the "four tigers," Singapore is a major economic force in Asia.2 The Port of Singapore is one of the world's busiest, handling 102 million freight tons in 1982.1 Singapore's prosperity de- rives from its role as a gateway for Southeast Asia, its growing manu- facturing and services industries, and its position as a major financial center." The economy's shift to manufacturing, spurred by a govern- ment industrialization program in 1961, 5 has continued as rising labor costs in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan have forced those nations' industri- alists to look elsewhere for manufacturing facilities.' United States * J.D., University of Pennsylvania, 1990, B.A. Dartmouth College, 1985. 1 See Wawro, Enforcing Creditors' Claims Abroad: The Basics, L.A.
    [Show full text]
  • International Coordination of Financial Supervision Why Has It Grown? Will It Be Sustained?
    International Coordination of Financial Supervision Why has it grown? Will it be sustained? Richard J. Herring [email protected] Wharton School Managing Global Financial Risks: Shifting Sands and Shock Waves 22nd Annual Financial Markets Conference Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta May 8, 2017 1 Overview Why has it grown? —Avoidance of negative externalities —Achieving positive externalities —Given these externalities what factors make cooperation more likely? How did these factors affect the growth of coordination in international banking? (Basel Committee) —In Securities Regulation and Supervision? (IOSCO) —In Insurance Supervision? (IAIS) The aftermath of the Crisis: G-20 & FSB Future of international supervisory cooperation? 2 What’s the motivation for international cooperation? 3 Motives Avoidance or mitigation of negative externalities —Generally after shock has occurred —Sometimes to avoid an anticipated shocks • Usually more difficult to reach consensus regarding events that may happen Attempts to achieve positive externalities —Generally less powerful • Often considerable uncertainty re: benefits vs. costs 4 Factors that facilitate cooperation International cooperation is more likely 1. The smaller the group of countries that must agree 2. The broader the international consensus on policy objectives and potential gains from cooperation 3. The deeper the international agreement on the probable consequence of policy alternatives 4. The stronger the international infrastructure for decision making 5. The greater the domestic influence of experts who share a common understanding of a problem & its solution 5 The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Why cooperation began first & has been most ambitious in banking sector 1. Relatively small group of countries controlled 90% of cross-border banking activity 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Bull 2-2006.Pmd
    bulletin Newsletter from the EABH 2/2006 European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. Editorial Dear Colleagues, Money- everybody’s talking about, everybody wants it! In this 18th edition of the EABH Bulletin, we examine money and banking in a variety of forms- from the pre-banking world of a Mennonite set- tler in Russia who struggled to survive without the convenience of modern financial services, to banking in Central Africa in the interwar period; we inspect the creation of savings banks in Tsarist controlled Lithuania and look at the development of economic nationalism in Central East Europe in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. We also examine the magnificently simple financial inven- tion- the bond, which enabled cross-border money-lending, and we take a look at an informative anthology of Greek banknotes which trace the history of modern Greece. We also take a look at the marvellous architectural creations designed by Norman Forster, and dedicated to the housing of money. Although one normally associates money with a certain coldness and frigidness- it is seen as im- personal and without character- money has a lot to do with identity and belonging. Indeed, money is an essential motivation for people to live together in a social setting. While the basic functions of money are stability, measurement and exchange, money also has a cultural function. The ways people in a small town, city, country or pan-national political system handle (and mishandle) money offers a deep insight into cultural practices. This cultural character is related to the deep symbolism of money.
    [Show full text]