Did U.S. Agricultural Policy Lock Farmers Into Wheat? the Capitalization of Farm Policies Into Land Prices in the U.S and Canada

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Did U.S. Agricultural Policy Lock Farmers Into Wheat? the Capitalization of Farm Policies Into Land Prices in the U.S and Canada A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Alston, Lee J.; Rucker, Randal R.; Weidenmier, Marc D. Working Paper Did U.S. Agricultural Policy Lock Farmers into Wheat? The Capitalization of Farm Policies into Land Prices in the U.S and Canada Claremont Colleges Working Papers in Economics, No. 2000-27 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Claremont McKenna College Suggested Citation: Alston, Lee J.; Rucker, Randal R.; Weidenmier, Marc D. (2000) : Did U.S. Agricultural Policy Lock Farmers into Wheat? The Capitalization of Farm Policies into Land Prices in the U.S and Canada, Claremont Colleges Working Papers in Economics, No. 2000-27, Claremont McKenna College, Department of Economics, Claremont, CA This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/94625 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Claremont Colleges working papers in economics Claremont Graduate University • Claremont Institute for Economic Policy Studies • Claremont McKenna College • Drucker Graduate School of Management • Harvey Mudd College • Lowe Institute • Pitzer College • Pomona College • Scripps College Did U.S. Agricultural Policy Lock Farmers into Wheat? The Capitalization of Farm Policies into Land Prices in the U.S and Canada by Lee J. Alston Department of Economics and Political Science University of Illinois Research Associate, NBER Randal R. Rucker Department of Economics Montana State University and Marc D. Weidenmier Department of Economics Claremont McKenna College & Claremont Graduate University September 5, 2000 * Lee Alston and Peter Lindert initiated this project. We thank Lindert for his inights. For additional comments we are grateful to Frank Lewis, Marvin McInnis, and the participants at the NBER summer institute and a seminar at Victoria University in Wellington NZ. Lee Alston is grateful for financial support from the Earhart Foundation for the initial research for this project. 2 I. Introduction The twentieth century witnessed a array of government farm policies in Canada and the U.S. To the extent that the programs benefitted farmers the return to government programs would be capitalized into land values. The reasoning is straightforward. Any program designed to make farming more profitable raises the demand for all inputs into the subsidized farming activities. Of these, the input that is most inelastically supplied to the farm sector, usually land, will gain the largest percentage price gain. Since land is a durable asset, any expectation that the support policies (or other profit increasing activities) will continue will raise the purchase price of land. The initial landowners, rather than workers or prospective farmers or landowners, will pocket a large share of the gains. Conversely, a large share of any reduction in support will be translated into capital losses for current landowners. The capitalization effect is well understood though difficult to measure.1 The main obstacle to measuring the overall effects of farm programs on farm land prices is the difficulty of finding a sample, a laboratory experiment, in which the variables fluctuating most are farm policy and farm land values. In the usual time series it is hard to separate policy influences on land values from the effects of changes in technology, weather, demand, and transportation. This paper presents tests from the appropriate kind of sample, one dominated by variation in farm land values and farm policy. We follow the history of a strip of contiguous crop reporting districts in upper North Dakota and southwestern Manitoba where farmers initially concentrated heavily on wheat production. It is a region of fairly homogeneous climate, soil, technology, labor supply and capital supply, divided by an international border. To the extent that tax policies are relatively constant, major movements in farm policies should drive movements in land values. There are two possible reasons why we might not directly observe the capitalization effect in a ratio of land values from our sample: 1) Our approach assumes that crop mix on both sides of the border remains 1 See for example Schultze; Johnson (1984), pp. 25-28; Melichar (1979); Reinsel and Reinsal (1979); Doll and Widdows (1981); Melichar (1981); Castle and Hoch (1982); Scott (1983); Pope et al. (1979); Barry (1980) and Burt 3 the same throughout the period; and 2) farm policies on either side of the border could affect land values on the other side to the extent that either country can influence the world price. This is most likely to happen in response to U.S. agricultural policy with its emphasis on production controls through acreage restrictions. It is likely that these policies have an impact on world prices and that Canadian farmers could respond on two margins: intensive, i.e., higher yields and extensive, i.e., more acreage. The paper is organized as follows. In Section II we chronicle Canadian and U. S. wheat policy since World War I followed by a discussion of our data and empirical methodology in Section III. In Section IV we present our empirical results followed by (Section V) the implications of our preliminary results and our directions for further research. In Section VI we outline the tasks for a research assistant. We offer a conclusion in Section VII. II. Wheat Policy since World War I In this section we survey the U. S. and Canadian government policies that may have caused international differences in the value of wheat-growing prairie land. We abstract from world-market influences that are likely to have had the same effect on wheat prices in both countries. A. Canadian Wheat Policy2 Before the establishment of the Canadian Wheat Board as a monopsonist and monopolist in 1944, Canada did not directly intervene in the market for wheat, except during wartime and the depression years. On June 11, 1917, Canada established the Board of Grain Supervisors and gave it monopoly control of wheat. The Board was empowered to buy Canadian grain; to fix uniform national prices with regard to location, transportation costs, quality, and grade; and to resell grain to domestic millers and Allied purchasing agents (Fowke (1957) p. 169). Open market trading resumed on July 21, 1919 but closed again 10 days later to stem what was viewed as excessive speculative activity. On July 31, 1919 the Dominion government (1986). 2 For our historical treatment of Canadian wheat policy we relied on Fowke and Wilson (1957). For a more 4 established the Canadian Wheat Board and vested in it the power to buy and sell the 1919 crop. This one- year stop-gap organization went out of operation in August 1920. Because it was temporary in both intent and fact, we doubt that landowners significantly capitalized its perceived benefits into land values. The return to open market trading coincided with a sharp decline in the prices of wheat. Although there was no causal link between the cessation of the first Wheat Board and the wheat price drop, farmers argued strongly against free markets. They associated the high wartime and immediate postwar prices with monopoly marketing. As a result, farmers in the major wheat-producing provinces formed voluntary cooperatives to market their grain. The pools were organized in 1923 and 1924 and incorporated provincially. They operated in concert through a jointly owned Central Selling Agency that was incorporated in 1924 by the federal government. The pools marketed 37% of the 1924-25 crop and then slightly more than half the crop for the next five years. (Fowke (1957), p. 235). The motivation for the pools was a belief that speculators were reaping profits at the expense of producers. Particularly irksome to farmers was the fact that grain prices varied over the year. While the pools guaranteed farmers the same price throughout any season they could not suppress inter-seasonal price variation.3 Hindsight, suggests that the pools did as well as could have been expected, though they could not bring back the peak prices of the war years. The impact of the pools on land values depends on how firmly farmers believed pooling would solve intra- and inter-seasonal price variation and on whether they went through a bubble cycle in expecting a later discussion of the Canadian Wheat Board, see Schmitz and McCalla (1979) and McCalla and Schmitz (1979). 3 Debate broke out between the pools and the Winnipeg Wheat Exchange over who paid farmers higher prices. The evidence that exists is inconclusive (Levine, (1987), pp. 60-62). 5 return to wartime values.4 If they correctly perceived the pools as just a seasonal stabilizer, the net benefits would have been very small. As such we do not anticipate finding a measurable effect on farm values in the 1920s. Also small, we suspect, were the effects of the subsidization of credit through the Canadian Farm Loan Act of 1927. The provincial pools went bankrupt in 1931. In 1929 the Central Selling Agency overestimated the final market price of wheat and as a result made initial payments to farmers that exceeded the final prices received.
Recommended publications
  • CONGRESSIONAL RECORD-SENAT:M SENATE
    • 1934 _CONGRESSIONAL RECORD-SENAT:m 1039 Societies, representing upward of 100,000 men, against House Hale Lonergan Pittman Thomas, Utah Harrison McAdoo Pope Thompson bill 5978 relating to birth control; to the Committee on the Hastings McCarran Reynolds Townsend Judiciary. Hatch McGlll Robinson, Ark. Trammell Hatfield McKellar Robinson, Ind: Tydings 1707. Also, petition of Philip and Felicia Kornreich and Hayden McNary Russell Vandenberg 46 other residents of Paterson, N.J., against the passage <>f Johnson Murphy Schall VanNuys the Tugwell bill; to the Committee on Interstate and For­ Kean Neely Sheppard Wagner Keyes Norris Shipstead Walcott eign Commerce. King Nye Smith Walsh 1708. By Mr. SNELL: Petition of citizens of Canton, N.Y., La Follette O'Mahoney Steiwer Wheeler protesting against war preparations of the United States; to Lewis Overton Stephens White the Committee on Appropriations. Logan Patterson Thomas, Okla. 1709. By Mr. SUTPHIN: Petition of West End Parent­ Mr. FESS. I desire to announce that the senior Senator Teachers Association, endorsing the principles enunciated in from Rhode Island [Mr. METCALF], the junior Senator from the proposed revision of the present Federal Food and Drug Rhode Island [Mr. HEBERT], the Senator from South Da­ Act; to the Committee on Agriculture. kota [Mr. NORBECK], and the Senator from Pennsylvania [Mr. REED] are necessarily absent from the Senate. Mr. LEWIS. I desire to announce that the Senator from SENATE Louisiana [Mr. LoNG l is necessarily detained from the Senate. MONDAY, JANUARY 22,, 1934 The VICE PRESIDENT. Ninety-one Senators having (Legislative day of Thursday, Jan. 11, 1934) answered to their names, a quorum is present.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Farm Bills, National Agricultural Law Center
    A research project from The National Center for Agricultural Law Research and Information University of Arkansas • [email protected] • (479) 575-7646 Agricultural Act of 1949 Pub. L. No. 81-439, 63 Stat. 1051 (Originally cited as ch. 792, 63 Stat. 1051) The digitization of this Act was performed by the University of Arkansas’s National Agricultural Law Center under Cooperative Agreement No. 58-8201-4-197 with the United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Library. 6,;3 STAT.] 31sT CONG., 1ST SESS.~CHS. 791, 792-QCT. 31, 1949 1051 [CHAPTER 792J AN ACT OctobN 31, HH9 To stabilize prices of agricultural commodities. [H. R. 5.145] JPublic Law 439] Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representative" of the United States of America in Congress assembled, That this Act may Agricultural Act of be cited as the"Agricultural Act of 1949". D49. TITLE I-BASIC AGRICULTURAL COMMODITIES PrIce support to co· S>:c. 101. The Secretary of AgricuJture (hereinafter called the operators. "Secretary") is authorized and directed to make available throngh loans, purchases, or other operations, price support to cooperators for any crop of any basic agricultural commodity, if producers have not disapproved marketing quotas for such crop, at a level not in excess of 90 per centum of the parity priee of the commodity nor less than the level provided in subsections (a), (b), and (c) as follows: The level of support shall be not less (a) For tobacco (except as otherwise provided herein), corn, than the follow- "heat and rice, If the supply percentage
    [Show full text]
  • THE NEW DEAL, RURAL POVERTY, and the SOUTH by CHARLES
    THE NEW DEAL, RURAL POVERTY, AND THE SOUTH by CHARLES KENNETH ROBERTS KARI FREDERICKSON, COMMITTEE CHAIR GEORGE C. RABLE LISA LINDQUIST DORR ANDREW J. HUEBNER PETE DANIEL A DISSERTATION Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the Department of History in the Graduate School of The University of Alabama TUSCALOOSA, ALABAMA 2012 Copyright Charles Kenneth Roberts 2012 ALL RIGHTS RESERVED ii ABSTRACT This dissertation examines the political and administrative history of the Farm Security Administration (FSA) and its predecessors, the New Deal agency most directly associated with eliminating rural poverty. In addition, it studies and describes the efforts to remedy rural poverty, with an emphasis on farm security efforts (particularly rural rehabilitation) in the South, by looking at how the FSA’s actual operating programs (rural rehabilitation, tenant-purchase, and resettlement) functioned. This dissertation demonstrates that it is impossible to understand either element of the FSA’s history – its political and administrative history or the successes and failures of its operating programs – without understanding the other. The important sources include archival collections, congressional records, newspapers, and published reports. This dissertation demonstrates that New Deal liberal thought (and action) about how to best address rural poverty evolved considerably throughout the 1930s. Starting with a wide variety of tactics (including resettlement, community creation, land use reform, and more), by 1937, the New Deal’s approach to rural poverty had settled on the idea of rural rehabilitation, a system of supervised credit and associated ideas that came to profoundly influence the entire FSA program. This proved to be the only significant effort in the New Deal to solve the problems of rural poverty.
    [Show full text]
  • Processed Egg Products Antitrust Litigation
    Case 2:08-md-02002-GP Document 748 Filed 10/05/12 Page 1 of 224 IN THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA IN RE: PROCESSED EGG PRODUCTS ANTITRUST LITIGATION ______________________________________ MDL No. 2002 THIS DOCUMENT APPLIES TO: 08-MD-02002 ALL ACTIONS DEFENDANTS’ STATEMENT OF LAW SUBMITTED PURSUANT TO CASE MANAGEMENT ORDER NO. 19 Case 2:08-md-02002-GP Document 748 Filed 10/05/12 Page 2 of 224 TABLE OF CONTENTS Table of Authorities .....................................................................................................................xi I. Introduction ....................................................................................................................... 1 II. Federal Agricultural Cooperative Immunity Defenses ..................................................... 4 A. Overview ............................................................................................................... 4 1. Section 6 of The Clayton Act of 1914 ...................................................... 5 2. The Capper-Volstead Act of 1922 ............................................................ 7 3. The Cooperative Marketing Act of 1926 .................................................. 9 B. Capper-Volstead Decisions of the United States Supreme Court, U.S. Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit, and Third Circuit District Courts ..................................................................................................... 10 C. Structural Requirements for Capper-Volstead Immunity
    [Show full text]
  • A History of Information in Interwar Agricultural Economics Thomas Delcey, Guillaume Noblet
    ”The Eyes and Ears of the Agricultural Markets”: A History of Information in Interwar Agricultural Economics Thomas Delcey, Guillaume Noblet To cite this version: Thomas Delcey, Guillaume Noblet. ”The Eyes and Ears of the Agricultural Markets”: A History of Information in Interwar Agricultural Economics. 2021. hal-03227973 HAL Id: hal-03227973 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-03227973 Preprint submitted on 17 May 2021 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. ”The Eyes and Ears of the Agricultural Markets”∗ A History of Information in Interwar Agricultural Economics Delcey, Thomas† Noblet, Guillaume‡ May 2021 Abstract This article offers a historical analysis of the contributions of U.S. interwar agri- cultural economics to the economics of information. Concerned with improving the circulation of information on agricultural markets, agricultural economists an- alyzed the relationship between agents’ information and the behavior of prices on agricultural commodity exchanges, thus anticipating modern debates on informa- tional efficiency. We show that these debates were part of a more general context of agricultural market reform led by the U.S. administration to improve the pro- duction and diffusion of economic information. We argue that such reforms were a prerequisite for theoretical discussions on information, and established institutional tools that are still active today, such as the USDA market news service.
    [Show full text]
  • Manipulation of Commodity Futures Prices-The Unprosecutable Crime
    Manipulation of Commodity Futures Prices-The Unprosecutable Crime Jerry W. Markhamt The commodity futures market has been beset by large-scale market manipulations since its beginning. This article chronicles these manipulations to show that they threaten the economy and to demonstrate that all attempts to stop these manipulations have failed. Many commentators suggest that a redefinition of "manipulation" is the solution. Markham argues that enforcement of a redefined notion of manipulation would be inefficient and costly, and would ultimately be no more successful than earlierefforts. Instead, Markham arguesfor a more active Commodity Futures Trading Commission empowered not only to prohibit certain activities which, broadly construed, constitute manipulation, but also to adopt affirmative regulations which will help maintain a 'fair and orderly market." This more powerful Commission would require more resources than the current CFTC, but Markham argues that the additionalcost would be more than offset by the increasedefficiencies of reduced market manipulation. Introduction ......................................... 282 I. Historical Manipulation in the Commodity Futures Markets ..... 285 A. The Growth of Commodity Futures Trading and Its Role ..... 285 B. Early Manipulations .............................. 288 C. The FTC Study Reviews the Issue of Manipulation ......... 292 D. Early Legislation Fails to Prevent Manipulations .......... 298 II. The Commodity Exchange Act Proves to Be Ineffective in Dealing with M anipulation .................................. 313 A. The Commodity Exchange Authority Unsuccessfully Struggles with M anipulation ................................ 313 B. The 1968 Amendments Seek to Address the Manipulation Issue. 323 C. The 1968 Amendments Prove to be Ineffective ............ 328 tPartner, Rogers & Wells, Washington, D.C.; Adjunct Professor, Georgetown University Law Center; B.S. 1969, Western Kentucky University; J.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Historical Introduction to the Farm Credit System: Structure and Authorities, 1971 to Present
    Reprinted and Distributed with Permission of the Drake Journal of Agricultural Law HISTORICAL INTRODUCTION TO THE FARM CREDIT SYSTEM: STRUCTURE AND AUTHORITIES, 1971 TO PRESENT Richard L. Manner† I. Introduction .................................................................................................... 280 II. Snapshot of the System Under the Original 1971 Act .................................. 281 A. Overview of System Structure: The Traditional Twelve Farm Credit Districts ................................................................................. 281 B. Additional Organizational and Structural Aspects of the Banks and Associations ............................................................................... 286 C. Eligibility to Borrow .......................................................................... 288 D. Non-Loan Authorities ........................................................................ 289 E. Other Farm Credit System Institutions and Non-Farm Credit System Affiliates .............................................................................. 290 1. Service Organizations ................................................................. 290 2. The Farm Credit Councils ........................................................... 292 III. Restructuring of the System Under the Agricultural Credit Act of 1987 ..... 292 A. Structural Change under the 1987 Amendments ............................... 293 1. The Formation of the Farm Credit Banks ................................... 293 2. The Formation
    [Show full text]
  • FULL THESIS 19 September
    The United States Federal Government and the Making of Modern Futures Markets, 1920-1936 Rasheed KM Saleuddin Corpus Christi College September 2017 This dissertation is submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. i ii The Unites States Federal Government and the Making of Modern Futures Markets, 1920-36 Rasheed Saleuddin In 1921, 1924 and 1929-1934, markets for the future delivery of wheat went through periods of extreme volatility and/or significant depression, and in all three cases there were significant and long-lasting changes to both the institutional and regulatory framework of these Chicago- dominated grain markets. There was no real change after these key reforms until 1974, while indeed much of the original regulatory and market innovation remains. The result of the severe depression of 1921 was the Futures Trading Act of 1921. In 1924-25, the so-called ‘Cutten corner’ market turmoil was followed by three key institutional innovations brought about in 1926 by US federal government coercion of the grain futures trading industry in collusion with industry leaders. The Great Depression gave birth to the 1936 Commodity Exchange Act. This Act was based on research done by the government and/or with government-mandated evidence that essentially saw the small grain gambler as needing protection from the grain futures industry, and was pushed through by a coalition of farmers’ organisations and the agency responsible for the 1922 Act’s administration. The government demanded information that was begrudgingly provided, and the studies of this data formed the basis of a political and intellectual justification of the usefulness of futures markets to the marketing of farm products that influenced the Act of 1936 and – more importantly - continues to today.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 of 2 DOCUMENTS Commodity Futures Trading Commission FUTURES TRADING ACT of 1982 TITLE: FUTURES TRADING ACT of 1982 (PART 1) DO
    Page 1 1 of 2 DOCUMENTS Commodity Futures Trading Commission FUTURES TRADING ACT OF 1982 TITLE: FUTURES TRADING ACT OF 1982 (PART 1) DOCUMENT TYPE: HOUSE REPORT DOCUMENT NUMBER: 97-565 (PART 1) DATE: MAY 17, 1982 LEGISLATIVE HISTORY: FUTURES TRADING ACT OF 1982 97TH CONGRESS 2D Session HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES REPT. 97-565 Part 1 FUTURES TRADING ACT OF 1982 MAY 17, 1982. -- Ordered to be printed Mr. DE LA GARZA, from the Committee on Agriculture, submitted the following REPORT together with ADDITIONAL VIEWS AND SEPARATE VIEWS [To accompany H.R. 5447] [Including Congressional Budget Office cost estimate] The Committee on Agriculture, to whom was referred the bill (H.R. 5447), to extend the Commodity Exchange Act, and for other purposes, having considered the same, report favorably thereon with an amendment and recommend that the bill as amended do pass. See original document-page 1 Page 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Committee Amendment 4 Summary of H.R. 5447 25 Purpose and Need for the Legislation 36 I. Extension of Funding Authorization 36 II. CFTC/SEC Jurisdictional Accord 38 III. National Futures Association/User Fees 41 IV. Expanded Role for the States 44 V. Interagency Coordination 45 VI. Agricultural Options 47 VII. Regulatory Powers and Enforcement 47 (a) Extension of Registration Requirements 48 (b) Streamlining Registration Procedures 50 (c) Framework for Delegation of the Registration Function 52 (d) Enforcement 52 VIII. Remedies for Violations of the Act 54 (a) General 54 (b) Reparations 55 (c) Arbitration 56 (d) Private Rights of Action 56 IX. Commission Emergency Powers 57 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Chronological Landmarks in American Agriculture (AIB-425)
    A. 2 '/^i> 'è ^¿^ //?^{S United States i)] Department of ^"' Agriculture Chronological Economics Research Service Landmarks In Agriculture Information Bulletin American Number 425 Agriculture It's Easy To Order Another Copy! Just dial 1-800»999"6779. Toll free (in the United States and Canada). An other areas pïease dial 301-725-7937. Ask for Chronological Landmarks in American Agriculture (AIB-425). The cost is $11.00 per copy. For non-U.S. addresses (including Canada), add 25 percent. Charge your purchase to your VISA or MasterCard, or we can bill you. Or send a check or purchase order (made payable to ERS-NASS) to: ERS-NASS P.O. Box 1608 Rockville, MD 20849-1608. We'll fill your order by first-class mail. Revised version, Washington, DC November 1990 CHRONOLOGICAL LANDMARKS IN AMERICAN AGRICULTURE Compiled by Maryanna S. Smith and Dennis M, Roth INTRODUCTION This chronology lists major events in the history of U.S. agriculture. A source to which the reader may turn for additional information on the subject is included with most of the events. Generally, each source appears only once, although it may apply to more than one chronological citation. The reader interested in a particular subject can compile a short bibliography by consulting each citation for that subject. Key inventions, laws, changes in land policies, individuals, contributions, the development of institutions, and the introduction of new types of crops and livestock are included. There are also notes on all commissioners, secretaries of agriculture, and agencies established in response to new programs in the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Immunities of Cooperative Associations
    ANTITRUST IMMUNITIES OF COOPERATIVE ASSOCIATIONS JOHN HANNA* Cooperative associations other than agricultural are subject to the same rules on restraint of trade as other corporations.1 Agricultural cooperatives in their normal marketing and purchasing activities have nothing to fear from state antitrust legis- lation. Without any exemption in federal antitrust laws, the state and federal legislative approval of farm cooperatives, expressing a widespread public confidence in the utility of cooperative enterprise, would likely have induced the courts to conclude that the slight and incidental restraints on trade by agricultural associations in their normal operations are not unreasonable. To make this certain, agricul- tural producers' cooperatives are granted a degree of immunity by the Clayton Act, the Capper-Volstead Act, and the Robinson-Patman Act. This immunity is not ab- solute, but so long as the agricultural associations conduct themselves with some sense of responsibility and refrain from conspiring with non-agricultural interests, the antitrust laws need not be of much concern to those who formulate the policies of the associations. This .conclusion could have been and was reached by most students of agricultural cooperatives during the rapid expansion from 192o to X930, and requires no modification today. Farmers expressed their sense of economic insecurity during the latter part of the nineteenth century, and later, by enthusiastically aiding in the passage of state antitrust laws and the Sherman Act. They tried, sometimes successfully, to have their own organizations exempted from the penal provisions of these statutes. Where they were unsuccessful they often found that their first feeble attempts at coopera- tive action were held to be illegal, while the enlargement of business units con- tinued with only minor setbacks.2 Where they were successful the outcome in *A.B.
    [Show full text]
  • Federal Re Ulati N F the U~S~ D Arketin Stem
    Minnesota Economic FEDERAL RE ULATI N Regulation Monograph 4 F THE U~S~ D ARKETIN STEM Miscellaneous Report AD-MRm2338 Agricultural Experiment Station University of Minnesota 1985 FEDERAL REGULATION OF THE U.S. FOOD MARKETING SYSTEM Tim Burke and Dale C. Dahl Minnesota Economic Regulation Monograph #4 Minnesota Agricultural Experiment Station Miscellaneous Report AD-MR-2338 University of Minnesota St. Paul, Minnesota February 1985 FOREWORD This monograph is part of the Minnesota Economic Regulation Monograph series, a comprehensive survey of law pertaining to the production, processing and distribution of food and other farm comr modities in the United States. It outlines two types of regulations: (1) those designed to protect the health and safety of consumers and improve their knowledge about food purchasing; and (2) those that protect the farmer's product and input markets, particularly in terms of trade practices and bargaining power. Dale c. Dahl Project Leader CONTENTS Preface. vii Chapter 1. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND. 1 Development of American Food Laws in the Nineteenth Century 1 Evolution of the Major Federal Acts • 1 Federal Food and Drugs Act of 1906 • 2 Packers and Stockyards Act • 3 Fair Packaging and Labeling Act. 3 Notes to Chapter 1. 4 Chapter 2. CONSUMER-ORIENTED REGULATION • 7 Major Legislation • 7 Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act • 7 Structure of the Act. 7 Relevant Definitions. 7 General Provisions. 7 Special Provisions. 10 Fair Packaging and Labeling Act. 11 Basic Provisions. 12 Enforcement Authority • 13 Poison Prevention Packaging Act. 13 Inspection Acts • 14 Federal Meat Inspection Act. 14 Basic Provisions. 14 Personal Exemption. 15 Imported and Exported Meat.
    [Show full text]