<<

PARTY ADAPTATION, ELITE TRAINING, AND POLITICAL SELECTION IN REFORM-ERA

A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE AND THE COMMITTEE ON GRADUATE STUDIES OF STANFORD UNIVERSITY IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

Charlotte P. Lee June 2010

© 2010 by Charlotte Ping Lee. All Rights Reserved. Re-distributed by Stanford University under license with the author.

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution- Noncommercial 3.0 United States License. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/3.0/us/

This dissertation is online at: http://purl.stanford.edu/jn431dw0841

ii I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in opinion, it is fully adequate in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Jean Oi, Primary Adviser

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequate in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Beatriz Magaloni-Kerpel

I certify that I have read this dissertation and that, in my opinion, it is fully adequate in scope and quality as a dissertation for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Michael McFaul

Approved for the Stanford University Committee on Graduate Studies. Patricia J. Gumport, Vice Provost Graduate Education

This signature page was generated electronically upon submission of this dissertation in electronic format. An original signed hard copy of the signature page is on file in University Archives.

iii Abstract

How and why have seemingly outdated political organizations of the Chinese

Communist Party (CCP) persisted through China’s past three decades of economic liberalization and social transition? In answering this question, I focus on the CCP’s nationwide system of political training academies, or party schools, to piece together the story of these schools’ role within the party apparatus and subsequent adaptation to changed incentives and circumstances. By investigating the logic of party organization and examining sub-party actors, this dissertation seeks to address broader questions regarding how ruling parties in authoritarian regimes are able to generate incentives for both institutional continuity and adaptation.

During market reforms, CCP leadership has invested in reviving and updating party organizations of bureaucratic management. In the case of the party school system, party authorities have sought to adapt these core political organizations to a market context not by insulating them from market forces, but by linking organizational survival to market savvy. Central party authorities have induced adaptation by opening party schools to local and national market forces. This study thus uncovers a market-based path by which organizations within a Leninist party persist through – and even thrive on

– economic transformation. I draw on organizational theories of competition and redundancy to explain the logic of these developments – and resultant “party entrepreneurialism”.

Two sets of findings emerge from my research. First, the party school system in

China continues to be an important site of political control over individual bureaucrats.

My analysis of survey and career history data reveals that party school enrollment

iv increases the likelihood of attaining a higher administrative rank and more rapid

promotion up the career ladder. In the principal-agent relationships which suffuse

China’s hierarchically organized political system, the party must solve the problem of

how to select bureaucratic agents at all levels of the system. This selection problem

comes prior to the monitoring of agents and is particularly salient in the highly

competitive bureaucracy of the Chinese party-state. By employing a matching method on

large-N survey data and analyzing an original dataset of the career histories of central- level officials, I find that party school training constitutes a pipeline to high office.

Second, party schools have fulfilled this selection function while responding to the demands of multiple markets. These include the local and national markets for goods and services opened under the reforms of the past thirty years and a training market created by central party authorities. Party authorities have harnessed market forces in

order to generate incentives for traditionally closed party schools to turn outward for

income, innovative training content, and new partners. Content analysis of an original

dataset of Central Party School training syllabi from 1985 to 2007 reveals the extent of

change in party school training content. Findings from field visits to the party schools of

two provinces, one Special Economic Zone, and the Central Party School in

uncovers the means by which these organizational actors have leveraged the limited local

autonomy granted to them and become highly entrepreneurial. One result has been an

expansion in the diversity of educational and profit-making activities on party school

campuses, developments that both complement and conflict with the core function of

these schools as elite training grounds.

v These findings illustrate the balance that China’s ruling party has sought to strike between encouraging organizational reform while maintaining preexisting institutional arrangements for managing political elites. The “party entrepreneurialism” that has developed in the party school system has implications for central-local relations in China as well as strategies of organizational adaptation within the CCP. Market opportunities embed party schools more deeply in local economies, and this has the potential to strengthen the ties between schools and local constituents – at the risk of compromising school responsiveness to central dictates. At the same time, the marketization of cadre training has generated strong incentives for party schools to search actively for innovative solutions to challenges from party and non-party competitors. Over the past three decades of reform, party schools have proven to be nimble political and economic actors: school leaders have developed an entrepreneurial spirit, in the process retaining the relevance of their organizations within the party and profiting from the market-based turn that internal party reforms have taken.

vi Acknowledgements

When I began my graduate studies six years ago, I had little idea that the road to

producing a dissertation would be so delightfully peopled with teachers and friends, both old and new, who would inject much wisdom and encouragement into what is otherwise a long, wearying process. Along the way, I have become indebted to so many individuals

– at Stanford, in China, and from my alma mater, UC Berkeley – and each has contributed to my research and thinking in ways that are difficult to measure. I am grateful for the generosity of ideas and spirit that many mentors, friends, and family have bestowed on me these years.

Heartfelt thanks goes to my advisor, Jean Oi, whose energy, unflagging curiosity, and deep knowledge of Chinese politics have been an inspiration to me. I still remember feeling exhausted just watching Jean conduct one interview after another in the townships and villages where rural China has taken off, far from the glamour and resources of the big cities. Her formidable skills in the field and in the classroom will continue to shape my approach to research and teaching.

I also could not have completed this project without the encouragement of my two other dissertation readers, Beatriz Magaloni and Mike McFaul. Beatriz challenged me always with her questioning and thinking about how the China case fits into our understanding of authoritarian systems, and she did so while achieving an admirable work-life balance. I am grateful for Mike’s big questions and his amazing ability to support my work while handling calls from the “situation room.”

Special thanks go to Andy Walder for pushing my research in new directions and chairing my dissertation defense with humor and care. Alice Miller has also taught me a

vii great deal about how to put together a terrific class while teaching me volumes about the

intricacies of elite politics in China. I also thank her for bringing her expertise to the table during my dissertation defense. Although he was not on my dissertation committee,

I am also indebted to Larry Diamond for his mentorship over the years and admire his

ability to bridge the policy and scholarly worlds.

The process of writing this dissertation was also due in no small part to the

support of my colleagues at Stanford and beyond. I thank the members of my

dissertation writing group, Bethany Lacina, Jed Stiglitz, Luke Condra, and Roy Elis for

their gentle comments in the face of glaring flaws. Thanks also go to my

interdisciplinary writing group, including Daniel Kreiss, Johanne Eliacin, Rekha Balu,

and Zhanara Nauruzbayeva, for their fresh perspectives. I thank Leslie for her

critical spirit and introduction to the Berkeley graduate student community.

In the social sciences at Stanford, I am fortunate to be surrounded by a collegial

circle of China researchers, and the brilliance of my colleagues continually inspires me.

Thanks go to Yuen Yuen Ang, David Barmore, Chris Chan, Joo-Youn Jung, Jen Haskell,

Xiaobin He, Xiaojun Li, Chao-Chi Lin, Paul Ling, Sung-Min Rho, Kay Shimizu, Mee

Smuthkalin, Jeremy Wallace, and Rachel Wu for their support and help throughout.

My deep thanks and appreciation go to each of my many friends and

acquaintances in China. They must remain anonymous here, but without their time and

insights this dissertation would not have been possible. I consider myself fortunate to

have met so many Chinese officials, teachers, and students who were willing to share

their experiences and, in so doing, illuminate some of the challenges and solutions

devised within their complex political system.

viii In a field where the data collection challenges are daunting, I am grateful for the research assistance of Kiki, Chelsea, Haihui, Shaorong, Xiaoya, and Zhaofen.

My research would not have been possible with without financial and administrative support. The National Science Foundation and, at Stanford University, the

Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies and Center for East Asian Studies provided grants to support my research and dissertation write-up. I also thank Chandelle

Arambula, Eliana Vasquez, and Tram Dinh for being oases of sanity.

Many personal friends and mentors provided words of wisdom, lent sympathetic ears, and opened their homes to me over the years, especially during my various trips spent crisscrossing China on a student budget. I thank Nancy Rogers for her far-sighted advice. I also thank my many dear friends from the 1997-98 UC EAP program in China.

Over the years, we have shared an abiding interest in China’s rise.

Finally, I am deeply grateful to my immediate and extended family members for their boundless generosity and support. When I was in the Peace Corps in Romania and typing graduate school applications on a borrowed computer, my parents, Ken and Jean

Lee, put the documents in the mail and got the whole process started. My brothers, Eric and Kennon, have been able problem-solvers along the way and constant sources of laughter. The entire “village” has kept me well-nourished and grounded all these years.

Finally, I am indebted to my partner, Nik Crain, who endured through countless midnight practice presentations and managed every crisis with aplomb. Without his patience, fortitude, and love, this project would be much diminished.

Charlotte Lee Cupertino, CA

ix Table of Contents

Acknowledgements vii

List of Tables xi

List of Figures xiii

Chapter 1: Introduction 1

Chapter 2: The Organizational Landscape 38

Chapter 3: Managing the Managers 64

Chapter 4: Fusing Party and Market 109

Chapter 5: Organizational Strategies of Adaptation 146

Chapter 6: Conclusion 186

Appendices

A. Number of party schools, by locale and national share of leading cadres 223

B. Note on sources and research methods 224

C. City Z training allocations, 2008 228

D. PSM descriptive statistics and robustness tests 230

E. Central Party School Young Cadre Training Classes descriptive data 235

F. International partnerships, central and provincial-level party schools 238

G. Categories for coding training syllabi 240

References 242

x List of Tables

1.1 Turnover in party and state managers, 1988 to early 1990s 12

1.2 Turnover in Chinese party and state managers 13

2.1 Provincial-level party school leadership 49

2.2 City Z planned training classes, 2008, by type and enrollment levels 54

2.3 Percent increase, over previous year, in CPS Young Cadre trainees, 61 total leading cadres, and total CCP members, select years

2.4 CPS Young Cadre Training Class enrollment, 1980-2000 61

2.5 Highest educational attainment of cadres, by historical period 62

2.6 Educational attainment of leading cadres after 1982-84 reforms 62

3.1 The organization of public officials in China, 1998 70

3.2 Descriptive summary of cadre and general population 79

3.3 Probit regression results for propensity score estimation 82

3.4 Marginal effect for significant control variables 84

3.5 Total cadres in treated and control groups, by propensity score block 85

3.6 Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) 86 Enrollment in a non-degree party school training class

3.7 Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) 87 Party school degree

3.8 Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) 88 University degree

3.9 Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) 88 Party school training and university degree

3.10 Occupational categories of cadres, by rank 89

3.11 Cadres who do not experience promotion, 2000 and 1995 classes 96

xi 3.12 Career tracks of CPS trainees in stalled careers (1995 and 2000 classes) 97

3.13 Total trainees, by CPS Young Cadre Training Class 101

3.14 Current administrative rank, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni 103

3.15 Current administrative level, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni 103

3.16 Current occupation category, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni 104

3.17 Comparing average ages, by rank 105

4.1 Summary of local party school expense categories and income sources 120

4.2 Provincial-level party schools and administrative institutes 129

4.3 A selection of training bids, by locale and awardee 136

5.1 2001 Income and Expense Report, Province B’s CYL School 150

5.2 Local party school entrepreneurial activities 156

5.3 Provincial party school partnerships with Chinese universities 162

5.4 party school and administration institute international 164 partnerships

5.5 Central Party School training syllabi analyzed, by year 167

5.6 Comparison of CPS and provincial-level party school training content 179

xii List of Figures

2.1 Local party organs involved in cadre education 47

2.2 Government organs involved in civil servant and cadre education 47

3.1 Frequency of administrative rank, 2003 China GSS 80

3.2 Distribution of propensity scores for treated and control groups 84

3.3 Pre-match propensity score distribution 85

3.4 Post-match propensity score distribution 85

4.1 Central-level organizations of cadre training 122

4.2 Share of total training, by school type 137

4.3 Central Party School trainee volume, 1977-2000 139

4.4 Domestic training market entrants, by year and type of organization 141

5.1 CPS training content by category, percent of total training time (1985) 168

5.2 CPS training content by category, percent of total training time (2007) 168

5.3 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to orthodox theory 170

5.4 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to the theories of reform-era 171 leaders

5.5 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to party 172

5.6 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to party building 174

5.7 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to management 176

5.8 Percent of CPS training time dedicated to policy briefings 177

5.9 Percent of training class time dedicated to case studies 178

xiii Chapter 1 Introduction

Political institutions that constrain elected officials in democracies are often established in autocratic contexts to serve the dictator’s bid to stay in power. Such

institutions facilitate the ordering of state and society, extend the coercive capacity of the

ruler, and they do so across time and space. Designing, constructing, and maintaining

institutions of governance are vital to the state-building process, if not synonymous with

it. That institutions in authoritarian regimes often possess a complexity on par with their

democratic counterparts is not surprising, but the purpose(s) of these non-democratic

institutions are at all times conditioned by the political context of which they are a part,

i.e., to sustain the dictator’s continued rule. Given this core assumption, the task lays in

discerning the functions served by a particular authoritarian institution and, beyond this,

evaluating this institution’s capacity for coping with the uncertainty, the unforeseeable

circumstances, and contingencies that all rulers in power must eventually confront.

These matters of institutional design and adaptiveness are complicated by the “sunk

costs” that accompany the creation of any institution, by tradition and the inertia that may

resist pressures for change.

Elections, legislatures, and parties are among the most prominent and well-studied

examples of political institutions adopted by authoritarian leaders.1 The channels through

which they contribute to regime survival are several: by co-opting potential opposition

(Gandhi 2008b; Gandhi and Przeworski 2007; Lust-Okar 2006); managing elites in

opposition groups (Blaydes 2008; Lust-Oker 2005; Tezcur 2008); providing political

1 Surveys of the literature on the underlying logic for party formation include Magaloni and Kricheli (2010) and, on elections, Gandhi and Lust-Okar (2009).

1 information (Cox 2009); and limiting economic predation by the autocrat (Gandhi 2008a;

Wright 2004). More generally, institutions allow the dictator to make a credible

commitment to sharing power with supporters (Magaloni 2008). This solves a core

dilemma facing all dictators. In order to remain in power, the dictator must rely on some

base(s) of support, but these groups are unwilling to back a dictator who may, once in

power, renege on promises. To generate confidence in his decision to extend benefits to

those who provide loyal service, a dictator may create “power-sharing institutions” that

over time generate some confidence in a dictator’s willingness to abide by non-arbitrary

rules to the game.2

Parties are instrumental for solving this credible commitment problem. Single

ruling parties in particular allow the dictator to make credible commitments to loyalists

by promising access to locally-generated revenues or future privileges in exchange for

service in the present (Lazarev 2005; Lazarev 2007). One mechanism for this is the

allocation of party membership and positions; the privileges of party office present an

intertemporal solution to the dictator’s commitment problem. This present-service-for-

future-privileges arrangement has been tested empirically in the Soviet regime where the

party controlled all political, economic, and social mobility, but this monopoly is not a

necessary condition for the arrangement to remain credible. As the Chinese case attests,

the emergence of an economic elite that is separate from the party does not imply the end

of high demand for party office. Importantly, these institutions lengthen the regime’s

time horizon. Because of this expectation of regime durability, parties also structure

2 A dictator nonetheless possesses, in theory, the authority to abolish an institution at will, though the threat of revolt by dissenting elites and/or the general population presents one potential deterrent. It is also the case that institutions may, by design or over time, obtain their own authority, resources and legitimacy, all of which serve as bulwarks against arbitrary dissolution.

2 intra-elite conflict by offering elites the promise of “medium and long-term gains despite

immediate setbacks” (Brownlee 2007: 12). A party’s success at maintaining this

intertemporal bargain thus coincides with the party’s time horizon (or expectations of the

durability of its rule) and concomitant willingness to invest in development (Olson

1993).3

Within the menu of institutional choices facing a dictator, party creation helps the

dictator to solve several additional problems. Parties, unlike collective leadership under

military rule, generate strong incentives for party members to support the authoritarian

status quo because these party members and cadres depend on the party for rents (Geddes

2006).4 Even more, by dispersing authority over a broader political base, parties provide

a counterbalance to the threat of military coup (Geddes 2008). Parties are also guilty of

the “tragic brilliance” in which corruption and suboptimal policies are accepted by the

general population because of the party’s ability to maintain widespread patronage

networks (Diaz-Cayeros, Magaloni, and Weingast 2003). Studies have found that in

China, the narrower extension of party patronage to economic elites forges the credibility

that encourages private investment (Gehlbach and Keefer 2008).

While those who invest resources in party creation are engaging in several

tradeoffs – e.g., dispersing authority, investing limited resources in party organization

3 While party creation may mitigate this problem of incredible commitments, there are limits to this institutional strategy. Reforms in the USSR failed because CPSU authorities were unable to commit credibly to a long-term growth strategy. Instead, the party maintained discretion over whether or not to adhere to growth-promoting policies (Litwack 1991). 4 I use the term ‘cadre’ to refer to individuals who hold positions of authority – though not necessarily ranked positions – within the bureaucracies of a Leninist party-state. Lee (1991) spells out the evolution in this term, describing cadres as “people whose high level of political consciousness qualified them to assume responsibility for specific political tasks. In this original sense, cadres are the leaders, in contrast to the masses, who are the followers in a revolution. However, after the CCP became the ruling party, the meaning of cadre expanded to include all those who were paid from the state budget but not engaged in productive manual labor. Thus, the current Chinese concept of cadre includes two analytically distinct categories: the political elite and the functionaries staffing the huge party-state apparatus,” (p. 4).

3 rather than repression – this institutional choice ultimately enhances the durability of the regime. Party creation appears to be a successful institutional strategy: in the post-World

War II period, authoritarian regimes led by a single party have enjoyed long durations of

rule in comparison to authoritarian counterparts without a ruling party.5 Among the

institutions that a dictator may choose to establish or maintain, then, ruling parties are

perhaps the most critical for understanding questions of authoritarian resilience.

While acknowledging that parties serve these important functions of elite

management and mass mobilization, this project shifts the analytical focus to problems of

party organization. In reviewing the state of knowledge on one-party regimes, Magaloni

and Kricheli (2010) state that ruling parties serve two critical functions, “a bargaining function, whereby dictators use the party to bargain with elites and minimize potential threats to their stability, and a mobilizing function, whereby dictators use the party machine to mobilize mass support,” (pp. 124-5). In much of the existing literature, there

is less emphasis on drilling down into the party itself and asking questions of party

structure, the consequences of organizational design, and how these intermediate choices

lay the foundations for stable single-party rule. Rather than treating parties as monolithic

institutions, this project attempts to map a more interior terrain. Its point of departure and

focus is on variation in intra-party organization. In particular, this project will argue that

organizations located within the party contribute to solving an important selection

5 Among the authoritarian types identified by Geddes, single-party regimes have persisted for, on average 34 years, which compares favorably with the averages of 10 years for military and 18 years for personalist regimes. Regimes exhibiting characteristics of these ideal types, or hybrids, last the longest in her accounting. These averages span the period 1946 to 2000. See Geddes 2003, p. 78. Smith (2005) argues that this effect is due to the outliers of Mexico under PRI rule and the USSR, but Magaloni’s separate accounting, with its finer-grained breakdown of authoritarian regime types, supports the original Geddes (1999) finding. Brownlee (2007) also controls for economic, region, duration, and other institutional variables to find that single party regimes are significantly more likely to endure than other authoritarian regime types (pp. 30-32).

4 problem. To flesh out the contours of this problem first requires a detour through the organization – and organizational problems – of perhaps the most highly structured of single-party regimes, those led by Leninist parties.

Inside Lenin’s “organizational weapon”

Because of their emphasis on organization and hierarchy, Leninist party systems present an ideal case for probing the purposes, risks, and advantages of particular decisions in party-building. The revolutionary, and eventually totalitarian, aspirations that motivated the creation of these parties translated in practice to party organization that would facilitate the complete control of state and society.6 Lenin’s original conception

for the party was of an organization led by “professional revolutionaries” who were

promoted from within the “rank and file” membership.7 He wrote that “the only serious

organizational principle for the active workers of our movement should be the strictest

secrecy, the strictest selection of members, and the training of professional

revolutionaries.”8 In contradiction to egalitarian ideological commitments, the party

would be “an organization which of necessity is centralized.”9 The bureaucratic centralism that Lenin’s party eventually embraced was done unapologetically (Wolfe

6 See Lenin’s 1902 essay “What is to be Done? Burning Questions of Our Movement” (Lenin 1964: 347- 529). Nearly two decades later, in his 1918 essay “The Chief Task of our Day,” he calls for the Bolsheviks to learn from the German model, which he saw as driven by “principle[s] of discipline, organization, harmonious cooperation on the basis of modern machine industry, and strict accounting and control.” Party control of the media and cultural expression is discussed in Lenin’s “The Party Organization and Party Literature,” (Tucker 1975: 148-152). 7 “What is to be Done?” (Tucker 1975: 75-77). 8 Ibid., p. 90. 9 Ibid., p. 86.

5 1984: 24-26, 192-95).10 In conceptualizing the party he was to lead, Lenin was also

aware of the importance of flexibility in political organization. As he wrote during the

first years of the twentieth century,

It would be a grievous error indeed to build the Party organization in anticipation only of outbreaks and street fighting, or only upon the ‘forward march of the drab everyday struggle.’ We must always conduct our everyday work and always be prepared for every situation.11

The Communist Party of the Soviet Union became the organizational embodiment of the pragmatic recommendations bound up in Lenin’s political vision. The party was to coordinate political functions, distribute economic power, and play the crucial centralizing role in the command economy and politically closed system that endured for over seventy years (Klugman 1989). In theory, it was also to possess the organizational flexibility to respond to unforeseen circumstances and contingencies.

Following the diffusion of Leninist principles across Russia’s borders and around the globe, these parties have become highly structured and complex organizations, with extensive functional differentiation of constituent parts.12 A range of sub-party

organizations play a supporting role in the maintenance of the party’s political authority:

propaganda bureaus, party personnel departments, courts, unions and other mass

10 In his early theorizing about the organization of the party, Lenin held democratic practice to be a secondary concern, since “'broad democracy' in Party organisation, amidst the gloom of the autocracy and the domination of gendarmerie, is nothing more than a useless and harmful toy,” (Lenin 1964: 479). 11 Tucker, p. 110. 12 In his collected letters (Tucker 1975), Lenin expresses some antipathy toward the “bureaucratic bog” of Russia (“Letter of January 1922 to A.D. Tsiurupa”, pp. 717-18). His complaint was one of the impotence of the citizen in the face of bureaucratic authority: “The complete lack of rights of the people in relation to government officials and the complete absence of control over the privileged bureaucracy correspond to the backwardness of Russia and to its absolutism,” (“The Tasks of the Russian Social-Democrats, p. 10). While pointing out the obstacle of the bureaucracy, he is also pragmatic: “Bureaucratism cannot be ‘sent packing’ from a peasant country, cannot be ‘swept from the face of the earth.’ One can only reduce it by slow, stubborn effort,” (“Letter of May 1921 to M.F. Sokolov”, p. 714.

6 organizations, party schools, and the like. The central committee of a ruling communist party becomes the principal to these various organizational agents, and this relationship is mirrored at lower administrative levels in the system, forming overlapping chains of principal-agent relationships. This parallels the principal-agent relationship between higher-level cadres and their subordinates, for example the principal role played by a city party committee over agents in a county or township located within the city’s jurisdiction.

The pervasiveness of these hierarchical relationships within the political system, at both the individual and organizational levels, provides the structural basis for governance and the distribution of political power.

Hierarchical Leninist systems are characterized by a critical relationship that is often overlooked in general studies of parties in autocracies: party management of the bureaucracy. Party organization, specifically party integration with and dominance over the bureaucracy, constitutes a source of political power (Barnett and Vogel 1967;

Selznick 1960). As the most prominent example of an extant ruling party formally organized along Leninist lines, the maintains and reinforces its organization through party penetration of the bureaucracy.13

While there have been attempts to draw an analytical and empirical line between the party and bureaucracy in China (Zheng 1997), in practice the two political bodies remain intertwined.14 Existing work on the Chinese case characterizes the relationship as suffused with bargaining and negotiation (Lampton 1992; Lampton 1987; Naughton

13 Drawing on the cases of England and the city-state of Venice, Gonzalez de Lara et al. (2008) make the interesting argument that the possessors of administrative power, not the threat of citizen revolt, may constrain rulers. For autocrats, then, control over the bureaucracy and those segments of society with administrative capacity is a critical cooptation strategy. 14 E.g., officials who occupy party and government offices simultaneously, government funding of party bureaus, party and government training centers integrated on the same campus.

7 1992); a reflection of elite conflicts (Dittmer 1978); and, above all, distinguished by party

domination and coordination (Harding 1981; Li 1994; Schurmann 1970). In this sense,

the bureaucracy in China is not a “neutral layer” between the ruling party and the

governed but rather an instrument in the service of political power holders (Massey 1993).

At the individual-level foundations of this arrangement, who becomes a cadre is of fundamental and paramount importance. Since “the formation of cadres is a basic task

of communist organization,” (Selznick 1960: 19), it becomes vital for party authorities to

manage who may enter and move up the ranks within this vast bureaucratic apparatus. In

this sense, the party serves a function not accounted for in the literature: it presents an

organizational means to solve a political selection problem. This function is both

separate from and part of the elite bargaining function studied by other scholars. The

party is an organized means for selecting those who are most likely to advance party

goals. In the case of China, it is in the interest of CCP authorities to devise effective

instruments for controlling bureaucrats and party organs at various levels of

administration because disciplined party agents are more likely to implement party

policies, hence extending the scope of party rule over a hierarchically organized political

terrain. In light of the critical role played by those party institutions that control who

joins the party elite, this project will focus on party strategies of both bureaucratic

management and political control.

Through interlocking but functionally specific bureaucratic organizations, a

Leninist ruling party attempts to control several overlapping groups of key political actors:

party members, rank-and-file party and government cadres, and senior (leading) party

and government cadres. Controlling promotion to and within this latter group, the senior

8 cadre ranks, is a crucial arena for the party’s maintenance of “organizational health” (Nee

and Lian 1994). This is especially critical in a system as decentralized as China’s

(Landry 2003). Inability by higher-level authorities to manage party and government

reformers is tantamount to a loss of party authority. The collapse of the Soviet Union

reinforced for Chinese party authorities the danger in, among other things, a decline in

party discipline (Shambaugh 2008a; Shambaugh 2008b; Wang 2002; Xiao 2002).

Elite personnel decisions – and the selection processes this implies – are a

paramount responsibility of the party (Naughton and Yang 2004). Furthermore, authority

relations between party managers and their subordinates are dynamic. While these

relationships are moderated by the institutions that authorities use to monitor and control

subordinates and the flow of information between levels, they are subject to the dictates

of new generations of leaders and system wide shocks – such as the transition to a market

economy, technological change, new global balances of power, and shifting international

alliances.

Placing China in context: High growth, low bureaucratic exit

While the tasks of political elite selection and party organization must be

confronted in all single-party authoritarian regimes, the CCP faced particular

circumstances and challenges at the onset of reforms, as the Chinese state was “growing

out of the plan” (Naughton 2007: 92-93). Comparatively low bureaucratic turnover

during the post-Mao economic transition generated pressures for internal updating of

cadre administrative skills. Party leaders, beginning with Deng Xiaoping, realized the

need to engineer a bureaucratic transformation to meet the demands of a market transition,

9 but political constraints were such that another purging of party managers was not a

feasible policy option. The normalization of party politics in the aftermath of the

Cultural Revolution (1966-76) and the legitimacy wielded by the old revolutionary cadre generation limited the range of alternatives. At the same time, the demands of an assertive economic modernization program were straining the human resources of a political system designed to manage a command economy.

With the implementation of liberalizing economic and social reforms under Deng, the party faced a problem: Chinese leaders realized that the party comprised a high number of public managers with outdated and irrelevant skills. The rallying cry was to develop a “revolutionary, younger, more educated, and more technically specialized”

(geminghua, nianqinghua, zhishihua, zhuanyehua) cadre corps.15 There existed a cadre

class that suffered from “one high and two lows” – bureaucrats were, on average, too old

(i.e., their age was too high) while their education and professional skills were

insufficient (Lee 1983: 676).

This bureaucratic transformation was to take place in the context of

unprecedented economic development. Since the initiation of reforms in 1978, China’s

economy has undergone dramatic change in terms of growth and industrial development.

Official annual growth rates stand at 9.6 percent on average for the period 1978 to

15 See Manion (1985) for a discussion of the personnel policies resulting from these “four transformations” (si hua), Deng also wrote in an essay dated November 2, 1979, “But the problem we face is the shortage of younger, professionally competent cadres. Without them it will be impossible to carry out the program of modernization.” See Deng Xiaoping, “Senior cadres should take the lead in maintaining and enriching the party’s fine traditions,” available online at http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/dengxp/vol2/text/b1360.html, accessed 24 February 2010. This idea of well-trained and professionalized cadres leading the modernization drive was repeated in a speech before the Poliburo, where Deng’s opening remarks linked China’s economic development and political advancement with the “urgent need to discover, train, employ and promote a large number of younger cadres for socialist modernization, cadres who adhere to the Four Cardinal Principles and have professional knowledge.” See “On the reform of the system of party and state leadership,” available online at http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/dengxp/vol2/text/b1460.html, accessed 6 March 2010.

10 2007.16 Industrialization has also taken off in urban Special Economic Zones and through collective and “local state corporatist” strategies in the countryside (Liao, Pan, and Zeng 1999; Oi 1992; Oi 1998a). This authoritarian state-led development has challenged assumptions about the correlates of economic growth. Modernization theorists posit a positive, causal relationship between economic development and political liberalization, (Lipset 1981; Rostow 1960: Chapter 2), and this has found some support in more updated analyses of the correlates of democracy (Geddes 1999;

Przeworski et al. 2000). The economic miracle presented by contemporary China has a seemingly incongruous basis in a single-party authoritarian regime, which begs further examination of how the ruling CCP has remained relevant and maintained organizational discipline during this period of rapid and apparently successful economic liberalization.

One way to place the Chinese case in its comparative context is to contrast the problem of low administrative turnover in China with the transformations taking place in other communist party states such as the Soviet Union and Eastern Bloc countries of

Central and Eastern Europe. This is an imperfect comparison due to the simultaneous political and economic transitions that took place in Western communist party states, but in all cases bureaucratic transformation was a requirement for successful economic reforms. In each country, engineering a revolution in bureaucratic talent was also complicated by the lure of new market opportunities. As part of their emphasis on party control over all political, economic, and social activity, Leninist party-led systems traditionally rely on monopsonistic control by the party over labor markets.17 Over the

16 “Industrialization on track: report,” China Daily, 29 January 2007, http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/china/2007-01/29/content_794936.htm, accessed 20 December 2008. 17 I.e., the party was the sole buyer in a labor market comprising many sellers of political, managerial, and administrative talent.

11 course of market reforms, skilled labor that was formerly dependent on state entities for

upward mobility found new exit options in newly created non-state sectors. When

compounded with political reforms and, ultimately, revolutions such as those in Eastern

Europe and the Soviet Union, there was considerable turnover in the bureaucratic ranks.

This is observed in data from a survey of post-communist countries taken in 1992 and

1993.

Table 1.1 below presents rates of bureaucratic turnover, ranging from a low of approximately 25 percent in Russia to 51 percent in the Czech Republic by 1993.

Table 1.1: Turnover in party and state managers, 1988 to early 1990s

Percentage of individuals Percentage of individuals

in cadre positions in 1988 in cadre positions in 1988

who reported the same who reported the same

occupation in 1992 occupation in 1993 Country N Bulgaria 66.9 64.6 131 Czech Republic 58.7 49.0 208 Hungary 66.7 57.4 129 Poland 76.0 68.7 179 Russia 78.7 74.9 211 Slovakia 67.3 59.5 153 Source: Social Stratification in Eastern Europe after 1989: General Population Survey, 1993. I defined ‘party and state managers’ as individuals reporting occupations which fell in the ‘legislator and manager’ category of the survey (ISCO codes 1000 to 1319).

Unfortunately, this data does not capture whether communist party-era cadres opted for

non-party and -state sector professions over the course of transition or were ousted by

incoming political elites and forced to turn to private sector alternatives.

China, in comparison, realized much lower rates of bureaucratic turnover during

its reform period despite the option for cadres with managerial experience or connections

to “jump into the sea” (xia hai) of capitalism. Table 1.2 below summarizes occupational

change among cadres from 1988 to the early 1990s as well as change from the onset of

reforms in 1978 to the early 1990s.

12 Table 1.2: Turnover in Chinese party and state managers …continued to report a …continued to report party or government a party or government In China, rank in 1992 rank in 1993 N Percentage of individuals in cadre 85.8 84.2 183 positions in 1978 who… Percentage of individuals in cadre 93.7 92.7 381 positions in 1988 who… Source: China General Social Survey 2003. I defined ‘party and state managers’ as individuals responding to a survey question on administrative rank in 1988 and 1978 and reporting non-party or -state occupations in 1992 and 1993.

Even as the CCP withdrew from its monopoly on economic opportunity, exit by bureaucrats to the private sector was rare. Turnover from 1978 to 1992 and from 1988 to

1992 was due entirely to retirement.18 Only one cadre reported joining the private sector during the period between 1978 and 1993; the rest was due to retirement. This pattern was repeated in the cadre population from 1988 to 1993, with only two individuals reporting private sector occupations by 1993 and the remainder leaving the cadre ranks due to retirement.19 These patterns may be explained by the particular fiscal incentives in place for cadres to stay in the system and realize benefits from profit-sharing contracts with party authorities and/or party-sanctioned extrabudgetary revenues (Ang 2009b;

Solnick 1998: Chapter 7). Such high retention rates may bode well as an indicator of party legitimacy, but this low turnover pattern has leaders with the problem of

how to retrain the administrative class to cope with the implementation and management

of economic and social reforms.20

18 This is 26 and 24 individual retirees, respectively. 19 This was 28 retirees in 1978 and 26 retirees in 1988, respectively. 20 One possibility was recruiting those with relevant management skills from the newly-created private sector. Scholars have examined how the party has attempted to absorb capitalists in the reform era (Dickson 2003; Tsai 2005; Zheng 2006). In 2000, Jiang Zemin’s “Three Represents” declaration that the party should represent the most productive forces in society (i.e., capitalists) reflects an important moment in party adaptation. Still, China does not yet have a “revolving door” between political office and the private sector, and entrepreneurs rarely become cadres (Interview 82, with a Central Party School professor, December 2007, and Interview 212, city organization department official, April 2010).

13 This project will address whether and how the party adjusts its organizations of

bureaucratic control and management to account for new elite selection criteria and the

increased decision-making autonomy that accompanies market reforms. In a Leninist system in particular, party organizations designed for a command-based economy and ideologically disciplined cadre corps would seem outdated and out of place in a decentralized market setting. This prompts several questions aimed at probing strategic choices made by an authoritarian ruling party: How does the party maintain the relevance of its political organizations during a period of economic transition? In the case of China, has the CCP replaced, reformed, or otherwise rejuvenated inner party organizations during the past three decades of economic growth? Throughout this transition, how does the party maintain control over the bureaucracy? In particular, how has the CCP sought to reshape and control its powerful cadre ranks in such a way that the party’s administrative capacity is not diminished?

The organizational puzzle posed by the case of the CCP is the persistence of seemingly anachronistic party organizations in the post-Mao period. The party needed to adjust its Leninist organizations to a market context in which institutions that centralize decision-making, such as the plan and the collective, have been replaced in large part by market mechanisms. The old standbys, Marxist-Leninist tenets and Mao’s writings, would not be enough to guide cadres’ administrative decisions in a market economy characterized by expanding trade, new forms of industrial production, and increasing global exchange. “For managers, entire careers spent learning how to maneuver through the planning bureaucracy to obtain scarce materials, to lower plan targets, to lobby for an

14 increased wage fund, and so on become irrelevant to success in a marketized context,”

(Hanson 1995: 312).

While the education system could take on some of this burden of re-educating the

administrative class, regular universities and schools might not promote entirely ‘correct’

ideas.21 In seeking to exert party control over individual bureaucrats, it would seem

logical for party officials to draw on existing organizational resources. An examination

of the CCP’s cadre training system reveals how the party has sought to retrain, manage,

and select administrators during a period characterized by dramatic economic growth,

low exit from the cadre ranks, and the need for skilled public managers.

Party schools, party reform

Party schools, the organizations responsible for the ideological training of revolutionary CCP cadres, serve as a well-situated case for examining how the party has generated incentives for party organizations to respond and adapt to the new demands of the post-Mao reform period. Numbering nearly 3,000 campuses nationwide, party schools constitute an extensive network of training academies for China’s political class

(Appendix A). Party schools are the anchor within a larger category of organizations charged with cadre training.22 The centrality of party schools within this organizational

landscape is due to their exclusivity, since they are officially reserved for party members and, within this population, those holding party office.23 These schools are a prime

21 See, for example, comments by a provincial party school teacher: “Ideological training must be preserved (baozhang). You can’t have liberal-minded (ziyou zhuyi) university teachers teaching cadres, this task can’t be divided [between institutions],” Interview 211, May 2008. 22 This includes cadre schools located in party organs such as SOEs, socialism schools, and communist youth league schools. At one time, the total number of cadre training organizations numbered over 11,000 (Central Party School yearbook 1985; Shambaugh 2008). 23 Party schools such as those located within universities are also tasked with training party activists.

15 example of Leninist party organizations that would appear incompatible with a market

economy and its accompanying social context. Yet, economic reforms and

modernization in China have brought into focus the need for new administrative capacity

within the bureaucracy of the party-state, and reforms in cadre training would be one way

to meet these demands, however unclear the path to realizing these objectives.

I argue that by altering incentives while leaving Leninist party organization intact,

the CCP has managed in the post-Mao period to induce organizational adaptation that has

bridged, however incompletely, the disjuncture between new realities and prior institutional arrangements. As the following analysis of party schools will demonstrate, this adaptation is a result of deliberate marketization by central party authorities and the introduction of organizational competition, or redundancy, to the system. Before diving into the logic behind these changes, I first explore in more depth why party schools constitute key sites for understanding the mix of organizational continuity and adaptiveness observed in the CCP.

Placing party schools in context: Changing forms of political control

It is not the case that all institutions of political control within the party have remained as robust schools during the reform period. In this sense, the story of party school survival provides important clues regarding internal processes of party reform. The resilience of party schools, and the criticality of cadre training for China’s

transition, stands in contrast to the waning of other key institutions of political control,

16 i.e., political campaigns (yundong).24 The relative decline of campaigns in the economic transition period highlights the centrally-directed nature of organizational change and the capacity of central party leaders to shape the geography of political institutions in accordance with new preferences and realities. Campaigns, which were most effective during the “mobilizational phase” of the party, have waned in centrality as the party completes its transition to an “institutionalization phase” (Li and Bachman 1989: 91; Li and White 1988).

In the past, the staging of periodic political campaigns, as a form of “internal remedialism” (Harding 1981), had been a powerful means for the CCP to communicate

“policy winds” and shape the actions of party members, bureaucrats, and citizens.

Campaigns entailed an intensification of activity in order to meet goals that were often economically and politically transformative in intent. Such mass mobilization served several functions: political socialization, policy implementation, and as a way to realign party ranks (Zheng 1997: 153-158). Individual performance during campaigns – as indications of political intelligence and ability to meet campaign goals – factored into the career prospects of political leaders (Bo 2002). During the Mao era, political mobilization requiring broad public participation and demonstrations of party loyalty by bureaucrats created a tension between mass unrest and party control, but this has historically been resolved in favor of party authority (Townsend 1969). Selznick likewise views Soviet campaigns through a cynical lens, arguing that mass mobilization was a tool of elite control, deployed to manipulate an “unstructured” and “alienated” population that has been “absorbed into the organization” (Selznick 1960: 288-9). In the

24 Cell (1977) defines a campaign as “organized mobilization of collective action aimed at transforming thought patterns, class/power relationships and/or economic institutions and productivity (p. 7). For a list of campaigns under Mao, see Cell, Appendices 1-3.

17 end, despite the intense levels of organizational activity required by political campaigns,

scholars have found that this political tactic did little to realize the goal of genuine

attitude transformation (Whyte 1974).

Chinese citizens exhausted by the seemingly endless campaigns under Mao found relief when Deng rose to power, though there remained the reflexive deployment of a nationwide anti-bureaucratic campaign in 1977 to unify the bureaucracy in the wake of the (Morgan 1981). In 1979, Deng called an end to reliance on political campaigns and exhorted comrades to turn instead to the tasks of economic development:

In addition to economic work, the Party committees perform many other kinds of work, but many issues involve economic affairs. .... Instead of conducting campaigns, such endeavors should be accomplished through routine and chiefly economic work.25

On the heels of Deng’s call for the cessation of campaigns, party authorities issued

official condemnation of the intense political mobilization of the Cultural Revolution and

sought to restore order to bureaucratic ranks (CCP Central Committee 1981).

Campaigns were not eliminated entirely from the political landscape, as illustrated

by party mobilization to enforce family planning policies and maintain the vanguard nature of the party, but they have waned in frequency and intensity (Manion 1985;

Shambaugh 2008a; White 1990).26 Institution-building within the party has replaced ad

hoc political mobilization, representing a normalization of political life. Campaigns are

25 “Some Comments on Economic Work,” Speech by Deng Xiaoping, 4 October 1979, published online by the People’s Daily, Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping, Volume II, 1975-1982. http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/dengxp/vol2/text/b1330.html, accessed 21 May 2007. As early as 1956, Liu Shaoqi stated, in his political report to the 8th CCP Congress, “Mass struggle must give way to the rule of socialist law and order.” This statement was given in the context of political struggle between Liu and Mao, which Mao ultimately won. 26 O’Brien and Li reference rural public opinion survey results to argue that “campaign nostalgia” has emerged, most often with respect to cadre malfeasance, though the breadth of this sentiment across the general population is unknown (O'Brien and Li 1999).

18 no longer intended to engineer a wholescale transformation of society so much as target

particular political issues. Anti-corruption campaigns are one example. These have persisted in the post-Mao period, but they differ from the mass campaigns of the past by

relying instead “on short bursts of hyper enforcement by state and party agencies,

wherein the ‘masses’ are asked to report corrupt cadres but are not allowed to take on an active or leading role,” (Wedeman 2005: 93, fn. 1). Political campaigns have left their organizational legacy, since the organization of small groups continues today in more institutionalized settings.27

More orderly forms of party management, such as cadre training, have risen in

prominence. Like campaigns, training is a form of ex ante political control: it offers general prescriptions for action and increases local awareness of general legal (or normative) boundaries set by higher level authorities.28 These qualities are particularly

suited for transitional environments in which local circumstances are shifting rapidly and

local agents must act autonomously based on knowledge of central goals.29 Cadre

training, like campaigns, provides individuals with incentives to promote central political

goals. “In the cadre party, with its heavy emphasis on indoctrination and institutional

character-formation, this means that party members may be relied on to carry out party

policy even under conditions which do not permit direct control over the member by

regular party organs,” (Selznick 1960: 65). Unlike cadre education at training schools

27 See Whyte (1974) for a discussion of the (ideal and actual) purpose of small groups under Mao. The study groups he describes engage in more coercive activities such as intense group- and self-criticism, which have waned in the present: the organizational form remains, though the content has changed. 28 On the distinction between ex ante versus ex post controls, see Huber and Shipan (2002). 29 In his seminal study of behavior among U.S. forest rangers, Kaufman identifies training as the vehicle for shaping rangers’ decision making under highly autonomous circumstances (Kaufman 2006). Few public servants are as self-directed or isolated as rangers, but in times of heightened uncertainty higher-level authorities must rely more heavily on the knowledge of local agents and grant them more decision making authority.

19 and universities, however, campaigns are not amenable to organizational competition and,

by implication, lack the capacity for local innovation that these organizations may develop.

An alternative explanation: Party schools as a reward for party service

In the reform period, central CCP leadership has tackled two critical tasks: attempting to maintain internal control over ‘leading’ public managers and party organs

while seeking to engineer a bureaucratic transformation. Cadre training, and the party

school system in particular, brings together these tasks. Before attempting to map the contours and mechanisms of this control and adaptation, I must first address a key critique. There exists the prospect that party schools are outdated institutions with an irrelevant mandate, anachronisms in China’s market-oriented development agenda. This suggests the null hypothesis that party schools are inconsequential for understanding internal dynamics of party change, that training is epiphenomenal to the true bases of party authority. At the individual level, this implies that training has a negligible effect on the careers of upward bound officials (who are already on track for promotion).

A potential problem with a proposed study of cadre training – and the party school system at its core – lays in the risk that such institutions exist solely as a reward, or “club good” for the party faithful. Historical accounts link the initial creation of

China’s party school system to its Soviet counterpart, which suggests international institutional mimicry as the justification for their existence (Chen 2007: Chapter 4).30

30 Party schools are not unique to China and have existed in the Soviet Union and its political satellites in Central and Eastern Europe and Asia. In the USSR, party school education was mostly remedial and not a significant channel to the most prestigious and lucrative offices at the central level (Farmer 1992). Party school counterparts in Russia and Eastern Europe have, remarkably, outlasted the party system: the central

20 From this perspective, the party school system derives legitimacy from an (extinct) external source and may thus be both hollow in purpose and motivated by the need to continue perpetuating a myth of its own usefulness in order to survive (Meyer-Sahling

2006).

From this perspective, the primary purpose of party schools is to provide material rewards to party managers who have demonstrated loyalty to the party. Ritual and reward suffuse the training experience. For example, county-level trainees at the Central

Party School must swear allegiance each day of training to the Chinese flag.31 Other trainees who attend programs at the new cadre executive academy at Jinggangshan are issued revolutionary-style fatigues and backpacks and led on treks up Jinggangshan in an attempt to capture the spirit of revolutionary survivors before them.32 These efforts reflect an attempt to reignite a revolutionary fervor among cadres too young to have lived through the civil war leading up to the founding of the PRC in 1949, but this has the effect of reducing the dense relationship between myth and experience to “revolutionary tourism” (Pieke 2009a: 184). On the reward side of the equation, the material comforts of party school training assignments are difficult to ignore. During in-residence training classes at party schools from the central level down, cadres enjoy state-of-the-art leisure facilities which range from indoor basketball courts to hotel-style banquet halls.

If cadre training at party schools is primarily a reward for loyal service to the party, two important inconsistencies arise. First, cadres’ performance in training

Russian party school in Moscow has since become a school of public administration and joined the market for professional higher education. Romania’s central party school, the Stefan Gheorghiu Academy for Training and Development of Leading Cadres, also reinvented itself as a secular public administration academy in 1989. 31 “Five thousand county officials big training-in-rotation,” Southern Weekend, 4 January 2007. 32 Interview 114, Central Party School professor, party building department, February 2008.

21 programs are recorded in their personnel files, and these training records are reviewed during regular evaluations.33 The Trial Regulations on Cadre Education and Training

Work (2007) state that “each cadre education and training department must in

accordance with cadre management powers create and perfect a cadre education and

training file and submit cadres’ training situation and evaluation results,” (Art. 43).

Thesis papers and field reports written by cadres during training must also be submitted to these personnel files, though interviewees have noted varying degrees of seriousness in the grading of these papers. More importantly, the personnel management agencies of the party, organization departments, will send monitors to observe and record cadres’ performance during training.34 Overall student performance in training, including

appearance (biaoxian) throughout discussion sessions, field investigations, and on-site

visits, all are submitted to each cadre’s personnel file. In short, while there are elements

of ritual to party training, there are also organizational links between training programs

and a cadre’s career prospects within the party and government.

Second, the view that party schools should be dismissed as peripheral

organizations of marginal purpose is inconsistent with internal and external efforts to

update the relevance of party school training for reform-era public managers. Party

schools have sought to adjust their pedagogy, training materials, teaching staff, and

training content to meet perceptions of shifting needs in a rapidly changing context. This

suggests an organizational objective that extends beyond ritual or reward. Schools may

33 A certain number of points are allocated to training in recent performance evaluation rubrics. Interview with a county-level city organization department cadre, Interview 206, May 2008. According to this official, individual cadres have a “study and training” (xuexi peixun) component to their evaluation package. Individuals require at least 60 points to pass, and training performance is worth up to 20 points. 34 Only one interviewee, at a department (chu)-level training at the CPS, said that discussion sessions were tape recorded (Interview 40, October 2007). Interviews with party school officials and organization department officials at the city level and below indicated that organization department monitors are sent to take handwritten notes.

22 beat the drum of Marxist-Leninist-Maoist doctrine and provide some sort of retreat experience for hard-working cadres, but they may also fulfill purposes above and beyond these. The entrepreneurial streak that party schools exhibit today in both training content and income generation would be even more puzzling if these schools were only places of respite. Party schools on one level are the embodiment of the perks of party membership, but evidence suggests that they serve additional, more important functions for the ruling party, e.g., managing the career chances of upwardly mobile cadres and conveying party goals to these increasingly autonomous, market-oriented agents of the party.

In short, party schools are more than a “perk” of party office. By drilling down into these core party organizations, I seek to explore how the party school system has adapted to the changed conditions of the reform period while contributing to the continuity and stability that are significant features of the CCP’s bureaucratic structure.

One key driver of party school adaptation is the introduction of new incentives for internal organizational innovation. These incentives have spurred the reform of existing party organizations. Rather than destroy and rebuild its bureaucracy as other communist party states did in their dual transitions to democratic rule and market capitalism, the

Chinese party-state has transformed its bureaucracy from within, through a focus on reforming specific party organizations. It has done so through the introduction of competition, the logic of which is spelled out in organization theories on redundancy.

2 Inducing organizational adaptation: Competition and redundancy

The ideal Weberian bureaucracy, indispensable to the modern state, is at its core a legal-rational structure. Rules and expertise govern bureaucratic behavior and

23 administration, while organizational rationality derives from functional specialization

across bureaucratic offices. Leninist parties incorporated many of these features, notably

the organization of party units according to the various functional needs bound up in the

revolutionary transformation of society and, ultimately, in the more mundane tasks of

governance. Each core task of the party-state would have its own bureaucratic proxy, a

bureaucracy within the bureaucracy. A central organizing principle is bureaucratic

monopoly according to functional domain. While this lends coherence to the

organization of the party-state and facilitates the assignment of both responsibility and

blame, it is problematic from the standpoint of adaptability to change. A monopoly lacks strong incentives to innovate since there is inelastic demand for its output. In this sense,

monopolies have a predisposition for “the quiet life,” and innovate rarely because they do

not employ the same “diversity of processes” found in a competitive system (Niskanen

1971: 161).

In the post-Mao period, broad-based systemic changes have tested the party’s

flexibility and adaptiveness. The general problem to overcome is one of “trained

incapacity”, where party functionaries reach a “state of affairs in which one's abilities

function as inadequacies or blind spots. Actions based upon training and skills which

have been successfully applied in the past may result in inappropriate responses under

changed conditions. An inadequate flexibility in the application of skills, will, in a

changing milieu, result in more or less serious maladjustments,” (Merton 1968: 252).

The antidote to the individual- and organizational-level dysfunction that Merton observed

across bureaucracies is creating incentives for “adaptive efficiency”, i.e., “an institutional

structure that in the face of ubiquitous uncertainties … will flexibly try various

24 alternatives to deal with novel problems that continue to emerge over time,” (North 2005:

154).

The CCP response to these institutional weaknesses has been to modify the

Weberian and Leninist emphases on functional monopoly: with the onset of reforms, central party authorities have promoted inter-organizational competition to cope with new economic and social uncertainties. This reflects the logic that the reliability of a system of imperfect, and hence fallible, parts may be increased through the introduction of competition or redundancy (Landau 1969).35 Redundancy, taken to the realm of governance and public administration, refers to the introduction of additional agencies to fulfill an organizational goal previously monopolized by a single agency.36 It applies in

all cases where agencies “make some contribution to the achievement of the system’s

goal, but this contribution is blurred because some other element(s) make(s) a similar

contribution,” (Felsenthal 1980: 248). In this sense, redundancy is the introduction of

slack, or additional resources, to a system (Landau 1991). This slack then generates the

35 Redundancy is often used interchangeably with competition, but they are not precisely the same thing. Bendor (1985) notes, “All competitive structures are redundant, but the converse is not true; there are non- competitive types of duplication,” (p. 54). Competition is thus a subset of the possible universe of redundant systems. The difference lays in the nature of the incentives driving competitive systems. Competitive, as opposed to non-competitive redundancies, offers stronger incentives to individual agencies. Competitive systems imply a rivalry between actors, since they must compete for finite resources, and this serves as a stronger incentive to search for alternatives and innovate in the face of problems. The drive to innovate is reduced or even nonexistent in systems where agencies function in parallel without any mutual threat to survival. 36 The most detailed analyses of bureaucratic competition have focused on public administration and institutional design in democracies, but the principle is not dependent on the regime type of a polity. In Landau’s classic 1969 essay, he raises the many examples of redundancy in the US political system: “separation of powers, federalism, checks and balances, concurrent powers, double legislatures, overlapping terms of office, the Bill of Rights, the veto, the override, judicial review, and a host of similar arrangements,” (p. 351). See also Mittal (2008) for a historically grounded discussion of the founding fathers’ intention to embed redundancies in the US political system in order to increase the adaptive efficiency of the structure overall. However, the decision to introduce redundancy or competition in a bureaucracy is also not limited to democracies. Inter-agency competition may develop accidentally or by fiat. Downs (2008) points out that redundancies, at the agency level, arise most often when there are unclear boundaries between agencies; this provides the conditions for the pursuit of expansionist agendas. Redundancy may also be introduced to a system through executive order. These are not mutually exclusive pathways, and both may play a role in the development of competition in a bureaucracy.

25 reserve capacity that enables a system to become more tolerant of failure. Redundancy

thus produces two important results: increased system reliability and incentives for organizational adaptation.

While reliability, or the mitigation of system failure, is the more widely researched benefit of redundancy (Streeter 1992), this study focuses on a second, but equally important outcome: competition as a means to induce organizational change and adaptation to unforeseeable circumstances. In their study of inter-service rivalry in the

US military, Enthoven and Rowen (1959) argue that “human limitations being what they

are, there is good reason to believe that a decentralized competitive system, in which

people have incentives to propose alternatives, will usually meet this test [of developing

comprehensive defense capabilities] more effectively than a highly centralized system,”

(p. 5). Competition increases the diversity of perspectives brought to bear on a particular

issue, which increases the chances of discovering new alternatives. Because competition

entails some ambiguity in the jurisdictional boundaries between bureaus, some blurring

of organizational purpose, this “loosens structure” and “facilitates an expansion of the

range of possible organizational responses to problems” (Lerner 1978: 20). One of the

most powerful effects of the introduction of competition to a system, then, is to stimulate

change in preexisting actors.

The rationale behind the introduction of competition is to raise a system’s overall

capacity to generate multiple alternatives for solving a problem. In this sense, it presents

a logical response to the uncertainty that waxes and wanes in different policy contexts.

Furthermore, competition induces rival agencies to search more aggressively for

alternatives. By increasing the number of agencies focused on a task, a greater number of

26 possible alternatives are considered and pursued in the interest of fulfilling a system wide goal. High uncertainty obtains in the case of post-Mao China. During this period, party authorities have run into deep uncertainty over how to cross the river of economic change.

The party leadership has set policy by “feeling for stones” each step of the way, and this oft-invoked metaphor captures the party’s heightened uncertainty over policy and governance matters in recent decades. Introducing competition to areas deemed critically important to party rule thus increases confidence in the ability of the system to weather through unpredictable environments.

A case study of cadre training in China contributes to understanding the processes of creating a competitive system where there was previously monopoly. Introducing competition, and not only uncompetitive redundancy, to party organizations in China has resulted in party entrepreneurialism. Party entrepreneurialism, as a response to market- based competition for resources, encompasses a bundle of interrelated activities that include service provision, programmatic innovation, and the search for lucrative new ventures. Some of these activities reflect significant changes in the substance of cadre training in China, and other activities are more limited (and local) in scope.

This study departs from previous studies of competition within the Chinese bureaucracy in several ways. First, previous studies have not examined the introduction of competition to party organizations with primarily political, rather than economic, purpose(s). Mertha (2006), for example, maps the emergence of a “policy enforcement market” across the PRC’s intellectual property rights protection regime and finds that redundant systems are more effective at monitoring compliance with state regulations.

Second, existing studies do not explore how the introduction of competition, in the form

27 of a partially open market, leads to significant organizational evolution within party

organizations. By peering inside party schools and mapping the range of organizational activities therein, this study offers concrete indicators of change. Third, the competition presented here is broader in scope and spills beyond the boundaries of the bureaucracy: the market for cadre training encompasses party, state, private, domestic, and international actors.

Crucially, competition in cadre training brings market principles into the heart of

party activities. In Mertha’s examination of copyright and trademark enforcement, the

entry of competition is highly curtailed by central authorities. Cadre training, in contrast,

saw the creation of a training market in which virtually any educational institution could

compete. This mix of public and private actors, all vying for the privilege to train

China’s political elite, should in theory yield new approaches to training itself. Finally,

more than policy implementation is at stake in this process. Marketization of cadre

training addresses issues of organizational survival as well as competing visions for the

skills and loyalties that the party’s elite should possess.

It is important to note here that the introduction of competition to a particular

bureaucratic function does not imply privatization. Competition may take place solely

between government and/or party bureaus, and this should still yield the outcome of greater system adaptiveness and innovation. Introducing private actors is one option among many for diversifying the range of players in a competition, which in turn should increase the pressures for organizational creativity (Miranda and Lerner 1995).

Subjecting a bureaucratic agency to competition implies greater diversity in organizational activity, the search for an edge over rivals, and ultimately some innovation

28 at the system level, but the participation of private market actors is not a necessary precondition for these processes to unfold.

There is further logic to the introduction of market-based competition. First,

“markets promote high-powered incentives and restrain bureaucratic distortions more effectively than internal organization,” (Williamson 1989: 150). Because some degree of risk accompanies market-based competition, the stakes are higher than for a monopolistic bureaucracy. From the perspective of participating agencies and institutions, the risk of failure implies that they must compete for scarce resources. Second, a market in which competitors enter and exit freely may mitigate the problem of determining when there are a sufficient number of actors in a system. One predicament facing planners of a redundant system is ascertaining how many agencies, or how much redundancy, is optimal. One solution is to apply a satisficing principle, or ceasing expansion when some minimum threshold of competition is reached (Simon 1979). A market configuration presents a more self-regulating solution. Where there is market-based competition, agencies will continue to enter the market for a particular good or service until there is no longer a marginal gain for additional entrants. This depends, however, on the freedom of

market entry. As will be discussed in the case study of the party school system, there is some interference by central party authorities and hence only partial marketization.

Some additional design considerations accompany the introduction of redundancy to a bureaucratic system. Competition will lead to the highest levels of creativity when three conditions prevail.37 Downs (1967) asserts that competing agencies must be close

enough in purpose that their funding derives from the same sources. This transforms

37 Bendor (1985) explores the criticality of independence across agencies, under the assumption that nonindependence might risk to the spillover of failure across agencies, but he finds that nonindependence is difficult to achieve in practice and that the usefulness of redundancy still obtains in cases of overlap.

29 competition into a zero-sum scenario, which raises the stakes for success and agency

survival. Second, these agencies must be distant enough in purpose that there is no significant exchange of personnel between them. Third, rival agencies must possess discretion over which programs to pursue (Bendor 1985). Krause and Douglas (2003) have also argued convincingly that competition is effective only when new entrants offer alternatives that are of similar or higher quality than the original monopoly agency. If competition presents an inferior standard, this has the perverse outcome of lowering standards throughout the system.

There exist several problems with the introduction of competition to a bureaucracy. First is the possibility of unpredicted interactions between agencies in a

competitive system and the unknown outcomes these may produce. Ironically, while

redundancy may be introduced to mitigate uncertainty, it can introduce uncertainties of

its own. Another concern is the opportunity cost of devoting resources to a redundant

function when those resources might be committed elsewhere. The problem with

assessing this critique, however, is the difficulty in assigning costs to a given outcome as

well as observing the counterfactual case. There are also the deeper considerations such

as coping with the possibility of market failure and the suitability of redundant systems

for nonexclusionary goods.38 There is no easy means to dismiss these issues. Safeguards

against market failure will inevitably constrain the extent of competition that is possible

or safe to introduce into a system. Nonexclusionary goods, on the other hand, may be

amenable to competition. Classic examples, such as defense and security, do contain

high degrees of overlap in agency jurisdiction (Bendor 1985: 3-22; Felsenthal 1980).

38 Landau 1991 raises but skirts these issues in his advocacy for introducing redundancy as a virtue and not a sin of public administration design.

30 Overall, these critiques present a sobering limit on those who would propose the universal application of redundancy to government functions.

While the discussion thus far has emphasized the advantages of competition to

bureaucratic management, it cannot be imposed without expectation of resistance or

complication. Introducing redundancy to a system entails a series of strategic decisions.

Principals must first decide whether or not to create a redundant system at all, whether to

assign agents to similar tasks or otherwise determine the range of choice, and then agents must choose how much effort to expend based on their particular policy preferences

(Ting 2003). This sets up the expectation that the “old guard” will resist the introduction of competition. The tendency toward bureaucratic monopoly in Leninist systems would also seem to advantage those agencies in a monopoly position. Whether and how

monopolistic agencies resist the introduction of competition is thus another focus of this

project’s empirical case study.

In sum, introducing competition may appear to fly in the face of the bureaucratic tendency toward monopoly, particularly in a highly centralized, authoritarian regime.

Yet, as Bendor (1985) points out, this preference is not based on empirical tests of the

various advantages of monopoly over competition in matters of public administration:

“the empirical warrant for monopoly in government … is virtually nonexistent,” (p. 252).

Crucially, Niskanen (1971) finds that a monopolistic public bureau is not more efficient

than systems with overlapping or competitive bureaus.39 Aversion to innovation by

monopoly agencies within the CCP lies at the heart of the party’s concern with the old

39 He defines efficiency in terms of the production costs for a good or service, though he notes that the problem of oversupply still exists in competitive bureaucratic systems. I also note here that he uses a Weberian definition of bureaus as organizations that do not allocate any difference between revenues and costs as personal income, which is violated in the case of Chinese bureaus. See Ang 2009 for a discussion of Chinese exceptionalism in this regard.

31 state of affairs in cadre training. As this study demonstrates, central party authorities deliberately turned to market-based competition to induce change in party organizations, indicating the party’s capacity for significant organizational rethinking behind the veneer of a relatively unchanged political structure.

3 Précis of study

Across authoritarian regimes, parties fulfill – to varying degrees – rulers’ search for institutional solutions to the basic and centrally motivating question of how to survive in office (Geddes 1994). Parties make possible the credible commitment that is instrumental in a ruler’s attempt to co-opt elites and the general population. Parties are also a means to solve the elite selection problem that exists in hierarchical political systems. The contribution of this project is to identify how the party, as a complex organization comprising many sub-party bureaucracies, addresses the latter problem.

That the party does so in a changing environment has brought about, in the Chinese case, a shift in the incentives that structure the decisions of key party organizations of elite selection. China thus presents an important case for understanding these questions of party organization and change within its broader context of domestic and global transformation. Previous research on the Chinese case has drawn attention to adjustments in the criteria guiding the selection of political elites, but there has been less attention on the organizational changes taking place within party agencies. Party schools, as relatively understudied sites of political control and bureaucratic management, offer a window into this restructuring of incentives and how the CCP has exhibited surprising adaptability in the face of significant economic and social change.

32 I will argue in this study that the CCP has selectively enhanced the adaptability of sub-party organizations by applying a principle more commonly studied in democracies, inter-organizational competition. In the Chinese case, this competition has been broadly market-based and spilled beyond the boundaries of the party-state, but the central motivation has been to improve the party’s adaptive capacity. This argument raises several questions: What were the processes by which party authorities introduced competition to a bureaucratic realm previously dominated by one set of party organizations? Who was allowed to compete and why? What have been the organizational responses to this competition? What are some ways to measure organizational change? Has the goal of stimulating organizational innovation been met?

Have there been unintended consequences, either welcome or not? Are party schools still relevant? In answering these questions, I will present findings at two levels of analysis.

To show that party schools are an organized means for the party to manage processes of political elite selection, I will consider individual-level career patterns and the

“treatment” of party school training on career paths. At the same time, in carrying out this selection function the party school system has been subject to competitive pressures.

To understand these changes, I embark on a school-level analysis to map out organizational responses to centrally-driven policies.

Chapter two of this dissertation will begin with an overview of the party school system, its history, and organizational context. Existing research on party schools is divided into roughly two groups: studies that focused on the functions of the Central

Party School (CPS) and, more recently, those that have looked at the school system beyond Beijing. This scholarship has viewed party schools as indicators and drivers of

33 ideological change within the party. My study takes a different tact and emphasizes

processes of organizational change as they unfolded throughout the system, in the CPS and beyond. In so doing, I introduce a key selection function that these schools are able

to carry out, beyond the dissemination of the party’s ideology. I build upon the interpretation that party schools are part of the party’s continual state-building project – but identify more precisely the actors, motivations, and processes driving organizational changes in the post-Mao period.

Chapter three will explore the theoretical and empirical relationship between cadre training and elite selection. In the principal agent relationships which suffuse a hierarchical political system such as China’s, the party’s selection problem comes prior to the other problems, more commonly studied, in a principal-agent relationship (i.e., moral hazard, which is solved by monitoring, rewards and sanctions). This chapter will test whether selection for training at a party school constitutes a channel for promotion to higher cadre office. By employing a matching method on large-N survey data, this chapter will present findings from analysis of a national sample of individuals on an administrative and/or political career track as well as results from an original dataset of the career histories of Central Party School trainees. It will also consider mechanisms for selection, including screening, signaling, and the role of networks.

Chapter four shifts the level of analysis to discuss the marketization of cadre training, unraveling the processes by which competition was introduced to the party school system. Beginning in the mid-1980s, different sets of preexisting and new organizations were allowed to enter a cadre training market. At the same time, party schools were also allowed to engage in market activity that extended beyond their core

34 training work. These two sets of market opportunities emerged via top-down, center-led

processes which local actors then seized for local gain and to effect system wide change.

Some intentionality can be deduced from central policy documents, while field interviews

reveal a more mixed terrain: a combination of collaboration and rivalry characterizes the

relationship between the organizations that now compete for cadre training contracts.40

This chapter will also discuss an important precondition to this marketization strategy, limited fiscal and administrative decentralization.

Chapter five peers inside party schools to unpack the various school responses to competition and the development of party entrepreneurialism. Party school leaders have pursued a variety of income-raising schemes, some of which exist purely for pecuniary gain, while others attract income as well as improve the quality of the school’s core training outputs. This chapter will also consider change in the content of party school training through content analysis of Central Party School training syllabi from 1985 to

2007. Together, these varieties of party school activity demonstrate the range of organizational responses to competition. Site visits to training organizations at the central, provincial, city, and county levels form the basis for case studies of party school adaptation across regions with varying levels of economic development (Appendix B).

In all locales, party school adaptation is a function of organizational responses to two markets: the market opportunities created by Deng’s liberalizing economic reforms and the pressures presented by a second market in which a variety of party-approved organizations compete for trainees. Schools must thus adapt to two imperatives:

40 Field work focused on localities located within a coastal Province A and inland Province B. Appendix B provides an overview of my field research strategy, a summary of interviewee data, and comparative analysis of field sites.

35 maximizing income streams in a new market economy and updating the content of cadre training.

The concluding chapter will consider the implications of these changes. One result has been greater search by party schools for new income-generating projects, which in turn embeds party schools more deeply in local economies. Political embeddedness results because training signals to ambitious cadres the skills that they must demonstrate in order to move upward within the party ranks. Economic embeddedness occurs through the pursuit of revenue streams from local partnerships.

This, in turn, speaks to larger questions of the tension between party efforts to remain relevant and at the forefront of China’s economic development while avoiding the danger of granting too much autonomy to local actors.

Looking beyond the China case, the theory and findings presented here offer an explanation for how a hierarchical ruling party may develop the capacity to adapt to systemic shocks and uncertainty. In the case of China, change initiated in one realm has created pressures for adaptation in others: the decision to introduce market reforms to

China’s state-managed economic sector has motivated shifts in the organizational geography and survival strategies of political institutions. This dynamism challenges accounts of the brittleness and inertia of communist-party led systems.41 The particular approach chosen by the CCP, introducing market incentives to organizations of political control, suggests the diffusion of market principles beyond the economic realm to the political. In creating a training market to introduce competition to the party school system, the party leadership has sought to put in place incentives for continual adaptation

41 A critique of the rigidities of the socialist system can be found in Kornai 1992.

36 by party institutions, at the same time retaining the party’s hold on the loyalties and careers of ambitious cadres.

37 Chapter 2 The organizational landscape

As discussed in the previous chapter, institutions of elite management located within the ruling party are crucial for maintaining bureaucratic order in authoritarian regimes. Controlling selection to party and government office remains a crucial part of the foundation upon which party rule is built. As stated in CCP study materials, “the party manages cadres” (dang guan ganbu), and from this principle flows the party’s monopoly over the pathways to political authority (CPS 2004). Among the CCP’s cadre management strategies, cadre training – its organization, the content of training programs, and how it has changed over time – presents untapped insights regarding how the party has exercised authority over the career paths and political knowledge of its leading managers and administrators.

Cadre training has been a topic of study by scholars of contemporary Chinese politics, and this chapter will first situate the present study in existing scholarship on party schools. The second part of this chapter will “set the stage” and place party schools in their political and institutional context through a discussion of the history, organization, and management of party schools. An historical examination of the development of the party school system demonstrates that while party schools are grounded in the early ideological ideals of the party, they now reflect and embody the pragmatic objectives of more recent organizational reforms. In this chapter and the next, I will argue that cadre training is viewed by party authorities as a vehicle for updating the knowledge of party and government bureaucrats and, furthermore, that party schools are training academies with a measurable impact on the career development of bureaucrats throughout the party-

38 state. Framing the function of party schools’ in this way differs from existing scholarship,

which has focused instead on how party schools, as incubators of party ideology,

reinforce CCP authority.

2 Contribution to existing scholarship

Early scholarly analyses of party schools centered on the Beijing-based Central

Party School’s role in developing and conveying the party line.42 As such, there was less emphasis on its flagship role within a broad-based web of cadre training institutions.

Unquestionably, the CPS possesses considerable ideological authority and has been the site of breakthroughs in party theory. Under Hu Yaobang’s vice-presidency, the CPS became a locus for formulation of “practice as a sole criterion of truth” and debate of the post-Mao “two whatevers” ideological stances (Schoenhals 1991). During the reforms and intellectual debates of the 1980s, the CPS was the institutional base for independent- minded intellectuals within the party ranks (Ding 1994). The CPS also carries symbolic weight as the site of major declarations of party doctrine: Jiang Zemin elaborated on his

“Three Represents” there in 2001, followed by Hu Jintao’s call for a “harmonious society” in 2005 (Zheng 2010). Prominent scholars in both the CPS and the National

School of Administration, also located in Beijing, have presented new ideas for political reform within the party and ways to move from “harmonious society” to “harmonious socialism.”43 In June 2007, at the CPS, Hu Jintao expounded on the major themes of the

42 A review of the literature on party schools, both pre-1949 and after, can be found in Pieke (2009a), p. 35 fn. 19. 43 “Beijing Brain Trusters Propose a New Path for the Political Reform in China,” Yazhou Zhoukan, 27 May 2007. See also, “CPC National Congress to Launch New Resolution on Intra-Party Democracy,” Hsin Pao, 23 March 2007.

39 17th Party congress, several months before the October convening of the congressional

delegates (Fewsmith 2007: 7; Shambaugh 2008a: 111-5).

Other studies have considered the development of the CPS’s responsibility to

train central-level leaders on core party policies, but these works have remained Beijing-

centric (Fewsmith 2003; Wibowo and Fook 2006). Scholars have also noted the

importance of the CPS as a think tank and the positional advantage that party school

scholars enjoy in promoting their research and policy recommendations on political reform (Fewsmith 2008). In limiting their scope to the Central Party School, however, these studies do not consider when, why, and how cadre training more broadly may be a useful instrument of political control and change for successive generations of central party leaders.

Another body of research has placed party schools and cadre training in the context of general processes of party adaptation. Party schools thus reflect the party’s efforts to study and learn from cases of failed communist party-led reforms elsewhere

(Shambaugh 2008a: Chapter 7). With these historical lessons in mind, recent passage of training-related legislation reasserts organizational discipline over cadre ranks.44 These studies have also moved beyond Beijing and considered diversity in the organizational actors that contribute to cadre training. Greater access to field sites has enabled more detailed observations of how immersive training experiences contribute to the building of a distinct cadre identity (Tran 2003). Through a vertical case study of the party school system, Pieke (2009a) has probed how party schools reflect the party’s efforts to

44 Examples of these official declarations include the “Resolution on the CCP’s strengthening and improving party school work in the twenty-first century”, available at http://wlzx.hdpu.edu.cn/zzb/Article_Show.asp?ArticleID=125, accessed 6 June 2006 and the “2004 CCP Party School Work Trial Regulations”, available at http://wlzx.hdpu.edu.cn/zzb/Article_Show.asp?ArticleID=126, accessed 6 June 2006.

40 redefine socialism in a changed context and contribute to the party’s larger “neo- socialist” state-building project.45

This dissertation makes a separate but related argument to these more recent, local and system wide studies. First, this study supports and expands upon existing work by demonstrating with new data the mechanisms by which party schools contribute to the party’s management of human resources, in particular the exercise of party control over cadre careers. This study draws out assumptions that are implicit in existing studies to test whether party schools play a significant role in the construction of China’s political elite. Beyond the ideological import of these schools, this project maps out their function within the organizational machinery of a rational Leninist party-state. By measuring the effect of party school training on cadre promotion, I show how these schools generate positive incentives for cadres to adhere to the dictates of the ruling party, beyond any individual-level commitments to ideology.

Second, I depart from extant literature by investigating how party authorities have induced organizational change within the party school system itself and how this provides traction on the larger, multi-faceted story of CCP survival in the reform period. This study builds upon Shambaugh and Pieke’s observation that the party has embarked on a broad-based institution-building project. Arguably, this project has been in progress since the founding of the republic, but in its current form it is characterized by

“interlocking patterns of neo-socialist marketization, bureaucratization and party building,” (Pieke 2009a: 18). My contribution is one of specificity: I unravel why party schools, and not other institutions of party management such as political campaigns, were

45 By neo-socialism, Pieke is referring to “the creation of a strong, effective and modern bureaucracy … while at the same time maintaining the party’s Leninist control,” (Pieke 2009a: 18).

41 developed in the reform period. In this narrative, I consider the logic underlying the

decision to introduce market-based competition rather than apply bureaucratic reforms of a less radical nature. All of this is to lend a meso-level, or institution-driven view of how

the party acts on its fundamental desire not only to survive through present reforms but

remain their central architect.

My third contribution to the literature is empirical. Through field visits and

interviews conducted in the local party schools of provinces in the coastal and central

regions of China, I present a more ground-level understanding of organizational change

within the party. This allows for both a vertical and horizontal examination of how these

key party organs work, across regions and administrative levels. Such an empirical

approach provides a more complete picture of the incentives, responses, and risks

underlying political change in China.

3 An historical overview

A tour through the history of cadre training in the PRC, where the party school

system has remained a central and enduring feature, demonstrates that party-led cadre

education has experienced an uneven trajectory over time: from early, limited efforts to

institutionalize cadre training, followed by the decade-long disorganization of the

Cultural Revolution, to more recent, top-down efforts to unify the party school system.

Cadre training has long been a component of CCP policy, beginning with revolutionary

education during the Republican period (1912-1949). For parties initially guided by a

Marxist-Leninist ideology, the dissemination of theory to party members and leaders was

a prerequisite for organizing revolution. Training in the Leninist historical narrative and

42 accompanying weapons of the party – such as how to formulate class-based rhetoric,

disseminate propaganda, establish base camps – took place in party schools. While the

concept of training schools for cadres and other revolutionary actors (e.g., workers,

peasants) has existed since the early years of the CCP, these organizations have

undergone expansion and contraction from the first half of the twentieth century to the

present.

The schools were established in province by party and

Communist Youth League members in 1923 (Wang 1992: 33-4).46 What was to become

the Central Party School was established in 1933 in Ruidian, province, and persisted through the Long March to become, by 1955, the Advanced Central Party

School (Zheng 2010). In the 1950s, during the party’s laying of organizational

foundations in the new republic, most provinces saw the construction of a provincial-

level party school. During this first decade of Communist party state-building, leaders attempted to create a system for training, recruiting, and educating cadres. “The period of the early to mid 1950s saw the major development of systematic cadre management practices. The party specified more clearly the criteria for cadre appointments and promotions, there was an increased effort to expand training to help cadres acquire necessary technical and political credentials, and a formal network of parallel Party and state institutions for cadre management was set up,” (Manion 1985: 206, citing Harding’s

Organizing China). Drawing from émigré interviews, Whyte details cadre education during the 1960s as characterized by a “strict political atmosphere” in certain work units,

46 During this period, training consisted of small groups studying subjects such as ‘capitalism and China’, ‘workers’ movement’, ‘rural movement’, ‘social revolution and people’s revolution’, and ‘world revolutionary history’. They also engaged in propaganda writing. Detailed histories of the party school system are available in English ((Pieke 2009a: Chapter 2) and Chinese (Chen 2007) scholarly work.

43 emphasis on doctrinal study, personal political evaluations, and peer criticism (Whyte

1974: Chapter 5). During these early decades of the republic, then, there existed the notion to codify cadre education via a network of party schools, but training plans and

general operating principles were as yet unsystematic.

By the late 1970s, after reopening from the closures of the Cultural Revolution

(1966-76), cadre training was still relatively ad hoc: cadres attended occasional field

investigation reports by elder cadres and were assigned mentors by their direct

superiors.47 This system depended largely on the initiative of individual cadres with management authority, and no formal rules governed, for example, the number of lectures to organize or mentors to assign. Local schools focused on staging short-term

classes for the study of party documents, major party meetings, and party congresses.48

Before Deng’s reforms, training consisted of two parts: the “five old topics”, all based on

fundamental Marxist theory, and the study of party documents.49 Then, during the anti-

bureaucratic campaign of 1977-1980, party leaders shifted from political means for

rectifying the bureaucracy (e.g., struggle sessions, media-intensive propaganda

campaigns) to emphasis on rational managerial means such as retiring old cadres and

enhancing technical training (Manion 1993; Morgan 1981).

With the triumph of Deng’s reformist camp and the onset of economic

transformation in the 1980s, central leaders emphasized the significance of cadre training:

“The needs of modernization require large-scale, well-planned training of cadres to

improve the quality of the cadre ranks. Cadre training … guarantees the continuity of the

47 Interview with a Ministry of Foreign Affairs cadre, Interview 26, December 2006. 48 Interviews with provincial party school professors, Interviews 93 and 94, December 2007. 49 Interview with a CPS professor, party history department, Interview 114, February 2008. The “five old topics” (wu ge lao men) were Marxist philosophy, Marxist economics, scientific socialism, party history, and party building.

44 party line and thus is of major strategic importance,” (Central Organization Department

1983: Appendix 3, 67). In these declarations, there remains a clear ideological purpose to

training, though subsequent reforms have placed cadre training within the larger

administrative modernization project of the party. Hu Jintao, the leader of China’s fourth

generation of party officials and also the president of the Central Party School from 1993

to 1998, declared, “As required by the Three Representatives theory, establishing a team

of high-quality party cadres is the key to the development of our party and our country in

the new century. … To train a new generation of young party cadres, the party school is

shouldered with great responsibility.”50 Compounding this training burden was the need to rotate bureaucrats through remedial programs and prepare them for the changes brought on by the economic liberalization and social reforms of the post-Mao period. As detailed in the previous chapter, low turnover in China’s party and government bureaucracies lent additional urgency to retraining efforts.

During this period, there was also an effort to take the loosely organized party school system and create a more coherent approach to cadre training. Officially, May

1982 saw the birth of the school system, beginning with the movement by

Central Party School President Wang Zhen (1982-1987) to standardize (zhengguihua)

cadre training throughout the country (Wibowo and Fook 2006).51 This standardization

has met with limited success. Local party schools all organize young cadre training

classes and short training classes following major events such as party congresses, but

there remains variation in the final lineup of training classes mandated by local party

50 “Promote the party school education to a new level,” People’s Daily, 7 June 2000. 51 Standardization included attempts to unify party school training content and the types of classes organized by local schools (Interviews with CPS party history professors, Interviews 112 and 120, February 2008).

45 committees and conceived by the schools themselves. Before exploring each of these

types of training classes, it is necessary to set the stage with a brief foray into party

schools’ larger organizational context in the contemporary period.

4 Organization and oversight of the party school system

Local party schools are enmeshed in a variety of formal and informal

relationships with party and government bodies located at the same administrative level.

At the same time, oversight of party schools cuts horizontally through locales as well as

vertically through various party bureaucracies. To situate party schools in their

organizational contexts, Figures 2.1 and 2.2 below offer a description of the local party

and government organizations involved in cadre training.

On official organization charts, a local party school is under the managing authority

(zhuguan bumen) of its local party committee. This within-locale authority relationship

contributes to the organizational autonomy enjoyed by party schools. That a local party

school’s affairs are managed by a party organ located at the same administrative level

highlights the local nature of party school supervision. If a party school wishes to

experiment with new programs, for example, the local party committee stands to benefit

from any positive outcomes generated by these ventures, even if they are not necessarily

consistent with central directives. Less successful ventures, furthermore, can be

contained within the local party bureaucracy. This arrangement has the effect of aligning

the interests of local party committees with their respective party schools and generating

strong incentives for local, rather than system-wide, development.

46

Figure 2.1: Local party organs involved in cadre education

District government 区政府

District District District government administration personnel ministry training District finance institute department centers 区财政局 区行政学院 区人事局 部门培训中心

• Organizes training of Civil servant section • Allocates funds to party 公务员科 Ex: District Tourism non-leading cadres and Training Center and government organs civil servants 旅游培训中心 for cadre/civil servant •Generally located on the • Collaborates with training party school campus and administration institute on shares staff civil servant training

Figure 2.2: Government organs involved in civil servant & cadre education

District party committee 区委

District District District discipline District party organization propaganda and inspection school department department department 区委党校 区委组织部 区委宣传部 区纪委

Theoretical education Party’s clean Often combined with: Cadre bureau section government education District administration 干部局 理论教育科 office institute 党风廉政教育室 区行政学院 • Coordinates with the • Maintains delegation of District socialism school party school on leading lecturers on party theory • Responsible for anti- 区社会主义学院 cadre training (讲师团) corruption education •Responsible for leading cadre study group content within work units (领导干部 E-education office 中心组的学习 ) 电化教育办公室

• Responsible for Party member education distance learning department programs 党员教育处

• Responsible for CCP Cadre online study member education at the credit office district and lower levels 网上干部学分考核 办公室

• Responsible for online training system

47 At the same time, local party schools are subject to less formal but nonetheless powerful monitoring by higher level party schools, party personnel (organization) departments, and finance bureaus. First, party schools are embedded in a web of relationships with other party schools. These relationships are characterized as advisory in nature (zhidao guanxi).52 Such consultative relationships stand in contrast to the more coercive, binding control that exists in other aspects of the bureaucracy. Customs

(haiguan) bureaus, for example, must follow the dictates that flow down through the system from the center to the localities. Instead, the local party committee, in consultation with the local party school, organization department, and other relevant bodies such as the education and personnel departments, drafts annual plans and training targets. Actual implementation of training plans resides with party school administrators.

Integration of personnel within a given locale also colors the relationship between local party committees and party schools. As in many other realms of Chinese political organization, party school principals hold concurrent posts. Table 2.1 below lists the names and concurrent offices held by provincial party school leaders.

One of the vice-party secretaries for a locale is often, but not always, the titular head of the local party school, while day-to-day administration is carried out by one or more vice-principals. In , for example, the principal of the provincial party school,

Wang Mingfang, is also a provincial vice-party secretary; party school management is carried out by five vice-principals.53 In other provinces, such as , the current

52 This is stated in Article 11 of the most recent CCP Party School Work Regulations, available at http://www.sina.com.cn, accessed 13 November 2008. The Chinese equivalent for top-down, compulsory control that interviewees repeated again and again was lingdao guanxi. 53 See http://www.ahdx.gov.cn/sm2111111124.asp for a listing of Anhui Provincial Party school leaders, accessed 18 Jun 2009. Wang Mingfang’s concurrent status as vice-party secretary within the provincial party committee can be found in the Central Party School’s Study Times (xuexi shibao), http://www.china.com.cn/xxsb/txt/2007-04/09/content_8089276.htm, accessed 18 June 2009.

48 Table 2.1: Provincial-level party school leadership

Provincial- level Unit Party School Principal Concurrent Post(s) Anhui Wang Mingfang Provincial vice-party secretary Beijing Wang Anshun City vice-party secretary Political-legal committee party secretary Zhang Xuan City vice-party secretary Liu Weiping Provincial vice-party secretary Guangdong Hu Zejun Provincial organization department head Provincial administration institute head Liu Qi Provincial organization department head Zhou Tongzhan Provincial vice-party secretary Provincial CPPCC party committee vice-secretary Yang Song Provincial vice-party secretary Wuhan city party secretary Hunan Zheng Peimin Provincial vice-party secretary Zhang Lianzhen Provincial vice-party secretary Provincial CPPCC president Provincial vice-party secretary Zhang Chengyin Provincial vice-party secretary Provincial vice-party secretary Jiang Yikang Provincial party secretary Shanghai Shen Hongguang City organization department head Xue Yanzhong Provincial vice-party secretary Ke Zunping Provincial organization department head City party secretary City administration institute head Yunnan Yang Chonghui Provincial vice-party secretary Si Xinliang Provincial organization department head Sources: Author’s dataset. Notes: Leadership information not available for , , , , , Jiangxi, , , , , and Tibet. See (Guo and Shan 2009) for a list of provincial-level party school presidents and their positions on party committees, the Central Committee, and other party organs. principal of the party school and administration institute, Hu Zejun, is the head of the provincial organization department, an office that is typically a vice-party secretary position on the provincial party committee. Below Hu, the Guangdong party school is managed by a team of seven: one standing vice-principal and six vice-principals.54 Again, this integration between party committees and party school leadership is within-locale and underlines local party schools’ independence from higher level party bureaus.

54 The Guangdong Provincial Party School leaders and party committee members are listed at http://www.gddx.gov.cn/xyxk/xrld.htm, accessed 18 June 2009.

49 These local lines of authority are balanced, however, by structural checks and

monitoring mechanisms between party schools and various party authorities. Such intra-

party monitoring ensures greater consistency throughout the party school system than

might be assumed when looking only at the formal lines of authority that exist within

locales. Monitoring between party authorities and party schools ensures some degree of

quality control. There are three major types of supervision in place: sending down work teams and observers, bringing party school heads to training classes and conferences at higher levels, and imposing reporting requirements.

Work groups, as the most obvious form of top-down inspection, are sent down from organization departments and higher level party schools, generally one administrative level up, to observe affairs in junior counterparts.55 The Central Party

School has been known to increase the number of work teams it sends out after important

events, such as the most recent Seventeenth Party Congress, to ensure that local schools

are aware of the special congress-related training sessions that they must organize and

carry out.56 This “police patrol” monitoring occurs frequently in the system, though the

regularity of such inspections is unclear.

For important training classes, party school planners can also expect local

organization departments to designate a minder for each small group formed within a

training class. For some classes, small groups will have minders from both the

organization department and party school.57 When higher-level party committee members

55 Pieke 2009 (Chapter 3) offers a detailed overview of the organizational measures in place to organize and monitor cadre training in a locale. During one field visit to a county-level party school in November 2006, I observed part of a work team visit from the nearby city-level party school. The visit lasted half a day, with the team meeting throughout the morning with school officials, then culminated in a banquet lunch and afternoon departure. 56 Interview 108, February 2008, retired CPS professor. 57 Interview 208, May 2008, provincial party school professor.

50 are invited to schools to give speeches at the beginning or conclusion of training classes, this is another form of examination (kaohe) and allows both parties to share information about what is happening at each level.58

Second, party school heads will be invited to partake in “research and discussion”

classes at higher level party schools. According to CPS yearbooks, such classes were

held in 1991 and 1995 for the principals of city (prefecture, diting)-level party schools.

These small classes, for around 50 school principals and ranging from one to three weeks

in duration, were organized not by the CPS’s core training department (peixun bu) but

rather by the theory (lilun bu) and advanced training (jinxiu bu) departments . The

Central Party School also hosts nationwide meetings in which provincial and city party

school heads submit reports to peers and central leaders.59 These meetings comprise celebratory elements as well as the substantive exchange and filing of official reports.60

Third, party school heads also send reports of school affairs up the system, to the

local finance bureau and the local organization department.61 Party school vice-

principals (chang wu fu xiaozhang, i.e., the vice-principal in charge of day-to-day affairs)

also file reports with the school principals who are generally vice-party secretaries on

local party committees.62 Taken together, these monitoring strategies illustrate how party

schools are connected to the larger party school system and key bureaus at the local level,

58 Ibid. 59 Records exist for the first “National Party School Work Meeting” convened in 1979, followed by a second in 1983 (Jiang, Zhang, and Sheng 1983). Other meetings were reported in each of their their respective CPS yearbooks (1985, 1990, 1992, 1995, 1996, and 2001). 60 I was invited to observe the closing banquet at one such reporting conference. This meeting was convened by a provincial-level party school and hosted by a county-level party school in Province A. In addition to a lunch banquet, the meeting allowed provincial party school leaders to collect reports from city, district, and county schools that were participants in the provincial school’s distance degree programs. See field notes May 2008. 61 Interview 176, April 2008, city party school teaching department head. 62 At the CPS, the current head vice-principal, Li Jingtian, reports to the principal, , who sits on the Politburo Standing Committee and CCP Secretariat.

51 despite the advisory nature of the relationships. Party schools thus “operate more as a

cluster of hierarchically embedded networks rather than an impersonal bureaucratic

hierarchy,” (Pieke 2009a: 122). Throughout this hierarchical system, party schools all

organize certain general categories of training classes.

5 Types of training

Despite attempts in the early reform period to standardize party school training

outputs, party schools continue to offer a broad range of educational programs and training sessions. One basic breakdown is to distinguish between degree and non-degree programs. Degree programs are a more recent offering, beginning in 1983 with two-year undergraduate (benke) training classes at the CPS and the creation in 1985 of distance education programs (hanshou jiaoyu) that, under CPS leadership, radiated downward through the system.63 Officially, these residential and non-residential programs were

intended to raise the educational level of cadres in the post-Mao period and answer

Deng’s call for a more educated cadre corps. With time, distance education degree

programs have involved party schools from the county to the central levels in profit-

sharing networks.64 As such, they have become an additional revenue stream for schools

and supplement transfers from local government finance departments. Generally, higher

level schools issue diplomas and set curricula and testing standards, while lower level

63 The syllabi from these early CPS undergraduate training classes are available in the 1985 CPS yearbook, pp. 224-232. 64 Pieke 2006 offers a detailed description of the profit-sharing arrangement between the CPS and Yunnan party schools at the provincial, city, and county levels. A county party school principal in Shandong informed me that 60 percent of tuition from distance coursework programs remains at the county school, while 40 percent is sent up to provincial and central levels. Interview 232, July 2008. This is somewhat consistent with a newspaper article report that the CPS correspondence program allocated tuition accordingly: 10 percent to the CPS, 15 percent to branch campuses, 20-25 percent to schools below branch campuses, and the remainder to the “tutorial stations” (fudao zhan). Zhu Hongjun, “Central Party School calls for the end of correspondence degrees,” Southern Weekend, 29 November 2007.

52 schools provide course support and serve as marketing and distribution points.65 In 2007, distance degree programs ceased to admit new students, but interviews yielded vague responses regarding the enforcement of this decree. Graduate degree programs, furthermore, continue to exist at the central and provincial levels.

The second category, comprising non-degree training programs, is enormously diverse. Training defined by Chinese government documents includes four types of non- degree programs, ranging from new hire training classes to less defined “special topic” training programs (Zhang 2005: 233-235). Local party schools tend to use a different categorization system. Core (zhuti) training courses are mandated by the local party committee and supported by funding from government coffers.66 Auxiliary (fei zhuti)

courses vary more across locales and depend on what the party school leadership wishes

to offer, in consultation with the local party committee.67 Core training courses include

those which are for orientation or on-the-job training purposes, but they can also include

more select classes for young cadres with promotion potential. Auxiliary classes often

address special topics or are geared for specific party bureaucracies. All of these non-

degree party school programs vary in duration, level of study, and content. Table 2.2

below offers an example of the allocation of training courses, by type, scheduled by a

city-level party committee for 2008.68

65 One consequence of this is some interesting overlap in the educational experiences of local officials. In one inland county that I visited, a township party secretary was enrolled in a provincial party school degree program while a party discipline committee cadre in a different township had opted for the CPS distance degree program, though it was more expensive. While most of the coursework consisted of independent study, they went to their local county party school for periodic lectures and program support. The county party school was the local study center for these provincial and central party school distance degree programs. Interviews 10 and 11, November 2006. 66 These are also referred to as “inside-the-plan” (jihua nei) training classes, in accordance with annual training plans approved by each local party committee. 67 These are also referred to as “outside-the-plan” (jihua wai) training classes. 68 See Appendix C for a full listing of this city’s annual training plan.

53 Table 2.2: City Z planned training classes, 2008, by type and enrollment levels Core training Auxiliary training Total classes classes Number of training classes 20 20 40 Enrollment, in number of 1,490 2,295 3,785 students (39%) (61%) 518 417 Enrollment, in student-months 935 (55%) (45%) Note: Row percentages in parentheses. Source: Internal school document.

Out of 40 scheduled classes, an equal share of courses was dedicated to core versus auxiliary programs. While the total number of cadres enrolling in special topic training classes is greater than for core classes, the total student-months dedicated to core training is higher, implying longer core classes.

In terms of which type of training class a cadre might attend, a basic division of students at party schools are those 1) who are paying for degrees, 2a) sent to core training classes and 2b) sent to auxiliary training classes.69 The first population includes graduate students and cadres taking degree courses on weekends or through correspondence courses, mostly to pass a standardized exam and/or fulfill an employment requirement.

Some are allowed to take an extended leave of absence to complete a degree, as is the case for party school teachers interested in earning a graduate degree. This has bearing on promotion prospects insofar as promotion to certain ranks requires particular levels of education.70 Cadres enroll in party school degree programs with these job requirements in mind, and though they are expected to pay from personal funds, in reality their

69 Interview, Central Party School teacher, Interview 17, November 2006. 70 By 1983, the Central Organization Department had called for all leading cadres under 40 years of age to improve their educational credentials by attaining at least a middle school education, technical high school degree, or technical college degree within three years. All future leading cadres were to have at least a high school degree (Manion 1985, p. 223, fn. 66). By 2006, cadres promoted to the leading ranks (county- or department-level and above) required at least a tertiary-level education (daxue zhuanke yi shang wenhua chengdu). See “Questions and answers on cadre promotion policies and regulations,” Yimen Organization Department webpage, available at http://www.yimendj.gov.cn/Article/ShowArticle.asp?ArticleID=216, accessed 30 June 2009.

54 workplace often produces a scholarship or other financial aid. Graduate students,

concentrated at the central and provincial party schools, focus on predictable disciplines

such as party history and socialist theory, but there are also more contemporary

specializations such as law and finance.

Core training programs include routine, periodic (lunxun) training classes for a variety of cadre populations such as those working in mass organizations, minority cadres,

and reserve cadres. Promising cadres with the potential to rise through the ranks are also invited to a key point training for “young cadres” that is common across all party schools.

Interviewees have indicated that invitation to training programs may be a matter of negotiation with direct superiors or at the behest of supervising organization departments.71 Advanced (jinxiu) trainings exist for leading cadres, such as the CPS’

three-month training for cadres at the provincial (ministry) level and five-month training

program for bureau-level cadres. The CPS has an advanced training department

dedicated to crafting these classes at the central level, while local party schools often

lump together advanced and other core training classes as part of the work of their

education departments.

Auxiliary training programs have no generalizable target populations of cadres

and can include cadres of all ranks and functional responsibilities. This increased variety and specialization of party school training classes reflects a broader, more general

emphasis on cadre training in the reform period. The next section will discuss the various

ways party authorities have supported cadre training and turned to party schools as an

instrument for supporting China’s modernization and economic reform.

71 Interviews, CPS department chief training class (chu ji pei xun ban) student, Interview 65, November 2007; provincial party school vice-principal, Interview 66, November 2007.

55 6 Reform-era focus on cadre training

Developments in three areas attest to the growing importance of cadre training in

contemporary China: declarations in speeches and policy documents, investment in

training infrastructure, and growth in training programs for the most promising “young

cadres” (zhongqing nian ganbu). Notably, institutions of cadre training such as party schools, cadre schools, administrative institutes, and cadre executive academies fall squarely under the leadership of the Central Committee, the State Council, the Central

Organization Department, and the Ministry of Personnel, not the Ministry of Education.

This implies, in turn, the positioning of cadre training as a mechanism for party control over cadres and bureaucrats, not simply a means to increase professional competence.

Official declarations of support

Interwoven throughout efforts to systematize and codify cadre training over the past 20 years, there has been official acknowledgement that the ability of the Chinese government to prepare its agents for implementation of reforms hinges on the quality of training programs. Deng Xiaoping declared in 1980,

The current problem, in a nutshell, is not that we have too many cadres but that their training does not match their work, and that too few of them have specialized training in their particular field of endeavor. The solution lies in education. One way is to open schools and training courses for cadres, another is self-education. It is essential for everyone to devote serious effort to study.72

Turning to the most recent generation of CCP leadership, Party Secretary Hu

Jintao declared in his speech before the 17th Party Congress in 2007,

72 Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping, “The Present Situation and the Tasks Before Us,” speech given in Beijing on January 16, 1980, available online at http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/dengxp/vol2/text/b1390.html, accessed 21 March 2007.

56 We must strengthen Party building in all respects. Ideologically, we will focus on fortifying the convictions of Party members. Organizationally, we will put emphasis on bringing up Party members and cadres of quality … We will continue to train cadres on a large scale, making full use of Party schools, schools of administration and cadre academies to substantially improve the quality of cadres … We will develop modern distance learning programs for Party members and cadres in rural areas throughout the country.73

Such pronouncements are part of a larger CCP initiative to transform itself from a

revolutionary party to a ruling party with an emphasis on its ability to “govern” (zhizheng)

and become a “learning party” (xuexi xing zhengdang).74 , president of

the CPS from 2002 to 2007, declared that “Party schools at all levels [are] the main

channel for training the core of high-standard governing personnel, the main front for promoting the building of a learning-type political party.”75 Within this new tact,

“advancing party members’ training on the advanced nature of the party is the most

important measure in strengthening the party’s governance capacity,” (Dai 2006: 317).

Training has been singled out by the party leadership as a vehicle for party reinvigoration

and to raise the oft-invoked but vaguely defined notions of cadre “quality” (suzhi) and

“ability” (nengli).

A slew of policy documents have sought to give administrative flesh to such

ambitious official pronouncements. First, the 2003 Regulations on the Selection of Party

73 Hu Jintao, Report to the 17th Party Congress, Section XII, “Comprehensively carrying forward the great new undertaking to build the party in a spirit of reform and innovation,” 15 October 2007. This section is also where Hu uses the term, “learning party” (xuexi xing zheng dang) to refer to the CCP’s new direction. As early as 2003, he called for raising the quality of party and government cadres in a speech entitled, “Implement the Strategy of Human Resources and a Strong Country, Firmly Uphold the Principle of the Party Managing Human Resources.” 74 The key document is the CCP Central Committee’s “Decision on the Enhancement of the Party’s Governing Capacity”, adopted at the 4th plenum of the 16th Party Congress in 2004. See “CPC issues document on ruling capacity,” Xinhua, 27 September 2004, http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/english/doc/2004-09/27/content_378161.htm, accessed 6 March 2009. Hu Jintao also uses this term in his 2007 Party Congress report. 75 “Zeng Qinghong speaks at Central Party School on Building up Governing Capability,” Xinhua, 24 September 2004.

57 and Government Officials specified that candidates for a leadership post at the county

level or above must have 1) a bachelor’s degree or higher, 2) at least three months of

training in a party school or other executive training program, and 3) at least five years of

work experience (Li 2007a: 24).76 Second, for the period 2003-08, the Central

Organization Department, the powerful bureau charged with party personnel matters, declared that almost 110,000 government and party leaders from the county level up must undergo three months of training over the five-year period (Li 2006).77 Third, in 2004

the COD issued a document to renew focus on cadre training (Central Organization

Department 2004). This was because “strengthening and improving party school work

is … an urgent need of the party” as it faces “global change on many fronts.”78

Performance during training classes was also explicitly linked to cadre evaluation.

A 2006 set of trial regulations for cadre education and training called for a given

student’s “attitude and appearance (taidu he biaoxian), grasp of political theory and

policy, job-related knowledge, and cultural knowledge” to be recorded and referenced

during annual performance evaluations (Central Organization Department 2006: 122-135;

Ministry of Personnel 2006: Section 7). These regulations went so far as to assert that “in

the future, a cadre’s education and training will become one of the key means for

76 The three month training requirement was stipulated as early as 1995, in the Central Committee’s Interim Regulations on Selection and Appointment of Party and Government Leading Cadres. Training could take place at “party schools, colleges of administration, or other training institutes,” (Bo 2004: 82). Interviewees indicated that some officials receive their pre-promotion training after assignment to a new post, but this “make-up training” (bu xun) does not appear to be a common practice. Interview 65 with a former CPS trainee, November 2007 and Interview 191 with a county-level party school vice-principal, May 2008. 77 This figure includes “about 500 provincial-ministerial-level leaders, 8,800 prefecture-division-level leaders, and 100,000 county- and bureau-level leaders [who] must participate in these training programs,” (2006-10 Nationwide Cadre Education and Training Plan, Section 3). 78 For a text of this document, see the Chinese Yearbook of Ideological and Political Work (2001), pp. 50- 54.

58 assessing the cadre’s work and promotion prospects,” (Ministry of Personnel 2006:

Section 7, Article 41).

New investment

Speeches and policy documents may offer a limited sense of trends and intentions;

stronger evidence lays in the dedication of real resources to cadre training. Central finance has earmarked more funds to the general category of cadre training: “In 2005, for instance, the Ministry of Finance raised its own (non-capital construction) spending for cadre training at the central-level by 10.2 percent,” (Pieke 2008: 8).

It is unclear how evenly this funding is spread across training programs, but a building boom is also taking place across local party schools. In site visits to county- and district-level schools in the wealthy coastal Province A, all the schools were in the process of being rebuilt from the ground up on both larger chunks of state land and with expanded facilities. During a visit to one county-level school in this province, the vice- principal boasted to me that the school’s new campus cost 85 million yuan, or approximately 10.6 million dollars.79 While systematic financial data are difficult to

obtain, these figures give a sense of the infusion of funds to party school development.

Targeting young cadres

Training program enrollment levels are another indication as to whether cadre

training is an increasingly important strategy of cadre management. During the period

1997 to 2004, for example, a total of 20.2 million trainees passed through training

79 Half of the investment came from selling the old party school property and the other half was obtained from a direct transfer from the county finance department. Interview 195, May 2008.

59 programs at the provincial, city, and county administrative levels.80 Since the onset of

reforms in 1978, the CPS has trained in excess of 50,000 medium- and high-ranking

cadres.81 There is evidence that within these general statistics, more targeted investment

is being made in specific training classes. One CPS interviewee indicated that there has

been increasing emphasis on “young cadre training classes” and other selective, but

regularly scheduled, training programs.82

Young cadre training classes (zhongqing ban) were noted by interviewees as the

most significant training classes for rising cadre talent. These long-term training

programs, organized at party schools of all administrative levels are invitation-only

classes for those cadres, often in their thirties or forties, with the brightest futures in the

party. For the years where data is available, the pace at which young cadre training

classes grew, at the central level, generally outstripped the growth in the total number of

leading cadres in the country (Table 2.3 below). This is a somewhat noisy trend, though,

since there was a drop in growth of trainees and a spike in the growth of leading cadres in

the mid-1990s. It is not the case that these classes were expanding due to general

increases in the recruitment of new party members, as CCP membership grew at a

relatively slower pace than Young Cadre Training classes.

80 “Accomplishments in party organization work since the 15th Party Congress,” 12 February 2004, http://www.xfdjw.gov.cn/show.asp?id=79, accessed 3 November 2007. This figure is for total training- person sessions, not total individuals trained; some cadres may have attended more than one training session during this period. A total of 114,000 training sessions were organized nationwide during this period at the three levels, averaging a rather high 177 trainees per training session. 81 “China’s Central Party School trains 50,000 officials in 30 years,” Xinhua, 2 October 2007. 82 Interview 216 with a CPS teacher, May 2008. He noted that core, general training programs in the CPS’ Training Department (peixun bu), which organizes these “young cadre training classes”, were receiving more emphasis than the more targeted training classes organized by the Advanced Training Department (jinxiu bu)

60 Table 2.3: Percent increase, over previous year, in CPS Young Cadre trainees, total leading cadres, and total CCP members, select years Percent increase over Percent increase over previous year, total Percent increase over previous year, CPS number of leading cadres the previous year, total Year Young Cadre trainees in the country CCP members 1981 160 9.5 2.4 1982 33.6 8 1.9 1991 22.8 5.4 2.2 1994 12.2 3.2 3.8 1995 3.1 10 1.9 Sources: CPS Yearbooks, 1985-2001, Central Organization Department 1999.

The CPS’ young cadre training enrollment has increased from 1981 to 2000, and

the training class’ share of total CPS trainees has also increased (Table 2.4). This

suggests that party authorities have focused more narrowly on building the political

knowledge, networks, and career prospects of a select group within the administrative

class. Funding data are not available, but these are resource intensive classes since

trainees are housed on campus for duration of the training program (10 and a half months

or 23 months, depending on whether the training class is for one or two years) and sent

on multiple study trips throughout the country and abroad.

Table 2.4: CPS Young Cadre Training Class enrollment, 1980-2000

Total Central Party Young Cadre Training Young Cadre Training School enrollment, in Class, in trainee- Class, as a percent of Year trainee-months months the CPS total 1980 13,920 605 4.3 1981 17,055 1,573 9.2 1982 11,207 2,101 18.7 1990 9,309 1,595 17.1 1991 12,205 1,958 16.0 1993 8,150 1,892 23.2 1994 8,493 2,123 25.0 1995 7,300 2,189 30.0 2000 8,098 2,552 31.5 Source: CPS Yearbooks, 1985-2001

61 These findings suggest that the CCP has placed increasing emphasis on training those leading cadres with the potential to provide long tenures of service to the party.

Tables 2.5 and 2.6 below capture these changes since the founding of the PRC.

Table 2.5: Highest educational attainment of cadres, by historical period Cultural Early PRC, Revolution, Reform era, Education Level 1950-1965 1966-76 1977- No formal education 5.0 0 0 Elementary 20.0 34.0 3.0 Middle school-level vocational 20.0 17.0 12.5 Middle school 30.0 14.9 15.5 High school 20.0 14.9 15.2 Technical school 0 4.3 1.5 Three-year college 5.0 10.7 23.0 Undergraduate 0 4.3 11.4 Graduate and higher 0 0 0.6 N 20 47 279 Notes: Figures are in percentages. Individuals are sorted into periods based on the first year for which they reported a cadre occupation. Source: 2003 China General Social Survey

Table 2.6: Educational attainment of leading cadres after 1982-84 reforms Percent Percent college college educated educated after before 1982- 1982-84 Administrative level 84 reforms reforms Ministers and vice ministers 38 59 Directors and deputy directors of the State Council 35 52 Directors and deputy directors of central party organs 43 53 Heads and deputy heads of bureaus of central party organs 50 56 Provincial party secretaries, governors and vice governors 20 44 Directors and deputy directors of provincial bureaus 14 51 Municipal leaders 14 44 County leaders 14 47 Source: Lee 1991.

Official declarations and documents, funding increases, and targeted investment in early- career cadres lend support to this argument. The creation of entirely new systems of

cadre training organizations, discussed in the following chapters, also supports – and

problematizes – this argument. When considered alongside educational data that Chinese

political elites are now much more highly educated than their counterparts of three

62 decades ago, these changes suggest that reform-era emphasis on cadre training is bound up in the elite transformation that has developed over recent decades (Li and White 1990).

As noted in the previous chapter, this transformation has also occurred with relatively low bureaucratic exit to the private sector, which stresses the importance of retraining efforts.83 Forming cohorts of public managers capable of coping with new market-based realities from the planned economy generation also sets China’s experience apart. Party schools are implicated in this bureaucratic transformation as sites where new bureaucrats are trained and selected for higher office. As the next chapter will detail, these schools are significant organizational channels for moving bureaucratic talent to leading positions within the party and government.

83 To ensure turnover of old revolutionary cadres, the enforcement and diffusion of retirement norms have been an important development; see Manion (1993).

63 Chapter 3 Managing the Managers

Studies of single-party regimes have begun to unpack the “black box” of the party

to understand the informational challenges that party leaders face and the strategies they pursue to address these problems. Hierarchical, single-party systems must solve the problems bound up in the principal-agent relationships that pervade the party and, for party-state systems, characterize the relationship between the ruling party and its state bureaucracy. Understanding the delegation of responsibilities in this relationship requires

an examination of the interests of each set of actors as well as the institutional context in

which policy decisions are made. For the party managers who are principals to the agents

charged with implementing policies and making decisions at the street level, there exist

two problems, one of “hidden action” by agents on the job and a second of “hidden

information” (Braun and Gilardi 2006; Epstein and O'Halloran 2006; Milgrom and

Roberts 1992; Miller 2005). Problems of “hidden action”, or moral hazard, are mitigated

through monitoring and the structuring of incentives.84 Both “police patrol” and “fire

alarm” mechanisms, which draw upon the monitoring abilities of higher authorities and

receiving publics, respectively, may curb agents’ temptation to shirk their administrative

duties (Lorentzen 2008; Lupia and McCubbins 1994; McCubbins and Schwartz 1984).

More generally, principals may devise both ex ante and ex post strategies for coping with

these agency problems (Huang 1995; Schubert 2002).

84 Huang (2002b) presents an overview of the direct and indirect controls in place to cope with problems of hidden action in the Chinese bureaucracy. A related discussion of the inability of authorities in the Soviet Union to solve the moral hazard problem within the bureaucracy and the contribution of “hidden action” by bureaucrats to regime breakdown, see Solnick 1998 and Solnick 1996.

64 The problem of hidden information arises prior to and compounds the difficulties

presented by moral hazard. Private information possessed by agents about their abilities

hinders the work of higher level party officials since the ability of superiors to set

objectives for agents depends on private information about agents’ abilities (Miller 2005:

138-158). Hidden information also affects personnel decisions regarding hiring, firing

and promotion and can result in adverse selection. In political labor markets affected by adverse selection, the presence of hidden information by the bureaucratic agents

competing for official posts can result in two undesirable outcomes for the party:

increasing the cost to the party of supplying services or decreasing the revenues the party

is able to collect (Milgrom and Roberts 1992: 149-159). Findings in studies of executive

and legislative control over the U.S. bureaucracy suggest that appointment processes,

which include decisions about structure as well as personnel, have the largest influence

on policy outcomes: “Only if there is slippage at the appointment stage do either agency

discretion or after-the-fact political control take on any importance,” (Calvert,

McCubbins, and Weingast 1989: 605).

Furthermore, among the various external and internal influences on a bureaucrats’

compliance with organizational objectives, the most important are inherent to the agents

themselves. That is, selecting agents with professional, functional preferences that are

consistent with the objectives of the organization yields more effective bureaucratic

administration than the monitoring used to address problems of hidden action. In this

sense, “the process of selecting and indoctrinating bureaucrats is the process that

matters … [and] the problem of adverse selection trumps the problem of moral hazard,”

(Brehm and Gates 1997: 202).

65 There exist two alternatives for mitigating this selection problem: inducing agents

to reveal private information or devising strategies to screen for certain types of agents.

These differ in terms of the initiating party. Agents may signal their abilities in a bid to

differentiate themselves from less qualified contenders, for example through education credentials (Spence 1973). Signaling may be a powerful mechanism for overcoming selection issues, but they depend on the accuracy and credibility of a signal for conveying information. An educational signal is accurate so long as low productivity (or less desirable) workers are not able to or uninterested in expending the effort to attain the higher levels of education that signal high productivity.

In contemporary China, a credentialing frenzy has taken hold of the bureaucratic class. Party and government bureaucrats now signal their abilities through ever more and

higher educational credentials (Lee 1991; Li 2007b). The expansion of higher education

and the emergence of technocratic norms have contributed to this movement. However,

signaling by bureaucratic agents may break down for at least two reasons. First, there are

limited ways an individual can signal certain unobservable qualities that may be valuable

to the party, such as commitment to the political system. Political authorities may instead opt to design ways to screen for these qualities. Second, credentials may not signal

ability accurately. Following the unrest of the Cultural Revolution, in which the

educational sector shut down and a “lost generation” of uneducated citizens entered the

market for political office, many high ability bureaucrats did not possess requisite

credentials. One consequence was a pool of political and managerial talent lacking outward signs of competence. While many of these individuals have sought to obtain

66 higher education degrees in the decades since, the variation in degrees and degree- granting institutions presents yet another complication.85

In addition to agent signaling, principals may devise and rely upon screening

mechanisms to differentiate between the abilities of competing agents. From this

perspective, selection for enrollment in an educational institution may also serve a

screening purpose (Arrow 1973). Schools serve as “double filters” – in the selection of

students and the evaluation of students over the course of their schooling. In an

authoritarian political system where the ruling party wishes to screen agents on a variety

of dimensions – objective managerial skills, policy expertise, and party loyalty – the use

of party-controlled screening mechanisms remains a politically logical move for party

authorities (Zhao and Zhou 2004). Political criteria, which may render the screening

strategy adopted less efficient than relying purely on educational credentials (Stiglitz

1975), nonetheless explains the persistence of party-managed organizations for training

and credentialing bureaucrats.

This selection problem becomes even more salient during a period of transition,

when central party decision makers begin to value one type of agent over another. In

communist party systems, the transition from planned to market economies demanded a

new type of public manager. While party membership may continue to serve a

preliminary screen, political loyalty is not enough. Public managers in a market economy

face new challenges: enforcing vastly changed and increasingly complex regulations,

forming relationships with contractors in the new private sector, and, in some cases,

making shrewd decisions about public investment and enterprise.

85 As the analysis below will show, degrees from party schools are often sought by cadres but are not correlated with an increased likelihood of promotion.

67 Scholars have documented the bureaucratic transformation that has taken place to

cope with the demands of economic transition (Lee 1991; Walder 1995). Bound up in

this Deng-era push for “a more educated and specialized” bureaucratic class have been

efforts by party authorities to retain control over who is selected to move from a party

activist to party manager role – who shall represent the party, carry out the tasks of

governance, and also benefit from the privileges of office. Controlling promotion to and

within the cadre ranks is crucial because cadres – and leading cadres in particular – make

the decisions that radiate throughout the millions of party members charged with toeing

the party line and maintaining party rule over the general population (Walder and Zhao

2006).

In this chapter, I will first detail the scope of the selection problem facing CCP leaders. Then, drawing on data collected in the 2003 China General Social Survey, I will test whether party school training has an effect on promotion to higher office. This chapter also examines patterns in the career trajectories of cadres trained at the Central

Party School to determine which posts in the party and government such high-level party

school alum eventually occupy. As pipelines to higher office, party schools constitute an

organizational means within the party to control access to positions of authority.

2 Scope of the selection problem

Who is a member of the political elite in China? Scholars have identified this

population in general by employing a variety of criteria, beginning with the vague

parameter of those in possession of “decisive” political power (Smith 1979: Appendix A)

or those who enjoy “exclusivity, superiority, and domination” (Farmer 1992: 2). This is

68 consistent with Putnam’s (1976) emphasis on those who “influence[e] the policies and activities of the state, or (in the language of systems theory) the … authoritative allocation of values,” (p. 6). These definitions, which have the advantage of comparative application, are difficult in practice to apply defensibly to particular cases. In earlier work, Mills’ (1959) defines a “power elite” as those in positions of authority. I draw from this precedent and employ a positional, or occupational, approach to defining the political elite in China. Those members of the party and state bureaucracy who have attained some “leading” rank at the level of county magistrate or equivalent, are considered members of the political elite within China, though attaining such rank often requires marching up the grassroots ranks of the party-bureaucracy or civil service. The disadvantage of this approach is its emphasis on formal title, as opposed to informal bases of power, which is risky in an increasingly diverse Chinese society where entrepreneurial talent, global connections, and political authority may be interconnected but separate bases of political influence.

In a Leninist system, cadres are responsible for party and government administration at various levels of government and across functional areas of specialization. This population of party and government managers is then divided into increasingly smaller and exclusive ranks, at one time up to 25 ranks in the PRC.86 “To distinguish itself from the Nationalist Government that it had fought in a civil war, the

CCP referred to its functionaries by the generic term ‘cadre’ (ganbu), regardless of whether they worked for the party, the Government or the army. In this usage, cadre referred to those who had a certain level of education (initially secondary school level),

86 Interview 112 with a Central Party School teacher and party historian, February 2008. Today, the ranking system has been streamlined to two ranks per administrative level, and this system is compatible with the hierarchy within the ministry system.

69 who had some specialist ability, and who carried out ‘mental’ rather than ‘manual’

labor,” (Burns and Bowornwathana 2001: 23).87 More bluntly, a cadre is anyone who

“eats the state’s grain” (chi guojia liang shi).88

At present, the Chinese bureaucracy, in all its organizational variety, comprises over 46.5 million individuals.89 Table 3.1 below offers a sketch of the size of the entire bureaucratic system and levels within the system:

Table 3.1: The organization of public officials in China, 1998 Administrative Administrative N “leading” Examples Level Rank (lingdao) cadres? Township and Section (ke) level ~46 million No Section head in a below and below county-level ministry, township party secretary County Department (chu) 500,576 Yes County party secretary, level mid-level supreme court judge City Bureau (siju, 45,688 Yes City mayor, Provincial diting) level party school principal Provincial Ministry (bu) level3,665 Yes Ministry head Central Premier (zongli) Yes Source: COD (1999) and Heilmann et al. (June 2000).

At the very top of this hierarchically-organized system is a stratum of individuals whose appointments are managed by the Central Committee of the CCP.90 A slightly larger population of “leading cadres” (lingdao ganbu) comprises officials from the county and department levels on up. This group, collectively, possesses local policymaking and allocation authority for the party and state. Leading cadres maintain the party’s political dominance and the state’s administrative authority. This nomenklatura and leading cadre class produces the policies which the rest of the bureaucracy must implement (Burns

87 Burns draws from Strauss’ distinction between “lettered official” (wenguan), public servant (gungwuyuan) and cadre (ganbu) and Lee (1991) for this definition of cadre. 88 Interview 112, Central Party School party history department, February 2008. 89 For a breakdown of this figure by funding type, see Ang 2008. Shambaugh distinguishes party cadres, which number 6.9 million, from state cadres, which number 33.6 million. He cites a 2002 Central Organization Department source for these numbers. These differ from the Ang figures, which derive from a 2003 Ministry of Finance publication and include public service unit employees. 90 Changes in nomenklatura are reviewed in Burns (1994; 2003)

70 1989b; Burns 2006). In 1998, this category of political and administrative leaders, or

“leading cadres”, totaled 549,929 individuals (Central Organization Department 1999).

In other words, the more than 45 million public officials in China must be sifted through to produce an elite decision-making corps of fewer than 1 million.

Walder (2004) sums up the selection process at work within this bureaucratic population and the critical importance of party and bureaucratic discipline:

The political elite of 500,000 cannot rule the country unless it can retain the obedience of 40 million state cadres — especially the 38 per cent of whom are Party members. … If the elite maintains the discipline of state bureaucrats and the allegiance of Party members, it can withstand challenges from other groups in society, even in periods of economic hardship and social upheaval. If, however, challenges from other groups stimulate a defection of the Party membership and parts of the state bureaucracy, the elite is in real trouble (this is what happened in China, temporarily and briefly, in May 1989).

This discussion illustrates what is at stake should the party lose control over its elite cadre ranks, though smart political selection is aimed at mitigating this problem.

CCP authorities thus face an enormous selection problem: they must devise strategies for choosing from among the 46 million low-ranking cadres at the lowest, deputy-section level to promote to the leading ranks at the county (department), city

(bureau), provincial (ministry), and central levels. Fewer than 600,000 individuals populate these elite levels of the party and government hierarchies, which translates to a selection rate of less than two percent. Low bureaucratic turnover, as discussed previously, also contributes to the tight competition for elite posts. To determine who

will be the one in a hundred to earn a place among the leading cadre ranks, the CCP has

in place the regulatory and organizational framework to vet cadres through party schools.

71 Cadre training at party schools is not the only solution, however. Across

authoritarian systems, there exist a variety of pathways for resolving this selection

problem. Performance evaluation presents one alternative. Cadre evaluation has evolved

considerably from a system of annual reviews based on vague performance standards to

an increasingly regularized and rule-based institution, though it is still weakened by

patronage relations (Chow 1988; Chow 1993; Heimer 2006; Minzner 2009).

Modifications to evaluation criteria over time also indicate “adaptive learning on the part

of principals” (Whiting 2004: 101). Evaluation systems are a significant aspect of the

CCP’s overall ability to monitor cadre behavior, but they require costly, police-patrol

monitoring. The recent cadre evaluation procedures tested and promulgated in 2006 are

even more onerous on local party personnel bureaus, as they call for internal party

assessments along with feedback from the public (Guo and Gore 2007). Furthermore,

evaluation objectives are difficult to identify as the efforts of local officials do not relate

directly or immediately to local developmental outcomes (Landry 2003). Monitoring and

evaluation of cadre behavior has been further complicated by the entry of market

institutions, which create incentives for opportunistic activity while placing greater stress

on the party’s monitoring capacity (Nee and Lian 1994).

Another alternative for identifying political talent is through controlled elections.

Elections are a common feature of non-democratic regimes; during the post-World War II

period, 98 out of 101 non-democracies held at least one legislative or presidential

election.91 In PRI-ruled Mexico, for example, elections were employed nationwide for the

selection of local and national leaders and to provide party leaders with information on

91 Analysis of the Przeworski et al. dataset in which regime type is coded based on the presence of competitive elections (Przeworski et al. 2000).

72 public opinion and candidates’ mobilizational abilities (Magaloni 2006). In the Chinese

case, elections began as village-level experiments in the 1980s and have since become

compulsory exercises nationwide. As a selection mechanism, elections have been limited

to the very lowest levels of governance and are proceeding slowly, on a trial basis only,

to the township and county levels.92

Selection through party schools may also coexist with patronage networks and the privileges accruing to hereditary ties. Clientelism in CCP court politics has long been a topic of study, and there is also evidence of the benefits of a “princeling” background for

high political office (Li 2008a; Nathan 1973).93 This reflects the mix of impersonal and

personal in China’s bureaucratic culture, where there exists the “paradox of bureaucratic

impersonality and personalization of administrative ties” (Zhou 2010). While these

personal networks are difficult to trace in practice, their influence may be bound up in the

processes by which individuals are invited to and evaluated in a party school training

program. Party school training thus reflects the distillation of many disparate pieces of

information about a particular candidate and her likelihood to perform well in higher

office. From this informational perspective, selection through party school training programs carries advantages over selection though alternatives such as performance evaluation. In short, a nationwide network of schools provides the systematic, orderly option that is consistent with the CCP’s drive to deepen the institutionalization of party governance.

92 Studies of are extensive, and local party officials may use election results to gather information on local political talent. Reviews of this literature are numerous (Alpermann 2001; Epstein 1996; Gadsden and Thurston 2001; Kelliher 1997; Manion 1996; Oi and Rozelle 2000). 93 This is despite official COD regulations, for example those against employing family members in the same work unit. See Bo (2004).

73 All of these control mechanisms point to the dense, overlapping institutions that

contribute to the crucial task of personnel management. Whereas elections are risky and

performance evaluations are resource-intensive, vetting candidates through party schools

may capture whether a candidate possesses various ingredients for political success in

China. These include the desire and ability to signal political ambitions, access to

political networks, and managerial potential. As the organizations where these various

individual qualities may be observed and developed, party schools are key sites for

building China’s administrative and political elite.

3 Party school training: A pipeline to higher office

There is both official and unofficial support for the argument that party school

training performs a gatekeeping function. The Chinese popular press has reported, “on

[the Central Party School] campus even taxi drivers stop for pedestrians because they

don’t know whether that someone crossing the street in front of them may be the CCP’s

next party secretary.”94 Such recent, and often positive, coverage of the Central Party

School in the popular press, domestic and foreign, suggests more critical testing of

competing hypotheses regarding the substance of party schools’ role within the CCP.95

In the provisional 2006 Cadre Education and Training Work Regulations, a cadre’s

education and training record is considered an “important factor for promotion” (Article

41).96 Development of cadre training and education is also a recommendation proffered

94 Southern Weekend (Nanfang Zhoumo), “China’s most special school – the Central Party School,” 8 November 2007. 95 For coverage of the party school system in English language outlets, see for example Melinda Liu and Jonathan Ansfield, “Life of the Party,” Newsweek, 30 May 2005. 96 For a full text of the trial regulations, see http://wlzx.hdpu.edu.cn/zzb/Article_Show.asp?ArticleID=858 http://www.sz.gov.cn/rsj/zcfggfxwj/zcfgjgfwjqt/rsbzgbywpx/200809/t20080917_50492_4369.htm, accessed August 2008. Training requirements applied to SOE managers as early as 1991, when a decision

74 in the internally-circulated (neibu) 2004 publication, Research on Certain Questions in

Building a Governing Party (zhizheng dang jianshe ruogan wenti yanjiu). As one official expressed, “Training is critical to promotion because we are a one-party system, and the party needs training to control human resources.”97 Media accounts further claim that

“one-third of Young Cadre Training Class graduates [from the Central Party School] are promoted to the provincial (ministry) rank.”98 Young Cadre Training Classes, which all party schools convene each year in accordance with local training plans, remain the most selective and prestigious programs for ambitious party officials.

Despite these assertions, the actual effect of party school training on a cadre’s promotion prospects remains unexamined. Furthermore, whether party schools serve this functional purpose within party organization remains untested in extant literature. The existence of “party-sponsored upward mobility” does suggest that party school training, as an educational option nested within a larger universe of party-related educational paths, serves a sorting function in the context of party personnel policy (Li 2001; Li and Walder

2001). To date, no scholarly work on party schools has tested whether schools are an organizational strategy for addressing the selection problem inherent to a large and complex bureaucratic system. This chapter thus presents several empirical tests of the argument that party school training constitutes a channel for individuals to move up the cadre ranks. This in turn investigates whether and how Leninist mechanisms of cadre control remain relevant in the transition to a market economic context.

was made at a National Enterprises Leader Training Conference: “Starting in 1993, all leaders of the nation’s large- and medium-size enterprises would not be qualified for their leading positions unless they received a certificate of professional training issued by the National Economic and Managerial Cadre Training Committee,” (Liu 2001: 107). 97 Interview with a retired central-level ministry cadre, Interview 34, October 2007. 98 Zhao Xue, “China’s most special school – the Central Party School,” Southern Weekend, 8 November 2007.

75 This line of reasoning stands in contrast to the null hypothesis, discussed

previously, regarding the purpose of party schools in the CCP’s organizational universe.

It may be the case that party schools are only a reward for cadres who may have earned

the opportunity to withdraw from work responsibilities for several days or weeks to relax

on a party school campus. In this sense, time spent at party schools constitutes a “club good” to be shared among party managers. In interviews, some cadres also expressed a belief that party school “vacations” are part of the perks of a cadre occupation. “Maybe

10 to 20 percent of all section-level cadres will be chosen to attend the city [party school’s] Young Cadre training class, and being sent to this is really a reward of some

sort.”99 From this perspective, invitation to a party school training class does not

necessarily indicate potential to climb the administrative ranks. Instead, the invitation to

train at a party school is an end unto itself.

To adjudicate between these hypotheses, national survey data (from the 2003

China General Social Survey) will be used to test the following:

ƒ Hypothesis 1 (null) Party schools as rewards: If a cadre attends a party school training program, then s/he is not more likely to be promoted to a higher administrative rank.

ƒ Hypothesis 2 Party schools as pipeline to higher office: If a cadre attends a party school training program, then s/he is more likely to be promoted to a higher administrative rank.

The latter hypothesis implies that party school training of any amount has a positive effect on a cadre’s promotion prospects.

Results from tests of these hypotheses suggest that enrollment in different types of party school training programs affects whether a cadre is promoted and how quickly.

99 Interview with a city-level cadre, January 2008, Interview 104. This sentiment was echoed in another interview with a towship-level cadre, May 2008, Interview 196.

76 The first test considers the subset of cadres within a national survey of Chinese citizens

(N=589). I employ this data to ascertain whether the “treatment” of training at a party school has a positive effect on career advancement. Selection bias poses a methodological challenge for identifying the effect of training, and I employ propensity score matching in an attempt to correct for this. Results from estimating the average treatment effect of training show that individuals who have been selected for a party school training program are more likely to reach a higher administrative rank compared to individuals with similar characteristics but no training experience.

This test captures the general, positive effect of all party school training programs on career advancement, but field interviews suggest that the most important training program for upward bound cadres is the Young Cadre Training Class organized by party schools throughout the system. A second empirical test considers a subset of the leading cadre population, those who have attended the Central Party School’s version of this class.

Analysis of the career histories of this elite population demonstrates that individuals who participate in this highly selective training course reach high office at younger ages than the national average, thus laying the groundwork for long tenures of service to the party.

4a Analyzing the effect of training in the 2003 China General Social Survey

Ideally, promotion serves two functions within organizations: to match individuals of certain skills with appropriate office and to generate incentives for improved performance (Baker, Jensen, and Murphy 1988). In trying to identify the effect of training on promotion, selection bias arises as a methodological problem. It may be the case that cadres with certain characteristics are more likely to be selected for party

77 schools and promoted, and these confounding factors confuse the true effect of party

school training on cadre promotion. To determine the effect of training, the

counterfactual question to answer is, what would have happened to the careers of those who received the treatment of party school training if they had not received treatment?

Conversely, what would have happened if those who were not sent to training were given

a party school training opportunity? One way to estimate the effect of a treatment is

through experimental design: randomly assigning treatment to an individual and none to

another, identical individual. When such an experimental approach is not possible, as in

the present study, an alternative is to create a counterfactual group by matching survey

respondents along a set of observable characteristics.

I employ propensity score matching, a technique to reduce selection bias by

predicting via a probit regression and a set of observed predictors the probability that an

individual will be in a treatment versus control group. Pre-treatment characteristics are

summarized in a propensity score for matching purposes. After determining propensity

scores for each individual, randomly drawn nearest neighbor matching from the common

support region is employed: an individual in the treatment group is matched to an

individual in the control group based on the closeness of their propensity scores. In the

case of a tie between individuals in the control group, a match is randomly drawn

between tied controls for a given individual in the treatment group. Drawing from the

common support places an overlap condition on the individuals that may be matched and

maximizes exact matches while excluding more cases of inexact matching. The average

treatment effect on the treated (ATT) is then determined by differencing the mean values

on an outcome variable across matched individuals from the two groups.

78 Propensity score matching reduces, but does not eliminate selection bias entirely.

Bias exists so long as treatment is not assigned completely randomly to two individuals

with the same propensity score (Becker and Ichino 2002). Furthermore, it is limited in

that hidden biases may still remain because matching only controls for observed variables

included in the first-stage probit regression (Pearl 2000). Mismatch error is also difficult

to calculate using this technique (Lan and Rosenbloom 1992). Yet propensity score

methods, while imperfect, have been shown to produce results closer to experimental

treatment effects than nonexperimental estimates (Dehejia and Wahba 1999).

Data for this analysis were obtained from the China 2003 General Social Survey,

a representative national sample comprising 5,894 Chinese citizens. A total of 589

respondents reported careers subject to the party and government ranking system.

Table 3.2: Descriptive summary of cadre and general population Cadres General Population N=589 N=5,894 Variable Mean SD Min Max Mean SD Min Max Age 50.8 12.1 20 72 43.4 13.1 15 77 Total years of 6.8 4.6 0 70 4.3 3.5 0 70 education Years of CCP 22.4 13.1 0 56 19.6 13.2 0 56 membership Source: 2003 China GSS

This survey was jointly conducted by the Hong Kong University of Science and

Technology Research Center and the Sociology Department of the People’s University of

China.100 Table 3.2 summarizes characteristics of the cadre sub-population within the

general population surveyed. Within this population, 156 (26.5 percent) were female and

408 (69.2 percent) were CCP members. This compares with a CCP membership of 18.6

100 A report of the CGSS sampling design and survey methodology is available at http://www.ust.hk/~websosc/survey/GSS2003e0.html. Tibet, Hong Kong, , and Taiwan were excluded from the survey. The ratio of the urban sample size to the rural sample size is 5900:4100, giving an urban bias to the sample. First-stage egression estimates are presented with weights to compensate for this.

79 percent among the sampled population, of which 51.9 percent were female.101 Somewhat

contrary to Deng’s prescription for transforming the cadre population, cadres in this

sample were older than the general population. Consistent with Deng’s mandate,

however, this group was more educated and possessed longer tenures of CCP

membership compared to the general population. Mean comparison tests show that

differences in each of these areas are statistically significant at the 0.01 level.

The outcome of interest is whether, conditional on party school training, a cadre is

more likely to be promoted to the next higher administrative rank. A dummy outcome

variable was coded for the three administrative categories for which there are sufficient

survey respondents in the China GSS: no rank/section rank, section rank/department rank

and no rank/some rank. Due to small population size, a separate analysis was not

conducted on those who reported a bureau rank (ditingju ji) or higher in their careers

(N=15). The histogram below summarizes the distribution of administrative ranks over

the 589 surveyed cadres:

Figure 3.1: Frequency of administrative rank, 2003 China GSS

400

350

300

250 241 No party school 200 Attended party school

150 Total individuals Total

100 100 63 50 108 9 27 35 0 6 Below Section Section Department Above Department Rank

101 The national numbers are lower: according to 2007 figures, total CCP membership stood at 5.6 percent of the total population. See “Chinese Communist Party membership exceeds 74 million in 2007”, Xinhua, 1 July 2008, available online at http://www.china-embassy.org/eng/gyzg/t470863.htm, accessed 28 December 2008. National population figures available from China Data Online.

80

A dummy variable which captures whether an individual attended a non-diploma

training program at a party school is hypothesized to have a significant, positive

correlation with the administrative rank outcome variables. These are the programs in

which cadres are chosen by local organization departments or work units, not the degree-

based programs with open enrollment.

The first-stage probit regression model will estimate individual-level propensity

scores of the treatment (non-diploma party school training) on several demographic characteristics, including an individual’s age, gender, and total years of schooling.102

Individuals also reported their socio-economic status.103 Political control variables

included an individual’s party membership and that of his parents, whether or not an

individual served in the military, and whether an individual was “sent down” to the

countryside for hard labor during the Cultural Revolution. Finally, a dummy variable

coded for whether an individual self-reported frequent interaction with his direct

managers.104 Individuals’ home provinces were also coded as a set of dummies.

Descriptive statistics of these variables are reported in Appendix D. Table 3.3 below

gives the results from the first-stage probit regression analysis, where the dependent

variable is whether an individual was chosen for party school training.105

Several of these control variables were statistically significant. Unsurprisingly,

party membership was an important characteristic among those selected for party school

102 Alternate specifications for these control variables included total years in the workforce (instead of age) and highest educational level attained. 103 While self-reported and subjective, these dummy variables were used instead of income data. There were irregularities with self-reported income data, for example individuals reported monthly and annual incomes that were often inconsistent. 104 These data are unanchored. The nature of these interactions and the actual frequency as a measure of time per week, for example, were not given in the data. 105 This model was estimated using the pscore command in Stata.

81 training, though parents’ party membership was not. Those with military backgrounds

were less likely to undergo party school training, and this may be due to the separate career track – along with related training at military academies – for individuals in the

military. Since the early 1980s, with policies to encourage the professionalization of the

PLA, there has been increased emphasis on the recruitment and training of military

officers at military academies (Zheng 1997: 228-231). Those with “sent down” experiences were also less likely to attend a party school training class, but this was marginally significant at the 10 percent level. It is unclear why these particular life

events might be negatively correlated. Some provincial-level dummy variables were significant, both substantively and statistically, in the first-stage probit regression, but there does not exist a theoretical explanation for why these particular locales might

Table 3.3: Probit regression results for propensity score estimation DV: non-degree party school training Robust program (dummy) Coefficient SE ** Constant -2.05 0.90 Age 0.001 0.01 Female -0.05 0.18 Education (total years) -0.01 0.02 SOE level (lower middle) -0.26 0.25 SOE level (upper middle) -0.12 0.24 SOE level (upper) -0.06 0.31

Political control variables (dummies) *** CCP membership 1.24 0.20 Father’s CCP membership -0.02 0.18 Mother’s CCP membership 0.19 0.25 *** Military experience -0.44 0.18 * Sentdown experience -0.41 0.23 Frequent interaction with superiors 0.32 0.50

Provincial-level dummies Beijing 0.29 0.60 Tianjin 0.65 0.59 Hebei 0.70 0.66 Shanxi 0.04 0.86

82 Robust Provincial-level dummies, continued Coefficient SE Neimenggu 0.95 0.71 Liaoning 0.04 0.65 Jilin 1.34 0.88 Heilongjiang 0.09 0.82 Shanghai 0.89 0.60 Jiangsu 0.71 0.64 0.55 0.82 Anhui -0.33 0.63 Fujian 0.68 0.68 Jiangxi 0.63 0.74 Shandong 0.29 0.68 Henan -0.23 0.63 ** Hubei 1.41 0.61 ** Hunan 1.17 0.61 Guangdong 0.45 0.60 Guangxi 0.44 0.64 ** Chongqing 1.95 0.83 Sichuan 0.68 0.73 Guizhou -0.78 0.75 Yunnan 0.58 0.63 Shaanxi -0.46 0.79 * Gansu 1.30 0.73 Iteration 0: log pseudolikelihood -351.59717 Iteration 1: log pseudolikelihood -279.76579 Iteration 2: log pseudolikelihood -275.81003 Iteration 3: log pseudolikelihood -275.73312 Iteration 4: log pseudolikelihood -275.73306 N 574 Wald chi2(45) 107.71 Prob > chi2 0 Pseudo R2 0.22 Notes: Significance codes: *** for p<0.01, ** for p<0.05, * for p<0.10. To ensure that the mean propensity score is not different for treated and control groups across blocks, the test of balancing property was satisfied for this model. This tests whether means of covariates are the same across blocks. Dropped categories: “Lower class” SOE level (dummy); Xinjiang regional dummy. Source: China GSS 2003 correlate positively with selection for a party school training class. The table below gives a summary of the marginal effect of each statistically significant control variable. An individual who is a party member, for example, is 44 percent more likely to attend a non-

83 degree party school training program than a non-party member, holding all other characteristics constant.

Table 3.4: Marginal effect for significant control variables Marginal Variable effect CCP membership 0.44 Army experience -0.16 Sentdown experience -0.15 Hubei 0.50 Hunan 0.42 Chongqing 0.69 Gansu 0.46 Notes: Other control variables were held constant at their medians.

During the second stage of the propensity score matching procedure, individuals

are matched based on the proximity of the propensity scores assigned to them in the first

stage probit regression. The histogram and table below illustrate the distribution of

estimated propensity scores for individuals by treatment status. Treated individuals in

Figure 3.2 are tallied in the bins above the horizontal axis, while untreated individuals are

below the axis.

Figure 3.2: Distribution of propensity scores for treated and control groups

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1 Propensity Score

Untreated Treated

The histogram shows that there is overlap between the treatment and control groups for a broad range of propensity scores. Treated individuals with a propensity score of 0.8 and higher have no comparisons in the control group and are not included in estimations of

ATT limited to the common support. However, because of the broad overlap in

84 propensity scores across treated and untreated groups, it is possible to carry out differences-of-means tests across the two groups and determine the ATT.

Table 3.5: Total cadres in treated and control groups, by propensity score block Propensity Control Treated Total score block 0 235 19 254 0.2 97 50 147 0.4 66 60 126 0.6 15 43 58 0.8 0 4 4 Total 413 176 589

The following kernel density graphs demonstrate the distribution of propensity scores across the treatment and control groups both before and after matching. While the kernel densities are not perfectly matched in the post-match graph, the distance between the treatment and control groups has decreased after the matching process.

Figure 3.3: Pre-match propensity Figure 3.4: Post-match propensity score distribution score distribution 3 2 1.5 2 1 1 .5 Kernel density of respondents Kernel density of respondents 0 0

0 .2 .4 .6 .8 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 Propensity score Propensity score

Treated pre-match Control pre-match Treated post-match Control post-match

To confirm that matches are balanced, the results of t-tests for the equality of means in the treatment and control groups, both before and after matching, are presented in Appendix D. There were no statistically significant differences in the means of control variables across the treatment and control groups, post-match, with the exception of the

“lower middle SOE level” dummy. This variable was not significant during the first- stage probit regression, however.

85 Using nearest neighbor matching over the common support, Table 3.6 below presents the ATT on several binary outcomes of interest, whether a cadre was promoted to a section, department, or any rank during his career.

Table 3.6: Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) Treatment: Enrollment in a non-degree party school training class DV N treated N control ATT SE t-statistic Section rank 170 86 0.221 0.078*** 2.861 (dummy) Department rank 170 66 0.137 0.060*** 2.266 (dummy) Any rank 170 96 0.229 0.062*** 3.708 (dummy) Notes: Estimates obtained over the common support using nearest neighbor matching (random draw version). Bootstrapped standard errors are reported (200 replications)

These results are statistically significant at the 99 percent level. For the two administrative ranks with sufficient numbers of surveyed individuals, those who participated in a party school training program had a higher likelihood of promotion than individuals with similar observable characteristics who did not attend party school. To interpret the ATT in substantive terms, an individual who attends party school is 22.1 percent more likely to attain a rank of section chief than a peer who did not attend a party school training class, while this becomes 13.7 percent for attaining the rank of department chief. Those who attended party school training were 22.9 percent more likely to achieve some rank in comparison to untrained peers. Results from propensity score matching confirm the core intuition articulated at the beginning of this section, that party school training has a significant, positive effect on promotion up the ranks of party and government office. It is also notable that the treatment of any non-degree party school training includes all manner of programs, from core to auxiliary to vocational classes, so the effect of training on promotion might be even higher for certain key point

86 classes. Data limitations are such that I am unable to determine the particular type of

training class beyond its degree designation.

In comparison, separate tests to determine the ATT of party school degree

programs found no statistically significant effect (Table 3.7).

Table 3.7: Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) Treatment: Party school degree (dummy) DV N treated N control ATT SE t-statistic Section rank 52 35 0.010 0.104 0.093 (dummy) Department rank 52 38 -0.064 0.100 -0.645 (dummy) Any rank 52 47 0.000 0.075 0.000 (dummy) Notes: Shandong and Guizhou dummies were dropped from the first-stage probit regression (and Xinjiang included) in order to satisfy the balancing property. Estimates obtained over the common support using nearest neighbor matching (random draw version). Bootstrapped standard errors are reported (200 replications)

This suggests that individuals who enroll in party schools for a degree are not more likely

to be promoted to higher administrative ranks, reinforcing the importance of selection

and invitation to a training program. Signaling the intention to serve in the party

bureaucracy by pursuing a party school degree does not appear to yield payoffs in terms

of climbing the career ladder.

On the other hand, individuals who attain a university degree do stand better chances of promotion to the leading cadre ranks (Table 3.8). While a university education does not have an effect on an individual’s promotion to the lowest section ranks, this changes dramatically for the transition from section to department, or non- leading to leading cadre positions. As the table below illustrates, individuals with a

university degree are 25.9 percent more likely to be promoted to the department rank than

peers without a degree. Overall, the findings are somewhat uneven: an individual with a university degree at the lowest administrative ranks might not expect higher chances of

87 promotion, but there does appear to be a strong effect for the transition to a career as a

leading cadre.

Table 3.8: Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) Treatment: University degree (dummy) DV N treated N control ATT SE t-statistic Section rank 122 45 -0.138 0.090 -1.526 (dummy) Department rank 122 50 0.259 0.100*** 2.603 (dummy) Any rank 122 59 -0.057 0.061 -0.948 (dummy) Notes: Estimates obtained over the common support using nearest neighbor matching (random draw version). Bootstrapped standard errors are reported (200 replications)

Finally, what is the combined effect of both party school training and higher

education? Previous studies have shown that the combination of party membership, as a

key political credential, and higher education open the doors to administrative positions

of authority (Walder 1995). Since party school trainees are a subset of the party

membership, this joint effect should be particularly salient for high administrative ranks.

The results from the data, however, are mixed (Table 3.9).

Table 3.9: Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) Treatment: Party school training and university degree (dummy) DV N treated N control ATT SE t-statistic Section rank 39 23 0.038 0.124 0.308 (dummy) Department rank 39 24 0.265 0.131*** 2.017 (dummy) Any rank 39 30 0.051 0.097 0.530 (dummy) Notes: Estimates obtained over the common support using nearest neighbor matching (random draw version). Bootstrapped standard errors are reported (200 replications)

The joint effect of party school training and higher education on the likelihood of promotion to the leading cadre ranks is greater than for either of these credentials alone.

Again, there was no effect on the likelihood of promotion to the section rank or a higher

rank generally, but for the important transition from a section to department rank, individuals with party school training backgrounds and a university degree were 26.5

88 percent more likely to be promoted than their untrained and non-degreed peers. These findings are somewhat inconclusive, however, since only 39 individuals in the sample hold both a university degree and have attended at least one party school training program.

There are additional implications to the hypothesis that party schools prepare cadres for increasing positions of authority in the party. Analysis of career histories shed light on whether party school-trained bureaucrats are more likely to end up in key political, as opposed to technical or administrative, occupations. Previous studies have identified the emergence of “dual track” career patterns in the reform period (Li and

Walder 2001). These tracks capture the tension between authority and expertise in bureaucratic relations. Individuals with technical expertise fill functional posts, whereas individuals who pass through party-sponsored educational programs are channeled to positions with decision-making authority (Table 3.10). The career trajectories of cadres in the sample confirms this trend, where individuals with party school training are more likely to land positions as party leaders rather than more technical positions.

Table 3.10: Occupational categories of cadres, by rank Vice- Vice- section Section dept Dept rank rank rank rank Party school training? Y N Y N Y N Y N Occupation percent percent percent percent percent percent Percent percent CCP cadre 50.01 26.83*** 54.16 33.34*** 70 25.92*** 33.33 31.43 Law and order 5.56 3.66 4.17 5.66 10 3.7 0 2.86 Government 25 19.51 22.22 18.24 10 14.81 13.33 2.86* Economic planning 11.12 12.2 5.56 15.73** 0 11.11* 40 14.28** Education 0 6.1* 5.56 8.19 10 25.92* 13.34 17.15 Other 8.31 31.7*** 8.33 18.84** 0 18.54** 0 31.42*** Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Notes: Code for significance of two-sample t-tests: *** for p<0.01, ** for p<0.05, * for p<0.10. Data: China GSS 2003

89 4b Testing mechanisms

While the analysis presented here suggests that party school training has some effect on a cadre’s likelihood of promotion to a higher rank, the next step is to consider the mechanisms driving this result. At least three mechanisms may be at play, all of which assist party officials with making decisions of bureaucratic selection. First, it might be the case that individuals attend these training classes in order to signal their intentions to pursue careers in the bureaucracies of the party and state, and they might lobby their superiors or organization department leaders in order to attain these credentials. Additionally, it is possible that individuals are more likely to be promoted because of their ability, demonstrated during training, to make strong contacts and forge the political networks that might propel them to higher positions of authority. On the other hand, it may also be the case that party schools serve a screening function for higher party authorities. In this sense, these schools are more of a party-driven – as opposed to cadre-driven – organizational strategy for solving the selection problem facing the rulers of a country with a massive, expanding bureaucracy. These are not mutually exclusive mechanisms and all three may converge on the experience of party school training. The discussion below will consider each mechanism in turn, as well as testing strategies to ascertain which mechanisms may be at play.

Signaling

In assisting personnel officials with hiring, promotion, and other selection decisions, party schools may be used instrumentally by cadres to signal career intentions.

In a competitive market where bureaucratic positions are scarce, those of high ability

90 seek ways to indicate their potential and distinguish themselves from other competitors.

Party school training presents one means for ambitious party officials to signal potential.

In order to accomplish this, an individual might maneuver for an invitation to training classes.106 If this were the case, then individuals attending party school training would all

be of a certain type, i.e., those with a high potential to serve the party well as bureaucratic

managers. For party schools to serve as a signaling device, it must be the case that only

high potential cadres attend, thereby signaling their type. The intuition behind the “party

school as signaling device” story is that the process of undergoing training does not

reveal any information about cadres’ potential or add to a cadre’s abilities. Rather, only

cadres of a certain type attend party schools.

This “high potential” might comprise many characteristics such as loyalty to the

party, managerial talent, and personal connections. Some of these characteristics are

observable and controlled for through the first-stage regression in the matching procedure

detailed above. For example, the regression analysis captured some qualities of an

individual’s political background: his party membership and parents’ CCP membership,

which may be one proxy for party loyalty or the “redness” of an individual’s background.

Education level also controls for managerial ability. In alternate specifications of the

probit regression, dummies for university majors in management and engineering were

statistically insignificant.

106 In the first-stage probit regression results, however, there was no significant correlation between an individual’s selection for party school training and whether or not she interacted frequently with her managers. It is difficult, however, to draw strong conclusions from this finding due to the lack of information the substance of these interactions and their actual frequency. Furthermore, the categories themselves are subject to interpretation by each respondent, as the questions do not include an anchoring measure.

91 The matching strategy employed in this chapter suggests, however, that party

school training serves other functions beyond signaling. This is because individuals who

wish to signal their type through enrollment in a party school training class are matched to those with similar characteristics but who are not selected for training. As the results

from matching indicate, high-ability individuals sent to party school training are still

more likely to be promoted than high-ability matches not sent to party schools. This

supports the prospect that while signaling by cadres may be one mechanism at play, party

school training accomplishes additional functions.

Networks

Scholars have also examined the importance of schools for generating the

political networks, and political capital, that propel bureaucrats to higher office. Putnam

(1976) counts educational institutions among the channels for elite recruitment, alongside parties, bureaucracies, and local governments, due to the professional network-building that takes place in these organizations (pp. 49-52). France’s grandes ecoles are the centerpiece of a long tradition in which public and private elite connections are forged

(Suleiman 1977). In his longitudinal study of political elites in Mexico, Smith (1979) notes the pivotal role of a single national university in building the careers of public officeholders from 1900 to 1971, since it is at this school where students “formed crucial friendships and alliances” (p. 86).

China is no exception, and party-managed institutions of cadre training would be a prime site for the creation of both administrative and personal networks. Party schools are sites for cadres to reinvigorate “both the formal institutional arrangements and

92 informal relationships that make the party-state work,” (Pieke 2009a: 148-151). One

CPS professor, for example, noted glibly how training classes at party schools are a time for cadres to “study, make connections, rest, and eat well (xuexi xuexi, lianxi lianxi, xiuxi xiuxi, mishi mishi).”107 Another city party school vice-principal declared that party

schools “are the only place where networks can be built, which is important for

coordinating across different ministries. … These networks are stronger than college

networks because trainees are concentrated in a locale.”108

While party schools may serve this networking function, which is vital in China’s bureaucratic and business worlds, evidence from field interviews remains mixed.

Interviewees tended instead to cite the social, rather than professional, value of networks

formed during party school training, though the boundaries between these are blurry.

One provincial-level official who attended several training classes at the Central Party

School, for example, could not recall any professional problems that he actually solved

by accessing networks from his party school training classes.109 Two vice-principals at a

city party school were also dismissive of the network-building potential of their party

school training classes. “Most training classes for cadres in leadership positions aren’t

really about building networks. Most students already know each other before they

arrive.”110 Another party school teacher corroborated this and pointed out how “cadres

107 Interview with a CPS professor, Interview 57, October 2007. 108 Interview 131, April 2008. Another interviewee, a teacher at a county-level party school, noted how training classes are a time for officials to “learn about the work in every department [in government],” (Interview 201, May 2008). Along this vein, during one party school training class that I observed in 2008 in Province B, each trainee was given a red-covered class directory (tongxun lu) at the class’s closing celebration. This particular class included mostly university party secretaries, some Communist Youth League party school principals, and the heads of military academies. All of these officials were working in the same inland province. (Participant observation at a party school training class closing banquet, April 2008.) 109 Interview 182, April 2008. 110 Interviews 202 and 203, May 2008.

93 are seeking broad networks, so they want to attend training classes as high up as possible.

They want more than local connections.”111 The success of connections thus depends on

the type of training class a cadre is sent to, the level of the party school, and her individual initiative.

If access to elite networks and the opportunity to create all-important personal

networks are benefits of party school training, this effect is uneven across schools,

programs, and individual cadres. One party school trainee, who was sent to CPS for a one-month, in-residence training class, noted in an interview, “Some students develop

very close relationships, but for me they were nothing special (yi ban de). For me,

networks were not very important in the class that I enrolled in, but this can be an

important aspect of a training class.”112 A county-level official who was sent to a city-

level Young Cadre Training Class reported the opposite experience. “Many of my

classmates [at the Young Cadre Training Class] were city officials, and after training in

2003, I can now just call them and they will take care of (anpai) things for me.”113 Party

school training classes have the potential to generate the personal networks which

enhance individual careers, but the effect appears to be uneven. Until more systematic

data are available to test the utility of these school networks, anecdotal comments from

field interviews paint at best a somewhat murky picture.

111 Former city-level party school teacher, Interview 215, May 2008. 112 Interview with a CPS trainee, now a county-level university official, Interview 65, November 2007. His training class at CPS was for cadres and administrators in universities. 113 Interview with a city-level party school trainee, now a vice-county-level official, Interview 88, December 2007. In an interview with the vice-principal of a provincial-level socialism school, the official also noted that longer classes (“classes longer than two weeks”) are more conducive to the formation of social groups and “social capital”. (Interview 95, December 2007)

94 Screening

Beyond signaling and network formation, selection for party school training may

correlate positively with upward mobility within the party-state apparatus because

training provides party officials with information regarding a particular bureaucrat’s

fitness for higher office. Furthermore, if party schools serve a screening function, it follows that some individuals will not meet the criteria, either formal or informal, established for bureaucrats to continue upward in their careers. To test this, one strategy is to examine post-training career paths. If cadre training itself, and not the selection process for training, serves a screening function, this implies that a certain number of cadres may stall in the upward march of their careers in the periods following party school training. Further analysis of bureaucrats’ careers captured in the China GSS and the official biographies of Central Party School alumni reveals that not all bureaucrats selected for training move to higher administrative ranks.

Within the population of bureaucrats in the China GSS, a total of 94 out of the

589 individuals in the sample, or 16 percent, were not promoted to a higher rank following enrollment in a party school training class. Career histories collected on the officials sent to key point Young Cadre Training Classes at the Central Party School offers additional evidence (Table 3.11). These longer term classes, which last anywhere from several weeks to one year, provide central authorities with an extended period of time to observe the behavior – e.g., knowledge of party policies, leadership ability – of select managers. While a certain degree of screening takes place during the selection process that culminates in an invitation to the class, further screening takes place during

95 the one- and two-year training process at the Central Party School. The table below on

post-training promotion paths suggests that some screening does occur:

Table 3.11: Cadres who do not experience promotion, 2000 and 1995 classes Difference in rank, (present rank - rank at time of training) N Percent 0 45 16.73 1 145 55.13 2 64 24.33 3 10 3.80 Total 264 100.00

Those individuals whose difference in rank, i.e., their rank in 2009 minus their rank at the

time of training, is zero have stalled in their careers. Based on available data,

approximately 17 percent of trainees are not promoted at all following their enrollment in

the elite CPS Young Cadre training class. This is similar to the “stall rate” in the general

cadre population sample. This figure is not surprising, given the intense competition to

reach higher ranks. While 1.26 percent of all cadres eventually become leading cadres

(department rank and above), only 1 percent eventually attain a bureau rank and this is

whittled down to 0.005 percent at the provincial/ministerial level. If, during ten or more

months of highly monitored training, a cadre lets slip any sign that he is unsuitable for the

responsibilities of national leadership, potential replacements are already being prepared

from among the hundreds toiling away in lower ranks.

Table 3.12 below lists the career tracks of CPS-trained bureaucrats who have

stalled in their careers despite the investment of one year of training in their skills sets.

Of these 45 individuals who were not promoted to a higher rank following their enrollment in the CPS Young Cadre Training Class, the largest number were on a propaganda career track. About one quarter of those who stalled were in economic

96 management positions, while the remainder were evenly distributed across science and engineering, security, and law-related occupations.

Table 3.12: Career tracks of CPS trainees in stalled careers (1995 and 2000 classes) Career track N Percent Science/Engineering 5 11.36 Security 6 13.64 Law 6 13.64 Economic management 11 25.58 Propaganda 17 38.64 Total 45 100.0

In short, evidence exists to support the line of reasoning that party school training serves some sort of screening function. This is in addition to or instead of a signaling function; the tests presented in this chapter cannot adjudicate between whether the signaling or screening function is more salient, only that party schools potentially serve both functions. Further tests might also establish the criteria used to screen cadres within these training classes. Creating tests to separate which of these mechanisms is truly at play presents a challenge, given data constraints, but the present analysis suggests that information about individual bureaucrats is revealed during party school training and does have some effect on the subsequent achievement of higher office. In other words, party school training is more than a device used instrumentally by ambitious cadres who desire high office and more than a reward distributed to loyal servants of the party.

Training is also a device used by party officials to assess cadres’ potential.

4c One leading cadre’s story

Statistical tests illuminate patterns and tendencies, but individual stories lend nuance to the life and career trajectories of cadres. The experiences of one such official, randomly chosen from the 2003 China GSS data, add texture to the numbers presented in

97 the previous sections.114 This official became a leading, department-level (chuji) cadre in

1984, at a state-owned business in Guangdong. She was 45 at the time of promotion and

retired only 11 years later (in 1995). As this was a relatively late promotion, chuji was

the highest rank she acquired over her working lifetime. Such a career achievement was all the more remarkable because this cadre reached a high rank despite some unlikely

personal background characteristics: she had only a middle school level of education,

neither of her parents was a party member, and she joined the party at the relatively late

age of 37. Her workplace relationships may have facilitated this advancement, however,

given that she reported “frequent” interaction with her superiors, subordinates, and

workplace peers.

She spent the entirety of her 37-year working life in a series of state-owned

enterprises (guoyou qiye) and state-owned businesses (guoyou shiye). Her occupations ranged from teaching at an elementary school located within a state-owned business, accounting at an SOE, and finally managing a state-owned business. The critical year in her career history was 1978, when she switched from accounting to administration and was promoted to a section-ranking position. This was followed in 1984 with promotion to the department rank as a company leader (qiye fuze ren). The timing of this official’s training history is illustrative: in 1978, the year of her first promotion, she attended a six- month training program at a city-level party school. This was the only time she attended a party school.

Taking such a condensed tour through one individual’s life history fleshes out the preceding analysis in at least two respects. First, a party school training course was the launching point for this official’s transition to an administrative-managerial career within

114 This was survey respondent 1224.

98 the state-owned sector. Data are limited, but it would be ideal to know what type of

training class this was and what kind of training content she might have been exposed to.

It is likely that her training was a combination of remedial education, orthodox theory,

and basic administrative coursework. Key point young cadre classes did not yet exist in

1978. Second, party school training preceded her promotion to the lowest, section-level

rank but did not precede her promotion to the higher, department level. This is consistent

with the statistical findings presented earlier, which show that the impact of party school

training is most pronounced, for rank-and-file cadres, at lower administrative ranks.

5 The select few: Central Party School Young Cadre Training classes

While analysis of the CGSS demonstrated that enrollment in party school training

programs increased the likelihood of promotion to higher administrative ranks, this

section will consider the effect of party school enrollment on the rate of promotion, i.e.,

whether party school training has an effect on the timing of promotions within an

individual’s career. Within China’s bureaucracy, an individual cadre’s career

development is a long and complex process, and those who are identified early in their

careers stand a stronger chance of achieving high office.115 By testing the following

hypothesis, this section will shift the focus to consider whether party school enrollment increases the rate of promotion for selected public managers:

ƒ Hypothesis 3 Key point training classes place select cadres on a career fast track: After enrollment in a key point party school training program, cadres are promoted more quickly to higher ranks compared to peers not yet enrolled in such programs.

115 This is compounded by such factors as the enforcement of retirement laws under Deng.

99 This hypothesis was tested using an original dataset of the educational and career histories of Central Party School alumni. GSS data are insufficient on at least two levels.

First, survey data do not indicate the type of training program that individuals were enrolled in. As discussed earlier, there exists a wide variety of training program types, from general new hire orientations to specific training classes for cadres in a particular functional hierarchy within the bureaucracy. This section will compare students who have enrolled in similar types of training programs rather than, for example, lumping together those in new hire training programs with those in training programs for their specific professional specialty. One starting point is studying Young Cadre Training classes. These are convened in all party schools, at all administrative levels, and they are an increasingly emphasized core (zhuti) training class for all party schools.116

Second, GSS data do not contain enough cases of individuals at each administrative rank, especially the higher ranks, to test variation in the rate at which individuals are promoted from one rank to the next. Using CPS name lists skirts this problem to some degree because officials invited to CPS training classes have obtained, at a minimum, department-level (chu) rank. Furthermore, their public biographies often list the years they were promoted from vice-section chief on up. In the case of the CPS

Young Cadre Training Classes, students at the time of training were clustered in the vice- bureau and bureau ranks, which are upper-mid-level managers. Depending on the quality of each official’s published biography, this provides the opportunity to code careers from the grassroots, vice-section level up to the ministry level for this population of cadres.

This empirical strategy is not without its own problems. It would be ideal to obtain the career histories for individuals who enrolled in CPS Young Cadre Training

116 Interview with a CPS teacher, Interview 216, May 2008.

100 Classes and locate non-CPS-trained matches for each of these students. This may be possible by identifying cadres with similar posts to the CPS trainees for the period just prior to their enrollment. However, personnel data of this nature is not often in the public record. Furthermore, even after determining matching criteria, locating such information is difficult given the need to find records of public officials in 2000, the most recent year for which a name list is available.

Class roll call lists were published irregularly in the CPS yearbooks (which were also published irregularly), but names for students of the Young Cadre Training Class

(zhongqingnian ganbu peixun ban) were available for assorted classes from the inaugural

1980-81 class to the 2000-01 class listed in the most recent publicly available yearbook

(2001). This analysis will draw on a dataset of career histories for the training classes held in 2000-01, 1995-96, and 1995-97. Table 3.13 below summarizes the total number of trainees, according to published name lists.

Table 3.13: Total trainees, by CPS Young Cadre Training Class Total Year students 1980-81 55 1981-82 143 1982-83 191 1990-91 145 1991-92 178 1993-94 172 1994-95 193 1995-96 199* 2000-01 243 Total 1519 *Note: The 1995-1996 class total includes 160 ten-month trainees and 39 two-year trainees. This latter group was in residence at the CPS from 1995 to 1997. Source: CPS yearbooks

In compiling the educational and professional backgrounds of these individuals, I relied most heavily on official biographies published online. Information was obtained from

101 government web pages whenever possible (e.g., ministry web pages, local government

homepages, Xinhua news service).

A descriptive summary of the trainees from two Young Cadre Training Classes is

available in Appendix E. The majority of trainees were men (81.9 percent) and in their

forties at the time of the training. The educational attainment of the trainees has

increased over time, with 24.6 percent of students in 1995 reporting graduate-level

education credentials, compared to 34.6 percent in 2000.117 A high number of trainees

also listed graduate degrees from party schools, most often the CPS but in rare cases

provincial party schools. In 1995, one third of trainees obtained their graduate degrees from party schools, in majors ranging from Marxism to economic management.

Approximately one-fifth of the biographies for students of the 2000 class listed party school degrees (19.8 percent), though the more vague “part-time graduate degree” was a common phrase and degrees obtained from party schools could fall under this category.

A comparison of the university majors across the 1995 and 2000 training classes finds relatively higher shares of economics, management, law, and humanities majors.

This is consistent with analyses of Chinese political elite that find a recent move toward

diverse educational backgrounds and away from more narrow technical training (Li

2007b; Li 2008b). Almost 10 percent of the 2000 class consisted of law majors,

compared to 7 percent listing engineering majors. This compares with 7 percent and 5

percent, respectively, for the 1995 class.

117 This includes those who were part-time graduate students (zaizhi yanjiu sheng), a common educational choice among Chinese officials.

102 The next series of tables summarize the current positions of 2000 and 1995 CPS

Young Cadre Training Class alumni within party and government hierarchies. Table 3.14

lists the current administrative rank of offices occupied by alumni.

Table 3.14: Current administrative rank, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni 2000 1995 Combined N% N% N % Dismissed 2 0.8 3 1.5 5 1.1 Department level 0 0 1 0.5 1 0.2 Vice-bureau level 25 10.3 9 4.5 34 7.7 Bureau level 109 44.9 37 18.6 146 33.0 Vice-minister level 75 30.9 96 48.2 171 38.7 Minister level 10 4.1 35 17.6 45 10.2 Vice-premier level 0 0 2 1.0 2 0.5 NA 22 9.1 16 8.0 38 8.6 Total 243 100.0 199 100.0 442 100.0 In terms of administrative rank, the largest share of 2000 class alumni now hold bureau

level (sitingju ji) positions (44.9 percent). Alumni of the 1995 classes are clustered one

administrative rank higher, at the vice-minister level (fubu ji), and the combined number of 1995 alumni at the vice- and full-minister level is 131, or 65.8 percent of the total class.

Turning to the administrative level of cadres’ current positions, most are clustered at the provincial and central levels (Table 3.15). This is unsurprising, given the division of labor across party schools. Party schools are responsible for training cadres at one lower administrative level, hence city leaders are trained at provincial party schools while city party schools absorb county-level leaders.

Table 3.15: Current administrative level, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni Combined 2000 1995 N% N% N % Central 130 29.4 75 30.9 55 27.6 Provincial or provincial capital 242 54.8 121 49.8 121 60.8 City 34 7.7 26 10.7 8 4.0 County 1 0.2 0 0 1 0.5 NA 35 7.9 21 8.6 14 7.0 Total 442 100.0 243 100.0 199 100.0

103 Table 3.16 below summarizes the present occupation of CPS alumni. Though it is

common practice for officials to hold multiple titles – for example, a city mayor is often a

vice-party secretary for that city – the table below tabulates results based on the first

occupation listed for each individual in official biographies.

Table 3.16: Current occupation category, CPS Young Cadre Training Class alumni Combined 2000 1995 N % N% N% Party secretary 38 8.6 18 7.4 20 10.1 Government head 42 9.5 20 8.2 22 11.1 Party administrative assistant (mishu) 14 3.2 9 3.7 5 2.5 Economic development and planning 69 15.6 40 16.5 29 14.6 Security 9 2.0 4 1.6 52.5 Foreign affairs 10 2.3 8 3.3 2 1.0 Media 26 5.9 12 4.9 147.0 Personnel 16 3.6 8 3.3 84.0 Discipline and inspection 12 2.7 2 0.8 10 5.0 Propaganda and party history 20 4.5 13 5.3 7 3.5 Courts 19 4.3 13 5.3 63.0 People's Congress 24 5.4 5 2.1 19 9.5 CPPCC 18 4.1 7 2.9 115.5 Other mass organization 9 2.0 6 2.5 3 1.5 United Front 4 0.9 3 1.2 1 0.5 Party school 3 0.7 3 1.2 0 0.0 Education 26 5.9 18 7.4 84.0 Social/cultural 24 5.4 15 6.2 94.5 Scientific 21 4.8 16 6.6 52.5 Dismissed/retired 5 1.1 2 0.8 31.5 NA 33 7.5 21 8.6 126.0 Total 442 100.0 243 100.0 199100.0

The most common current occupational category is economic development and planning, which includes leadership posts in powerful bodies such as central and local

Development and Reform Commissions (fagaiwei) and State Council State-Owned

Assets Supervision and Administration Commission (guoyou zichan jiandu guanli

weiyuanhui). Provincial and city party secretaries and government heads were also

common occupations, totaling 15.6 and 21.1 percent of 2000 and 1995 alumni,

104 respectively.118 Sensitive occupations, such as those in the security, personnel and court systems were less common. This may be due to separate training systems for cadres in these fields.119

To test the hypothesis that invitation to and enrollment in a party school training program increases the rate of promotion to higher administrative ranks, cadre career histories were coded in terms of the age at which an individual assumed office at a particular rank. Table 3.17 below summarizes the average age, by rank, for cadres of the

CPS Young Cadre Training Class of 1995, as compared to national averages.120

Table 3.17: Comparing average ages, by rank 1995 CPS Class 1995 National Average121 Two-sample t-test N Average N Average Department level 91 34.8 407,207 48.0 *** Bureau level 124 43.5 35,620 53.2 *** Ministry level 26 54.7 2,459 58.9 *** Mean comparison test significance codes: ***=p<0.01, **=p<0.05, *=p<0.1 Data sources: Author’s dataset and COD 1999

Findings provide support for the hypothesis. No cadres attend training at CPS if they are ranked below the department level, hence the impossibility of evaluating

118 It is also important to note that these percentages represent absolute, rather than relative, totals by occupation category. It is not possible at present to control for the size of different bureaus. For example, the relatively low number of alumni assigned to posts in the United Front system may be due to the small size of this bureaucracy relative to others. Such data limitations prevent a more precise analysis of the share of posts in different occupations that are allocated to CPS graduates. 119 The Beijing Institute for International Studies, located across from the Central Party School, for example, is a training ground for foreign-oriented intelligence officers. Legal training for judges takes place at, among other institutions, the National Judicial College and, more recently, rapidly expanding law programs at public universities. Interview with a National Judicial College teacher, Interview 35, October 2007. 120 National data for cadres in 2000 were not available for comparison. 121 To calculate these averages, which were obtained from official statistics released by the COD, I had to make three assumptions. These data gave the age profile for leading cadre ranks (department, bureau, and ministry) in terms of five-year age ranges. Weighted averages were calculated assuming that the distribution of ages within each age category was uniform. Second, to take into account the youngest and oldest age categories, which were open-ended (“35 and under” and “60 and over”), I calculated a high and low national average. The low averages assumed that individuals could have attained office in a given rank as early as 25 or as late as 60; the high averages assumed 35 and 65 for these categories, respectively. The high age of 65 was calculated based on mandatory retirement ages. T-tests using these high and low averages were also significant at the same 0.01 level. Finally, because the COD data does not give age information for deputy-ranked cadres at each administrative level, I assumed that the share of deputy- and full-ranked cadres at the department, bureau, and ministry levels in the CPS trainee class mirrored the national share.

105 whether cadre age at the time of promotion is significantly lower for non-leading ranks.

CPS trainees were, on average 13 years younger than counterparts at the time they

obtained a department-ranked position. At the bureau level, this difference was 10 years,

while CPS-trained cadres were, on average, four years younger than counterparts when

they obtained ministry-level office. Two-sample t-tests found each of these differences

significant at the 0.01 level. This further reinforces the importance of party school

training for screening cadres with the potential for long tenures of service to the party.

Moreover, the time to promotion for leading ranks above the department level is

significantly shorter after training than before: a cadre can expect to work 4.78 years at

the vice-bureau level before promotion to the bureau level, if he has not yet attended the

CPS party school training, but this time is shortened to 3.17 years after training. For

bureau level cadres, those without CPS training experience must work, on average, 8.26

years before promotion, compared to 4.52 years after training. This represents a 45.3 percent reduction in time-to-promotion for bureau level cadres. These figures, while not a full analysis of all available cadre trainees’ career histories, provide preliminary support for the argument that party school training places cadres on a ‘fast track’ to promotion.

6 Conclusion

Hierarchical single-party systems such as China’s are capable of projecting the party’s authority over large populations and territories. In perpetuating and reinforcing this party organization, party authorities must confront the informational problems inherent to the principal-agent relationships that pervade the party hierarchy and the party’s relationship to the bureaucracy. One problem, that of hidden information

106 regarding a given agent’s type (and subsequent ability to serve the party well), presents a selection problem for the party. To address this, the party has invested in a set of political organizations for selecting cadres of the party and government and promoting those with the most promise. Party-managed schools of cadre training thus present an institutional means for party authorities to gather information on an individual bureaucrat’s fitness for higher office. One objective of this organizational strategy is to identify cadres with the potential for long tenures of service to the party, hence the emphasis on screening cadres early in their careers. During the current economic transition, furthermore, the party requires cadres with skills that may not be demonstrated or developed in the political campaigns of the Mao period. With this historical context in mind, there is a political logic to the persistence of seemingly outdated Leninist organizations such as party schools.

This chapter has sought to identify and test the party’s organizational solution to its selection problem. It is assumed, in studies of party schools, that these organizations serve some function(s) within the party apparatus. This chapter has tested two competing hypotheses regarding the utility of party schools for the party: whether these schools are a reward for cadres, i.e., a “club good” of some sort, or constitute a pipeline to higher office. The preceding analysis has drawn upon large-N survey data and an original dataset of high officials’ career histories to support the claim that party schools serve the latter function. Selection for party school training improves a cadre’s chances of promotion to higher office. The mechanisms driving this outcome are less clear, though evidence suggests that party schools may be both a means for ambitious, capable cadres to signal their abilities as well as a means for higher party officials to screen for those

107 cadres who do not possess requisite skills or qualities. In this sense, at least two

processes are at play: first, high ability cadres may seek to distinguish themselves by

signaling their abilities with a party school training credential, but what happens during

training also has some bearing on a cadre’s career prospects.

Over the past three decades of economic and social liberalization, the party has maintained formal strategies for managing the managers of the party and government.

These, in turn, lend the party organizational discipline. They are also indicative of the strong political institutionalization that maintains order in periods of transformation

(Huntington 1968). At the same time, these findings are one piece of a multi-faceted process. The promise of promotion is an incentive for cadres to seek invitations to party

school training classes, and the screening that takes place during training explains the survival of these organizations well into the reform period, but the content of what is taught in the schools themselves is equally, if not more, crucial. Understanding the

content of training, how this has changed over time, and how party schools themselves

have adapted to the changes of the reform period suggests what skills and attributes are most desired in the cadres that the party now seeks to recruit. This will be the task of the next two chapters, which unpack the various processes that have motivated dramatic changes within the party schools themselves.

108 Chapter 4 Fusing party and market

Contemporary China remains one of the few surviving Leninist political systems

in the world today, and its global ascendance over the past three decades presents the

puzzle of how seemingly outdated political institutions have managed to coexist with and

guide the transition to a market economy. In accordance with Leninist party principles,

directives radiate from collective leadership at the CCP’s center.122 Yet, with the party

initiation of market reforms in the late 1970s, individuals at various levels of the Chinese

Communist Party’s (CCP) organizational framework have shifted some decision making

authority from the plan to market mechanisms. In order to maintain political control over

these economic changes, CCP leadership has stressed the importance of organizational

learning. One adaptive response of the CCP has been to connect market forces directly

with internal efforts to update party organizations.

In embarking on this initiative to transform the CCP, political leaders have begun

reforming sites of elite training and education situated within the party itself. Party

schools in particular are key point organizations of cadre training and would seem an

ideal site for centralized dissemination of updated information on the party line and

122 With respect to cadre training, policies and directives emanate from three central actors within the CCP: the Central Committee, the Central Organization Department, and the Central Party School. The Central Committee issues five-year training plans as well as major documents such as the call to revitalize the party school system in 1977 and the 1983 Decision on Standardizing Party School Education (Central Committee Document Number 14, available online at www.fjdx.gov.cn/document.asp?docID=6943, accessed 3 May 2010). The Central Committee comprises approximately 200 members who endorse major party decisions made by the Politburo (20-25 members) and, within the Politburo, its Standing Committee (currently 9 members). The Central Organization Department issues documents related to cadre management, and reforms in cadre training and education may have the COD stamp on them. One example, discussed in detail in this chapter, is the COD’s 1983 Notice. Finally, the CPS may also issue statements and documents that apply to the entire party school system, such as the 1982 speech by CPS principal Wang Zhen to regularize the entire party school system.

109 unifying beliefs throughout the system. This chapter will demonstrate that central

authorities, since the early 1980s, made a deliberate choice to decentralize decision

making over certain areas of party schools’ organizational management. The outcome of

these decentralizing policies was a more fluid state of affairs in which local school

decision-makers could act independently to avail themselves of opportunities granted by

central authorities. At the same time, there are limitations to this local autonomy. Local

schools are constrained by a variety of system-wide monitoring mechanisms and the

prerogative, retained by central authorities, to impose centralizing policies at will.

Because of the balance struck between these local and central actors, a system has

emerged in which local experimentation is offset by the imperative to comply, at least

minimally, with plans emanating from central authorities.

Documentary research and findings from site visits suggest that two markets have

reshaped the incentives facing party schools. The first market, which opened up with the

liberalizing reforms of Deng Xiaoping, created the conditions for party schools to engage

in entrepreneurial, income-generating activities. The second market, which has

developed more recently, has been the creation by central party authorities of a training

market whereby other organizations are allowed to compete with party schools for

training contracts. The result of these reforms is that local party schools possess limited

autonomy over training content but face harder budget constraints than in the past. In the

tension between maintaining central control and granting local actors the independence to

act on local knowledge and conditions, the pendulum has swung in favor of the latter.

This is moderated, however, by the disciplining effect of market competition: local actors must now weigh whether to be responsive to local, national, and international factors.

110 One feature of the system, limited administrative and fiscal decentralization, has been a necessary condition for the emergence of market-based incentives. Together, decentralization and market forces are the channels through which the party has induced party organizations of cadre training to adapt to the economic changes of the reform period. These changes are significant in that they bring market forces into the party, beyond those units – such as state-owned enterprises – which have a more direct relationship with the new market economy. These changes also pit party organizations in competition with each other for market share, which plants the seeds of intra-party competition for scarce resources. This competition, however, is constrained by a combination of top-down policy decisions and local market conditions.

This chapter will explore the central and local processes that have brought together party schools and these two markets, and the following chapter will examine party schools’ various responses and resultant organizational change. Party schools have, in the process of opening up to market forces and rising to the challenge of competition, become more deeply embedded in local markets and intertwined with a variety of public and private actors. Competition has reduced party school “market share” and raised the stakes for these organizations to search more intensively for creative solutions to problems both fiscal and relating to their core training function.

2 Bringing in the market

In leading the complex transition from plan to market, central party officials had begun, by the mid-1980s, to introduce market incentives to party and state organizations.

The resultant “bureaucratic entrepreneurialism” entailed “government officials engag[ing]

111 in for-profit economic activities, using means and resources available only to the state,

and in pursuit of objectives broader than purely business concerns,” (Gore 1998: 6).

These incentives included the hardening of previously soft budget constraints and the relaxation of controls over self-raised revenues by various party and state units. The party school system was no exception to these more general, macro processes. Driving this story of marketization was a combination of deliberate choices made at many levels throughout the system, e.g., new policies originating from central party authorities and initiatives pursued by local party school leaders.

Fiscal and administrative decentralization constitutes a necessary condition for these market processes to unfold. Decentralization, or the transfer of fiscal, policy, and/or political authority from central to local governments, has been on the increase across countries and regions since the mid-1970s (Dethier 2000; Rodden 2004).

Processes of decentralization in China began under Mao and have encompassed both economic and administrative dimensions throughout the reform period.123 As the party

matured, decentralization posed less of a threat to organizational unity. As Selznick

observed in his study of Russian Bolshevik tactics, “One of the advantages of a firmly

established organizational character is the possibility of increasing decentralization

without sacrificing unity of policy or stability of command,” (Selznick 1960: 65).

Economic decentralization has political implications, and scholars have debated

whether the political authority of the party and central government have eroded with the

devolution of authority and economic resources to localities (Huang 1996; Oi 1992; Oi

123 There is a considerable literature on the relationship between decentralization and economic growth. The debate has ensued between those who argue for the growth-generating effects of “market-preserving federalism” (Montinola, Qian, and Weingast 1995; Qian 2003; Qian and Weingast 1997) and those who find no such relationship (Cai and Treisman 2006; Yang 2006).

112 1999; Yang 2006).124 Attempts to recentralize tax revenues through fiscal reforms in

1994 have led to strategies by locales to preserve locally-generated revenues (Jin and Zou

2003; Shi 2000; Zhang 1999; Zhang and Zou 1996). More recent 2001 reforms in

treasury management have streamlined the flow of revenues and expenditures through the

system (Ang 2009a). Despite efforts by the center to rein in localities and especially the

provinces, China remains a remarkably decentralized system: nearly 70 per cent of

government revenues is generated by localities, a level which places China among the

most decentralized of countries tracked by the IMF (Landry 2007: Chapter 1; World

Bank 2002).

Reforms leading to administrative decentralization and their implications have

been studied most extensively with respect to personnel appointments and monitoring

(Burns 1993; Huang 1995; Landry 2007; Manion 1985). Despite this large body of work,

scholars have paid less attention to the effect of these decentralizing trends on the

incentives facing local, sub-party organizations. Within the organizational geography of

cadre training schools in China, local party schools and administration institutes possess

limited autonomy in at least three areas: financial management, organizational structure,

and curriculum matters.

Limited local autonomy in financial matters

Within the organizational framework discussed in Chapter 2, funding for party

schools is localized. Rather than allocate funds at the central level and then transfer

124 Huang and Yang, for example, make the case that devolution of authority has been by design of the central government, which retains the ability to re-centralize authority. Oi, in her analysis of the rise of local state corporatism, finds a relative strengthening of local government in the early reform period, only to be followed by waves of recentralization efforts in the 1990s and again in the 2000s.

113 financial support downward through the system, local schools from the provincial to the

township levels receive funding via a horizontal transfer from their respective local

government finance department. This arrangement has been in place since at least

1983.125 In the pre-reform period, revenues and expenditures were centralized in a mode

common to command economies of the Soviet model. Sub-national administrative levels

sent up revenues and received budgetary allocations from central authorities (Ang 2009b:

Chapter 2). One implication of this more recent local fiscal independence is a harder

budget constraint, and schools are left to flourish or flounder as their local fiscal situation

allows.

Given disparities in levels of economic development across locales, there is

variation in how much local party schools receive from their respective public finance

bureaus. A teacher at the provincial capital party school in Province A reported a

stupendous 140 million (1.4 yi) yuan transfer from city finance in 2008, whereas the

school’s counterpart in Province B, the provincial capital of an inland province, received

13 million yuan.126 This difference is even more striking when considering the higher

number of leading cadres per capita in Province B compared to Province A.127 Such

variation is the result of relative financial booms and sluggishness across locales; no

significant central-level transfers reach party schools to equalize differences. These

125 See Appendix 3: Main Points of the National Cadre Training Plan in the Notice of the Organization Department of the Central Committee, 5 October 1983, in Burns (1989a, pp. 50-83). The appendix states that “the operating expenses of cadre colleges and schools should be incorporated in the budget of the departments in charge, which are to draw their funds from the financial departments at the same level. When budgeting the operating costs and investments in capital construction for cadre colleges and schools, party committees and governments at different levels should fulfill the Central Committee’s intent of gradually increasing the investment in cadre education so that funding in this area can be well taken care of and assured,” (pp. 73-74). 126 Interview 207, May 2008, and Interview 177, April 2008, with provincial party school teachers. Unfortunately, no nationwide numbers are publicly available, making systematic comparison beyond such interview data difficult. 127 For the period from 1981 to 1998, Province B’s total number of leading cadre’s as a percentage of the province’s population was 0.028, compared to 0.020 for Province A. Source: COD (1999).

114 horizontal disparities are also reflected vertically within the system. Schools at the

lowest, township level are left to languish from lack of local resources. With the

increasing reliance of schools on local sources of funding, the fate of party schools is

often a reflection of the robustness of local economies.

Central authorities have compounded the problem of disparities in local party

school development by placing pressures on locales to improve training and generate

their own funding for such initiatives. In what amounts to an unfunded mandate, schools

have been asked to advance Deng Xiaoping’s drive for a “revolutionary, younger, more

knowledgeable, and more specialized” cadre corps. Central documents call for capital

investments to be made to realize these goals and keep party schools on par with other

institutions of higher learning (Central Committee 2004). At the same time, these

upgrades must be done with the provision of funds from local finance bureaus and each locale’s planning bureau should allocate capital funding in support of these training endeavors (Ibid., Article 24). Such top-down pressures do little to relieve disparities across locales.

Organizational experiments

Second, there is evidence of decentralization in administrative and local organizational matters. Local party schools possess the authority to test novel

organizational arrangements. In Province A, for example, the provincial capital party

school is merging two county schools and six district schools under the roof of the city

party school.128 This organizational shuffling was conceived by a city vice-party secretary

and party school vice-principal in order to “improve teacher quality” and “consolidate

128 Provincial and city party school teachers, Interviews 207 and 208, May 2008.

115 resources”.129 Interviewees reported that this decision reflects concerns with the financial

viability of and staff qualifications at these lower level schools, so city leaders decided to

take matters into their own hands and combine school programming and management

under one party committee.

There is evidence of organizational consolidation elsewhere in the country. In

Shandong province, both city and county party schools are under the guidance of the

Shandong provincial party school (Guo and Shan 2009). Lower-level schools within this province enjoy budgetary autonomy but receive administrative guidance from the provincial party school. Whether or not the quality or solvency of schools will improve with these experiments remains an open issue, but local schools do have the leeway to pursue new organizational arrangements.

Local school control over training content

Third and finally, higher-level schools cannot impose their training content on schools at lower administrative levels. Local party schools have some freedom to design their own training curricula and teaching materials. This is illustrated by the Central

Party School’s publication of a set of books on core socialist theory, leadership, and party history, ostensibly to guide curricula at local schools. When asked about these materials, a city party school teacher responded, “We don’t use them here and the Central Party

School doesn’t have the authority (quanli) to impose their publications on us.”130

Similarly, a provincial party school head declared that “We use our own materials here,”

129 Ibid., Interview 207. 130 Interview 75, December 2007.

116 and complained that centrally-produced materials became outdated too quickly to keep up with changing circumstances in the province.131

At the same time, there is consistency across schools in the general topics taught to cadres. The vast majority of training classes will start with some nod to the guiding party theory of the day, though schools will address these topics to varying degrees.

Party school officials have reported in interviews that they do turn to other party schools in the system for guidance in curricula matters. One provincial official characterized the relationship as one where schools will “imitate each other” (huxiang mofang).132 This is in part because party schools transmit their training syllabi up and down the party school system as part of their advisory, exchange-based relationship. Provincial schools will look to the CPS and other provincial party schools for ideas on updating curricula and pedagogy, though “the party school head has leeway to structure the school’s curriculum and teaching methods, so there is some unpredictability.”133 Some teachers have welcomed non-party school training providers as yet another source for guidance on updating curricula.134

This discussion demonstrates the various areas where party school leaders may exercise some discretion, though they remain constrained by a variety of monitoring mechanisms. There are benefits to central authorities for the decentralization that local autonomy implies. First, this reduces the monitoring costs associated with a heavily centralized system, since each level is responsible for monitoring the activities of schools located one or two administrative levels down. Second, sub-national units gain the

131 Interview 66, November 2007. 132 Interview 182, April 2008, Provincial party committee policy research office director. 133 Ibid. 134 Interview 143 and 144, April 2008, Provincial party school professors.

117 flexibility to respond to local circumstances rather than being bound to possibly irrelevant

central-level plans. This local innovation generates the model sites that central

authorities may decide to replicate nationally. In this sense, it is in the interest of central

authorities to encourage localized innovation and allow localities to absorb the risks from

such endeavors. After reviewing local efforts, the center can chose to disseminate

successful local experiments and either ignore or quash unsuccessful ones.135

Official incentives to “dive into the sea” of market activity

The dependence of party schools on funding from local finance bureaus has

implications for the financial and managerial decisions made by school leaders. Along

with many other segments of China’s population, this group of actors began to engage in

new income-generating activities as planned market controls loosened in the post-Mao

period. With “reform and opening” under Deng Xiaoping, China’s economy transformed into one of “mixed ownership structure in which public ownership is dominant among other types of ownership,” (Wang 2006). Because of the localized nature of party school

funding, it was in both the party’s and the schools’ interests for schools to develop

alternative revenue streams. Not only would this lighten the burden on finance bureaus,

but party schools themselves could leverage in-house resources and increase revenues

that would keep members of the danwei satisfied.

135 Official documents suggest that this central permissiveness and limited local autonomy is by design. As early as 1989, a published survey of party school education discussed the rationale for variation in content. “Because of differences between provinces, municipalities and autonomous regions, the party school education at different localities is different. Party school education in autonomous regions provides relevant training related to ethnic minority groups and strengthens the solidarity among different ethnic groups. In municipalities, party school training focuses more on urban development. In provinces, regional differences are reflected in party school education,” (Liu 1989: 114-118).

118 While national and local party school budget information is not publicly available,

some financial information comes to light during interviews at individual schools.

Because party schools are considered fully-funded public service units (quan’e bokuan

shiye danwei), they are in theory transferred enough funds from local finance bureaus to

cover operating expenses.136 In reality, transfers of public funds leave virtually no room

for organizational slack. This, in turn encourages revenue-seeking activity by school

leaders. For example, a local finance department may deliberately set the allocation level

to cover only a set percentage of the party school’s operating expenses and leave the

remainder for the school to raise through market activity. In Province B, for example,

one cadre stated that the transfer usually covers approximately 60 percent of operating

expenses.137

There also appears to be some regional variation in whether budgetary allocations

are trending up or down over time. In the relatively impoverished province of Yunnan,

budget allocations for local county schools have even been reduced in recent years, leaving schools severely constrained (Pieke 2009a: 132-40). Provincial-level training institutions in both Province A and B, did not report the sort of declines experienced further west.138 In the provincial capital of Province B, party school officials reported

increases in transfers over time, though the school was still experiencing ever larger

budgetary shortfalls. This party school received a 13 million yuan transfer from the local

finance bureau in 2007, which was insufficient for an operating budget of approximately

25 million yuan. This shortfall of 12 million yuan, or 48 percent of the operating budget,

136 Ang 2008 offers a lucid description of the distinction between public service units (or extrabureaucracies) and party or government bureaus. 137 Interview with a city party school professor, Interview 177, April 2008. 138 Interviews, provincial socialism institute principal, Interview 95, December 2007; provincial capital party school teacher, Interview 177, April 2008.

119 would have to be covered through auxiliary (jihua wai, or “outside-of-the-plan”) training

classes, degree programs, and other revenue schemes.

Table 4.1 below offers a breakdown of general expense categories and expected income sources for local party schools:

Table 4.1: Summary of local party school expense categories and income sources Expense Income sources General operating expenses Local finance bureau School-generated revenue Capital construction Local finance bureau Local planning/development and reform commission Training expenses (e.g., teaching materials, site visits, studying in other institutions) If: Training is outside-the-plan Trainees’ work units If: Training is in local annual training plan Local finance bureau and trainees’ work units Salaries Local finance bureau Employee benefits (e.g. mobile phone School-generated revenue service allowance, meal allowance)

Employee-related benefits constitute another party school expense category.

While local finance departments will transfer to party schools a certain amount for

employee salaries, there are other employee-related expenses that the local finance

department will not cover. These include employee benefits and salary supplements

(butie). Across party and government offices, there is wide variation in the level of

benefits enjoyed by employees. This is because such benefits and salary supplements are

linked to the fund-raising abilities of a particular office.139 In Province B’s provincial

capital, for example, each party school employee receives a different set of supplements

based on rank and whether that individual has civil servant status. On average, this

shortfall for the provincial party school is between 1000-1500 yuan per employee per month.140 Supplements can include direct transfers to employees to cover expenses

139 A detailed discussion of the components of cadre wages and benefits can be found in Whiting (2006). 140 Interview 177, April 2008. This cadre went on to say that leaders can expect supplements upwards of 3,000 yuan a month.

120 associated with mobile phones, transportation, and meals with guests, among other

categories.141 In one wealthy county school, the school vice-principal receives an 1800

yuan monthly supplement for car maintenance alone: though he provides his own car, the

insurance, road tolls, and gas can come out of this supplement.142

In summary, central authorities’ conscious decision to decentralize the

management of party schools created a new context within which these organizations

functioned. Fiscal and organizational decentralization generated incentives for party

school leaders to pursue new ventures for pecuniary gain and organizational efficiency.

In budgetary matters, schools could utilize self-raised funds to supplement budgetary

transfers from local finance departments. This organization-level discretion extended to

other areas of operation. In the reform period, party schools leaders could also initiate

organizational changes and reforms in school programming and curricula. Along with

these new opportunities, however, came significant challenges. While any new ventures

or initiatives pursued by party schools carried attendant risks, these risks were

compounded by yet another development in the organizational environment within which

these schools operated. Beginning in the early Deng Xiaoping period, party schools were

exposed to yet another aspect of the market: competition.

3 Motivations to marketize training

Party schools once enjoyed a near-monopoly on the training of party and

government leaders.143 Over the course of diversifying activities in a new market context,

141 Interview 162, April 2008, two provincial party school teachers. 142 Interview 191, May 2008, county party school vice-principal and teacher. 143 Ministries and state-owned enterprises may also have party schools or cadre training academies, but these were traditionally for lower-ranked cadres. Furthermore, party schools in other ministry systems

121 the leaders of party schools began to face pressure on another front: competition from

other organizations and schools for the privilege to train government and party officials.

Figure 4.1below depicts the variety of central-level cadre training organizations that are now in existence, many of which were established over the past three decades.

Figure 4.1: Central-level organizations of cadre training

Central Committee of the CCP State Council

Central United National School Government Central Party Organization Front of ministry School Department Department Administration training centers

Four branch Cadre executive United Front schools and leadership China Socialism cooperative academies: Institute profit-sharing Pudong, programs with Jinggangshan, local party Yan’an schools

Beginning in the 1980s and continuing through the present, new and existing institutions

were allowed, often by central decree, to plan and implement training programs for

cadres. These institutions included universities, administration schools, and new training

centers opened by other party units. In effect, these new organizational players were

given official sanction to claim training market share from party schools. The newest

additions include the National School of Administration and Cadre Executive Leadership

Academies.

(xitong) and SOEs are considered subsidiary schools (fenxiao) of the party school system (see, for example, the Beijing party school webpage for a listing of its subsidiary schools in ministries and SOEs and Beijing district party schools: http://www.bac.gov.cn/web/swdx/about/Link.aspx?NodeID=1&Link=区县站点导航 &Tag=3#, accessed 3 July 2009). The training of leading (chu ji yi shang) cadres in particular was a traditional responsibility of the party school system. For an overview of the history of these schools by province, see General View of the Nation’s Party Schools (1996).

122 Motivations ranged from the desire to expand the system’s capacity to carry out

large-scale and regularized cadre training to a more specific dissatisfaction with the

quality of party schools. Capacity building was a relatively straightforward goal since improvements in cadre training would fulfill Deng’s declaration to transform China’s cadres. While there existed a dual-track system for sorting individuals into state administrative versus party management careers (Walder, Li, and Treiman 2000), Deng’s generation of leaders nonetheless perceived a shortage of managerial talent. On a practical level, given insufficient capacity within the existing party school system, the logical solution was expansion of cadre training and channeling promising bureaucrats to new training academies (Liu 2001: 97).

Central-level policies calling for the expansion, and accompanying institutionalization, of cadre training can be traced to the early years of Deng’s leadership.

Along with the 1983 Central Committee policy declaration to “standardize party school education,” there was an early mandate to have all leading cadres and reserve cadres take remedial theory and vocational training courses over the period 1983 to 1990 (Central

Organization Department 1983: 68-70). In the 2001-2005 National Cadre Education and

Training Plan, the Central Party School and National School of Administration were to train 400 provincial-level cadres each year, totaling 2000 for the five year period. This was combined with the stipulation that all cadres at that level should have 3 months of training within a five year period. Since central cadres numbered over 70,000 by 2002, branch campuses (fenxiao) would have to make up the difference (Yang 2002: 286-295).

This was logistically challenging and provided motivation to expand the system.

Accordingly, the training plan called for “speeding up the construction of cadre education

123 training bases and reforming each administrative level’s party school education as the main channel for rotating party and government leading cadres through training.”144 As

recently as 2006, a minimum three-month training every five years was required for all

cadres. One provincial party school administrator complained how these requirements

strained school resources: “There are just too many grassroots cadres, it takes a lot of time and resources to train all of them, and we [party schools] still cannot train them all.”145 The numbers are revealing. Shambaugh observes that the CPS may train up to

5,000 cadres a year at present, so circulating 70,000 central-level cadres through this one

institution would take well beyond the 5 year cycle laid down in official training plans

(Shambaugh 2008a: 143).

While capacity concerns are politically palatable, there were also indications of dissatisfaction with the quality of party school education at the central and local levels.

The end result has been a push to diversify the kinds of organizations engaged in cadre

training. During the early reform period, worries over party school deficiencies were a manifestation of central-level displeasure with cadre management in general. At the 13th

Party Congress in 1987, Premier Zhao Ziyang reported,

The power of cadre management is over-concentrated and the people who handle personnel affairs lack professional knowledge; the methods are outdated and simplistic, which hinders the intellectual growth of talented people; the management system is flawed and there are no laws governing the way personnel are used.146

Concerns with the quality of party school training were addressed more directly in the

2001-5 National Cadre Education Training Plan, which sought organizational diversity as

the means to “raise training quality.” The plan stipulated that party schools “should

144 Section 4, 2001-2005 National Cadre Education and Training Plan 145 Interview 66, November 2007. 146 Quoted in Liu (2001), p. 67.

124 actively make use of administrative institutes, universities, research institutes and other

training resources” to carry out “multi-faceted, multi-level education and training.”

Likewise, party documents for internal circulation have recommended that “we should

expand the content of education for party cadres and improve education methods” due to

“the party’s changed mission and the request of cadres,” (CPS 2004: 142-145). In

official training plans, then, cadre training would and should include multiple actors.

As indicated in this 2004 CPS document, another source of the push for reforms

in the structure of cadre training came from cadres themselves. In evaluations of party

school-organized training programs, participating cadres complained about various

aspects of the experience, from the perceived old-fashioned thinking of the teachers to the lack of relevance of training content for cadre work on the ground.147 Beginning in the

mid-1990s, the provincial-level party school in Province A began to have open

discussions at the end of training classes to collect student feedback. When brought

together for discussion, cadre-students voiced their grievances. They pointed to the

rigidity (si ban) of the training system and the conservatism of the teachers (laoshi fang

bu kai).148 One cadre complained to me, “Party school teachers are terribly boring and

didactic, they have outdated knowledge and are uninspiring. They only teach old theories and are not creative. They must be the leftover teachers who couldn’t find work at real

schools!”149 This critique was not limited to students. A city organization department

official observed, “Some party schools, especially the grassroots ones, have low quality

teachers. These teachers aren’t interested in improving training, they are just interested

147 Interviews with a county-level civil servant (Interview 104, January 2008), county-level party school teacher (Interview 197, May 2008), provincial socialism school principal (Interview 95, December 2007). 148 Interview 208, Zhejiang party school teacher, May 2008. 149 Interview 104, city government cadre, January 2008.

125 in their own job security and benefits.”150 In Province B, a similar realization was dawning: the party school system was becoming ossified in the reform era and increasingly disconnected from problems that cadres were facing.151

But why a training market? Introducing market-based competition, rather than an

alternative arrangement such as a clear division of labor across training organizations, suggests a search for the institutional incentives and framework that would promote continuous organizational adaptation. There is the sense that central leaders considered markets more capable of shifting resources quickly to match new developments. At the founding of new cadre academies in 2005, for example, then-president Hu Jintao declared,

“The priorities of the training centers are to enhance the ruling awareness of the Party, improve its art of leadership and governance, and strengthen its governing capacity. With this foundation, the centers will continue to revise the training curricula, modernize the training methodology, better allocate the training resources and improve the training team, thereby increasing the overall training quality.”152 The invisible hand of the market

would provide strong incentives for organizational adjustment and, because of the

decentralized nature of market competition, respond to the unevenness of local conditions

in a way that top-down planning, with its informational disadvantages, could not.

4 Policies, processes, and the emergence of a training market

In the early 1980s, the Central Organization Department was pressing for the

construction of new cadre colleges and the integration and expansion of cadre training

150 Interview 212, May 2008. 151 Interviews 143 and 144, provincial party school teachers, April 2008. 152 Italics added for emphasis. CELAP webpage, “Congratulatory Letter by President Hu Jintao,” http://61.129.65.35/renda/node3284/node3286/userobject1ai39720.html, accessed 7 December 2008.

126 programs in universities and other educational institutions.153 Official declarations spelled out these designs. “Starting in 1985, the enrollment of specialized cadre training classes should be expanded step by step to reach 10 percent of the total annual enrollment of institutions of higher learning and secondary vocational schools,” (Central

Organization Department 1983: 74). By 1985, keypoint colleges and universities were to create advanced studies and training programs for cadres.154 There was also a call to increase construction of cadre colleges, whose main task was vocational training.155 This was part of the larger push to raise the educational credentials of cadres and follow through on Deng’s mandate for a “better educated and more specialized” cadre class.

The universe of training institutions in the early reform period thus included party schools and a variety of new actors in the push to modernize the cadre corps. However, universities and cadre colleges were to boost technical skills, not stand in as authorities of party doctrine.156 Party schools were still the pipeline for promotion to higher ranks within the party.157 For example, only party schools had long-term training classes for those bureaucrats tapped for top leadership positions. Party schools also dealt with this

153 This was not an entirely foreign proposition. Since the early 1950s, delegations of cadres were sent to the Soviet Union, Eastern Bloc, and small numbers of cadres were also selected for university education. See Liu (2001), p. 98. 154 These were to be funded by local finance departments. “Starting from 1984, financial departments at various levels should make unified appropriations to departments of education of funds for specialized cadre training courses and cadre training classes that are offered by institutions of higher learning and secondary vocational schools. These institutions and schools should no longer charge tuition for the sponsors of the trainees,” (Appendix 3: Main Points of the National Cadre Training Plan, Section 3: Expand the quota of cadre students enrolled by institutions of higher learning and secondary vocational schools, pp. 74-75). 155 Literacy and vocational courses were to constitute 70-80 percent of total credit hours, with Marxist theory filling the rest. Ibid., p. 73. 156 Pieke (2009) notes how the three most prestigious universities in China, all based in Beijing, have profited from the opportunity to train cadres in management and non-ideological coursework. In terms of training volume, in 2006 the School of Continuing Education at Tsinghua taught approximately 6000 cadres, projected to increase to 7500 in 2007 (p. 127). 157 All vice-ministers, for example, must attend the Central Party School prior to promotion to the minister rank. Interview 2, Beijing university vice-party secretary, September 2006.

127 challenge by drawing on party authority within universities and other educational

institutions. University party committees wielded considerable influence. At universities as diverse as Xiamen University (in Guangdong province) and People’s University (in

Beijing), party secretaries could shape the direction of management institutes that were

formally responsible for secular public administration training (Williams 1993). These

efforts, however, could not prevent the entry of universities as competitors to party

schools in an emerging national training market.

Building government capacity: Administration institutes

By the late 1980s, a new set of institutions emerged to challenge the dominance of

party schools over cadre training. Beginning in 1987, the movement to build a system of

public administration academies gained momentum with a resolution passed at the 13th

National Party Congress.158 Shortly after, construction of the Beijing campus of the

National School of Administration began, and, due to delays wrought by the Tiananmen

protests, in 1994 the organization officially opened its doors (Huang 1993a; Li 1993).159

Organizationally, the NSA falls under the guidance of the State Council, State Education

Commission, and the Ministry of Personnel (Huang 1993b). Since then, a web of

administration schools has spread to the provinces and sub-provincial levels.

Officially, administrative institutes train government bureaucrats, while party schools are responsible for the training of cadres in party units. In reality, however, the boundaries between the two are blurred. Party schools have dealt effectively with the

158 “NSA: Cradle of China’s Public Servants,” People’s Daily (English service), 10 July 2000, http://english.people.com.cn/english/200007/10/eng20000710_45138.html, accessed 21 February 2006. 159 During the construction phase, as early as November 1988, the NSA was involved in trainings for secretaries and directors of ministry departments and provinces. Many of these took place on the CPS campus. See Huang 1993: 100.

128 entry of this competition through cooptation. From the provincial to county levels, party schools have successfully merged with administration institutes. Table 4.2 below lists whether provincial-level party schools and administration institutes are located on the same campus.

Table 4.2: Provincial-level party schools and administration institutes Year party school Year administration Place Merged? established institute established Anhui No 1951 1991 Beijing Yes 1950 1993 Chongqing Yes 1997 1997 Fujian No 1995 Gansu No 1938 1990 Guangdong Yes 1950 2001 Guangxi Yes 1950 1994 Guizhou Yes 1950 1997 Hainan Yes 1988 1994 Hebei No 1950 1987 Heilongjiang Yes 1948 Henan Yes 1949 1996 Hubei Yes 1954 1993 Hunan (in 2003) 1951 1953 Jiangsu Yes 1953 1992 Jiangxi (in 2001) 1950 1981 Jilin (in 2006) 1948 Liaoning Yes 1946 1990 Neimenggu Yes 1948 1995 Ningxia Yes 1958 1996 Qinghai Yes 1956 1993 Shaanxi No 1942 Shandong No 1938 1992 Shanghai (in 1989) 1949 1986 Shanxi Yes 1949 1995 Sichuan (in 2001) 1952 1997 Tianjin Yes 1949 2001 Xinjiang Yes 1950 2000 Xizang Yes 1961 1991 Yunnan Yes 1950 Zhejiang Yes 1949 1988 Source: Author’s dataset.

Most administration schools reside on the same campus as party schools, and it is not uncommon for single school administrators to hold parallel, dual titles across both organizations. The rationale given for this system of “two signs, one set of personnel”

129 (liang kuai paizi, yi tao renyuan) is to benefit from overlap in organizational goals and

resources, though the party school holds the higher status and authority.160 Combining schools on one campus has not been exercised uniformly throughout the system; six out of 31 provincial-level units have separate party schools and administration institutes

(Table 4.2).

Intra-party competition: organization departments join the training market

Despite their official mandates to engage in cadre training, universities and administration institutes both lacked the stamp of party authority that party schools enjoyed. A more recent entrant to the training market presents a challenge on this front.

The newest additions to the universe of cadre training schools are a variety of organization department-sponsored training schools. At the national level is a trio of cadre leadership academies. These academies are funded and managed by the Central

Organization Department, not the State Council or the Central Committee of the CCP, and they possess near-equal status with the Central Party School in Beijing. They represent lavish investments in elite cadre training, with the construction costs of the

Pudong campus alone estimated at US$100 million.161

Early efforts to expand the country’s organizational capacity for cadre training

differ from these most recent initiatives. The decision to pull universities and

administration institutes into the domain of cadre training was aimed more directly at

160 In a country where no official matters are deliberate, a basic gauge of the importance of administration institutes versus party schools is evident in resource allocation: when I interviewed administration institution and party school counterparts in their respective offices, the party school office was inevitably the larger and more well-appointed one. On the importance of order and rank in Chinese politics, see Macfarquhar 1971. 161 The figure given during an interview with a Pudong professor was 900 million yuan, or approximately US$112.5 million. Interview 187, April 2008.

130 developing the professional skills of cadres. Universities, as well as cadre colleges, could

enhance a cadre’s educational credentials, but it was understood that he needed to pass

through a party school training program on the way up the political career ladder. Later

efforts to create a new system of cadre training academies more explicitly challenged the

dominant role that party schools had enjoyed in cadre training and established an

alternative training model within the party. Central party authorities were, in effect,

using competition to discipline party schools, which represents a significant shift away

from the top-down control more conventionally employed in Leninist political systems.

The 16th party congress in 2002 saw the introduction of this intra-party

competition. At the congress, CCP leaders approved the establishment of three central-

level cadre executive leadership academies (CELA) in Pudong (Shanghai), Yan’an

(Shaanxi province), and Jinggangshan (Jiangxi province) to train the population of elite cadres once channeled exclusively to the Central Party School.162 These academies

would remain distinct and separate from the party school system.163 Their creation, in the

words of one CELA administrator “represent[s] a new model of cadre training ... In

traditional [party school] training, there are too many traditional materials, too many

traditional teaching methods … Now the party schools have to produce results, otherwise

162 See the 18 Oct 2007 report filed by Ouyang Song, deputy head of the Central Organization Department, “Sound progress of the new and great project of party building since the 16th National Party Congress,” available at http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/90001/90776/90785/6285280.html, accessed 29 June 2009. The locations chosen are representative of the party’s bases of legitimacy: in a revolutionary past and economic future. Party school officials have also pointed out how this move by the COD was also related to a shift in the emphasis of training content. Market economics and law were emphasized as training topics from the time of the 16th party congress to the present (Interview 66, November 2007, provincial party school vice-principal; Interview 75, December 2007, city party school professor). 163 Similar to the funding situation for party schools, CELA, which are considered central-level training organizations, receive funding for inside-the-plan training classes from the Central Organization Department, via the central finance ministry, while individual work units or companies must bear the cost of training if they are commissioning auxiliary, or outside-the-plan training class. Interview 184, April 2008, CELA director.

131 they will be eliminated (taotai).”164 Making the competition explicit in policy documents, recent central-level regulations have called for “a system of orderly competition”

(jingzheng youxu de jigou tixi) and again acknowledged that other institutions such as universities and research institutes may “take on the task of cadre education and training.”165

During the period between the 16th and 17th party congresses, local organization

departments also began establishing their own cadre training schools.166 In Province A,

the provincial capital’s organization department decided to boost grassroots training by

opening a district-level cadre training base (jiceng ganbu peixun jidi).167 In Province B,

the provincial organization department required party and government organs to send

cadres to the organization department-managed revolutionary education academy

(geming jiaoyu xueyuan).168 These new training bases divert cadre trainees, and the

training funds that accompany them, from party schools to other party organs.

Beyond presenting an updated model of cadre training, an additional motivation

for organization departments to create new training bases rests in concerns about a loss of

respect for party school training by cadres. Creating organization department-managed

training centers is, in the words of this organization department cadre,

to turn training into something serious again, to give training the stamp of the organization department’s authority. … Party schools are like nannies (baomu) while the organization department is the master (zhuren). Party schools don’t really have the authority to discipline cadres, so cadres don’t take party school training seriously. Cadres are like kids toward their nanny [in their relationship

164 CELA director, Interview 184, April 2008. 165 Chapter 5, Art. 27, Cadre education and training provisional work regulations, 2008. 166 Interview 211, May 2008, provincial party school teacher. 167 The organization department has been organizing training classes for grassroots cadres since 2002 but decided in 2006 to open a formal training center. Interview 212, May 2008, city organization department cadre. 168 The plans to build the academy were announced in 2004. Total construction costs are reported to be 65 million yuan.

132 with party schools]. This is unlike the cadres who come to the organization department’s training center, they are very well-behaved (guaiguai).169

Opening new, competing training centers managed directly by organization departments

is one means to remedy these perceived shortfalls.

New experiments, new competition

Organization departments have also experimented with other training schemes in

which party schools are brought in direct competition with organization department-

approved training providers. The emphasis in these new programs has been on flexibility

in training content and cadre choice. The city party school has been caught up

in one of the more radical training reforms in the country and serves as a model for other

schools. Since October 2003, city civil servants and party cadres have participated in a

“self selection” (zixuan) training program in which cadres may select training sessions

from a course catalog. By national law, bureaucrats must fulfill five days of training each

year, and in Shenzhen they may meet this requirement by selecting their own training

courses. Three training days consist of mandatory theory and party building classes and

the remaining two training days consist of elective courses. Basic theory classes, for

example, are still mandatory.170

These self-selected training classes are offered by local educational providers, all

approved by the city organization and personnel departments and a committee

comprising representatives from the city’s party committee, people’s congress, and

people’s political consultative conference (CPPCC). The six selected training providers

169 Interview 212, city-level organization department cadre, May 2008. 170 Shenzhen’s “self selection” training guidelines are available at http://www.szps.gov.cn/zxpx/detail.aspx?NewsID=556, accessed 9 August 2009.

133 include: the Shenzhen party school, the adult education school of Shenzhen University,

the training centers of the Shenzhen media group, Shenzhen’s international human

resources training center, the Shenzhen management learning institute, and a national

economic and information technology training center.171 Whereas the party school will

focus on classes such as “Research and questions in ‘Three Represents’ important

thought” and “Research on leadership capacity,” the city university will feature courses

from its MPA and MBA programs.172 The party school thus takes part in creating

elective classes (zixuan ban) that local bureaucrats may opt to participate in.

This training scheme has the advantage of flexibility in that class offerings may

shift in response to student demand and busy cadres may choose classes which fit their

schedules and interests. Furthermore, training organized in this fashion is less costly,

since students do not live on campus as they do in more traditional party school training

classes. While this training arrangement exists alongside other courses organized

exclusively by party schools, this “self-selection” training model has pitted party schools

in more direct competition with other training providers than existed in the past.

Delegations from cities in Guangdong province have visited Shenzhen to inspect this

training model, and it has received attention from the national-level management training

academy in Dalian, located in northeast Liaoning province.173 Whether this model will spread to other locales, however, remains unclear.

171 “Shenzhen cadre ‘self selection’ training will start, six training institutions will take up positions,” Shenzhen Economic Daily, 8 Oct 2003, available online at http://www.southcn.com/news/dishi/shenzhen/shizheng/200310080733.htm, accessed 2009 August 8. 172 Ibid. 173 “Report on Guangdong study tours,” http://www.hnredstar.gov.cn/yueyang123/gbjy/gj_gjdt/t20060321_52030.htm, and “Several insights from Shanghai, Shenzhen, and Ningbo party school inspections” http://www.swdx.dl.gov.cn/yxlt/Document/5063/5063.html, accessed 8 August 2009.

134 Competition goes global

Beyond this domestic competition and experimentation, party schools must now

also contend with the entry of international training providers. As early as 2003, local

party committees, through their organization departments, were issuing public calls for

training proposals. The official motivation for initiating this bidding process was to

implement more effectively the goals stated in national cadre training regulations, and the

result has been explicit competition between training providers for local contracts.174 In addition to bids from Chinese universities, party schools, and other training centers, these calls attracted applications from universities located abroad. Table 4.3 below lists various local party committees’ calls for training bids and the eventual recipients of training contracts. A training class requested by the Wuhan organization department in

2008, for example, was awarded to UCLA for a training class on international trade.

The awarding of training contracts to such a variety of organizations reflects the competitive pressures that party schools must respond to in order to retain a place in an expanding training market. While there is some specialization, for example the organization of training classes on “e-governance” by a national training center on information technology, there does not appear to be a clear division of labor in the types of organizations awarded various training contracts. Even general training programs that party schools could once take for granted as part of their core responsibilities, such as

174 Official declarations of the motivations underlying the government procurement system for cadre training programs is available via www.chinabidding.org, the (only) website authorized by the State Development Planning Commission to post bidding notices. See http://www.chinabidding.com/zbjg- detailTwo-2534138.html and http://www.chinabidding.com/zbjg-detailTwo-2534139.html, accessed October 2009. The Guangdong provincial organization department’s webpage also refers to how a bidding process, which includes party schools, administration schools, cadre academies, universities, and research institutes will “improve training performance”. See http://www.gdzz.cn/javaoa/article/articleview_simple.jsp?act=view&articleID=999884555479ab276880f95 f70f56215&catalogID=8cf83a421ad83bf7f8dfcf1c0374f696&path=%E5%B9%B2%E9%83%A8%E5%9F %B9%E8%AE%AD/%E5%9F%B9%E8%AE%AD%E5%8A%A8%E6%80%81, accessed October 2009.

135 training classes for young cadres, have been subject to open bidding. This was the case in Heilongjiang province in 2009, when five separate organizations, none of which were the provincial party school, received contracts for young cadre training classes.

Table 4.3: A selection of training bids, by locale and awardee Year Locale Training contract awarded to Training topic(s) 2003 Wuhan, Hubei Tsinghua University Public Administration 2004 Mianyang, Sichuan Southwest University of Issues for female cadres Science and Technology 2006 Beijing >20 Chinese and overseas Leadership and universities (such as Peking management University, U , and Urban planning Georgetown University) Law Economics 2006 Shenyang, Liaoning Korean university Rural development (not specified) 2006 Sichuan National training center on E-governance information technology 2008 Wuhan, Hubei UCLA International trade 2009 Beijing Beijing Party School Chinese culture 2009 Zunyi, College of Minorities Leadership for minority cadres 2009 Hangzhou, Zhejiang Development, globalization, economics 2009 Harbin, Heilongjiang People’s University School of Leadership Education and Training 2009 Heilongjiang 5 institutions: Young cadre training class Harbin Institute of Technology Heilongjiang University Peking University Marxism Dept School of Administration Tianjin University Source: Author’s dataset.

5 Party school market share

An examination of the allocation of training contracts in one locale, City Z in

coastal Province A, illustrates the impact of competition on party school market share

(Figure 4.2). While the city’s party school still retains a majority share of local training

contracts, it has had to cede ground to the various competitors that have emerged during

the reform period.

136 Figure 4.2: Share of total training, by school type

Other training center 16%

University abroad 5%

Chinese university 16% City party school 61%

Central Party School 2%

Notes: Training share calculated as a percentage of total trainees planned for 2008. “Other training center” includes the following: Shenzhen Socialism Institute, the City Socialism Institute, Shanghai Socialism Institute, the City’s police academy, the cadre school at the provincial construction ministry, and the Central Discipline and Inspection Training Center.

Data on training class allocation were obtained from the city’s annual training plan. As is the convention in locales throughout China, the local party committee, in collaboration

with personnel-related party and government officials, established a training plan for

2008. This plan detailed the total number of training classes that would be funded by the

city’s finance department for the year, including the substantive focus of each training class. In 2008, the city’s party committee approved funding for 40 training classes,

totaling 3,785 local cadres. Classes ranged from large courses on the recently convened

Seventeenth Party Congress to more general “advanced” and young cadre training

courses. The party school was allocated 27 of these 40 training classes, though four of these classes were to be organized jointly with other training providers.175 In terms of

trainees, these classes totaled an estimated 2,345 students, or 61 percent of the total

planned for that year. Other training sites included provincial universities, universities in

175 Partners included the Central Party School (1 class), a provincial university (2 classes), and the city personnel training and testing center (1 class).

137 Hong Kong and Singapore, and national universities such as Fudan (in Shanghai) and

Fujian Universities. Central training centers such as the Central Party School and Central

Discipline and Inspection Training Center were also granted training contracts.

There did not appear to be discernible patterns in which type of training organization received a given training contract; the city party school was assigned both general and more specialized classes (e.g., a public security section chief training class, a grassroots letters and complaints training class). It might have seemed logical to assign more technical classes, such as those regarding enterprise management, to universities with cutting edge business schools, but the training plan does not seem to reflect such logic. Fudan and Tsinghua Universities were assigned contracts for “enterprise manager advanced research classes,” but the city party school was granted contracts for training classes on agricultural technologies and industrial economic management. A full list of classes and responsible training organizations is available in Appendix C. The pie chart below summarizes the 2008 allocation of training classes in City Z.

Data on the party school’s share of training during the pre-reform period is not available.

However, universities in China and abroad claimed one-fifth of training contracts in 2008, a share that would not have been possible prior to the creation of a training market in

China.

The effects of this competition are also observable at the apex of the party school system, the Central Party School in Beijing. CPS publications offer a glimpse of longitudinal trends in enrollment levels, information not as easily obtained at the provincial and lower levels. Figure 4.3 below captures enrollment levels, by year, based

138 on name lists published in CPS yearbooks. The yearbooks, which span 1985 to 2001, were not available each year but include class lists for assorted years from 1977 to 2000.

Figure 4.3: Central Party School trainee volume, 1977-2000 25000 20000 15000 Trainee-months 10000 5000 0

0 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 200 Year

Source: CPS Yearbooks, 1985-2001

The total number of cadres trained has been uneven over time, but trends are consistent with the advent of competition during the reform period. Enrollment rose during the period immediately after the tumult of the Cultural Revolution, which ended in 1976, as party authorities sought to rebuild cadre ranks. This expansion was followed by a drop in enrollment, beginning in the early 1980s, at the time that universities and other training centers were encouraged to engage in the national project of educating and training cadres. Since then, there has been a slow downward trend in CPS training capacity.

While annual figures are not available, it is possible to make some comparisons regarding the training capacity at the new COD-managed academies and the CPS. The

Jinggangshan CELA reported training 9,993 cadres from the time of its opening in 2004 until September 2007, while the Yan’an CELA reported over training over 7,200 cadres

139 from its opening in 2005 until 2007.176 This translates to an annual average of nearly

2,500 cadre trainees at each school, which exceeds the CPS annual average of 1,509

trainees for the period 1990 to 2000.

Market gains and losses

Over the past two and a half decades, this training market has generated winners

and losers. The CPS and other elite party schools, such as those at the provincial and city

levels, have relinquished some market share to new entrants but remained afloat – and, in

some cases, thrived. This prosperity was evident in the county, city, and provincial-level

schools visited in Provinces A and B, which were all in the process of or had recently

completed significant improvements to campus facilities. These renovations were all

supported in part by revenues generated through local party school ventures.

There is some evidence, however, that a subset of party schools proven vulnerable

to competitive pressures. Given the localization of finance, schools at the lowest

administrative levels often languish from lack of resources.177 In field interviews, party

school leaders acknowledged the potential risk of a grassroots crisis in the party school system.178 “Township party schools are basically local meeting halls with some signs [for

the schools] hung outside (gua paizi) so they can use the facilities for training village

leaders. They are empty institutions.”179 Higher level party schools are aware of a

potential crisis in grassroots training programs, but as a general rule, schools at different

176 On the Jinggangshan total, see “China’s Jinggangshan Cadre Academy trains nearly 10,000,” People’s Daily, 27 September 2007. On the Yan’an total, see “China’s Yan’an Cadre Academy reignites fire in a sacred revolutionary place,” China’s Personnel, 7 September 2007. 177 In his research of the Yunnan party school system from provincial to township level schools, Pieke finds relative paralysis of funding for the schools in counties and townships. See Pieke 2006, 2008 and 2009. 178 In 2008, for example, the Hubei provincial party school commissioned an investigation into the state of township party schools, but the report has not yet been made public. 179 Interview 180, former township vice-party secretary, April 2008.

140 levels remain administratively and financially separate. The atrophying of these party

schools demonstrates the disciplining nature of market-based competition and how the

struggle for training contracts has yielded uneven results. Yet, it is premature to draw conclusions about the fate of higher level schools, as it is not entirely clear whether the party school system will emerge victorious vis-à-vis new competitors.

In short, party schools throughout China have had to respond to new market- based pressures: budgetary constraints and competition from multiple training providers.

This process of marketization began in the mid-1980s, when the COD welcomed universities and other organizations to train cadres (Figure 3 below). Over time, there has been an accumulation in the number and variety of organizations participating in training activities once dominated by party schools. In the last decade, organization departments throughout the country have opened their own training centers. One important result has been the diversion of training funds to these various training providers. Some party schools, however, have proven nimble and developed various coping strategies, the subject of the next chapter.

Figure 4.4: Domestic training market entrants, by year and type of organization 1985 1987 2002

Chinese Administration Cadre Leadership Universities Institutes Academies

By central decree, At 13th Party Congress, At the 16th Party Congress, allowed to dedicate up to nationwide network of three keypoint academies 10 percent of annual schools created to train founded to address the enrollment to cadre government civil servants revolutionary spirit and training global outlook of cadres

141 6 Conclusion

This chapter has demonstrated that market forces directly shape the conditions

and decisions facing party schools. School administrators must now adjust to a certain

degree of financial insecurity and pressure to raise income beyond official budgetary

allocations. Compounding this problem, these once-cloistered party organizations must

also cope with new, market-based competition for training contracts. As a result of

several central policy decisions, party schools must contend with new training programs

offered by universities, administration institutes, and other training organizations in

China and abroad. One feature of political organization in China, limited decentralization,

has been compatible with and enabled diversification in the internal and external

environments of party schools. The provision of cadre training has fragmented, creating

a “many-headed” (duo tou) training landscape where there was once one core player.180

There is, furthermore, intentionality to this marketization: central party authorities delineated, in a series of formal policy declarations and de facto practice, the new political and economic contexts within which party schools would function in the post-

Mao period. The introduction of market forces such as competition and hard budget constraints to cadre training “takes the market not only to the state apparatus, but even further, right into the core of Leninist governance,” (Pieke 2009b: 23). These new competitive pressures reflect a priority toward shifting resources and attention to the professionalization of the cadre corps. This is an unfolding process and it remains unclear whether China’s technocratic elite will ever move beyond a hybrid one in which the professional and the personal coexist (Li and White 1990). Primers in contemporary

180 This description of cadre training was given during an interview with a county-level party school vice- principal, Interview 195, May 2008.

142 public administration now stand alongside lectures on the current party line. There has

also been a challenge to party schools’ ideological authority. While party schools have

sought to remain the party’s organizational authorities on the dissemination of party

doctrine to the cadre ranks, this distinction has eroded as a result of intra-party

competition. Through new training academies and revolutionary training schools,

organization departments have stepped into a space once commanded by party schools.

This change in status from being the only significant provider of bureaucratic

training and education to a market player among many competitors has echoes in the

Soviet experience. Party schools in the former Soviet Union have had to forge new

identities in order to adjust to the radically changed educational landscape in post-1991

Russia (Huskey 2004). The Soviet case differs from the Chinese in that the CCP has

moderated to some degree the entry of new players to the training market and, as the next chapter will show, the party retains, to some degree, the ability to rein in party school activities.

In some key ways, these developments mirror the “state entrepreneurialism”

(Duckett 2001) and “bureau-contracting” (Ang 2009b) that has emerged in government agencies and other extrabureaucracies (shiye danwei) of the Chinese party-state. Similar to the bureau-contracting observed in other agencies, party schools are now privileged to generate revenues beyond official budgetary allocations and possess de facto property rights over such extra-budgetary revenue. However, there are some key differences in the marketization of the party school system. First, party schools must compete with non-bureaucratic actors to secure training contracts. This is in contrast to the policy awards that other extrabureaucracies receive, from higher authorities, to provide public

143 services in exchange for some share of the revenue. As the next chapter will demonstrate, party school leaders exercise considerable discretion in devising income-generating activities that suit local conditions. It is not necessarily the case that new ventures must come about through top-down processes or with the explicit direction of higher levels. A second difference concerns the relationship between party schools and their managing bureaus (zhuguan bumen). Formally, party schools fall under the leadership of local party committees, which grants a certain degree of autonomy to local schools. But as noted earlier in Chapter 2, schools are immersed in a network of advisory and quasi- hierarchical relationships with other party schools, personnel departments of the party and government, and other party organs. These relationships are not as strictly hierarchical as those imposed on other extrabureaucracies, for example the government agencies responsible for public service provision. Third, these party ventures are not

“semi-legitimate” (Duckett 2001) and are instead part of official school reports to higher authorities.

The legitimacy granted to schools’ income-raising activities parallels in some respects the political and economic motivations driving “local state corporatism” in

China’s rural development (Oi 1992; Oi 1998b; Oi 1999). With the onset of economic liberalization, party school leaders, similar to grassroots party secretaries, faced strong incentives to engage in entrepreneurial, revenue-generating activities at the local level. In at least one important respect, however, party school entrepreneurialism differs from local state corporatism. Whereas local government debt and the pooling of assets are common features of local economic developmental schemes, party schools in my

144 research do not take out loans to finance new ventures, nor is there a transfer of resources

either between schools or within-locale to support new entrepreneurial ventures.

All of these developments, central party authorities seemed to hope, would prod party schools out of a Mao-era complacency and prompt significant organizational change. In response to these various market-based incentives, school leaders must now

evaluate between and adopt appropriate strategies to cope with new pressures.

Competition also presents the potential for party organizations to shift away from the

“counter-bureaucratic” practices of the Mao period and toward more shrewd decisions

about organizational purpose and priorities (U 2007).

145 Chapter 5 Organizational Strategies of Adaptation

In 2006, when I first visited the county-level party school in a coastal province’s

County Y, the school campus exuded all the allure of socialist-style concrete drab: gray

dormitory buildings, cold concrete-floored hallways, flaking interior paint. By the spring of 2008, when I visited again, the campus buildings appeared the same from the outside, but there were renovations and changes taking place within. The meeting rooms had glossy new furniture, there were new projectors in the classrooms, new air conditioning

units, and computers for all the school teachers.181 In pointing out these recently acquired amenities, the school vice-principal noted the school’s initiative to “improve the teaching environment” (gaishan jiaoxue huanjing), which was detailed in the school’s annual report. The initiative was straightforward enough: it called for the funding of various campus renovations through income from, among other things, property rentals. The vice-principal proudly boasted, “We used to engage in these sorts of activities before, but things have been going especially well in the past two years (zuijin liang nian zuo de tebie hao).” The school was reaping the benefits of local entrepreneurial opportunities.

Even more, the vice-principal announced that “there is a large-scale project in the works, a new building that will be built in the new development zone (kaifa qu) [of the county seat]. The party school will be a central part (dangxiao weizhu), along with a center for retired cadres and a training center for the people’s army (minbing xunlian

181 These upgrades represented investments totaling more than 300,000 yuan (or approximately US$37,500). This is a significant sum when compared to the approximately 200,000 yuan transfer from the local finance department that the school uses to cover annual operating expenses. Interview 232, county party school vice-principal, July 2008.

146 jidi).”182 He elaborated that the local government was planning the construction of a 22-

floor building to house multiple party and government organizations, though he was less

clear on the project timeline and budget. This ambitious plan was by no means unusual

across research sites. The intention to construct a new party school campus was well

beyond the planning phase in many of the schools I visited, from the county to the

provincial levels. Across Provinces A and B, schools were experiencing dramatic upgrades in school facilities and building booms. What explains these developments, and how are they connected to the market competition that has developed over the past three decades?

As discussed in the previous chapter, not long after the onset of Deng Xiaoping’s first liberalizing economic reforms, the party school system found itself shaped by a slew of new policies and central directives. These changes in the policy “wind” modified the

internal stability and external environment within which schools operated. Party school leaders found themselves confronting new challenges, including greater volatility in funding matters and competition for training contracts. This chapter will detail how, in response to these threats, schools instituted a variety of organizational changes.

In managing school finances, all variety of school employees – principals, faculty

and administrators – discovered the freedom to “dive into the sea” of entrepreneurial

activity. New ventures ranged from those that were more purely income-generating, such

as property rentals, to degree programs, which raised revenues as well as the profile of

party schools vis-à-vis competitors. All of these activities served, in multiple ways, to

increase the likelihood of party school survival in an increasingly crowded market.

Beyond entrepreneurial ventures, school leaders attempted to position party schools

182 Interview 232, July 2008.

147 within the training market as globally connected but ideologically authoritative training

centers. As part of this reorientation, they adjusted the content of what was actually

taught to cadres in an effort to remain at the forefront of the center’s drive to reshape

China’s administrative and political classes.

While the results of various strategies are mixed, that these changes were

implemented at all demonstrates an organizational adaptiveness and dynamism that is not

immediately apparent when one focuses on the seemingly static nature of the CCP’s formal organization. Officially, party schools continue to reside where they have always resided within the CCP’s bureaucratic structure, but to stop there would overlook significant organizational responses to new market-based challenges. While it would appear that party schools are at a disadvantage in comparison to the powerful organization department-sponsored academies that have entered the training market, this is not necessarily the case. “A bureaucracy need not be more powerful relative to its opponent, but only that it have the capacity to carry out the functions over which it is competing,” (Mertha 2006: 301). While other training systems had to begin from scratch, party schools had the advantage of decades of experience to draw from.

The changes detailed in this chapter reflect how processes bound up in the marketization of party schools have expanded the repertoire of schools’ activities, educational and otherwise, and transformed them into diversified, well-connected organizations requiring leaders with considerable entrepreneurial acumen. This in turn suggests how political organizations within the party have moved away from the old command-and-five-year-plan system of the past and toward a more hybrid model, one that blends central mandates and party control with local, market-driven adaptation. By

148 bringing the market into its organizational heart, party authorities and local party

entrepreneurs have potentially hit upon a strategy that renews the relevance and vitality

of communist party organizations with a seemingly outdated mandate.

2 Staying afloat through alternative income streams

Due to the local nature of budgetary allocations for party schools, financial

shortfalls have become a reality for many schools. Pressures to “self-raise” funds have prompted the search for independent, income-generating ventures. Party schools from the county level up are obliged to develop some entrepreneurial spirit, though the success of any given scheme is dependent on a range of factors, from local economic conditions to the perceived prestige of a given party school. School administrators and teachers have expressed frustration with the harder budget constraints of the reform period. As one teacher expressed, “Party schools can’t rely on their self-raised income (chuangshou) for survival, we must have a transfer from [government] finance. Earned income is hard to get, charging fees for training classes is annoying (taoyan).”183 Despite the

organizational adjustments required to survive in the training market, schools have

responded – and some have thrived.

An illustration of the financial struggles facing one training organization and its

coping strategies can be found in a case study of Province B’s Communist Youth League

(CYL) training school. This school, along with its counterparts in other provinces, trains

grassroots party activists and unranked or section-ranked cadres at the county and city district administrative levels, along with ranked cadres in provincial state-owned

enterprises. Transfers from the provincial finance department to the school were reduced

183 Province A capital party school teacher, Interview 207, May 2008.

149 significantly beginning in the 1990s. This was due to a policy shift which required individual work units to cover a greater share of the training and living expenses for cadres that they sent to the CYL school.184 The school has been suffering from dramatic drops in trainee enrollment since. In 1990, at its peak, this school organized 17 classes

for over 2000 trainees. These figures had dropped to 5 classes for 320 students by

2007.185

With such a decline in core training class enrollment, the school leaders have sought to plug up budget deficits through alternative means. The 2001 school budget is provided below in Table 5.1.

Table 5.1: 2001 Income and Expense Report, Province B’s CYL School Income from government transfers (in yuan) Provincial finance bureau transfer 1 130 000 Provincial finance bureau transfer (additional supplement) 70 000 Irregular transfer from provincial finance 150 000 Total income 1 350 000

Expenses Salaries 960 000 Employee benefits 110 000 Insurance 150 000 Public (operating) expenses 1 340 000 Total expenses 2 560 000 Balance -1 210 000

Self-raised income sources Degree program tuition 800 000 Outside-the-plan training programs 50 000 Rent 380 000 Total self-raised income 1 230 000

Net balance 20 000 Source: Internal school accounting document.

184 Provincial CYL school vice-principal, Interview 180, April 2008. He went on to note that a one-week training at his school would cost about 350 yuan in training fees, not including room and board, and after this 1991 policy shift, work units were reluctant to send employees to training programs at this school. 185 Interview 167, CYL school vice-principal.

150 In 2001, the provincial finance bureau transferred 1.35 million yuan to the school, enough

to cover approximately 44 percent of total expenses. The finance bureau added two

additional supplements, totaling 220,000 yuan, to this initial transfer. Taken together, the three finance bureau transfers cover 53 percent of the school’s annual expenses.186 Three

additional sources of income made up for the budget shortfall.

Income from degree programs

The first, alternative income source was tuition collected for degree programs organized by the school. A look at the school’s history of degree programs reveals a

convoluted and confusing jumble of ventures. Intermittently since 1985, the school has

partnered with the provincial party school and city universities to offer coursework in

topics such as ideology and administration. These programs culminate in associates

degrees for students and cadres (da zhuan xueli). In 1990, the campus also became the

home of a provincial “youth political school,” an educational institution that enrolled

secondary and post-secondary students in basic coursework. However, from 1996

onward, the school decided to narrow its target audience to secondary students interested

in vocational programs. In 2006, the campus became the home of yet one more school: a

provincial “youth vocational college,” which could enroll ordinary students for three-year

vocational degree programs. At present, this school offers technical secondary school

diplomas in fields such as education management and computer science. Located on the

same campus, the vocational college’s degree programs co-exist alongside the CYL

186 This is compared to a finance transfer covering one-third of total income for the Beijing city party school, reported in Pieke (2009, p. 129).

151 school’s training programs and the income from the former provide a bulwark against

ever-tightening government transfers.187

More broadly, offering degrees is a common practice throughout the party school system. These degree programs may assume a variety of forms, such as distance learning, night school, or satellite-campus instruction for degrees granted by other institutions. The

Central Party School initiated this movement in 1985 with the creation of distance learning degree programs that eventually involved provincial, city, and county-level schools. These lower level schools joined the endeavor for a share of the profits.188

Officially, these early distance degree programs were intended to meet a particular set of needs: to edify cadres from the Mao period who possessed low levels of formal education as well as the “lost” generation of cadres deprived of a decade of formal schooling during the Cultural Revolution. “At the start of the reforms, training was about general education, since many cadres lacked fundamentals,” one CPS professor of party history noted.189

Beyond meeting these official goals, there were additional benefits to party

schools’ various degree programs. They expanded the reach of party school education.

By 2002, CPS distance degree courses were being taught in approximately 2635 branches

187 According to the July 2007 edition of China Youth Daily, over 70 percent of independent CYL schools have this type of degree offering for ordinary citizens. The school’s official history indicates that vocational degree programs began under the ‘care’ of the provincial party committee and provincial government in 2003, and the provincial government formally approved the college’s credential in September 2006. 188 According to a retired head of the CPS distance degree program, the division of profits was as follows: 12 percent to the CPS, 18 percent to affiliated provincial-level party schools (fen yuan, or branch campuses), 25 percent to city party schools (xue qu, or study districts), and 45 percent to county-level party schools (fudao zhan, or tutorial stations). Profits were considerable. Whereas the overhead was approximately 1,000 yuan per student, tuition was in the neighborhood of 10,000 yuan. Interview 118, February 2008. 189 Interview 111, February 2008. The training curriculum for one of the Central Party School’s earliest combined training and degree class in 1984, for example, lists course topics such as basic sciences, math, logic, writing, and language arts (CPS 1985: 224-225).

152 (including fen yuan, xue qu, and fudao zhan) throughout the country.190 They also

signaled party schools’ willingness to compete with universities on their own terms, as

one other degree-granting option available to cadres – and members of the general public

– in need of secondary and tertiary education.

Partnership-based degree programs are common in the party school system, for

example between two or more party schools or between party schools and local

universities, to generate slush funds (xiao jin ku). The previous discussion of the CYL

school’s various degree offerings, in which programs and partnerships come and go,

reflects the deliberate creation of a space for school leaders to cope with insufficiencies in

government funding. This space exists in the broader national (and international) market

for educational services. The school’s experiments with different degree offerings were

not the actions of a rogue organization. On the contrary, this succession of different

schools and accompanying degree programs located on the party school’s campus is part

of the school’s official history. Each venture thus unfolded with government and party

approval, if not assistance. School leaders thus functioned in a context of official

permissiveness – or even encouragement – for seeking new income streams via the

private sector.

“Outside-the-Plan” Training Classes

A second source of income for this CYL school consists of “outside-the-plan”

training programs. These auxiliary training classes are often organized by the school in

cooperation with requesting work units. They may also originate from the school itself.

190 A listing of branch campuses and principals (fuze ren) is available in the CPS Correspondence Education Yearbook (Huang 2002a: 610-43). These branches exist in offices such as the Ministry of Railways, Finance Ministry, Chinese Academy of Sciences, and military bases.

153 CYL school leaders may decide to create a training class and advertise the course widely

to attract students whose sending work units then pay the training fees. By these two

routes for creating outside-the-plan classes, the school may procure some additional

income, though again the income is unstable and subject to negotiation. Even worse for

this particular CYL school, their outside-the-plan training classes are in competition with

other training organizations, such as provincial-level party schools and universities, and

they often lose out to these more prestigious institutions. By the late 1990s, the scope of

the CYL school’s training programs had narrowed because other, higher-ranked “party

schools were hungry for more trainees (dangxiao chi bu bao)” and had begun planning

training programs for cadres who once were the target audience for the CYL school.191

Rental income

The third source of income consists of rent collected from tenants of the school’s

on-campus dorms.192 This is a relatively straightforward and a common practice in many

party schools.193 In the case of the CYL school, rental income in 2001 was sufficient to

cover 15 percent of total school expenses. In Province B, the provincial party school

rents out rooms in the on-campus housing units to student exam takers every year from

November to March.194 In the case of a county-level school, the decision to rent rooms

191 Interview 180, April 2008. 192 Ibid. 193 At field visits to other schools, officials and professors noted (sometimes proudly) the rental of hotel and dorm rooms. This was the case in a provincial capital party school (Interview 140, April 2008, party school professor), a city party school (Interview 201, May 2008, party school professor), and a county party school (Interivew 232, July 2008, school vice-principal). 194 Interview 66, November 2007, provincial party school vice-principal.

154 for income on the school campus was not subject to pre-approval by the county finance

department, and the school could move forward quickly with such new ventures.195

The arrangement for renting out property can also vary across schools. In one provincial capital, the management of the party school’s hotel and restaurant halls were contracted out to a separate corporation. A party school teacher there pointed out, “the school’s hotel is the city government’s asset (zichan), so the government can decide to contract out the management and earn money from [these activities].” However, he went on to note that even with the school’s reduced control over this revenue stream, “the finance department is so pleased with us and the business we bring in,” and this gives the school leaders more bargaining power when requesting budget outlays from the local finance department.196

Beyond renting out residential units, party schools in both inland and coastal areas

are engaged in leasing out property for other uses and opening their facilities to a broader

range of clients. On a field visit to a city party school in Province A, a local private

insurance company had rented out the school dorms, cafeteria, and classrooms for a new hire orientation program. One newly-renovated county party school had rented out its hotel conference facilities for a local children’s tournament.197 Yet another school,

located in a tourist city in Province B, had created an office to provide logistical support

for tourists and out-of-town delegations of officials.198 Party school partnerships with

local entrepreneurs abounded. One school had a steamed bun stand located on campus, while another had an English school for kindergarteners. The steamed bun stand,

195 Interview 232, July 2008, county party school vice-principal. 196 Interview 133, April 2008. 197 City party school visit, May 2008; county party school visit, May 2008. 198 City party school teacher, Interview 207, May 2008.

155 established around 2003, was proudly announced to me by the vice-principal of the

county party school as part of the school’s fundraising efforts to “improve the teaching

environment.”199 The English school for kindergarteners was established in 2003 on the property of a county party school, a successful enterprise begun by an unemployed factory worker turned entrepreneur.200 One provincial party school vice principal

expressed to me that they were “lucky to be located near a national highway” so they could rent school property to various entrepreneurs on a shopping strip on campus.201

Based on these and other interviews, Table 5.2 below summarizes the range of entrepreneurial activities observed on party school campuses.

Table 5.2: Local party school entrepreneurial activities Activity Examples Purpose Partnership level Income Update Local National content Degree programs and Distance learning new schools programs, night school, vocational X X X programs, graduate programs “Outside-the-plan” Emergency X X training programs management seminar Renting property Dormitory rooms, X X strip mall units

Beyond satisfying the immediate goal of raising funds, these party school

activities are intertwined with and contribute to the development of entrepreneurship in

local economies. Schools leaders have been creative and astute at deriving pecuniary

benefits from the activities of local entrepreneurs. The various school ventures observed

at field sites, described in interviews, and documented in official reports all illustrate the

199 This initiative was noted in the vignette the beginning of the chapter. Interview 232, July 2008, county party school vice-principal. 200 Interview 192, May 2008, city party school teacher. In another interview with the school vice-principal, he reported an income of 900,000 yuan per year from rental property located on the school campus (Interview 191, May 2008). 201 Interview 66, November 2007.

156 broadened repertoire of activities that schools can engage in to diversify income streams.

Through these activities, party schools neatly fulfill the practical need to balance their

budgets. At the same time, they are fulfilling, in a more oblique manner, their mission as

cadre training organizations. The party-private sector partnerships that have resulted

from schools’ fiscal circumstances coincidentally dovetail well with the party-

entrepreneur alliance that Jiang promoted in his Three Represents doctrine. Looked at

from another perspective, the entrepreneurial activities of the party schools provide a

model of sorts for the cadre-trainees who pass through the schools in how to be

innovative and resourceful with organizational development.

Support for and opposition to party entrepreneurialism

Within the larger constellation of party and government organs connected to party

schools, the response to these income-generating ventures is mixed. Local finance

bureaus have little incentive to complain about business dealings between party schools

and the private sector. Income generated from these ventures decrease party school

dependence on government transfers as well as increase tax revenues. Matters are more

complicated with respect to central party authorities, however. Tensions over the

profitable nature of party schools’ distance learning and degree programs – and the

concern that these expanding programs distract party schools from their “core” work of

training officials – are evident in the abrupt call to end party schools’ distance degree

programs.202 This policy change, emanating from the Central Committee, has been de

202 This move is not necessarily because incomes from these degree programs are flagging. For example, a provincial capital party school professor bemoaned the school’s potential loss of over 10 million yuan in annual income from their correspondence degree programs (Interview 176, April 2008).

157 facto rather than publicly announced in official documents.203 The cue comes in part

from the omission of “correspondence degree programs” in official party school work

regulations.204 Accordingly, CPS officials recently declared that they would cease to

accept new correspondence degree applicants for undergraduate degree programs

beginning in 2008.205 While the Central Party School will take the lead in implementing

this policy, it will be carried out in a gradual national rollout. The actual effect of this

policy change on schools’ income is not clear, as party schools may still maintain revenue flows through correspondence degree programs for graduate students, night-and- weekend classes, and other non-degree offerings.

The motivations for this degree cancellation are several. Officially, CPS leaders have asserted the fulfillment of correspondence degree programs’ mission to provide older cadres with remedial education. Second, ending these degree programs is also consistent with the narrow function of party schools not as general institutions of higher learning but rather as focused sites for the transmission of skills and knowledge to promising cadres. As one party school teacher pointed out, the degree programs are not central to party schools’ organizational purpose, which according to him and official

203 While there are no publicly available official documents mandating the end of these degree programs, the registrar of the CPS correspondence degree office is quoted as saying that the “Central Committee ordered the CPS to cease organizing correspondence degree education.” See “Party school degrees difficult to cancel immediately,” Southern Daily, 9 October 2008. Zhao Changmao, the director of the CPS’s organization department, also stated that the CPS, “in accordance with Central directives” stopped accepting students for correspondence associate and undergraduate degree programs. See “Party schools gradually stopping acceptance of correspondence students,” Henan provincial education webpage, http://news.haedu.cn/GNYW/633609825171310000.html, accessed 19 July 2009. 204 This omission has been traced to the 2008 Party school trial work regulations. See CCP Party School Work Regulations (zhongguo gongchandang dangxiao gongzuo tiaoli), available at http://news.xinhuanet.com/newscenter/2008-10/29/content_10275191.htm, accessed 19 July 2009. 205 Zhu Hongjun, “Central Party School calls for stopping correspondence degrees,” Southern Weekend, 29 November 2007. Interviews 238 and 239, November 2006, county party school vice-principal and township organization department official.

158 declarations is to raise the quality (suzhi) and abilities (nengli) of cadres.206 On the other

hand, the cancellation may also be due to controversies stirred up by the lack of Ministry

of Education accreditation for party schools’ undergraduate degree programs and public

perceptions of party schools engaging in “degree selling”.207 The real reasons for the

cancellation lay somewhere between official declarations and the reports in the media.

Still, this cancellation policy has resulted in closing off one revenue channel for both the central and local party schools and illustrates how the Central Committee of the CCP has the wherewithal to interfere in party schools’ profit-generating ventures if they perceive a threat to the reputation of the party school system and, by implication, the party itself.

3 Coping with competition in the training market

Beyond fundraising activities, party schools have responded in several ways to the emergence of organizational competition for “training market share”. First, they have

stressed their unique position as institutions with deep party roots, in effect making a

reputational argument for government and party organs to continue enrolling their cadres

in party school programs. Based on their long history as core, “insider” party institutions,

party schools have also extended training programs to new, non-party audiences. Second,

they have sought to augment their program offerings through partnerships with secular

206 Interview 17, central party school teacher, November 2006. 207 See, for example, Liu Lan, “How could party schools sell diplomas?” Democracy and the Rule of Law (minzhu yu fazhi) 2004 (15). This article recounts how the Hainan provincial party school sold degrees from 2000 on and collected 37.5 million yuan from the enterprise. The Hainan party school webpage confirms that “there were some problems associated with the school’s management of its independent degree program,” (http://www.dx.hainan.gov.cn/html/intro.asp, accessed 2 June 2007). In one high-profile court case, a judge sued the Hubei provincial party school because he obtained a degree through their correspondence program in 2001, received a raised based on this advanced degree, and subsequently this degree was not recognized because of the school’s lack of accreditation. The judge is suing the school on the basis that they offered a fraudulent degree. See Southern Weekend, “Hubei judge sues party school for illegally issuing degrees,” 29 November 2007.

159 institutions of higher education. Third, in at least one case, a local party school has

sought to use back channels to thwart the emergence of new competitors. Finally, party

schools have updated their pedagogy and course content. Together, these changes reflect

the adaptability of the party school system – and the potential adaptability of party

organizations more generally – as a response to the introduction of competition, both

intra-party and with outside actors. This competition, in turn, reflects party leaders’

organizational strategies for responding to and initiating change within the party’s own

political structure.208

Maintaining school reputation

When asked about the pressures presented by new training schools and programs

springing up around the country, party school officials in interviews stressed how their

schools are preeminent sites of party study and doctrine. The Central Party School, on its

website, declares how it is the “most important venue for learning about the party’s

nature, and for studying and promoting Marxism, Leninism, Mao Zedong Thought, Deng

Xiaoping Theory and Three Representatives Important Thought.”209 One provincial

party school teacher averred that party schools provide an indispensable service to the

party: “There is some traditional content that you cannot let the market decide [whether

to teach or not]. There is too much diversity and freedom (ziyou) in universities, and the

208 There are similarities and differences between the intra-party competition discussed here and previous work on administrative bargaining and intra-bureaucratic bargaining. Earlier work has emphasized inter- and intra-bureaucracy bargaining in the context of policy and economic development. Consistent with Lieberthal and Oksenberg’s findings from studies of energy projects, the policy process in cadre training is “disjointed, protracted, and incremental” (Lieberthal and Oksenberg 1988: 24). While a similar competition for scarce resources is evident in the emerging cadre training market, Lampton (1987) emphasizes the consultative nature of bargaining in his case studies of water projects. The emphasis on fairness that Lampton finds is not, in my interviews, a component of the competition for training contracts. 209 Introduction to the CPS, htt://www.ccps.gov.cn/dxjj/index.jsp, accessed 29 June 2008.

160 central authorities will always emphasize cadre training in party schools … There will be

a division of labor based on market forces (shichang fenniu).”210 Certain routine training

programs, such as those following a party congress, do continue to be organized and

staged by the party school system. Following the 17th party congress in October 2007, there was a rollout of training sessions on how to study the documents issued by the congress, beginning with the CPS and cascading, in sequence, through party schools at the various administrative levels, where teachers would hold study sessions for cadres and other party school teachers below them.

Furthermore, party schools’ reputation as bastions of party authority continues to hold new, prominent audiences in thrall. Recently, the CPS has become a highly desired destination for entrepreneurs interested in understanding current party policies and future directions in party doctrine.211 Local schools are also organizing training programs for

private enterprises interested in establishing their own party committees or strengthening

party ties.212 Bringing private entrepreneurs and managers into party schools also fulfills

the mandate in the Three Represents for the party to absorb the “most productive” – code

for entrepreneurial – segments of society.

Forging partnerships

Reputation may not be enough to attract students, and party schools have also

strengthened their market position through partnerships. When the Central Organization

210 Interview 211, May 2008. 211 Private entrepreneurs are flocking to the CPS for 6-day training classes in which they learn about party history and policies from experts in the school and party think tanks. The cost for this program is 6,800 yuan. See He Huifeng, “Taking care of business at Central Party School,” South China Morning Post, 24 April 2006. The first group of entrepreneurs to train at the CPS, in 2001, was from Shanghai. See Li Weiping, “Shanghai entrepreneurs attend study program at Central Party School in Beijing,” Hong Kong Wen Wei Po, 10 Jan 2003. 212 Two party schools in Province A (one at the county and the other at the city level) had organized private enterprise training classes as early as 2005.

161 Department called for the implementation of cadre training programs by institutes of higher learning, party schools began to initiate partnerships with universities in China and abroad. These partnerships may take on a range of activities, from exchanging delegations of scholars and administrators to party schools sending cadres abroad for training. Table 5.3 below captures the variety of domestic partnerships established between provincial-level party schools and universities.

Table 5.3: Provincial party school partnerships with Chinese universities Year partnership Province University partner began Anhui Tsinghua University 2009 Anqing Normal School 2009 Beijing Peking University NA Beijing Foreign Language University School of Foreign Diplomacy Beijing Capital Normal School Chongqing Peking University 2009 Beijing Foreign Language University School of Foreign Diplomacy Beijing Capital Normal School Fujian Fujian Normal University 2008 Hubei Zhongnan Economics and Finance School 1993 Hubei University Chinese University of Geosciences, Wuhan Hainan HKUST NA Hunan Chinese Agricultural University 2008 Hunan University 2005 Jiangxi Tsinghua University 2007 Liaoning Shenyang University 1999 Qinghai China Tibetology Research Center 2009 Shaanxi Hong Kong Open University 1996 Peking University NA Shanghai Finance University NA Shandong Shandong University NA Shandong University 1998 Shanghai Shanghai Jiaotong University 2003 Shanxi Shanxi University 2002 Yunnan Tsinghua University 2002 Zhejiang Chinese Academy of Social Sciences 2009 Source: author’s dataset; party school web pages, official announcements, and online news articles.

162 It is likely that only those partnerships that might elevate the status of party schools are

broadcast to the general public, i.e., partnerships with national universities, which implies

an underreporting of the true number of party school-university partnerships.

International partnerships are another way for party schools to improve their

profile as forward-looking, globally-connected organizations. Two decades ago, when the training landscape began shifting, the CPS was the only party school with

international connections (Liu 1989: 110-114). The CPS took a leading role early on

with a research partnership, initiated in 1995, between its Center for International

Strategic Research and Harvard’s Fairbank Center for East Asian Research (Kirby, Ross, and Li 2005: ix-x). Beginning in 2002, around 60 officials have been sent each year to

Harvard’s Kennedy School of Government for two-month training programs in public administration.213 The CPS received a delegation in December 2007 from Louisville

University to give workshops on the US political system, though this was under the

purview of a partnership between the LU East Asian Studies Research Center and the

CPS Pacific Research Center.214 The purpose was to train party school scholars, which in

turn would enhance their ability to train cadres on the structure of foreign political systems. The rationale for these partnerships is simple: “It’s mutually beneficial.

Foreigners are banking on the possibility of influencing the thinking of rising Chinese leaders, and the Chinese government needs to develop its human capital.”215

Local schools have followed the example set by the CPS. The Wuhan city party

school, for example, lists on its webpage that it has exchange programs with the Moscow

National University, Far East Research Institute at the Russian Academy of Social

213 “China’s Central Party School trains 50,000 officials in 30 years,” Xinhua, 2 October 2007. 214 Interview 42, CPS professor. 215 Interview 34, October 2007, former central-level cadre.

163 Sciences, Hanoi Institute of Politics, and Lyon Institute of Public Administration.216

Some schools will also channel partnerships through their administrative institutes. Table

5.4 below lists the partnerships and exchange programs that the Shanghai city party school and school of administration have engaged in since 2000. These programs vary in their structure and have involved the exchange of school administrators, teachers, and students. A full list of publicly-listed international partnerships by provincial-level party schools is available in Appendix F.

Table 5.4: Shanghai party school and administration institute international partnerships School International Partner Year began Shanghai city party school Civil Service College in Singapore at least 2004 Ecole Nationale d' Administration German University of Administrative Sciences Speyer (Germany) at least 2006 Kennedy School of Harvard University at least 2007 Maxwell School of Syracuse University at least 2000 Nagoya University (Japan) at least 2008 Sciences Po (France) University of Alberta () at least 2004 University of Georgia at least 2004 Shanghai administration institute Civil Service College in Singapore at least 2004 Ecole Nationale d' Administration at least 2004 Ecole Normale Superieure Humboldt University at least 2004 Kennedy School of Harvard University Maxwell School of Syracuse University Postdam University (Germany) at least 2004 Sciences Po (France) at least 2004 University of Alberta (Canada) at least 2004 University of Georgia Source: Author’s dataset.

Organization departments, for their part, have not remained isolated.

International partnerships between the COD and institutions of higher learning abroad include a master’s degree program for cadres at the Nanyang Technological University in

216 Wuhan party school introduction, available at http://www.whdx.gov.cn/xyjj.asp, accessed 1 June 2009.

164 Singapore and a global public policy collaboration between the COD, Peking University,

Columbia University, Sciences Po Paris, and the London School of Economics (Li 2006:

20). In general, these partnerships and the additional training that cadres receive through

them are consistent with the “opening up” promoted by Deng and subsequent leaders. As

one CELA administrator pointed out, “Our leaders need to be taught how to borrow from

the entire world’s best cases. As Deng said, it doesn’t matter if it’s a black cat or a white

cat, so long as the knowledge and models we adopt are the best.”217 In order to compete

in a global economy, cadres require an outward orientation and knowledge of other

systems; their party education has been tailored to address this particular need. From the

perspective of party schools, which are now facing pressure from increasingly

internationally-oriented universities and organization department schools, partnerships

are instrumental for lending additional cache and depth to the curriculum. In the end,

though, these partnerships increase the number and types of institutions involved in cadre

training, which service the goals of the party’s marketization strategy to create the conditions for new content and expanded problem-solving capacity.

Outmaneuvering competition

In a less constructive vein, party schools have also dealt with competitors through preemptive maneuvers. One provincial party school has sought to stave off the opening of new training centers through connections and behind-the-scenes negotiations. One leading university in Province A sought to build a cadre education academy in 2005, but the provincial party school opposed the scheme. Party school leaders, along with contacts at the Central Party School, challenged the project on the grounds that

217 Interview 184, April 2008, CELAP director.

165 “ideological training wouldn’t be preserved at the university.” 218 In the end, the key

party authority, the provincial organization department, would not approve the new

academy “because they couldn’t ensure the quality of the ideological training [at this

proposed center].”219

Such a gambit may limit the efforts of universities, which are not party organs, but this strategy has limited leverage in the intra-party competition which has sprung up.

Preventing organization departments from opening training centers presents a thornier problem. An organization department cadre noted that the provincial party school may have been successful at blocking the university’s attempt to open a training center, but

“party schools don’t have any way to stop the organization department from building new centers.”220

In summary, party schools have pursued several strategies to cope with the

competitive pressures arising out of the reform-era training market. These responses,

some rhetorical and others more substantive, have opened up party schools to new

partnerships and brought about adjustments in how party schools situate themselves

within the training market. Peering inside party schools, furthermore, reveals how these

schools have adapted to new constraints and opportunities in the actual content of what

they teach cadres in the new training market.

4 Change measured: Content analysis of party school training

One consequence of the introduction of market processes and pressures has been a

rethinking of what should be taught and how. By examining the substantive impact of

218 Provincial party school teacher, Interview 211, May 2008. 219 Ibid. 220 Interview 212, provincial capital organization department cadre, May 2008.

166 these market forces on party school curricula, it is possible to identify what kind of

change party authorities have ushered in with the opening of the market floodgates. Party

leaders have framed cadre training as integral to the process of party and government

bureaucrats’ successful management of China’s economic development and the CCP’s

continued monopoly on political authority. CCP leaders portray cadre training as the

vehicle for creating the kind of flexible, up-to-date bureaucratic corps that the party

requires. How do party schools reflect the new priorities of central party leaders? What

is taught in party schools? How has this changed over time? Examining the content of

party school training classes reveals how party schools have “kept pace with the times”221

and, in so doing, embody the organizational adaptability that has in part defined CCP

leadership for the past three decades.

This section considers changes in the training content of classes at the Central

Party School, the flagship within the party school system. CPS yearbooks contain

teaching plans for training programs organized over the period 1983 to 2000, and

additional training syllabi were collected during site visits. Table 5.5 below offers a

summary of the syllabi collected, by year.

Table 5.5: Central Party School training syllabi analyzed, by year Year 1983 1984 1985 1990 1993 1994 1995 2000 2007 Total Training 2 1 5 5 9 10 14 7 9 62 Syllabi

Because of the low number of syllabi available for 1983 and 1984, these two years were

excluded from analysis. The categories used for coding syllabi are given in Appendix G.

221 In a tour of the new Pudong CELA, Zeng Qinghong of the CCP Central Committee (and former Central Party School president from 2002 to 2007) declared, “One of the most important reasons behind the Party’s successful advancement of the transformations in economic growth, social administration and the Party’s governance is efficient cadre training, which makes leading cadres at various levels change their ways of thinking and working by keeping pace with the times,” (Xinhua, 15 May 2007).

167 One starting point is to compare the share of total training time, for a given year, dedicated to various topics. Figures 5.1 and 5.2 below suggest that in some areas of training content, change has been dramatic.

Figures 5.1 and 5.2: CPS training content by category, percent of total training time

1985 2007

Orthodoxy Other Other 9% 5% Vocational Reform-era 4% training Orthodoxy theory 16% Vocational 31% 5% training 27% Management 19% Reform-era theory 0% Case studies Management Case studies 5% 6% 32% Policy Policy 26% 15%

Notes: Data obtained from CPS training syllabi. Study of party documents, including party-building documents, are included in the “policy” category.

It appears that political theory – the foundational works of Marxism-Leninism, Mao

Zedong Thought, and the political declarations of paramount leaders Deng, Jiang, and

Hu – has decreased from 31 percent to 14 percent (adding together “orthodoxy” and

“reform-era theory”). Case studies and vocational training (which includes

coursework in accounting, law and economics) has increased from a combined total

of 32 percent to 48 percent. Management, a separate but related category which includes training in crisis management, leadership, and speechmaking, among others,

has tripled from 6 percent to 19 percent of party school training time. However, these

figures present only a snapshot comparison of the two years that bookend the

available data and, as the preceding discussion will show, this comparison masks

168 some of the more interesting patterns (and noise) in examinations of longitudinal trends over the two decades. Still, these changes in training content offer hints as to what party leaders consider the most important knowledge and skills for cadres serving at various levels in the system.

First, what has happened to the teaching of core ideology, proxied by the study of party theory, in party schools? This is arguably the bread and butter of party school training. In the 1983 Central Organization Department’s 8-year cadre training plan, which called for the ‘regularization” (zhengguihua) of cadre training and spurred a movement toward professionalization of the party school system, Marxist theory was still accorded first mention in the COD’s vision for the content of cadre training (COD 1983: 68). As a gesture to the ideological underpinnings of the party’s rule, training programs often begin with a unit on “Fundamental Marxist

Theory” (CPS First Short-term Training Class in 1985).

By 1995, however, it is possible to detect a shift in the canon. The first section in CPS training classes jumped straight to study of Deng Xiaoping’s writings

(1995 CPS Yearbook: 172-92), dropping the works of Mao, Marx and Lenin. Still,

CPS syllabi continue to couch the general goals of training classes in terms of the long pedigree of thinkers shaping the Party’s ideology today. The 2007-08 Young

Cadre Training Class syllabus begins with a declaration of the objectives of the course: “In accordance with the professional needs of provincial and ministry-level leading cadre positions, we will systematically study fundamental questions of

Marxism-Leninism, Mao Zedong Thought, Deng Xiaoping Theory, ‘Three

Represents’ Important Thought, and contemporary world economy, world technology,

169 international law, global military affairs, global ideational trends, world religions,

etc.”222

Figure 5.3 illustrates the amount of training time, as a share of total training time,

dedicated to orthodox theory in the training syllabi collected. Orthodox theory in this figure is defined as course content dedicated to Marxism-Leninism and “Mao Zedong

Thought”.

Figure 5.3: Percent of CPS training time dedicated to orthodox theory .3 .2 .1 Percent of time class 0

1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

Arguably, this is an area where party schools possess a competitive advantage over other training organizations. At the same time, there may be pressure to push aside these topics in favor of more professional training. A test as to whether orthodox theory is still the core focus of party school training or more of a formality can be assessed by measuring the actual amount of training time dedicated to the foundational thinkers. There is a downward trend in the available data, from a peak of 30.7 percent of class time in 1985 to

9.3 percent in 2007.

222 Teaching plan, CPS 23rd One-year Young Cadre Training Class.

170 It may be that the decreasing emphasis on foundational thinkers has given way to

study of the ideas of more recent leaders. However, there also appears to be a general

decrease in the amount of training time dedicated to the theories and speeches of post-

Mao leaders from Deng Xiaoping to Jiang Zemin (Figure 5.4). Classes spent the most

time on Deng’s “reform and opening up” in the mid-1990s, but the overall amount of

time spent on studying the guiding words of top leaders has decreased from a peak of

20.6 percent in 1995 to 4.5 percent in 2007.

Figure 5.4: Percent of training time dedicated to the theories of reform-era leaders .25 .2 .15 .1 Percent of time class .05

1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

In field interviews, party school teachers and officials have explained why there might be a decrease in the attention given to orthodox party theory. One Central Party

School teacher mused,

[Content changed] because there was a realization that the old coursework was insufficient for solving the problems of the reform era. Marxism didn’t have the answers. Students needed to have a more global outlook (shijie yanguang). There was debate over these changes [in curricula], nothing public, but debate nonetheless. We are still debating these changes today. Some want to stay with the ‘five old subjects,’ some want issues in economic development and related theories to be central.223

223 Interview 114, CPS professor of party history, February 2008.

171 A second look at the data, however, tells a less conclusive story. There

has not been a steady decline in the study of core party ideology, more broadly

defined as Marxism-Leninism and the subsequent writings and declarations of

CCP leaders. A look at the total share of training time dedicated to party theory

shows a noisier trend (Figure 5.5), with declines in the mid-1990s and a

significant drop during the most recent year for which data is available.

Figure 5.5: Percent of CPS training time dedicated to party theory

0.35

0.3

0.25

0.2 post-Mao party theory Mao party theory 0.15 Marxism-Leninism

0.1 Percent of total training time

0.05

0

1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Year

The sharp increase in training time dedicated to foundational thinkers and party

orthodoxy in 2000 may be explained by two 20-week classes convened that year: the first

county party secretary training class (xianshi wei shuji jinxiu ban) and first western

region cadre training class (xibu diqu ganbu peixun ban). Both were non-routine training

classes and have not been organized since. Nearly half of the training time in these two

classes was dedicated to core party theory, from Marxism-Leninism to the writings and

speeches of Jiang Zemin. There appear to be varying motivations for the organization of

these two classes. First, a county-level training class was one manifestation of

centralization efforts begun during the Jiang Zemin administration. Given the convention

172 that party schools train cadres ranked one administrative level (or rank) lower, the CPS is

traditionally a training ground for central and provincial (ministerial) cadres. However,

five thousand county-level party secretaries and magistrates were sent to central training

schools in a five-year series of classes.224 Second, this special training class was also a

means to disseminate policy priorities bound up in building a “new socialist countryside”.

Similarly, the CPS training class targeting cadres from the western provinces came on the

heels of the 1999 rollout of the Western Development Program (xibu da kaifa jihua).

Trends are somewhat clearer but also puzzling with respect to training time

dedicated to party building, or course content focused on CCP doctrine and the party line.

Party schools in many ways embody and shape the party line of the day. Party members

study articles written by CPS leaders and party school-affiliated theorists to grasp the

evolution and future direction of party doctrine. By 2005, for example, leaders and

theorists in the CPS had developed the concept of a “harmonious society,” the idea

promoted by Hu Jintao to guide economic and social development under his administration. Yu Yunyao, vice president of the CPS, has written at length about bundling together this concept of social harmony with “scientific development,” two terms often seen in official declarations.225 Shen Baoxiang, also a CPS professor, has

contributed to the ideological and developmental agenda and noted the many “historic

topics” that the party must confront: “implementing the concept of scientific development

across the board, building a harmonious society, building a new socialist countryside, and

224 A Southern Weekly article on this training class, for example, noted that this class enabled the “policy- making level [of government] to grasp grassroots officials” (juece ceng zhijie ‘zhua zhu’ jiceng guanyuan). See http://www.nanfangdaily.com.cn/zm/20070104/xw/szxw1/200701040006.asp, accessed 10 February 2008. 225 “PRC Central Party School Vice President on Building Socialist Harmonious Society,” Guangming Ribao, 18 May 2005.

173 building an innovation-oriented nation.”226 Declarations emanating from party schools thus serve as a bellweather for shifts in party ideology, and it would make sense for cadres to attend party schools to learn about these cutting-edge developments.

Yet, party building as a topic in CPS training classes has suffered from uneven levels of attention over time (Figure 5.6). Party building is defined here as courses dedicated to party history, the party’s constitution, the party line, and the study of central party policies focused on party building. The trend is not altogether clear, but there is a decline in the amount of time dedicated to these subjects beginning in the 1990s.

Figure 5.6: Percent of CPS training time dedicated to party building .25 .2 .15 .1 Time dedicated to party-building to dedicated Time .05 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

Party-building Fitted Values

This downward trend may be due to crowding out by the more secular topics

(explained below) that have claimed increasing shares of training time, topics that are compatible with the professionalizing ambitions of recent administrative reforms. This trend may also be exacerbated, in more recent years, by the creation of organization department-sponsored training programs in which cadres are exposed to immersive,

226 Shen Baoxiang, “Reform and Opening Up is Still the Idea that Decides China’s Destiny,” Study times, 20 March 2006.

174 “revolutionary spirit building” activities that in some ways substitute for studying the party line. Such “experiential learning” may have claimed some of the ideological

ground once held by party schools, at least in terms of capacity to build “party spirit”.

One Central Party School teacher complained,

You have ridiculous training exercises [at these new CELA]. Cadres will be issued a revolutionary outfit and backpack and climb Jinggangshan. It’s so silly! In every 2- to 6-month long training class that the CPS organizes, trainees will have to spend 7 to 10 days at one of these academies and do this silly experiential learning (tiyan shi). Even township cadres have to go to these organization-department academies for revolutionary training.227

Such complaints present a stark contrast to the official story that party schools and

organization department training academies have a mutually supportive (hu wei buchong)

relationship.228 They also hint at an emerging division of labor, where party schools

remain sites for the serious study of party leaders’ theoretical development (hence

grooming trainees for leadership in party theory), while the organization department

handles matters of party esprit de corps.

Furthermore, in place of orthodox theory and party building, CPS training courses

now offer more diversity in content. Topics falling under the category of management

have claimed an increasing share of training time. Management-related content, in

contrast to the other categories discussed thus far, is more secular in nature and

administrative, rather than ideological, in focus. This category includes the following

topics: leadership theory or “the art of leadership,” crisis management, speechmaking and

227 Interview 114, CPS teacher of party history, February 2008. 228 A typical statement, repeated in interviews, can be found in official publications such as the Chinese Personnel Report: “Party schools, administration institutes and other cadre academies will each have their particular emphasis, be mutually supporting, and have a division of labor in cadre training.” He Xican, “Innovation in cadre education and training through the creation of ‘three academies’” available online at http://www.rensb.com/showarticle.php?articleID=10758, accessed 2010-03-09.

175 communication, media relations, principles of service-based government, public administration, and strategic thinking. The figure below captures this increase, with course time on general management skills consuming 16 percent of CPS training time in

2000. This year was significant as the inaugural year for a five-year rotational training program to train all county magistrates at the central level, “the front line commanders in the building of a new Chinese countryside.”229 Leadership and management training time increased overall from 5.6 percent in 1985 to 18.9 percent by 2007.

Figure 5.7: Percent of CPS training time dedicated to management .2 .15 .1 .05 Portionclass of time dedicatedleadershipto 0

1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

Leadership skills Fitted Values

Included in this shift to emphasizing more practical, professional skills has been

an effort to inform cadres on the state of various governance issues in China. Figure 5.8

gives the amount of training time dedicated to policy briefings. Experts are often invited

to the CPS to give briefings on some aspect of the “national situation” (guo qing). Such

training exercises reflect two opposing trends: a departure from orthodox theoretical

concerns and emphasis on practical knowledge as a key attribute of rising leaders.

229 Hu Jintao was quoted as saying this in a Southern Weekend article on this county-level magistrate training, “Five thousand county magistrate training by rotation,” 4 January 2007.

176 Figure 5.8: Percent of CPS training time dedicated to policy briefings .2 .15 .1 .05 0

Time dedicatedto briefings onthe national situation 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

natsitcps Fitted values

With the decrease in theoretical concerns, there have also been pedagogical shifts.

Content analysis of a combined dataset of national and local training syllabi (N=162) revealed an increase in the amount of training time devoted to case study as a method for informing cadres about the state of affairs in their own locales, elsewhere in China, and

globally. Figure 5.9 below indicates the amount of party school class time, on average,

dedicated to case studies, both domestic and international, across the CPS and local

schools.

A look at one case study used at the CPS in 2007 illustrates how leading cadres

are presented with a complex situation and then prompted to debate broader issues in

leadership. Case study 2007-015, “A party secretary’s controversial leadership style,”

tells the story of an anonymous city party secretary who uses heavy-handed tactics to clean up a poor, crime-ridden county. This party secretary pushes through public works projects by lowering wages and imposing corvee labor requirements on local villagers, privatizes all state-owned enterprises in the county, and brings in the media to report on corrupt subordinates. He claims that such rapid reform measures are necessary in order

177 for China to “walk in 50 years what the West walked in 300 years” (p. 7). There is

deliberate ambiguity in the “correctness” of the leadership practiced in this case study,

and cadres are asked via discussion questions posed before and after the case study to

reflect on their own management philosophies.

Figure 5.9: Percent of training class time dedicated to case studies .15 .1 .05 0 Portion of class time dedicated to studies case to time dedicated class of Portion 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year

gcs Fitted values

Such case studies illustrate the participatory shift in training and the move away from unidirectional, doctrinal learning. Developing such critical thinking skills is paramount

given China’s unpredictable, rapid local development and the aim of forging leaders

capable of making autonomous decisions which are nonetheless consistent with the

center’s developmental goals.

In sum, content analysis of CPS training syllabi allows for some measurement of

the change in what cadres are taught within the party school system. Training content is

a response to and a reflection of party leaders’ awareness that cadres often make

decisions under rapidly changing conditions and with a certain degree of autonomy.

Professional management skills are thus crucial and consume an increasing share of

training time. Less definitive evidence exists to support the conclusion that training time

178 dedicated to the theory of core party leaders – party orthodoxy – is on the decline. There

are also hints of a division of labor across training organizations, evident in the decreased

attention to party building at the CPS. It appears that the party school’s organization

department counterparts have moved toward more creative ways of instilling party spirit

in individual cadres, beyond the uninspired study and memorization of doctrine.

How much do local party school training classes differ from the Central Party

School? Data were insufficient to show trends over time for various topic areas, but a

comparison of CPS training content in 2007 with what was taught in the provincial-level

party schools of provinces A and B reveal similarities as well as striking differences

Table 5.6: Comparison of CPS and provincial-level party school training content Provincial Of which: CPS schools Province A Province B combined Year 2007 2008 2008 2008 Total syllabi 9 17 10 7 Percent of total training time dedicated to each category: Orthodoxy 9 2.7 2.2 3.5 Reform-era theory 4.5 2.8 0.4 6.1 Management 19.1 17.3 16.9 17.8 Party-building 11.5 13.3 15.8 9.6 Central policies 3.9 6.2 3.8 9.6 Local policies na 14.3 16.1 11.6 National briefings 19.4 8.7 9.2 7.8 Case studies 13.4 9.4 8.7 10.4 Economics 5.6 13.1 14.4 11.2 Law 5.6 5.7 4.6 7.2 Vocational skills 4.4 2.0 0.0 5.0 Other* 3.6 4.5 8.1 0.2 Total 100 100 100 100 *Other training content includes optional televised and weekly lectures (topics unspecified) and physical education. Source: Author’s dataset Analysis is based on the collected syllabi for core (“inside-the-plan”) training classes organized by each school. Table 6 below summarizes the content across these provincial- level counterparts to the CPS. Under the expectation that there will be some lag time before local schools are able to incorporate training content from training syllabi

179 transmitted down through the system, the comparison below summarizes training content from 2007 CPS and 2008 provincial party school syllabi.

What does this comparison suggest about the degree of central control over local school training content? There are similarities in the allocation of training time to certain topics, such as management, party-building, and legal studies. This suggests a system-

wide shift toward a hybrid identity for party schools as both traditional political

academies and more secular, forward-looking management schools. Local schools,

however, seem to be moving more quickly toward the latter identity. This is borne out by

local de-emphasis of party theory, a total of 5.5 percent of training time across the local

schools compared to 13.5 percent at the CPS (summing over the orthodoxy and reform-

era theory categories).230 There is also greater emphasis by local schools on official

policies, central and local. Policy analysis claimed 20.5 percent of local party school

training time, whereas this was only 3.9 percent at the CPS. There is also more emphasis

on economics at the local schools, in contrast to briefings on the national situation at the

central school, which reflects differences in the kinds of leadership decisions that

managers at these various levels may face in their daily work.

In the absence of longitudinal data, it is difficult to tell whether local schools have been drifting further from their central model over the course of the reform period. The evidence presented here indicates that local schools do enjoy some autonomy with respect to training content, as there are significant departures from the central curriculum across several topic areas.

230 The provincial schools make up for this difference through slightly more party-building content – e.g., the study of official party papers, visits to revolutionary historical sites. Party-building activities may have also increased this particular year as a build-up to the 17th Party Congress convened in October 2008.

180 5 Conclusion

In response to the challenges bound up in the marketization of cadre training, party school leaders have implemented a variety of organizational reforms. These strategies address the various dimensions to the problems presented by market competition and less stable income streams: diversification of revenue-generating schemes, the initiation of new programs and partnerships to cope with competition, and adjustments in the content of training classes. Above all, party schools now have strong incentives to search actively for solutions to ever-shifting circumstances. New entrepreneurial ventures served important functions for the school leaders who were responsible for the allocation of resources between official (training) and market

(entrepreneurial) activity: in maximizing revenues through new ventures, schools could offer increased benefits to employees and generate the resources for reinvestment in the school. These, in turn, would enhance a party school’s competitiveness. Through content analysis of Central Party School training syllabi, the mandate to craft a professional bureaucratic body is manifest in more management training and briefings on local, national, and global developmental case studies. All of these changes have added diversity to the training content received by local bureaucrats. This diversity, in turn, represents a locally adaptive response to incentives generated by central party authorities.

Entrepreneurial activities by party schools have accompanied substantive shifts in training content. A nationwide party school degree system, now officially defunct, was the beginning of a stream of income-generating activities devised by party schools.

School leaders have leveraged their particular organizational resources in the market by providing facilities and human resources to private actors in search of everything from

181 well-located rental property to event managers. Such entrepreneurship, which carries the

party stamp of approval, indicates that party organizations are making a fundamental shift:

rather than absorb entrepreneurial talent through the Three Represents, party leaders

themselves are embodying the new spirit of market-based competitiveness and the

innovation that comes with it.

At the same time, the most elite training classes emphasize general knowledge rather than specialization. The breadth of bureaucratic positions and responsibilities is so great, it is more logical for elite leaders to be groomed in the broad arenas deemed most relevant to contemporary leadership. “The ability to synthesize, to adopt global views and to make global decisions is considered the hallmark of the elite,” (Suleiman

1977: 142). As discussed in Chapter 3, party schools are part of the selection process for political elite. The criteria for selection, and the institutions implicated in these selection processes, has changed to reflect the new emphasis on a globally oriented, professional party bureaucracy.

Another related outcome of the introduction of market forces to party organizations has been an increasing integration of party schools in local economies.

Schools serve an economic function by contributing to party revenues and local development. This is due to schools’ entrepreneurial drive for new income sources, which in turn pushes them to turn outward and actively consort with a broad range of local actors: private companies in search of rental facilities; private entrepreneurs seeking out party school training to build professional networks; private corporations in need of retail space; party and government cadres interested in taking part time degree programs; party and government work units in search of made-to-order training classes; private

182 citizens seeking convenient and inexpensive degrees. These local transactions and

relationships all embed party schools more deeply in local economies. Party schools are

no longer closed, mysterious fortresses of party authority. Even more, this local

embeddedness suggests that party schools have carved out for themselves an expanded

role in local communities, beyond their traditional function as elite political training

academies. This has not been through a redefining of the role of party schools, but rather

by retaining the place of these schools within party organization and grasping new

opportunities.231 New functions have been layered atop the old. School leaders have developed formal and informal ties to those key actors in the party and beyond the party who can affect the conditions of party schools’ existence as increasingly local actors.

Local embeddedness also pays off within the national training market. Party schools in model regions may serve as interlocutors for interested governments located elsewhere in China but who are nonetheless interested in learning the secrets behind, for example, the success of a locale in a particular sector of economic development, or environmental standard enforcement, or for some other attention-grabbing reason. So long as the local party school is able to maintain a convincing research profile or knowledge of conditions in the locale, interested parties will inquire. Training classes organized by party schools in the most economically developed coastal cities, for example, provide cadres from inland regions with valuable reports and field experiences on different economic development models. City-level party schools will often have special research centers for investigating special topics. In one coastal, city-level party

231 This is similar to what Selznick pointed out in his study of the Tennessee Valley Authority, “In relations to the states, counties, and other local agencies, the TVA could not have operated successfully without framing its program within the existing pattern of government, including the powers and the traditional prerogatives of the local units,” (p. 55).

183 school, an in-house research center focuses on the development of the local private

sector.232 Local research conducted by school teachers and groups of cadre trainees are

then disseminated and stored in locally-distributed volumes of published field reports.233

This chapter also points to changing conceptions of the ideal leading cadre in

today’s CCP. In the past, selfless revolutionaries capable of carrying out Marxist

prescriptions for class-based conflict were the role models for aspiring cadres. Cadres

wore their “non-expert” status as a badge of honor.234 This was followed by a gradual

process of replacing revolutionaries with “semi-bureaucrats” and, more recently,

professional administrators (Lee 1984; Lee 1991; Li 1998; Vogel 1967). Training

content today paints a strikingly different ideal from the pre-reform period, or even the early reform period. The model cadre of the present is a professional, entrepreneurial, globally aware manager with a more artificial understanding of the party’s doctrinal foundations. This new emphasis on professionalization, however partial, accords with the view that a more effective bureaucracy should comprise (somewhat) independent- minded mandarins rather than bureaucrats subject to the mandates of all-controlling executives (Aberbach and Rockman 1988). Eddy U argues that Marxist-Leninist systems of rule have generated “counter-bureaucracies”, or systems departing significantly from

Weberian ideals of rational bureaucratic rule (U 2007). What appears to be taking place with the reform of cadre training and transformation of party schools is, in post-socialist

232 Interview 97, city party school teacher, Province A, December 2007. 233 When visiting one city-level party school, I was able to obtain an internal publication, “Materials from study and research activities” (xuexi diaoyan huodong cailiao) which included reports by cadre trainees. These contained data, sometimes comparative, that were obtained during field investigations on local political and economic developments (e.g., population issues, legal reform). 234 The idea was that so long as a cadre was “red,” a general background would nonetheless allow him to lead the experts. This was represented in the saying “experts must always be led by nonexperts” (waihang lingdao neihang). See Meiru Lu, p. 99, quoting page 1 of the Beijing Daily (Beijing ribao) dated 11 November 1979.

184 China, movement toward the professionalized bureaucracy that was so difficult to

achieve in the highly politicized climate of Maoist China. This professionalization,

however, should not be taken as an indication that politics are waning; rather, “the

promotion of technocratic rule serves enduring political agendas” (Pieke 2009a: 93) and

reflects a concerted attempt to deflect more destabilizing calls for democratization. The

project has become one of updating the “new socialist man” such that he can respond to

and generate prosperity in a changed context (Klugman 1989; Munro 1971).

Market processes in the party school system have thus served the interests of

central authorities by inducing party schools to contribute to the party’s project of

redefining the figure of the cadre in a market economy. The focus within the CCP on

developing “five capacities” (wuzhong nengli), which party leaders believe are crucial for

the party’s continued rule, require a new sort of cadre leader.235 This is because, in

grander terms, “the prosperity of our socialism and the future of China depend on whether our Party can cultivate a generation of highly qualified leading talent to enhance

the Party’s governance capacity,” (CPS 2004: 133). In the new training market, party

schools are generating content that caters to those desired skills and abilities.

235 These capacities are identified in internal party documents as: possessing scientific judgment of domestic and international conditions; the ability to manage the market economy; the ability to cope with complex circumstances; the ability to rule based on the rule of law; and the ability to manage situations in a comprehensive fashion. See (CPS 2004)

185 Chapter 6 Conclusion

What is remarkable about the communist party-led states of the twentieth century

is the overall longevity of their rule. Among current regimes in the world today, one-

party autocracies have lasted for, on average, 25.5 years,236 while collapsed single-party

communist regimes endured for an average of 48.3 years.237 A certain institutional

stability underlay the persistence of these regimes, and an appreciation of this toughness

precedes consideration of the ultimate demise that claimed many of the CCP’s political

peers. China under CCP rule is fascinating not only because it endured through the

ideological collapse and tumult of the 1980s and 1990s which engulfed the communist

world, but because many of its Leninist party structures have withstood the tests of

economic and social transformation. This project took such institutional resilience as its

starting point.

In embarking on this project of mapping institutional survival in China, I began

with a puzzle. Why is it that the party school system, which has roots in early CCP

organization and reflects the Mao-era importation of Leninist party forms, continues to

survive more than three decades into the reform period? What role do these

organizations play in the maintenance of the CCP’s political authority, what challenges

have these organizations faced, and what coping strategies have they adopted? I sought

to expand beyond earlier findings that party schools are drivers of ideological change

within the party. In focusing on party schools to gain traction on broader questions of

236 This is for the period 1960-2003, according to the Hadenius and Teorell dataset, totdur1ny and regime1ny variables (Hadenius and Teorell 2007). 237 See Dimitrov 2010 (N=10).

186 party change, I have asserted that party schools are a valuable window into how CCP organizations are capable of adaptive learning.

First, I sought to identify whether these party organizations contribute to solving a particular, internal problem of single party rule. While previous studies have focused on the ideological authority of party schools, this study has shown how these schools also perform a critical gatekeeping function. As such, they constitute an important mechanism of elite control. All authoritarian rulers must address an elite selection problem, and this complicates the stark choice between allocating resources to “guns versus votes.” Investing in sub-party organizations of elite selection is, in some ways, an investment in both sticks and carrots, insofar as political elites are the party agents who populate and manage the party’s repressive apparatus(es) and distribute the policy goods that placate the general population. In short, the party must invest in managers.

In Chapter 3, I demonstrated that the party school system is a channel for mitigating the selection problem facing party authorities. This suggests that cadre training more generally fulfills a selection function within the party. Importantly, this selection is anticipatory and represents an ex ante form of bureaucratic control. Within the party’s repertoire of controls over the bureaucracy, selection mechanisms such as training exist prior to those that monitor cadre behavior. Personnel selection is critical in an authoritarian system where policymaking is a fragmented process, implementation varies at the discretion of local bureaucrats, and monitoring remains weak. In a bureaucratic system that is hierarchically organized but subject to decentralizing forces, party schools are a manifestation of the unifying role of party organization in Chinese governance. Party schools lend structure and regularity to the party’s vital need to

187 manage personnel. As such, they complement other institutions of political personnel

management within China. This control is an important link in the chain of authority structures that support the CCP’s continued governance.

Throughout the reform period, party schools have also exhibited an adaptiveness to changing conditions. In recent decades, school leaders have had to cope with exogenous pressures imposed by central party authorities. They have responded to the

erosion of their monopoly position in the cadre training market and the introduction of

competition. Competition, by definition, introduces redundancy to the system.

Redundancy is primarily a safeguard against the failure of a bureaucratic system to fulfill

a task, given some probability that an individual agency might fail. Another benefit to a competitive system, and the motivation cited by central party authorities in China, has been the desire to update the incentives driving organizational survival and adaptation. A key force for change has been the creation by central party authorities of a training market whereby party and non-party organizations are allowed to compete with party schools for training contracts. This has led to a system of overlapping agency jurisdictions where one objective of a redundant system has been met, i.e., a more innovative system overall. Party schools have responded to these new, centrally- imposed competitive pressures and opportunities by exhibiting a certain degree of organizational agility. Market competition has disciplined party schools with harder budget constraints and induced them to search for more innovative training content and new organizational directions. Many have become more outward-looking, even global, organizations.

188 The opening of markets for goods and services, which were a key part of the

liberalizing reforms initiated by Deng Xiaoping from the 1980s onward, also created the

conditions for party schools to engage in entrepreneurial, income-generating activities.

This stands in contrast to concerns during the early reform period that bureaucrats would

exit the bureaucracy for private market opportunities and hollow out the bureaucracy of

managerial talent (Li 1998). Instead, party organizations themselves are incubators of

entrepreneurial activity. Party schools are now involved in a variety of activities to boost

revenues, from renting out facilities to partnering with local organizations. They now

have incentives to update both facilities and personnel to compete for clients and partners from the public and private sectors. Certain features of the organization of the party school system, e.g., the decentralization of funding and semi-autonomy over curriculum matters, produce the conditions for entrepreneurial activity and competition. All of this has generated greater variation in the breadth of school activities.

This study of the introduction of competition, or redundancy, to a particular bureaucratic task has produced mixed findings. As expected, competition has led to a general organizational search for activities that are most likely to increase the probability of survival, at a minimum, and profitable enterprise beyond that. When uncovering the actual range of activities pursued by organizations, however, the story takes on more twists and turns. Party schools, in accordance with the benevolent intentions and predictions that a proponent of bureaucratic redundancy would predict, invested in updating training content. On the other hand, schools have also become entrepreneurial actors in their own right and engaged in decidedly non-training activities. These investments, while seemingly “off mission,” are school responses to the financial

189 pressures (and opportunities) in a world of decentralized funding. It remains difficult to

tell which set of activities is now more central to party school survival. Whereas the

updating of training content accords with political imperatives, entrepreneurial ventures have the appeal of localized profit. Furthermore, in comparing the activities of party schools across regions with varying levels of economic development, the most salient variation appears to be across administrative levels rather than inter-regional. Schools at the city levels and above, across inland and more prosperous coastal provinces, exhibited a remarkable similarity in their embrace of market opportunities.

It is also noteworthy that processes of change affecting the party school system have been additive in nature. Reforms in cadre training have been characterized by layering on new organizations and actors rather than restructuring the management and selection of bureaucratic personnel that takes place in party schools. What has occurred

thus far has been a rethinking of the incentives driving organizational decisions, not

necessarily a wholesale renovation of the bulky apparatus that is cadre training in China.

Competition was introduced under the rationale that it would improve the innovativeness

and adaptive capacity of existing key players, namely, the party schools. This in turn

suggests the degree of institutional inertia that exists in the system and the difficulty in

building new institutions as opposed to modifying existing ones (Genschel 1997; Hannan

and Freeman 1984). More dramatic institutional change is nonetheless possible, however,

given the many possible consequences of creating a competitive bureaucratic structure.

But the “politics of institutional change” are such that significant modifications are often slow and hidden behind appeals to “restore tradition” or by gradual alterations to the dominant ideology (Clemens and Cook 1999: 459). What has been observed here has

190 been an enlargement of the organizational space within which a set of tasks is carried out.

The function of party schools within the party apparatus remains unchanged, though the

content of the political messages that these schools convey has changed with the times.

This case study of the party school system also speaks to a larger debate regarding

the depth and scope of party adaptation to the consequences of economic reforms.

Whereas some have framed the CCP as an increasingly cloistered organization without

the capacity to manage new social and economic pressures, this project supports the

opposite conclusion.238 A party-led focus on building “administrative civilization” (Pieke

2009: 121) is in full swing. This project has specified how the construction of an administrative civilization contains, beyond the ideological updating emphasized by existing scholarship, organizational responses to new economic incentives and the maintenance of the party’s institutions of elite selection.

The party has altered some core features of bureaucratic life under Mao, e.g., recruitment based on political credentials and mass campaigns, but this sea change has not led to a discernable decrease in the internal stability of the party-state. With the ascendance of the “second generation” of CCP leadership under Deng Xiaoping, the CCP has displayed a certain degree of ideological flexibility in favor of pragmatic governance.

Writing early in the reform period, Harding (1981) debated whether overtures to rationalize the bureaucracy were ephemeral or enduring. The verdict, based on the

238 See, for instance, Gordon Chang’s Coming Collapse of China (2001), which predicts that the CCP will not survive beyond this decade. Susan Shirk’s more recent and focused book on the insecurity of China’s leaders offers an analysis of both internal and external threats (Shirk 2006). In policy journals, Pei (2002) has noted that the CCP’s growing weakness lays in “the shrinkage of its organizational penetration, the erosion of its authority and appeal among the masses, and the breakdown of its internal discipline,” (p. 101). This dissertation provides evidence contrary to at least the latter two of these. Goldstone (1995) presents a neo-Malthusian argument, where population pressures, in combination with inadequate government capacity, will lead to significant political challenges to CCP rule. A discussion of the “pessimists” versus “optimists” on China’s political future can be found in Shambaugh (2009: Chapter 3).

191 evidence presented here, is in favor of the latter. The party school system, which has

long been an inner sanctum of ideological debate, illuminates the reach of efforts to

professionalize cadres and the pro-market form that party adaptation has taken. Whether

this marketization will extend to other areas of party management remains to be seen, and

the question also arises as to whether we might expect such a strategy carried out in other

authoritarian, single-party systems. The Chinese case, in which there has been party-led

marketization aimed at structures of the party itself, depends on necessary, but not

sufficient, pre-conditions such as a growth-oriented leadership that employed fiscal and

administrative incentives to effect a limited decentralization.

In brief, this study has explained how one enduring aspect of party management –

the functional role of a particular set of party organizations – persists alongside more

dynamic processes of internal adaptation. More simply put, the capacity for a

bureaucratic system to adapt to competitive pressures increases the likelihood that it will

continue to exist. In order to remain relevant in a new economic and social context, party

schools have adjusted to new market incentives by exhibiting such a capacity to adapt.

The processes underlying such organizational resilience are not immediately obvious when focusing solely on formal bureaucratic structure or elite politics. This has been a

story of organizational change in response to shifting policy winds. Understanding

changing incentives and adaptation within this set of party organizations demonstrates how seemingly anachronistic structures are able to persist and remain relevant in a market context. While decentralization has been an important part of the story, central

192 authorities have driven these processes of change. As with previous realignments of

institutional and individual incentives, central party authorities led the charge.239

One aspect of party resilience that I have revealed in this study is the tension between top-down, system-wide control and local school autonomy that exists within the party school system. While party schools would seem an ideal site for centralized dissemination of updated information on the party line and unifying beliefs throughout the system, field observations at schools from the provincial to county levels were at odds

with this unifying function. Central authorities have allowed local party schools to create their own training content and engage in independent, income-generating activities, and these have added diversity to the training content received by local bureaucrats. These organizational-level decisions indicate the tradeoff that central party leaders have made in demanding, on the one hand, that sub-national party organizations impart content that is consistent with central political goals but appropriate for local conditions while, on the other hand, reducing direct funding for such change. Rather than centralizing the financing of party schools and binding local party organizations more closely to central mandates, the approach has been to retain a decentralized – and more flexible – structure in the party school system. The party has opted to marshal market forces such as competition and entrepreneurship to achieve the desired outcome of training content that is locally relevant while still conveying central aspirations for China’s political and economic development. The risk to this set-up is some loss of central control over the end result in the localities. These choices, while risky, reflect a broader and significant

239 As noted in Chapter 4, these center-led and locally-grasped realignments have been studied in the context of the local state corporatism that characterized rural economic development, state entrepreneurialism within government ministries, and bureau-contracting in the public service units of the party and government.

193 party shift toward strategies that maintain the party’s wider relevance – and appeal – to diverse local audiences. Party authorities are now interested in building a party that represents and caters to the interests of a broad range of strategic segments of the population, which now includes those who generate economic prosperity at the local level.

Jiang Zemin, China’s third generation leader following on the heels of Deng

Xiaoping, emphasized that “whether a party and a state can develop excellent leaders to a large extent determines the survival of the party and the state.”240 It would appear that this is the core contribution of party schools and, more generally, institutions of cadre training to the maintenance of CCP rule. In using party schools as channels for the selection of bureaucrats – in effect, to control cadre careers – party authorities maintain the capacity to shape the bureaucratic class. At the same time, the party has loosened central control over these very same schools, releasing them to pursue market opportunities and self-determine strategies for market competitiveness. In light of these findings, I show how ruling parties are able to generate incentives for both institutional continuity and adaptation. A system of competition-based redundancy safeguards against system failure and generates the conditions for party entrepreneurialism. Significant changes are taking place within the party as institutional incentives are adjusted and reformed.

Zheng argues that “the CCP has become the major obstacle to state-building in post-1949 China” (Zheng 1997: 255). This study suggests otherwise. Party authorities have instead retained and reshaped organizational channels for selecting leaders of the party and government. Existing party organizations have also been reformed to promote

240 People’s Daily, 9 June 2002.

194 new bureaucratic priorities, namely the importance of professionalized, globally-minded

public managers. As the preceding examination of Central Party School training content

has shown, cadres passing through party school training programs receive strong signals

that professional managerial skills is now a key criterion for promotion.

2 Preconditions

The emergence of party schools’ entrepreneurialism has depended on several enabling conditions. The decentralization of fiscal and administrative responsibilities in the party school system, detailed in Chapter 4, paved the way for schools to engage in semi-independent activities for both pecuniary gain and to maintain party schools’ standing in a competitive training market. Beyond decentralization are other, more broad-based changes that, in combination, were necessary but not sufficient conditions for the changes observed. These critical phenomena include a growth-oriented leadership and normative reorientation in favor of market reform.

As a backdrop to this story of party adaptation, it was imperative that the Chinese leadership, particularly at the central level where key policy decisions originated, was growth-oriented. Barring this, incentives to invest in the organizational innovation observed in this study would be absent. If party authorities were instead focused more exclusively on fidelity to the ideological goals of the Mao period rather than broad-based economic growth, then there would not be the requirement that the party engineer a bureaucratic transformation to match new economic goals. The emphasis on party and government managers acquiring the professional skills to manage a particular set of economic priorities arose along with a longer term, growth-enhancing outlook on the part

195 of party leadership. The bandit of the state had become stationary and taken an

encompassing interest in development (Olson 1993). Furthermore, this change in outlook took the form of a commitment to shared growth, or growth that spilled beyond the

boundaries of the political elite. This more catholic dedication to general welfare was mirrored in other single-party regimes of East Asia, many of which have also sought to reform and professionalize their bureaucracies (Campos and Root 1996).

Crucially, China’s leaders were also inclined to pursue growth strategies through

pro-market reforms, which reflects a normative shift that has spilled beyond economic organization and into the managerial logic of the party. The protracted process culminating in the triumph of Deng’s reformist camp serves as some indication that there was no inevitability to the market path. The rise of markets and unleashing of consumption possibilities not possible under thirty years of Maoist rule paved the way for party schools to “dive into the sea” of market opportunity. These activities granted greater autonomy to local actors while potentially lightening some of the burden on local government finance bureaus. The normative shift that this entailed – along with changing expectations of bureaucratic competence – was critical for enlarging and shifting the boundaries of the universe of feasible reform strategies.

While the priorities of the political leadership mattered, timing was also key. The sequencing of reforms in the Chinese case and the decision to unbundle economic from political reforms, in contrast to the Soviet and Eastern European cases, had implications for the ability of the ruling party to control and respond to the unanticipated outcomes of economic reforms before they led to wholescale destabilization of the entire political and economic system. In this sense, I agree with Shirk’s (1993) analysis that a political logic

196 constrained but lent sufficient incentives for (possibly less efficient) economic reform

under CCP rule. Where my study departs from hers is in illuminating a different pathway

for policymaking. Policy outcomes may arise not only from elite, consensus-based

processes but rather through a more contentious, competition-driven process.

3 Risks

Marketization has led to reforms in the functioning – and priorities – of party

schools. What remains uncertain is whether the decision to introduce market

mechanisms might lead, inadvertently, to the unraveling of central party control over

cadre training. While the initiation of market processes hinged on central decisions, this has the potential to unleash a train of events that might prove difficult to restrain. In the reform period, there exist instances in which policy redirection has led to unanticipated outcomes and subsequent central retrenchment. In the early reform period, for example, the unleashing of local, collectively-owned enterprises led to explosive but unbridled

growth that central authorities sought to check through dramatic fiscal centralization

policies by the mid-1990s. This pattern has echoes in the political reforms shaping the

party school system. During the first decade of market reforms, schools expanded

rapidly their portfolios of non-training activities, particularly distance degree programs,

but central party authorities have recently attempted to rein in these practices while

leaving fundamentally intact initial pro-growth incentives. The decision to devolve authority to local party schools thus speaks to this enduring tension between central control and local interests.241 As with other policy areas, a balance has been struck. The

main risk to central authorities is whether the market, and its decentralizing tendencies,

241 See for instance the historical overview and thematic essays in Jia and Lin (1994).

197 will lead to an erosion of central party control over constituent parts. This might take place on at least two fronts. First, there is the risk that party schools will displace central goals in favor of their own, more local, interests. One implication is a reduction in local party school responsiveness to central directives, though existing controls may ensures some monitoring of local party school training content. Second, the partial nature of marketization entails some risk that party school failure would hinder processes of party personnel management, despite existing safeguards.

Choosing between profit and party service

Party schools are now striving to realize two distinct, though interrelated, goals.

First, as a link in the party’s transmission belt for sorting through cadres to promote to higher office, schools must provide information on these individuals’ potential as well as groom them for higher office. In carrying out this function, schools maintain a valued place within the party’s universe of core institutions. Second, schools must supplement this training work with additional ventures to remain financially viable. While these two goals are complementary and, in many cases, can be satisfied simultaneously, it is unclear

what schools will choose when presented with starker choices. Distance degree programs,

inside- and outside-the-plan training classes attract income and, to varying degrees, fulfill

schools’ training mandate. Renting property and starting side businesses are more clearly

in the service of income generation. Given limited resources, it is unclear whether

schools will exhibit an increasing tendency over time to maximize the financial goal at

the cost of the functional training goal. While schools must strive to fulfill both, the issue

is one of relative resource allocation. The market has introduced choice to party school

198 decision makers, but each choice entails an opportunity cost. Bound up in the decision

making process is a calculation of the benefits in meeting central goals versus local needs, and when these may be in conflict or agreement.

Under the Mao-era system of central transfers, the primary problem was one of

party schools shirking their duties as training institutions. Introducing competition may

have solved that problem to some degree, as schools are clearly updating their training

content in response to market incentives, but another problem has arisen in its place.

Market opportunities present more immediate rewards to school leaders. Gaps in the

monitoring capability of the state increase the attractiveness of diverting energy to more

lucrative options. School staffs may choose to comply minimally with the less profitable,

but more collectively important, goal (selection and training) and divert resources toward

activities that serve the more locally beneficial goal (entrepreneurial ventures). Even for

tasks where schools are most inclined to fulfill the goals of central and higher level

authorities, such as the implementation of planned training courses, they now have

incentives to curtail the allocation of resources to these activities in favor of pursuing

their own entrepreneurial endeavors. The result is the displacement of one goal in favor

of another. While there are monitoring mechanisms in place to keep the range of party

school activity within certain bounds, the localization of financial support eliminated

vertical ties linking center to locality.

Heightened tension between local organizational interests and broader party goals is one outcome of the loosening of central controls over the party school system. This tension will continue to exist so long as party schools possess some discretion over local organizational decisions. Whether this discretion can be taken away in a recentralization

199 effort, however, remains an open question. While it is difficult to envision party authorities closing the doors to the training market that they have now opened to such a broad array of actors, this does remain one possibility, however remote. As long as local party schools are minimally compliant with central goals, however, the two goals of center and locality will both continue to drive, to varying degrees, party schools’ organizational choices.

Local embeddedness eroding central mandates

While some compromise between central and local goals may take place as party school leaders decide how to allocate resources across party-mandated training programs versus other revenue-raising activities, this calculus is affected by the nature of schools’ revenue sources. As a result of the partial marketization of cadre training, party schools are now in direct contact with a greater variety of constituents, which represent a broader swathe of the population, and these constituents have, to varying degrees, an interest in school survival. The party now has a stronger street-level presence. This presence, furthermore, is more subtle than the imposition of democratically-elected grassroots councils. Party schools are deeply embedded within the party apparatus, but they are simultaneously building a locally relevant presence in response to competitive pressures.

This broadening of the party’s support base reflects a shift toward “inclusion”, whereby

“a ruling Leninist party’s perception that the major condition for its continued development as an institutionalized charismatic organization is to integrate itself with, rather than insulate itself from, its host society,” (Jowitt 1975: 72).

200 Post-Mao changes to the party school system have reverberated beyond the party, to communities in which party schools are located. The entrepreneurial spirit taking hold of party schools now generates incentives for localities to support party school development. Schools are no longer closed bastions of party learning, where only party members are permitted entry. Instead, school leaders are actively pursuing collaborations with all manner of local partners. Beyond their conventional audience of cadre trainees, party schools are now serving a more general audience. Everyday citizens have incentives to see party schools strengthen and grow within their local economies. The benefits to the party of a competitive training market parallel the benefits to local consumers of increased competition in the provision of local services and products. One advantage to the particular development of party school ventures is more general public support for the expansion of these party organizations and, by extension, the continued presence of the party as a local economic actor.

From this perspective, party schools are no longer mysterious party organizations set apart from the fabric of local economies. Schools are now embedded in these economies and providers of valuable services. They now have an interest in local development. No longer can schools rely on a steady stream of income from cadre- students assigned to periodic training courses. The demands of local groups and local consumers now drive to some degree the activity of local party schools. In this emerging dynamic, party schools are more accountable to and mutually dependent upon local non- party actors. There exists, in this arrangement, the potential that schools will be captured by local interests, particularly if schools are increasingly dependent on locally-derived income to bridge the gap between government transfers and operating expenses.

201 This local embeddedness may tip the scales in favor of local interests, at the risk

of eclipsing the mandates of central authorities. With the changes prompted by marketization – and the beguiling income-earning opportunities therein – party schools now have added incentives to settle central-local tensions in favor of the local. School leaders possess the means to be more responsive to local demands and circumstances, given the autonomy generated by decentralization and marketization. Taking this logic to its extreme, there is the risk that income generation through local entrepreneurial ventures displaces the original purpose of party schools as core sites of cadre training. And if this were the case, there exists the risk of central authorities losing control over the activities and goals of party schools. Studies of organizational behavior and examinations of central-local bureaucratic relations in the U.S., for example, have found that the more dependent a local public agency on the local environment for resources, the greater the relative importance of local influences on that agency’s decision-making (Pfeffer and

Salancik 1978; Scholz, Twombly, and Headrick 1991; Whitford 2002). One prescription for coping with this potential agency capture by local interests is through stronger

institutions of accountability within the party or between the party and the public, but at

present reform efforts remain weak (Bardhan 2009).

The risk of failure

Exposing party schools to market forces has created winners and losers.

Marketization, by definition, implies a process whereby actors become entrepreneurial

and are subjected to risks (Hebert and Link 1988). While some schools, through a combination of leadership, local economic conditions, and strategic partnerships, have

202 prospered in the training market, others have become hollow institutions. This is not

necessarily a surprising outcome, as agency failure is a recurrent theme in democratic

settings (Lewis 2002). In the Chinese case, significant reorganization of government

ministries has occurred periodically in the post-Mao period and entailed the eradication

of entire ministries.242 If party schools were to fail not by decree but through their own inability to compete, the question arises as to whether party authorities are prepared for

other institutions to fulfill party schools’ role in elite selection. While this is the intention

behind the creation of a redundant system, an assessment of actual conditions and

potential outcomes reveals some departure from theory.

One key motivation for introducing redundancy to a bureaucracy is to safeguard

against a functional vacuum should one component of the system fail. Competition in this context presents a form of reserve capacity. The training market abounds with

substitutes for party schools, but all of these are partial replacements. Other party

organizations, such as cadre leadership academies, may step into the space left by

uncompetitive party schools. This, however, raises an additional design flaw in the

emerging competition for cadre training contracts. The rise of organization department-

managed training academies, in combination with the powerful position already held by

organization departments in personnel matters, has the potential to concentrate further,

rather than diffuse, control over personnel management. This creates a further risk:

organization departments might become an even larger player in party management and

repeat, though on an even bigger scale, the descent into stagnation feared so much by

242 Prominent recent examples include the 1997 dismantling of 11 ministries and creation of high-level economic planning commissions and the 2003 merging of commissions and subsequent creation of a single economic planning and development entity. In personnel management, 2008 saw the creation of a “super- ministry” of human resources and social security, which replaced three state bureaus.

203 party authorities at the outset of the cadre training marketization project. In addition to organization departments’ control over hiring, promotion, and dismissal of cadres, the addition of control over training would consolidate personnel management and seem to be at cross purposes with the original intent of the reforms.

Another possibility is the substitution of universities for party schools. In the credentialing wave that has washed over China’s political elite, it would seem that universities are well-positioned to become channels for elite selection. Universities are sites for the recruitment of party members, and it may be a natural progression for university credentials to replace party school training certificates. The appeal of universities is further complemented by the Deng-era initiative to professionalize the cadre class. Secular public administration and management programs are poised to contribute to this trend. The risk this entails to the party, however, is a loss of control over the political content that it still considers a critical part of the cadre training process.

That cadre training has this homogenizing effect, namely, imparting expertise to those lacking in professional skills and enhancing the “socialist virtues” of technical experts cannot be dismissed (Pieke 2009a: 142).

Among these two possible substitutes, then, there is the risk of greater concentration on the one hand and too great a loss of political control on the other.

Obtaining data on the characteristics of trainees at organization department academies

and university management schools, if available, could speak to this issue. However,

data unavailability and the relatively recent entry of cadre leadership academies prevents

the assessment of longer term trends. Even without comparative data on these

alternatives, the party school system at present remains the most comprehensive, unified

204 system for cadre training. As such, it is positioned to continue serving as an institution of party elite selection. Creating an alternate system with the breadth of party schools would be a resource-intensive undertaking. This would be further complicated by the difficulties in uprooting an entrenched bureaucracy within the party bureaucracy, one vested with symbolic importance and a reminder of the ideological underpinnings of CCP rule.

For at least two reasons, it appears that odds are in favor of the party school system’s survival. First, marketization has been partial. Local party committees continue to be responsible for the allocation, each year, of a portion of the total training classes organized in a locale. I have not yet encountered the case of a party school receiving no inside-the-plan training contracts. This is further buttressed by the center’s prerogative to allocate training contracts to party schools in general. The implementation of a one-time, five-year county magistrate training program at the central party school and cadre executive academies is one illustration of this. This was also the case in the centrally- mandated rollout of 17th party congress study sessions throughout the party school system.

Central control and interference provides a hedge against the possibility that party schools will fade away in the presence of more well-endowed and globally-connected

competitors. That the center retains this coercive capacity further supports the argument

that redundancy in this Chinese context is primarily about adaptation and secondarily

about reliability.

Yet the past is not necessarily a predictor of the future in determining whether

party schools will continue to reinvent themselves or give way to the competitive

substitutes already chipping away at party school market share. During the first three

205 decades of reform, party school leaders have managed, on balance, to weather through one organizational challenge after another. On one end of the spectrum are universities with their global connections and professional management schools, and on the other end are the organization department academies which may be equally, if not more, privy to the inner sanctums of party power. Universities may rate the highest in terms of providing the quality education that the party, and society more generally, desires on the march toward modernity, but they are without the political substance to be found in those training organizations embedded within the party itself. This presents a conundrum which, for the time being, political authorities have been able to skirt.

I stress that the marketization of party schools is a dynamic process, one that in theory must maintain some stability in process and function in order to remain effective.

At the same time, this stability might be derailed by the very competition which has now become a driver of organizational adaptation. Competition, and the adaptation it promotes, requires multiple players, and the system is, counterintuitively, stable so long as there are multiple actors who eventually reach a division of labor, a division of the market, or some other “steady state” in which interference from central authorities are minimal. Should the system exhibit a tendency toward monopoly, then the benefits derived from competition decrease accordingly. In comparative case studies of redundant and nonredundant urban public transit systems in the US, for example, Bendor found stable arrangements so long as political authorities did not demand an end to the competition and organizational diversity was allowed to persist (Bendor 1985: 238-241).

206 4 Limits to party reforms

While opening up party schools to markets and competition may generate changes

in training content and embed party organizations in local economies, there are

significant limitations to the reach of these reforms. The marketization of party schools

does not create the mechanisms for coping with a particularly thorny aspect of institutional design in China – the absence of strong bureaucratic accountability. By

accountability, I am referring to the mechanisms in place to ensure that the behavior of

organizations and individuals may be constrained and checked by the public and/or other

governmental bodies.243 While party schools are now punished if they fail to tailor

training content to market and party demands, this checks the performance of schools and

not the behavior of cadres themselves. In this sense, this study does not speak to the

ability of party authorities to reduce the bureaucratic corruption which is drawing both

domestic and international ire and which, as Lu Xiaobo argues, may be bound up in the

historical evolution and organization of the CCP itself (Lu 2000; Pei 2008; Wedeman

2004). While it remains an open question as to whether the CCP’s efforts to curb

corruption are to any measurable extent successful, it is noteworthy that China is now in

the “middle of the pack” on international corruption indices (Wedeman 2010).

Corruption may thus be a “growing pain” that the ruling party must confront in its rapid

developmental trajectory rather than a “crippling disease” (Ibid., p. 118).

Subjecting party schools to competition sends a signal that schools must

strengthen their contribution to the particular dimension of the state-building project

243 Rather than focus on the vertical and horizontal forms of accountability that are the conventional focus of research on democracies, Dimitrov (2010) theorizes that another dimension to accountability exists in the Chinese case: “proxy” accountability between citizens, local officials, and the central government, whereby the center punishes local officials who are unresponsive to citizen complaints.

207 within their domain. This is not the same as requiring schools to complement, in some

fashion, the still weak monitoring organizations of the party-state. In theory, party schools could contribute to the monitoring of cadre behavior, constituting a form of horizontal accountability within the party. This does happen to some degree in the monitoring of cadre behavior (biaoxian) during training classes, but such monitoring has

little bearing on the range of activities that fall under official corruption. In terms of

vertical accountability, the marketization of the party school system detailed in this

project does not necessarily have any effect on the accountability of either these party

organizations or bureaucrats to a broader public. Marketization is instead about

improving the efficiency of cadre training itself, which has as one goal the creation of a

more competent bureaucratic class, broadly defined. Innovations in training do not

generate the incentives for political elites to refrain from seeking personal gain at the

expense of general welfare. A much denser network of administrative measures must be in place for cadre training to contribute to the more normative goal of an accountable, self-regulating bureaucracy. At present, this is lacking in the party and government apparatus. This project is thus silent with respect to whether party entrepreneurialism can address a more encompassing vision of sound governance.

A separate but related issue is the problem of individuals completely bypassing legal, organized routes for obtaining office. Official selection processes are not the only path to high office in China. One worrying phenomenon is the sale and purchase of public office. There have been some public disclosures of such occurrences in the

Chinese media, but the true extent of this practice is unknown.244 While party schools do

244 Newspaper reports of this practice have detailed, for example, the sale in 2006 of eight leading cadre offices (three at the city-level (tingji) and five at the department level (chuji)) in Hunan and 110 county-

208 appear to play a role in cadres’ career advancement, it is beyond the scope of this study to

determine the relative reach of less formal routes for obtaining office. That there exist

these extra-organizational channels for obtaining office erodes the party’s

institutionalization efforts and presents a serious threat to organizational integrity.

Third and finally, this study is limited to unraveling the development and

consequences of competitive pressures in the Chinese bureaucracy, and it does not

address more evaluative questions regarding the efficiency of such redundancy.

Importing market principles to bureaucratic functions may introduce an internal

opportunity cost in that the efficiency gains from competition may still be less than the

loss associated with devoting resources to similar (or redundant) tasks. Instead, resources

could be applied more broadly to different bureaucratic functions. This critique, however,

presumes the ability to measure these costs and benefits when in fact they may be

difficult to compare either quantitatively or qualitatively. Perhaps this concern is also

less relevant in an authoritarian context where there exist no institutionalized channels for

outside parties to express dissatisfaction with organizational decisions or obtain

information on resource allocation. Even more, this overlooks the dual motivations for

introducing competition. In addition to efficiency considerations, there is the relative

importance of devising strong(er) incentives for the organizational innovation that

supports adaptive practices. In the end, efficiency considerations are difficult to evaluate

level offices in Anhui. See “Loudi city, Hunan, party standing committee’s Xie Wensheng is arrested for selling office,” 21st Century Business Herald, 22 Apr 2008, and “Anhui county party secretary receives largest bribe amount from selling office,” China Youth Daily, 10 Dec 2007. In response to this practice, the Central Commission for Discipline and Inspection has warned that selling and buying office will result in dismissal, Xinhua, 20 Oct 2008, http://news.sina.com.cn/c/2008-10-20/182816489732.shtml, accessed 22 Feb 2010.

209 and it is doubtful that a comparison of the party school system before and after market

reforms, notwithstanding data limitations, is unlikely to yield a clear verdict on this issue.

5 Whither the party?

Finally, we turn to questions of the party’s evolution and continuing relevance in

the post-Mao period. Uncovering recent developments in cadre training is significant for

understanding several broader transformations in the priorities and outlook of CCP

leaders. State-building goals have evolved from the Maoist focus on creating a utopian,

collectivist system in which the party enjoyed a monopoly over all material production

and social mobility. That totalitarian vision of the party-state has given way to one where

the uneven withdrawal of the state from social and economic realms is granted in

exchange for the party’s unrivaled political hegemony. In formulating and pursuing this

new developmental path, the CCP is now committed to an experimentation-based

approach in which local inequalities are tolerated as a byproduct of the tide of prosperity

that will eventually lift all boats.

In this policy context, local party organs now have strong incentives to be drivers

of change, derive benefits from market opportunities, and open up to new influences.

The boundaries around these local activities are drawn at the point where they do not undermine in any overt way the legitimacy of the ruling party. These organization-level changes show how the party is acting upon its resolution to become a “learning party”.245

245 Documents issued during the 16th Party Congress (in 2002) reflect the party leadership’s focus on becoming a “learning party” (xuexi xing zhengdang) and grasping new global and national trends. See “Resolution on the Strengthening of the Establishment of the Party’s Ruling Capacity,” available online at http://www.people.com.cn/GB/40531/40746/2994977.html, accessed 13 September 2009. This initiative has spilled into the work of the 17th Party Congress. See, for example, the official interpretation, dated 17 November 2009, of the decision passed down at the Fourth Plenary Session of the Seventeenth Party Congress on “How to Build a Learning Party,” available at http://www.gov.cn/jrzg/2009-

210 In an assessment of the party’s trajectory over time, party authorities and scholars have presented “two transformations” as the catchphrase to describe the party’s transformation.

The first shift entailed the CCP transforming from a revolutionary to a ruling party. More recently, it has morphed from a party directing the planned economy to a party leading the processes of reform and opening up. This latter transformation has entailed a capacity to manage the complexities of a market economy (Shi 2006: 92-93). In order to carry out this second transformation, Chinese leaders have chosen to position the party as open and willing to learn from different models of public management.

Understanding party adaptation, then, calls for understanding the institutional means by which the party learns. Party authorities have invested strategically in building adaptive capacity. The emphasis on cadre training reflects this new (self-given) identity that the party seeks to embody and the concrete objectives that accompany it. Not only is this “learning party” rhetoric evident in speeches by high leaders such as Hu Jintao, but

CCP investment in cadre training reflects a real commitment of resources. It is within the bureaucratic class that the learning capacity of the party becomes manifest in policy decisions and implementation on the ground. That party-led bureaucratic modernization falls under the general category of activities that a learning party engages in will only buttress party control over the reinvention of the Chinese state.

11/17/content_1466399.htm, accessed 12 February 2010. This document lays out general directions such as “first, turning study into a political responsibility” and “second, integrating the study of party theory, professional skills, and all types of new knowledge”. This is related to an earlier interpretation in which “reform and innovation” (gaige chuangxin) were the watchwords. See also the related interpretation, dated 1 November 2009, of the decision passed down at the Fourth Plenary Session of the Seventeenth Party Congress on “Party building must persist in reform and innovation,” available at http://www.gov.cn/jrzg/2009-11/01/content_1453837.htm, accessed 12 February 2010. One academic book, published in China, which elaborates upon the priorities of this “learning party” is Xie Chunhong’s Research on Contemporary CCP’s Building of a Learning Party-State (2009), which argues that “not to study is to retreat or die” (bu xue z etui, bu xue ze wang).

211 Second, the record of cadre training over the past three decades reveals how the party is seeking new pathways for building the administrative capacity to manage a new

market-based economic and social reality. Above all, the CCP has had to adjust its

coping strategies to accommodate the uncertainties, pressures, and incentives of the

market. The party’s fate is now inextricably linked to the market. Marketizing cadre

training is a means to shore up the legitimacy of the CCP to diverse audiences, from the

cadre ranks to the communities where party schools are located. At the same time,

bringing market principles into party organization is part of the long, uneven reform

process of legitimizing market practices.

Accordingly, cadres must not only partake in all the rituals of party-building and

study the theoretical underpinnings of socialism with Chinese characteristics, but they

should be exposed to developmental models near and far. Case studies in governance

and lessons on the model economic projects throughout China all reflect the party’s

attempts to build a “managerial class” (Burnham 1962) more befitting China’s current

circumstances, where decollectivization, SOE restructuring, national markets and global

integration are the new imperatives of the day.246 Investing in administrative capacity is

one way to forestall the dangers of stretching scarce administrative talent too thinly over many reform fronts (Rawski 1994: 274-5). The state administrative capacity that is under

construction, however, is not necessarily one that will seep evenly throughout the

political system. As this study has indicated, marketization, while generating strong

pressures and incentives, lacks the tidiness of a more centralized effort to engage in state

246 This transformation was observed by Brzezinski in the late 1980s, who wrote that the CCP is “becoming less characteristic of a revolutionary party claiming to be the representative of the dictatorship of the proletariat and more that of a modernizing party of the dictatorship of China’s emerging state-sponsored commercial class,” (Brzezinski 1989: 147).

212 capacity building. The very lowest levels of administration may not share in the fruits of these efforts, indicating limits to the scope of the overall project.

As part of these shifts in identity and capacity, party authorities have striven to avoid the mistakes of other single-party regimes and also learn from domestic policy stumbles. While there have not been pronouncements as precise as the CCP’s decision that Mao was incorrect 30 percent of the time (Spence 1999: 643), a pattern of openness and retrenchment (fang/shou) has characterized the experimental, at times tentative nature of the post-Mao reforms (Baum 1996: Chapter 1). Looking abroad, CCP scholars and policymakers have noted the inability of the CPSU to combat deep economic stagnation, contain centrifugal nationalisms, rein in rent-seeking bureaucrats, and resolve myriad other domestic and international quandaries. Within the CCP, the most direct avenue for prompting awareness and discussion of these issues in an organized yet flexible way was through tried-and-true channels for allowing decision makers to discuss, analyze, reflect, and ultimately apply key lessons. The party school system was and is one such channel. The newest development in the party’s organizational evolution is that there is now greater choice, beyond party schools, where this learning may be staged. In short, this study accords with Shambaugh’s characterization of the current CCP as a party that is adapting rather than withering away.

This study of CCP-led reforms also refines those arguments in the comparative literature that seek to explain the resilience of the CCP in comparison to the unraveling of communist party rule elsewhere. Solnick (1996; 1998) rightly points out that reforms in

China generated incentives for local actors to remain loyal to a CCP-ruled system, but his focus on the monitoring capabilities of the party-state apparatus overlooks the crucial role

213 that the selection and training of bureaucrats played in the Chinese case. While

complementary to monitoring, selection is a prior concern. Furthermore, Solnick credits

the CCP’s avoidance of internal restructuring as a factor for regime stability, but I would

suggest that the introduction of market-based competition has been the driver of

significant changes which ultimately support the construction of an enduring party-state.

Counter intuitively, this resilience is a consequence of deliberate organizational fragmentation rather than center-led consolidation. Whereas the foundations of stability under the ancien regime of the USSR and satellite states of the Eastern Bloc were in the

party’s control over political, economic, and social resources, ironically the stability

achieved in one key aspect of party organization in China has been through a deliberate

relaxation of the party’s monopoly. In this particular realm, the party has moved beyond

a reflexive opacity and embraced, cautiously, a limited market-driven openness.

In other respects, pressures for institutional change in China are similar to elite

recruitment in the CPSU under Brezhnev’s leadership. In a study of elite selection and

socialization during this period, Klugman (1989) identifies pressures for new selection

criteria: “Somewhat more autonomy will be required to function efficiently in a more

loosely connected system, while increased discipline will require a more internalized

form of self-control” (p. 13). Comparable changes are taking place in reform-era China,

where higher level authorities use cadre training to instill and observe the “internalized

controls” which assist higher levels in coping with the increasing autonomy enjoyed by

sub-national bureaucrats.

These considerations of trends in CCP rule speak to broader issues in comparative

studies of authoritarian party resilience and breakdown. Rather than focus on the array of

214 internal party factions and cleavages that may affect party cohesion, this study has dwelled on organization-level determinants.247 Organizational characteristics, in particular the amount of competition and flexibility built into a bureaucracy, explain overall bureaucratic performance to a greater degree than individual-level characteristics such as values and norms (Punyaratabandhu-Bhakdi 1983). Organizational strengthening in which flexibility is built in to facilitate the dissemination and support of broad developmental goals moves the system away from breakdown. While a complete theory of regime survival must focus on both elites and organizations as drivers of political stability or instability, this study has focused on those observable structures of party organization, as they relate to elite management, rather than attempt to penetrate the more opaque realm of individual and collective preferences.

That the CCP remains the key political actor in the PRC today begs the bigger question, how has the party remained in command? Pieke points to the pursuit of a “neo- socialist” project within the party. This bundle of concepts and real policy priorities features a strong bureaucratic apparatus, continued market creation, and, above all, the maintenance of single party rule. This present study takes the latter factor in the neo- socialist project, maintenance of single party rule, as the starting point for central decision making in China. In this sense, a “political logic” (Shirk 1993) trumps the economic or social. That this political logic has led to the marketization – and rejuvenation – of Leninist party organizations rather than their quiet expiration attests to the resilience of the party’s political project more generally. At the same time, I note that

247 The presence of or potential for elite disunity is presented as negatively correlated with regime strength, though studies in this tradition do not offer an analytical framework for knowing ex ante when a given split might prove serious for regime survival or be symptom of factional politics as usual. See, for example, O’Donnell and Schmitter (1986) on hardliner versus softliner splits and, on elite divisions in Chinese politics, Nathan (1973) on factions and Tang (1976) on informal groups.

215 transformations in party outlook are attempts – that outcomes are far from determined.

The adoption of a “learning party” identity is as yet in its early stages and incomplete, the

building of market-embracing party-state structures is progressing in the now-familiar

manner of crossing a river of uncertain waters.

In some respects, the substantive changes that have taken place in the party school

system reflect the broader shift from a “plan ideological” system toward a “plan rational”

mode of organization, though one that remains fundamentally political rather than

economic in orientation (Johnson 1982: 18-24). In China, the transformation to a “plan

rational” system remains incomplete. As this case study of the party school system

reveals, shifts in the incentive structures driving organizational behavior within the party

now reflect to a greater degree the intention to meet particular developmental goals rather than the setting of plans and goals as ends in themselves. However, party authorities retain the prerogative to tighten or relax their control over local organizations as they see

fit. Overarching political goals, as envisioned through an increasingly “plan rational”

lens, are several: maintaining the primacy of party control over bureaucratic selection,

creating an updated administrative and political elite. Because the emphasis is on the

overall effectiveness of party rule, rather than efficiency, developments may be rescinded

at any time.

6 Limitations and new directions

The initial spark for this project was a narrow question on the current state of

party organization. Over the course of exploring the fate of party schools, the

marketization of cadre training, and resultant party entrepreneurialism, many questions

216 remain unanswered and beg further investigation. It would also be remiss not to report shortfalls in this present study, though, on an optimistic note, some of these limitations may transform into new research projects.

Nonrandom site selection

As detailed in Appendix B, the site selection process for my field visits and interviews was nonrandom. This reflects the realities and limits of in-depth field work as a research strategy in China. Due to the sensitivity of this research topic, I relied on local academic partners to introduce me to colleagues in party schools at various locales, and from these networks I was able to gain entry to the world of cadre training. I hope future studies might improve upon this rather idiosyncratic field research plan, but until there is reliable and open access to party organizations in China, I will report my findings with these caveats.

One saving grace may be to compare findings across studies. For example, the more economically-advanced regions discussed in this study may complement findings from research conducted in poorer areas (e.g., Yunnan province in Pieke 2009). I have sought, whenever possible, to corroborate the findings from one site or assertions made in interviews with comparable information obtained at other sites or in public documents.

This verification has, however, been most difficult with respect to financial information revealed during interviews.

Leading factions and inter-bureaucratic politics

The marketization of cadre training and its effect on the party school system has been to some degree a story of how sub-party organizations have confronted the

217 challenges and opportunities that arose out of their shifting political and economic context. There remains a question as to the extent that inter-agency rivalries, specifically

between the party school system and the party’s organization department, drove the

decision to bring competition to the party school system. It is uncertain, for example,

how powerful a voice the CPS leadership has had within the most inner circles of party

authority, how this has changed over time, and whether this has varied with the particular

groups that have dominated successive administrations. The present study has drawn

heavily on official documents and sub-national interviews to piece together the story of

party school reform and adaptation. A fuller telling of this story would include the tracing

of the relationship between these two party agencies over time, the specific central

leaders involved, the transfer of personnel between these two bureaucracies, and an

assessment of the relative rise and fall of each bureaucratic system (xitong).

Local party school content analysis

Examination of changes in party school training content is limited to materials

collected from the Central Party School. I have attempted to draw on trends across some

local party school training syllabi and information provided by interviewees. However,

gathering documents older than two years, much less five or even twenty years, from

local schools has proven daunting. As such, this study has not systematically tracked,

over time, how local schools may have diverged from or mimicked central content.

Demand side of training

This study has focused on the suppliers of cadre training, and less consideration has been given to the demand side of the training market. In interviews, there have been

218 hints that cadre training is becoming increasingly consumer-oriented. The most

progressive schools in model economic regions such as Shenzhen and Zhejiang are all

experimenting with training models where the preferences of cadre-students are taken seriously. Interviewees at schools in both coastal and inland provinces A and B also

noted that shifts in the content of training classes were a response to cadre input.

However, cadre trainees are not the only consumers with the power to drive new

directions in training content. As local governments and party organs issue public calls

for training proposals and widen their searches to international providers, they will also

push training format and content in new directions. This study has not probed the process

by which local party organs and state ministries, as consumers of training content, set

their own particular training goals, choose from a menu of possible providers, and how

higher level authorities may influence that process. While it may be the case that the

center is the player with the most influence over the general tendencies in cadre training,

this may vary at different administrative levels in the system and across functional areas of the bureaucracy.

Corporate culture and ideology

Further research is necessary to uncover the implications of party marketization for the corporate culture that shapes elite decision making in China.248 Pursuing this

avenue of research would require delving into individual-level beliefs and perceptions

that are beyond the scope of this study. Insofar as party organizations are governed by

and contribute to the perpetuation of a particular corporate culture, it would appear that marketization has the potential to undermine unification efforts. The new emphasis on

248 Kreps (1990) defines “corporate culture” as those principles that guide an organization’s actions, including the conveyance of those principles throughout a hierarchical system.

219 the professionalization of cadres and the waning of campaigns as tools of political control

would also seem to chip away at the strong corporate ties which bind together and unify

the ruling elite. Ironically, a clearly defined corporate culture is particularly salient during China’s reform period because it establishes the standards for action in times of uncertainty (Kreps 1990).

It is impossible to investigate the persistence and continued relevance of an elite corporate culture in contemporary China without also probing the fate of one of the reform era’s most significant casualties – orthodox Marxism-Leninism and Maoist ideology. But what of ideology more generally as “a verbal image of the good society and of the chief means of constructing such a society”?249 What place does ideology

have among political elites, in the party – and hence China – today? How do party authorities determine who the believers are, and what beliefs are truly sacred? These are only a few of the questions which might motivate an investigation into this labyrinth of related issues. One starting point might lay in the assertion that ideology, as a “shared mental model” improves group cohesion (Denzau and North 1994), but might this shared model be distorted beyond recognition after constant reshaping and retooling in its march through disparate locales? In the Mao period, the party school monopoly on cadre training, in tandem with intense political campaigns, maintained the cohesiveness of

China’s political elite and socialized cadres to the changing practices and vocabulary of

party leadership. Additional fieldwork and even survey-based research can unravel how

these various forces – elite socialization, the maintenance of a party corporate culture,

and the dissemination of a guiding ideology – have fared in a marketized context.

249 See Downs (1957), p. 96.

220 Areas for comparative study

It is unclear how far the logic of market-based competition and party entrepreneurialism has spread within the party bureaucracy, though its implications in terms of organizational adaptation have bearing for virtually all aspects of party rule. At its broadest, competitive redundancies could improve the state’s capacity for skillful and effective policymaking. While most studies of redundancy have been limited to democratic systems, there is no theoretical reason barring observation of the principle in authoritarian contexts. Furthermore, if redundancy is a means to reinforce the overall survivability of a system, then Chinese party authorities should apply it liberally and even more readily in those areas deemed most critical to the party’s continued existence.

Some promising work has begun to emerge that supports this logic. Scholars have begun to probe the processes and consequences of marketization in other party xitong, notably the propaganda apparatus. Shirk (2007) considers the implications of the party’s introduction of commercial incentives to media outlets, and others have argued that content is still manipulated to maintain popular support for the CCP’s leadership

(Stockmann and Gallagher 2009). Other potential areas of research include effect of competition on policymaking processes in environmental protection, the military, and public goods provision more generally. Whether market forces have a subversive effect or reinforce the regime’s legitimacy in what were once the most inner realms of the party promises a more encompassing understanding of the reality that moderates and informs theoretical possibilities.

221 In closing, I return to the underlying logic of organizational change observed

within the party itself. There exists a tension between the party’s loosening of

organizational controls in order to maintain a firm grip on the political elite that guide

Chinese state and society. Counter intuitively, central party authorities have reinforced

control over political elites by introducing competition and market forces to inner party organizations. This study has shown how, within the party, there are now greater “realms of freedom” (Oi 2004). It has also highlighted the party’s inner struggle to balance the various centrifugal forces that have arisen out of the protracted transition to a market economy. One critical development has been an increase in the autonomy of local bureaucratic agents of the party-state. Local experimentation and innovation are one positive outcome in the trade-off between central direction and local autonomy. While the center has continued to dictate general policy goals, the means for achieving these have been left to local agents that must now search more aggressively for viable solutions

or else lose ground to rivals. Limited decentralization and increases in the diversity of

local activities as well as the number of market players implies that the party is serious

about fostering the conditions for adaptive change. Party entrepreneurialism presents

further variation on the “local experiment to national policy” theme that has driven so

much change in modern China (Heilmann 2008: 25). It also presents a new twist on this

framework in that there is not necessarily the intention to unify local agents after a period

of experimentation. Diversity may be here to stay. The variation in organization and

training content observed across the party school system may be the intended outcome

rather than national unification.

222 Appendix A: Number of party schools, by locale and national share of leading cadres

Share of total Share of total Percent of total Number of leading cadres in leading cadres in Administrative Unit party schools Party Schools the country, 1985 the country, 1998 in the country (percent) (percent)

Beijing 55 2.00 3.05 3.15 Tianjin 31 1.13 2.85 2.51 Hebei 156 5.67 4.88 4.47 Shanxi 117 4.25 3.95 2.98 Inner Mongolia 90 3.27 3.05 2.43 Liaoning 134 4.87 4.10 6.91 Jilin 77 2.80 3.19 3.35 Heilongjiang 147 5.34 4.95 4.43 Shanghai 77 2.80 2.90 2.97 Jiangsu 84 3.05 3.34 4.03 Zhejiang 94 3.41 2.11 3.38 Anhui 82 2.98 3.67 3.08 Fujian 54 1.96 2.17 2.69 Jiangxi 90 3.27 2.65 2.41 Shandong 126 4.58 3.94 6.49 Henan 137 4.98 4.55 4.04 Hubei 131 4.76 5.04 4.89 Hunan 124 4.50 4.81 4.30 Guangdong 127 4.61 3.85 5.54 Guangxi 95 3.45 3.91 3.10 Sichuan 233 8.46 5.64 6.05 Guizhou 74 2.69 2.48 2.15 Yunnan 121 4.40 3.00 2.99 Tibet 8 0.29 1.47 0.93 Shaanxi 95 3.45 4.11 3.52 Gansu 84 3.05 2.80 2.41 Qinghai 40 1.45 1.14 1.15 Ningxia 14 0.51 1.05 0.97 Xinjiang 56 2.03 5.35 2.69 Total 2753 100.00 100.00 100.00 Sources: COD 1999; 1985 DXNJ, numbers include provincial, municipal/prefectural, county, and central ministry party schools.

223 Appendix B: Note on sources and research methods

This dissertation draws on three major data sources: interviews, documentary sources, and survey data. Over the course of 13 months of fieldwork in China from 2006 to 2008, I conducted 236 interviews with party and state officials on the topic of cadre training. To understand organizational change at various administrative levels and across locales with very different economies, interviews were focused in Beijing (central government), a coastal Province A, an inland Province B, and a Special Economic Zone

(SEZ). Interview sites included party schools, administrative institutes, socialism institutes, Communist Youth League schools, universities, and party and government organs from the central to township administrative levels. Basic demographic information about interviewees is summarized in the tables below. To protect the identity of Chinese interviewees, I have cited interviews by interview number and year. Some contacts agreed to be interviewed more than once to answer follow-up questions. When appropriate, I have also noted the occupation or station of the interviewee. To compare across sub-provincial localities, I strove to conduct interviews at the provincial capitals of

Provinces A and B and at least one city-level jurisdiction and at least one county-level jurisdiction in each province.

During the early stages of this project, I conducted preliminary research at sites in two coastal and two inland provinces. These initial visits were intended to assess the quality of access to schools and officials. I ultimately focused on two provinces, one from each region, and the decision was driven by practical data collection considerations.

There is, however, some basis for the selection of the two provinces which are the subject of case studies in Chapters 4 and 5. Both provinces are average with respect to the sizes

224 of their general and leading cadre populations (Figures 1 to 6 below). However, they are

both economic high performers within their regions, which may bias the findings

presented here in favor of a more optimistic general assessment. Cities and counties within each province were also selected nonrandomly.

In addition to field interviews, I collected published and unpublished documents during site visits, library searches in China, and from government internet sites. When visiting party schools, for example, I asked interviewees for copies of training syllabi and training materials. Additional data was available online. Central Party School yearbooks,

Central Organization Department publications, newspaper articles in Chinese and English, and online biographies were all valuable resources for constructing an understanding of the institutional lay of the land, system wide changes, and local experiences. Mainland libraries consulted include the National Library of China, the libraries of Tsinghua and

Peking universities, and the University Services Centre Library of the Chinese University of Hong Kong. In constructing career histories of Central Party School alumni, I relied most heavily on publicly-available official biographies.

Finally, statistical data were obtained from official government and party yearbooks and the 2003 China General Social Survey.

225 Appendix B, continued: Descriptive data on interviewees

Table 1: Administrative level of interviewees Administrative Level N Percent Township 12 5.08 County 38 16.10 City 58 24.58 Province 60 25.42 Central 68 28.81 Total 236 100

Table 2: Interviewee type Occupation N Cadre 177 Party school teacher 90 Part-time party school teacher 20 Party school student, part- or full-time 32 Party school trainee 78 Note: these are non-exclusive categories. For example, some interviewees were both trainees and students at some point, or some party school teachers were also administrators (i.e., ‘1’s in the cadre and party school teacher categories).

Table 3: Interviewee gender N Percent Male 166 70.34 Female 70 29.66 Total 236 100

226 Appendix B, continued: Scatterplots of provincial research sites

Figure 1. Cadre population and GDP per Figure 2. Cadre population and GDP per cap, cap, coastal region central region

Province A 6500 Province B 11000 6000 10000 5500 9000 5000 8000 GDP per capita (yuan) GDP per capita (yuan) 4500 7000 4000 6000 .0006 .0008 .001 .0012 .0014 .0016 .0006 .0008 .001 .0012 Number of cadres per cap Number of cadres per cap

Figure 3. Leading cadre population and Figure 4. Leading cadre population and GPD GPD per cap, coastal region per cap, central region

Province A 6500 Province B 11000 6000 10000 5500 9000 5000 8000 GDP per capita(yuan) GDP per capita(yuan) 4500 7000 4000 6000 .00025 .0003 .00035 .0004 .00045 .0005 .0002 .0003 .0004 .0005 Number of leading cadres per cap Number of leading cadres per cap

Figure 5. Leading cadre population and Figure 6. Cadre population and GDP per cap, GDP per cap, all regions all regions 30000 30000 20000 20000

Province A Province A GDP per capita (yuan) GDP per capita (yuan) 10000 10000

Province B Province B 0 0

0 .0005 .001 .0015 .002 0 .001 .002 .003 .004 Number of leading cadres per cap Number of cadres per cap

Notes: Data on cadre populations were obtained from COD 1999; all other data from provincial- level statistical yearbooks, China Data Online, 1998.

227 Appendix C: City Z training allocations, 2008

Duration Class name (days) Enrollment Location(s) Young cadre training class 45 60 City party school, Central Party School Spirit of the 17th Party Congress class 3 360 City party school City-level cadre advanced class 45 60 City party school, provincial university City-level cadre advanced class 45 60 City party school, provincial university Promoting urban and rural development and 3 74 City party school building a new socialist countryside advanced research class Building a civilized city and cultural production 3 49 City party school development research and discussion class Environmentally conscious city and civilization 3 52 City party school building research and discussion class Innovation and rapid transitioning economy 3 70 City party school research and discussion class "City of innovation" research and discussion 15 35 Hong Kong class university Social work management research and 15 35 Singapore discussion class university Enterprise manager advanced research class 7 120 Tsinghua University, Fudan University Enterprise manager advanced research class 7 120 Tsinghua University, Fudan University Agricultural technologies training class 7 50 City party school Democratic parties, Association of Industry 15 45 Shenzhen and Commerce, and non-party representative socialism institute training class Industrial economic management leader 7 50 City party school training class Personnel allocation training class 6 50 Fudan University Private enterprise party secretary 3 40 City party school demonstration class Newly promoted section-level cadre training 15 60 City party school class City party representative training class 2 100 City party school Party spirit education training class 3 City party school High-level crisis management research class 6 70 City party school Overseas Chinese Office cadre training class 7 50 Fujian university Family planning leading cadre training class 2 200 City party school Family planning leading cadre training class 2 130 City party school Grassroots letters and complaints leader 3 120 City party school training class Non-CCP young cadre training class 30 55 City socialism institute, Shanghai socialism institute

228 Duration Class name (days) Enrollment Location(s) Retired cadre training class 2 100 City senior citizen university CCP activist training class 4 200 City party school Discipline and inspection cadre training class 7 50 City party school The city's "Low income rural household 7 80 City party school wellness project" cadre training The city's "Low income rural household 7 80 City party school wellness project" cadre training Public security section chief training class 7 480 City police academy Retired cadre bureau chief training class 6 20 City party school Communist Youth League cadre training class 3 130 Another city Party affairs cadre training class 3 150 City party school City building leading cadre training class 15 30 Provincial construction ministry, Cadre school City military affairs civilian cadre training class 45 City party school, City personnel training and testing center Party committee office affairs training class 3 120 City party school Theoretical reserve cadre training class 3 200 City party school Discipline and inspection party secretary 15 30 Central discipline training class and inspection training center Source: Internal school document.

229 Appendix D: Descriptive statistics and robustness tests of PSM presented in Chapter 3

Table 1: Descriptive summary of variables Variable Obs Mean SD Min Max Party school 589 0.29 0.45 0 1 partydum1 586 0.70 0.46 0 1 totalyrsed 589 6.82 4.59 0 70 soelvl2 589 0.34 0.48 0 1 soelvl3 589 0.44 0.50 0 1 soelvl4 589 0.09 0.28 0 1 age 589 50.78 12.10 20 72 female 589 0.26 0.44 0 1 frqupdum 578 0.97 0.17 0 1 army1 588 0.20 0.40 0 1 sentdum 588 0.14 0.34 0 1 fccp 589 0.31 0.46 0 1 mccp 589 0.10 0.29 0 1

Table 2: Pairwise correlations between independent and control variables partydum totalyrsed soelvl2 soelvl3 soelvl4 age female frqupdum army1 sentdum fccp mccp partydum1 1.00 totalyrsed -0.04 1.00 soelvl2 -0.02 -0.08 1.00 soelvl3 0.03 0.05 -0.65 1.00 soelvl4 0.06 0.01 -0.22 -0.27 1.00 age 0.18 -0.32 0.07 -0.09 0.05 1.00 female -0.21 0.09 -0.11 0.09 -0.01 -0.11 1.00 frqupdum 0.08 -0.01 -0.05 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.01 1.00 army1 0.21 -0.17 0.03 -0.06 0.05 0.16 -0.23 0.01 1.00 sentdum -0.06 -0.01 0.07 -0.05 -0.02 0.11 0.09 0.01 -0.07 1.00 fccp -0.02 0.17 -0.06 0.10 -0.02 -0.39 0.11 0.01 -0.06 -0.05 1.00 mccp -0.04 0.11 -0.03 0.04 -0.02 -0.17 0.08 -0.01-0.01 -0.01 0.35 1.00

230 Appendix D, continued.

Table 3: T-tests for equality of means across treatment and control groups, before and after matching Mean Mean %reduct t-test Variable Sample Treated Control %bias |bias| t p>t Party school Unmatched 1 0 . . . Matched 1 0 . . . .

CCP Unmatched 0.91538 0.54633 91.3 7.93 0 Matched 0.91538 0.89423 5.2 94.3 0.58 0.563

Education Unmatched 6.5077 6.6294 -3.1 -0.3 0.764 Matched 6.50776.3192 4.9 -54.9 0.37 0.714

SOElvl2 Unmatched 0.36154 0.36422 -0.6 -0.05 0.958 Matched 0.36154 0.475 -23.5 -4135.6 -1.86 0.064

SOElvl3 Unmatched 0.46154 0.42492 7.4 0.71 0.48 Matched 0.46154 0.36731 18.9 -157.3 1.54 0.124

SOElvl4 Unmatched 0.08462 0.07029 5.3 0.52 0.602 Matched 0.08462 0.07115 5 6 0.4 0.687

Age Unmatched 49.57749.335 2 0.19 0.848 Matched 49.57749.742 -1.4 31.5 -0.12 0.908

Female Unmatched 0.26154 0.30671 -10 -0.95 0.343 Matched 0.26154 0.27885 -3.8 61.7 -0.31 0.754

Frqupdum Unmatched 0.97692 0.96166 8.8 0.81 0.42 Matched 0.97692 0.98077 -2.2 74.8 -0.21 0.83

Army Unmatched 0.14615 0.18211 -9.7 -0.91 0.362 Matched 0.14615 0.13077 4.1 57.2 0.36 0.721

Sentdown Unmatched 0.1 0.15016 -15.2 -1.4 0.161 Matched 0.10.13654 -11 27.2 -0.91 0.364

Fccp Unmatched 0.37692 0.3099 14.1 1.37 0.173 Matched 0.37692 0.32308 11.3 19.7 0.91 0.365

Mccp Unmatched 0.09231 0.08946 1 0.1 0.924 Matched 0.09231 0.09231 0 100 0 1

Beijing Unmatched 0.05385 0.10543 -19.1 -1.73 0.085 Matched 0.05385 0.06346 -3.6 81.4 -0.33 0.743

Tianjin Unmatched 0.1 0.09904 0.3 0.03 0.976 Matched 0.10.05769 14.1 -4314.1 1.26 0.207

231 Mean Mean %reduct t-test Variable Sample Treated Control %bias |bias| t p>t Hebei Unmatched 0.01538 0.03195 -10.9 -0.98 0.329 Matched 0.01538 0.01538 0 100 0 1

Shanxi Unmatched 0.00769 0.01917 -10 -0.88 0.379 Matched 0.00769 0.00577 1.7 83.2 0.19 0.85

Neimenggu Unmatched 0.02308 0.01278 7.7 0.79 0.43 Matched 0.02308 0.02115 1.4 81.3 0.11 0.916

Liaoning Unmatched 0 0 . . . Matched 0 0 . . . .

Jilin Unmatched 0.01538 0.00639 8.6 0.91 0.363 Matched 0.01538 0.03846 -22.2 -156.6 -1.15 0.252

Heilongjiang Unmatched 0 0 . . . Matched 0 0 . . . .

Shanghai Unmatched 0.07692 0.0639 5.1 0.5 0.62 Matched 0.07692 0.04423 12.7 -151 1.1 0.271

Jiangsu Unmatched 0.04615 0.03834 3.9 0.38 0.705 Matched 0.04615 0.05385 -3.8 1.6 -0.28 0.777

Zhejiang Unmatched 0 0 . . . Matched 0 0 . . . .

Anhui Unmatched 0.02308 0.06709 -21.3 -1.87 0.063 Matched 0.02308 0.01346 4.7 78.2 0.58 0.564

Fujian Unmatched 0.03077 0.03834 -4.1 -0.39 0.698 Matched 0.03077 0.03846 -4.2 -1.6 -0.34 0.736

Jiangxi Unmatched 0.00769 0.02236 -12.1 -1.05 0.292 Matched 0.00769 0.00962 -1.6 86.9 -0.17 0.868

Shandong Unmatched 0.03846 0.04792 -4.6 -0.44 0.663 Matched 0.03846 0.05962 -10.4 -123.6 -0.79 0.432

Henan Unmatched 0.01538 0.0607 -23.8 -2.05 0.041 Matched 0.01538 0.00769 4 83 0.58 0.563

Hubei Unmatched 0.16923 0.03514 45.2 5.02 0 Matched 0.16923 0.15192 5.8 87.1 0.38 0.705

Hunan Unmatched 0.12308 0.05431 24.3 2.52 0.012 Matched 0.12308 0.17308 -17.7 27.3 -1.13 0.258

232 Mean Mean %reduct t-test Variable Sample Treated Control %bias |bias| t p>t Guangdong Unmatched 0.06923 0.09904 -10.7 -1 0.32 Matched 0.06923 0.05962 3.5 67.7 0.31 0.753

Guangxi Unmatched 0.03846 0.03514 1.8 0.17 0.865 Matched 0.03846 0.04615 -4.1 -131.9 -0.31 0.759

Chongqing Unmatched 0.01538 0.00319 12.7 1.42 0.155 Matched 0.01538 0.01154 4 68.4 0.27 0.789

Sichuan Unmatched 0.02308 0.02236 0.5 0.05 0.963 Matched 0.02308 0.03269 -6.4 -1249.1 -0.47 0.639

Guizhou Unmatched 0.00769 0.04792 -24.6 -2.07 0.039 Matched 0.00769 0.00769 0 100 0 1

Yunnan Unmatched 0.04615 0.03514 5.6 0.55 0.584 Matched 0.04615 0.04038 2.9 47.6 0.23 0.82

Shaanxi Unmatched 0.00769 0.01917 -10 -0.88 0.379 Matched 0.00769 0.00577 1.7 83.2 0.19 0.85

Gansu Unmatched 0.03077 0.01278 12.3 1.29 0.196 Matched 0.03077 0.02308 5.3 57.2 0.38 0.703

233 Appendix D, continued.

Histogram 1: Absolute distance between the propensity scores of each treatment observation and nearest neighbor match 150 100 Frequency 50 0

0 .02 .04 .06 Absolute difference in propensity score

Tables 4-6: Estimation of average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) using different matching algorithms DV: Section rank (dummy) Treatment: Enrollment in non-degree party school training class N N Method treated control ATT SE t-statistic Nearest neighbor, random draw logit (attnd) 170 82 0.13 0.096 1.349 Nearest-neighbor, equal weight (attnw) 170 86 0.221 0.078 2.841 Stratification (atts) 166 378 0.116 0.061 1.91 Kernel (attk) 170 355 0.093 0.061 1.513

DV: Department rank (dummy) Treatment: Enrollment in non-degree party school training class N N Method treated control ATT SE t-statistic Nearest neighbor, random draw logit 170 70 0.105 0.071 1.489 (attnd) Nearest-neighbor, equal weight (attnw) 170 66 0.137 0.058 2.343 Stratification (atts) 166 378 0.096 0.047 2.04 Kernel (attk) 170 355 0.072 0.05 1.442

DV: Any rank (dummy) Treatment: Enrollment in non-degree party school training class N N Method treated control ATT SE t-statistic Nearest neighbor, random draw logit (attnd) 170 97 0.129 0.078 1.666 Nearest-neighbor, equal weight (attnw) 170 96 0.229 0.069 3.346 Radius (attr) 139 284 0.094 0.54 1.743 Stratification (atts) 166 378 0.132 0.051 2.588 Kernel (attk) 170 355 0.101 0.049 2.067 Note: Bootstrapped standard errors are reported (200 replications)

234 Appendix E: Central Party School Young Cadre Training Classes descriptive data

Table 1: Age at the time of training Total 2000 1995 N % N % N % 30-39 43 9.7 13 5.3 30 15.1 40-49 268 60.6152 62.6 116 58.3 50-55 38 8.6 24 9.9 14 7.0 NA 93 21.054 22.2 39 19.6 Total 442 100.0243 100.0 199 100.0

Table 2: Gender Total 2000 1995 N % N % N % Male 362 81.9200 82.3 162 81.4 Female 45 10.2 27 11.1 18 9.0 NA 35 7.916 6.6 19 9.5 Total 442 100.0243 100.0 199 100.0

235 Appendix E, continued.

Table 3: Home province at time of training Total 2000 1995 N %N%N % Beijing 12 2.7 4 1.6 8 4.0 Tianjin 9 2.0 5 2.1 4 2.0 Hebei 19 4.3 9 3.7 10 5.0 Shanxi 12 2.7 6 2.5 6 3.0 Neimenggu 9 2.0 5 2.1 4 2.0 Liaoning 18 4.1 10 4.1 8 4.0 Jilin 15 3.4 9 3.7 6 3.0 Heilongjiang 9 2.0 3 1.2 6 3.0 Shanghai 4 0.9 0 0.0 4 2.0 Jiangsu 21 4.8 13 5.3 8 4.0 Zhejiang 22 5.0 13 5.3 9 4.5 Anhui 15 3.4 11 4.5 4 2.0 Fujian 8 1.8 3 1.2 5 2.5 Jiangxi 11 2.5 4 1.6 7 3.5 Shandong 29 6.6 20 8.2 9 4.5 Henan 16 3.6 10 4.1 6 3.0 Hubei 13 2.9 4 1.6 9 4.5 Hunan 13 2.9 8 3.3 5 2.5 Guangdong 11 2.5 8 3.3 3 1.5 Guangxi 8 1.8 3 1.2 5 2.5 Hainan 7 1.6 3 1.2 4 2.0 Chongqing 5 1.1 3 1.2 2 1.0 Sichuan 12 2.7 6 2.5 6 3.0 Guizhou 6 1.4 2 0.8 4 2.0 Yunnan 8 1.8 4 1.6 4 2.0 Shaanxi 12 2.7 6 2.5 6 3.0 Gansu 8 1.8 4 1.6 4 2.0 Qinghai 8 1.8 4 1.6 4 2.0 Ningxia 4 0.9 0 0.0 4 2.0 Xinjiang 8 1.8 2 0.8 6 3.0 Tibet 7 1.6 3 1.2 4 2.0 NA 83 18.8 58 23.9 25 12.6 Total 442 100.0 243 100.0 199 100.0

236 Appendix E, continued

Table 4: Educational attainment Total 2000 1995 N% N% N % Professional school 1 0.2 0 0.0 1 0.5 Part-time specialized college 5 1.1 5 2.1 0 0.0 Full-time specialized college 21 4.8 12 4.9 9 4.5 University 71 16.1 36 14.8 35 17.6 Graduate school 133 30.1 84 34.6 49 24.6 Training apprentice 1 0.2 1 0.4 0 0.0 Other 112 25.3 47 19.3 65 32.7 NA 98 22.2 58 23.9 40 20.1 Total 442 100.0 243 100.0 199 100.0 Note: The ‘other’ category includes party school graduate degrees.

Table 5: Percent with party school degrees* Total 2000 1995 N% N% N % Undergraduate 10 2.3 4 1.6 6 3.0 Graduate 114 25.8 48 19.8 66 33.2 Total 124 52 72 *Notes: Many individuals only specify "part-time" graduate degree on their biographies, which may or may not be obtained from a party school. Cheng Li, in his analysis of the biographies of 103 Fifth Generation leaders, finds that 23 out of the 63 leaders with masters degrees obtained these through the CPS (Li 2008b).

Table 6: University major Total 2000 1995 N% N 5 N% Science 12 2.7 5 2.1 73.5 Engineering 27 6.1 17 7.0 105.0 Computer application and software 3 0.7 2 0.8 1 0.5 Medicine and pharmacology 2 0.5 2 0.8 0 0.0 Agriculture, forestry, fisheries, animal husbandry 10 2.3 7 2.9 3 1.5 Finance and economics 47 10.6 26 10.7 21 10.6 Management and administration 34 7.7 18 7.4 16 8.0 Law 38 8.6 24 9.9 147.0 Social sciences 6 1.4 1 0.4 5 2.5 Humanities 42 9.5 17 7.0 2512.6 Foreign languages 3 0.7 2 0.8 1 0.5 Education and information systems 3 0.7 0.0 3 1.5 NA 215 48.6 122 50.2 9346.7 Total 442 100 243 100 199 100

237 Appendix F: International partnerships, central and provincial party schools Year School Partner partnership began Central Party School Sozialdemokratische Partei Deutschlands (Germany) Instituto Español de Comercio Exterior Crawford School at the Australian National University National Defense University (US) Georgetown University The National Academy of Public Administration (Italy) National Academy of Politics and Public Administration (Laos) Sustainable Development Commission UK (SDC) National Political and Administrative Academy Ho Chi Minh (Vietnam) Brookings Institution Ministry of National Development (Singapore) Indian Institute of Public Administration The Department of Indian Affairs and Northern Development

(Canada) Canada School of Public Service National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies (Japan) Malik Management Centre, Switzerland Harvard Fairbanks Center for East Asian Research 1995 Anhui n/a Chongqing n/a Fujian n/a Gansu n/a Guangdong Canada International Development Agency at least 2004 Guangxi University National Political and Administrative Academy Ho Chi Minh Guizhou n/a Hebei n/a Henan n/a Hubei n/a Hunan Ministry of Internal Affairs (Vietnam) at least 2005 Central Civil Service Academy (Korea) at least 2006 European Administrative School at least 2006 Civil Service College (Singapore) at least 2006 International Centre for the Study of East Asian Jiangsu Development Kyoto University Jiangxi National Political and Administrative Academy Ho Chi Minh Ecole Nationale d'Administration University of Georgia at least 2004 Nanyang Technological University Jilin Jiangyuandao Human Resources Development Academy (Korea) National Academy of Public Administration (Belarus) Liaoning Loyola University Neimenggu n/a Ningxia n/a Qinghai n/a

238 Year School Partner partnership began Shaanxi Party School Spanish Agency for International Development 2008 (AECID) Shandong n/a Shanxi n/a Sichuan n/a Tianjin n/a Xinjiang n/a Xizang n/a Yunnan n/a Zhejiang Civil Service College (Singapore) Beijing California State University University of Georgia Baldwin-Wallace College Far East Studies Institute of the Russian Academy of Sciences Northwest Academy of Public Administration (Russia) Sciences Po (France) Administrative College of NRW (Germany) Korean Research Institute for Local Administration (Korea) University of Canberra (Australia) Kanagawa University (Japan) National Academy of Public Administration (Vietnam) Shanghai University of Alberta (Canada) at least 2004 German University of Administrative Sciences at least 2006 Speyer (Germany) Civil Service College in Singapore at least 2004 Maxwell School of Syracuse University at least 2000 University of Georgia at least 2004 Kennedy School of Harvard University at least 2007 Nagoya University (Japan) at least 2008 Ecole Nationale d' Administration Sciences Po (France) Russian North-Western Academy of Public at least 2004 Administration National Academy of Public Administration (Vietnam) at least 2004 National Political and Administrative Academy Ho Chi at least 2004 Minh (Vietnam) Korean Research Institute for Local Administration (Korea) Oxford University Sheffield Hallam University Netherlands Maritime University The National Academy of Public Administration (Italy) at least 2006 Milan Training Academy (Italy) at least 2006 The Institute of Public Enterprise (India)

239 Appendix G: Categories for coding training syllabi

Theory Marxist-Leninist theory Mao theory Deng theory – this includes ‘Socialism with Chinese Characteristics’ Jiang theory – this includes “Three Represents” Hu theory – this includes “Harmonious Society” Capitalist theory/non-Marxist western economic theory Liberal democratic theory General theories of socialism (no clear attribution) – e.g., socialist development, economy Minorities in a socialist system

Central party policy & documents Central party policy – economic development (e.g., SOE, agriculture, 5-yr. plans) Central party policy – social reform Central party policy – party building (including united front, unions, etc.) 16th Party Congress 17th Party Congress

Local party policy Provincial party policy – economic development Provincial party policy – social City party policy – economic development City party policy – social County party policy – economic and social (including building new countryside)

Party history and party building Party history Party constitution Party line/party building

Leadership studies Leadership theory/’art of leadership’ Management (including crisis management) Speechmaking and communication Media relations Principles of service government Public administration Strategic thinking

Case study International – US International – Asia International – W Europe International – USSR and E Europe International – general cases/lessons from abroad International – international organizations Domestic – building new countryside Domestic – coastal economic development Domestic – inland economic development

240 Basic educational disciplines Basic social science Basic humanities Chinese history and culture Basic sciences

Practical skills Investigation and basic writing (reports and composition) Budgeting and accounting Military training Foreign language

Law General Administrative law Business/finance law Criminal law Labor law Property rights

Other General interest lectures Ethics Elective course – via TV or internet Computer class

241 References

Aberbach, Joel D., and Bert A. Rockman. 1988. Mandates or Mandarins? Control and Discretion in the Modern Administrative State. Public Administration Review 48 (2):606-612. Alpermann, Bjorn. 2001. The Post-Election Administration of Chinese Villages. The China Journal 46:45-67. Ang, Yuen Yuen. 2009a. Centralizing treasury management in China: The rationale of the central reformers. Public Administration and Development 29 (4):263-273. Ang, Yuen Yuen. 2009b. State, Market, and Bureau-Contracting in Reform China, Political Science, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. Arrow, Kenneth J. 1973. Higher Education as a Filter. Journal of Public Economics 2:193-216. Baker, George P., Michael C. Jensen, and Kevin J. Murphy. 1988. Compensation and Incentives: Practice vs. Theory. The Journal of Finance 43 (3):593-616. Bardhan, Pranab. 2009. India and China: Governance Issues and Development. Journal of Asian Studies 68 (2):347-57. Barnett, A. Doak, and Ezra F. Vogel. 1967. Cadres, Bureaucracy, and Political Power in Communist China. New York: Columbia University Press. Baum, Richard. 1996. Burying Mao: Chinese Politics in the Age of Deng Xiaoping. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Becker, Sascha O., and Andrea Ichino. 2002. Estimation of average treatment effects based on propensity scores. The Stata Journal:1-19. Bendor, Jonathan B. 1985. Parallel Systems: Redundancy in Government. Berkeley: University of California Press. Blaydes, Lisa. 2008. Authoritarian Elections and Elite Management: Theory and Evidence from Egypt. In Princeton University Conference on Dictatorships. Princeton University. Bo, Zhiyue. 2002. Chinese Provincial Leaders: Economic Performance and Political Mobility Since 1949: M.E. Sharpe. Bo, Zhiyue. 2004. The Institutionalization of Elite Management in China. In Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era, edited by B. J. Naughton and D. L. Yang. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Braun, Dietmar, and Fabrizio Gilardi, eds. 2006. Delegation in Contemporary Democracies. London and New York: Routledge. Brehm, John, and Scott Gates. 1997. Working, Shirking, and Sabotage: Bureaucratic Response to a Democratic Public. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Brownlee, Jason. 2007. Authoritarianism in an Age of Democratization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Burnham, James. 1962. The Managerial Revolution. Bloomington: Indiana University Press. Burns, John P., ed. 1989a. The Chinese Communist Party's Nomenklatura System: A Documentary Study of Party Control of Leadership Selection, 1979-1984. Armonk and London: M.E. Sharpe, Inc.

242 Burns, John P. 1989b. Introduction: The Chinese Nomenklatura System. In The Chinese Communist Party's Nomenklatura System: A Documentary Study of Party Control of Leadership Selection, 1979-1984, edited by J. P. Burns. Armonk and London: M.E. Sharpe, Inc. Burns, John P. 1993. China’s administrative reforms for a market economy. Public administration and development 13 (4):345-60. Burns, John P. 1994. Strengthening Central CCP Control of Leadership Selection: The 1990 Nomenklatura. China Quarterly 138:458-491. Burns, John P. 2003. "Downsizing" the Chinese State: Government Retrenchment in the 1990s. China Quarterly (175):775-802. Burns, John P. 2006. The Chinese Communist Party's Nomenklatura System as a Leadership Selection Mechanism. In The Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by K. E. Brodsgaard and Z. Yongnian. London and New York: Routledge. Burns, John P., and Bidhya Bowornwathana, eds. 2001. Civil Service Systems in Asia, Civil Service Systems in Comparative Perspective. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: MPG Books Ltd. Cai, Hongbin, and Daniel Treisman. 2006. Did government decentralization cause China's economic miracle? World Politics 58 (4):505-535. Calvert, Randall L., Mathew D. McCubbins, and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. A Theory of Political Control and Agency Discretion. American Journal of Political Science 33 (3):588-611. Campos, Jose Edgardo, and Hilton L. Root. 1996. The Key to the Asian Miracle: Making Shared Growth Credible. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. CCP Central Committee. 1981. On Questions of Party History: Resolution on Certain Questions in the History of Our Party Since the Founding of the People's Republic of China: Beijing Review. Cell, Charles P. 1977. Revolution at Work: Mobilization Campaigns in China. New York: Academic Press. Central Committee. 2004. Decision on Facing the Twenty-First Century through Strengthening and Improving Party School Work. Beijing. Central Organization Department. 1983. Notice of the Organization Department of the Central Committee. In The Chinese Communist Party's Nomenklatura System: A Documentary Study of Party Control of Leadership Selection, 1979-1984, edited by J. P. Burns. Armonk, NY and London: M.E. Sharpe, Inc. Central Organization Department, ed. 1999. Party and government leading cadre statistical data compilation (dangzheng lingdao ganbu tongji ziliao huibian). Beijing: Party building reading materials publishing house (Dang jian du wu chu ban she). Central Organization Department. 2004. CCP Central Committee Decision on Facing the Twenty-First Century through Strengthening and Improving Party School Work. Beijing. Central Organization Department, Cadre Education Office. 2006. Reader on Trial Regulations on Cadre Education and Training (ganbu jiaoyu peixun gongzuo tiaoli (shixing), xuexi fudao): Dangjian duwu chubanshe. Chang, Gordon G. 2001. The Coming Collapse of China. New York: Random House.

243 Chen, Guisheng. 2007. China's Cadre Education, 1927-1949 (zhongguo gan bu jiao yu (1927-1949)). Shanghai: Huadong Normal University Press. Chinese yearbook of ideological and political work (zhongguo sixiang zhengzhi gongzuo nianjian). 2001. Central Party School Publishing House. Chow, King W. 1988. The Management of Chinese Cadre Resources: The Politics of Performance Appraisal (1949-84). International Review of Administrative Sciences 54:359-377. Chow, King W. 1993. The Politics of Performance Appraisal. In Public Administration in China, edited by M. K. Mills and S. S. Nagel. Westport and London: Greenwood Press. Clemens, Elisabeth S., and James M. Cook. 1999. Politics and Institutionalism: Explaining Durability and Change. Annual Review of Sociology 25:441-66. Cox, Gary W. 2009. Authoritarian elections and leadership succession, 1975-2004. CPS, ed. 2004. Research on certain questions concerning the building of a ruling party (zhizheng dang jianshe ruogan wenti yanjiu). Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Dai, Yanjun. 2006. The issue of strengthening the party's governance capacity (jiaqiang dangde zhizheng nengli jianshe wenti). In Compilation of CCP Central Party School Teaching Scripts 3: Studies of Marxism, Leninism, Mao Zedong Thought, Deng Xiaoping Theory, the Three Represents Thought and Other Issues (zhonggong zhongyang dangxiao jianggaoxuan 3: makesi liening zhuyi, maozedong sixiang, dengxiaoping lilun, sange daibiao zhongyao sixiang qianyan wenti yanjiu), edited by T. Shi. Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Dehejia, Rajeev H., and Sadek Wahba. 1999. Causal Effects in Nonexperimental Studies: Reevaluating the Evaluation of Training Programs. Journal of the American Statistical Association 94 (448):1053-1062. Denzau, Arthur T., and Douglass C. North. 1994. Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions. Kyklos 47 (1):3-31. Dethier, Jean-Jacques, ed. 2000. Governance, Decentralization and Reform in China, India and Russia. Boston and London: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Diaz-Cayeros, Alberto, Beatriz Magaloni, and Barry R. Weingast. 2003. Tragic Brilliance: Equilibrium Hegemony and Democratization in Mexico. Dickson, Bruce J. 2003. Red Capitalists in China: The Party, Private Entrepreneurs, and Prospects for Political Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dimitrov, Martin. 2010. Popular Accountability and Regime Resilience in Contemporary China: Evidence from Citizen Complaints: Dartmouth College. Ding, X.L. 1994. The Decline of Communism in China: Legitimacy Crisis, 1977-1989. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Dittmer, Lowell. 1978. Bases of Power in Chinese Politics: The Fall of the Gang of Four. World Politics 31 (1):26-55. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper. Downs, Eric S. 2008. Business Interest Groups in Chinese Politics: The Case of the Oil Companies. In China's Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by C. Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

244 Duckett, Jane. 2001. Bureaucrats in Business, Chinese-Style: The Lessons of Market Reform and State Entrepreneurialism in the People's Republic of China. World Development 29 (1):23-37. Enthoven, Alain, and Henry Rowen. 1959. Defense Planning and Organization. Santa Monica: Rand Corporation. Epstein, Amy B. 1996. Village Elections in China: Experimenting with Democracy. In China's Economic Future: Challenges to U.S. Policy, edited by C. o. t. U. S. Joint Economic Committee. Washington, DC: M.E. Sharpe. Epstein, David, and Sharyn O'Halloran. 2006. A Theory of Efficient Delegation. In Delegation in Contemporary Democracies, edited by D. Braun and F. Gilardi. London and New York: Routledge. Farmer, Kenneth C. 1992. The Soviet Administrative Elite. New York and London: Praeger. Felsenthal, Dan S. 1980. Applying the Redundancy Concept to Administrative Organizations. Public Administration Review 40 (3):247-252. Fewsmith, Joseph. 2003. Where do Correct Ideas Come From? The Party School, Key Think Tanks, and the Intellectuals. In China's Leadership in the 21st Century: The Rise of the Fourth Generation, edited by D. M. Finkelstein and M. Kivlehan. Armonk and London: M.E. Sharpe. Fewsmith, Joseph. 2007. Democracy is a Good Thing. China Leadership Monitor (22). Fewsmith, Joseph. 2008. A New Upsurge in Political Reform? - Maybe. China Leadership Monitor (24). Gadsden, Amy Epstein, and Anne F. Thurston. 2001. Village Elections in China: Progress, Problems, and Prospects: International Republican Institute. Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008a. Dictatorial Institutions and their Impact on Economic Growth. European Journal of Sociology 49 (01):3-30. Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008b. Political Institutions Under Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gandhi, Jennifer, and Ellen Lust-Okar. 2009. Elections Under Authoritarianism. Annual Review of Political Science 12 (1):403-422. Gandhi, Jennifer, and Adam Przeworski. 2007. Authoritarian Institutions and the Survival of Autocrats. Comparative Political Studies 40 (11):1279-1301. Geddes, Barbara. 1994. Politician's Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America. Berkeley: University of California Press. Geddes, Barbara. 1999. What Do We Know About Democratization After Twenty Years? Annual Review of Political Science 2:115-144. Geddes, Barbara. 2006. Paradigms and Sand Castles: Theory Building and Research Design in Comparative Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press. Geddes, Barbara. 2008. Party Creation as an Autocratic Survival Strategy. In Dictatorships: Their Governance and Social Consequences. Princeton University. Gehlbach, Scott, and Philip Keefer. 2008. Investment without Democracy: Ruling-Party Institutionalization and Credible Commitment in Autocracies. General View of the Nation's Party Schools (quanguo dangxiao gailan). 1996. Beijing: Red Flag Publishing House.

245 Genschel, Philipp. 1997. The Dynamics of Inertia: Institutional Persistence and Change in Telecommunications and Health Care. Governance 10 (1):43-66. Goldstone, Jack A. 1995. The Coming Chinese Collapse. Foreign Policy (99):35-53. Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira, Avner Greif, and Saumitra Jha. 2008. The Administrative Foundations of Self-Enforcing Constitutions. American Economic Review 98 (2):105-09. Gore, Lance L.P. 1998. Market Communism: The Institutional Foundation of China's Post-Mao Hyper-Growth. Hong Kong: Oxford University Press. Guo, Liangping, and Lance L.P. Gore. 2007. China's New Cadre Evaluation System. East Asia Institute Background Brief 324. Guo, Weigui, and Wei Shan. 2009. The Local Party Schools and China's Cadre Education and Training: Expectations and Realities. EAI Working Paper No. 151. Hadenius, Axel, and Jan Teorell. 2007. Pathways from Authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 18 (1):143-156. Hannan, Michael T., and John Freeman. 1984. Structural Inertia and Organizational Change. American Sociological Review 49 (2):149-164. Hanson, Stephen E. 1995. The Lenininst Legacy and Institutional Change. Comparative Political Studies 28 (2):306-314. Harding, Harry. 1981. Organizing China: The Problem of Bureaucracy, 1949-1976. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Hebert, Robert F., and Albert N. Link. 1988. The Entrepreneur: Mainstream Views and Radical Critiques. 2nd ed. New York: Praeger. Heilmann, Sebastian. 2008. From Local Experiments to National Policy: The Origins of China's Distinctive Policy Process. China Journal 59:1-31. Heilmann, Sebastian, and Sarah Kirchberger. June 2000. The Chinese Nomenklatura in Transition: A Study Based on Internal Cadre Statistics of the Central Organization Department of the Chinese Communist Party. China Analysis, Center for East Asian and Pacific Studies, Trier University (1). Heimer, Maria. 2006. The Cadre Responsibility System and the Changing Needs of the Party. In The Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by K. E. Brodsgaard and Z. Yongnian. London and New York: Routledge. Huang, Da-Qiang. 1993a. Promoting the Quality of the Chinese Government. In Public Administration in China, edited by M. K. Mills and S. S. Nagel. Westport and London: Greenwood Press. Huang, Da Qiang. 1993b. Promoting the Quality of the Chinese Government. In Public Administration in China, edited by M. K. Mills and S. S. Nagel. Westport and London: Greenwood Press. Huang, Shi'an, ed. 2002a. CCP Central Party School Correspondence Education Yearbook. Beijing: CCP Central Party School Publishing House. Huang, Yasheng. 1995. Administrative Monitoring in China. China Quarterly (143):828- 843. Huang, Yasheng. 1996. Central-local relations in China during the reform era: The economic and institutional dimensions. World Development 24 (4):655-672. Huang, Yasheng. 2002b. Managing Chinese Bureaucrats: An Institutional Economics Perspective. Political Studies 50 (1):61-79.

246 Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Huskey, Eugene. 2004. From Higher Party Schools to Academies of State Service: The Marketization of Bureaucratic Training in Russia. Slavic Review 63 (2):325-348. Jia, Hao, and Zhimin Lin, eds. 1994. Changing Central-Local Relations in China. Boulder: Westview Press. Jiang, Huaxuan, Weiping Zhang, and Xiao Sheng, eds. 1983. Record of Important CCP Meetings, 1921-2006 (zhongguo gongchandang zhongyao huiyi jishi). Beijing: Central Documents Publishing House. Jin, Jing, and Heng-fu Zou. 2003. Soft Budget Constraints and Local Government in China. In Fiscal decentralization and the challenge of hard budget constraints, edited by J. Rodden, G. S. Eskeland and J. I. Litvack. Cambridge: MIT Press. Johnson, Chalers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925-1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Jowitt, Kenneth. 1975. Inclusion and Mobilization in European Leninist Regimes. World Politics 28 (1):69-96. Kaufman, Herbert. 2006. The Forest Ranger: A Study in Administrative Behavior. Special Reprint ed. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future Press. Kelliher, Daniel. 1997. The Chinese Debate Over Village Self-Government. The China Journal 37:63-86. Kirby, William C., Robert S. Ross, and Gong Li, eds. 2005. Normalization of US-China Relations: An International History. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Klugman, Jeffry. 1989. The New Soviet Elite: How They Think and What They Want. New York and Westport: Praeger. Krause, George A., and James W. Douglas. 2003. Are Two Heads Always Better than One? Redundancy, Competition, and Task Performance Quality in Public Bureaus. In Annual Conference of the Association of Budgeting and Financial Management. Washington, DC. Kreps, David M. 1990. Corporate Culture and Economic Theory. In Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, edited by J. E. Alt and K. A. Shepsle. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lampton, David M. 1992. A Plum for a Peach: Bargaining, Interest, and Bureaucratic Politics in China. In Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China, edited by K. G. Lieberthal and D. M. Lampton. Berkeley: University of California Press. Lampton, Michael. 1987. Chinese Politics: The Bargaining Treadmill. Issues and Studies:11-41. Lan, Zhiyong, and David H. Rosenbloom. 1992. Editorial: Public Administration in Transition? Public Administration Review 52 (6):535-537. Landau, Martin. 1969. Redundancy, Rationality, and the Problem of Duplication and Overlap. Public Administration Review 29 (4):346-358. Landau, Martin. 1991. On Multiorganizational Systems in Public Administration. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory: J-PART 1 (1):5-18. Landry, Pierre F. 2003. The Political Management of Mayors in Post-Deng China. Copenhagen Journal of Asian Studies 17:31-58.

247 Landry, Pierre F. 2007. Decentralized Authoritarianism in China: The Communist Party's Control of Local Elites in the Post-Mao Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lazarev, Valery. 2005. Economics of One-Party State: Promotion Incentives and Support for the Soviet Regime. Comparative Economic Studies 47 (2):346-363. Lazarev, Valery. 2007. Political labor market, government policy, and stability of a non- democratic regime. Journal of Comparative Economics 35 (3):546-563. Lee, Hong Yung. 1983. China's 12th Central Committee: Rehabilitated Cadres and Technocrats. Asian Survey 23 (6):673-691. Lee, Hong Yung. 1984. Evaluation of China's Bureaucratic Reforms. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 476:34-47. Lee, Hong Yung. 1991. From Revolutionary Cadres to Party Technocrats in Socialist China. Berkeley and Oxford: University of California Press. Lenin, V.I. 1964. What is to be Done? Burning Questions of Our Movement. In Collected Works. Moscow: Progress Publishers. Lerner, Allan W. 1978. On ambiguity and organizations. Administration Society 10 (1):3- 32. Lewis, David E. 2002. The Politics of Agency Termination: Confronting the Myth of Agency Immortality. The Journal of Politics 64 (01):89-107. Li, Bobai. 2001. Manufacturing Meritocracy: Adult Education, Career Mobility, and Elite Transformation in Socialist China, Sociology, Stanford, Stanford. Li, Bobai, and Andrew G. Walder. 2001. Career Advancement as Party Patronage: Sponsored Mobility into the Chinese Administrative Elite, 1949-1996. American Journal of Sociology 106 (5):1371-1408. Li, Cheng. 2006. Reshuffling the Four Tiers of Local Leaders: Goals and Implications. China Leadership Monitor 18:1-22. Li, Cheng. 2007a. The big shake-up. China Economic Quarterly 2 (1):24-28. Li, Cheng. 2007b. China's Leadership, Fifth Generation. Brookings Institution, http://www.brookings.edu/articles/2007/12_china_li.aspx (accessed 8 Feb 2008). Li, Cheng. 2008a. China's Fifth Generation: Is Diversity a Source of Strength or Weakness. Asia Policy 6:53-93. Li, Cheng. 2008b. Will China's "Lost Generation" Find a Path to Democracy? In China's Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by C. Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Li, Cheng, and David Bachman. 1989. Localism, Elitism, and Immobilism: Elite Formation and Social Change in Post-Mao China. World Politics 42 (1):64-94. Li, Cheng, and Lynn White. 1988. The Thirteenth Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party: From Mobilizers to Managers. Asian Survey 28 (4):371-399. Li, Cheng, and Lynn White. 1990. Elite Transformation and Modern Change in and Taiwan: Empirical Data and the Theory of Technocracy. The China Quarterly (121):1-35. Li, David D. 1998. Changing Incentives of the Chinese Bureaucracy. The American Economic Review 88 (2):393-397. Li, Kangtai. 1993. Administrative Law in China. In Public Administration in China, edited by M. K. Mills and S. S. Nagel. Westport and London: Greenwood Press.

248 Li, Wei. 1994. The Chinese Staff System: A Mechanism for Bureaucratic Control and Integration. Berkeley: Center for Chinese Studies. Liao, Yuehui, Meichang Pan, and Yuqing Zeng, eds. 1999. The Development and History of China's Special Economic Zones. Shenzhen: Haitian Publishing House. Lieberthal, Kenneth, and Michel Oksenberg. 1988. Policy Making in China: Leaders, Structures, and Processes. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1981. Political Man. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Litwack, John M. 1991. Discretionary Behaviour and Soviet Economic Reform. Soviet Studies 43 (2):255-279. Liu, Jiaqi. 1989. Survey of Basic Principles of Party School Education (dangxiao jiaoyu yuanli gailun). Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Liu, Meiru. 2001. Administrative Reform in China and its Impact on the Policy-Making Process and Economic Development After Mao: Reinventing Chinese Government. Lewiston: Edwin Mellen Press. Lorentzen, Peter L. 2008. Regularized Rioting: Strategic Toleration of Popular Protest in China: University of California, Berkeley. Lu, Xiaobo. 2000. Cadres and Corruption: The Organizational Involution of the Chinese Communist Party. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Lupia, Arthur, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1994. Learning from Oversight: Fire Alarms and Police Patrols Reconstructed. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 10 (1):96-125. Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2006. Elections under authoritarianism: Preliminary lessons from Jordan. Democratization 13 (3):456-471. Lust-Oker, Ellen. 2005. Structuring Conflict in the Arab World: Incumbents, Opponents, and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and its Demise in Mexico. Edited by M. Levi, Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press. Magaloni, Beatriz. 2008. Credible Power-Sharing and the Longevity of Authoritarian Rule. Comparative Political Studies 41 (4-5):715-741. Magaloni, Beatriz, and Ruth Kricheli. 2010. Political Order and One-Party Rule. Annual Review of Political Science 13:123-43. Manion, Melanie. 1985. The Cadre Management System, Post Mao: The Appointment, Promotion, Transfer and Removal of Party and State Leaders. China Quarterly 102:203-33. Manion, Melanie. 1993. Retirement of Revolutionaries in China: Public Policies, Social Norms, Private Interests. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Manion, Melanie. 1996. The Electoral Connection in the Chinese Countryside. American Political Science Review 90 (4):736-748. Massey, Andrew. 1993. Managing the Public Sector: A Comparative Analysis of the United Kingdom and the United States: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited. McCubbins, Mathew D., and Thomas Schwartz. 1984. Congressional Oversight overlooked: Police Patrols Versus Fire Alarms. American Journal of Political Science 28 (1):165-179.

249 Mertha, Andrew C. 2006. Policy Enforcement Markets: How Bureaucratic Redundancy Contributes to Effective Intellectual Property Implementation in China. Comparative Politics 38 (3):295-316. Merton, Robert K. 1968. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: Free Press. Meyer-Sahling, Jan-Hinrik. 2006. The Institutionalization of Political Discretion in Post- Communist Civil Service Systems: The Case of Hungary. Public Administration 84 (3):693-716. Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts. 1992. Economics, Organization, and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Miller, Gary J. 2005. The Political Evolution of Principal-Agent Models. Annual Review of Political Science 8:203-25. Mills, C. Wright. 1959. The Power Elite. New York: Oxford University Press. Ministry of Personnel. 2006. Trial Regulations on Cadre Education and Training (ganbu jiaoyu peixun gongzuo tiaoli (shixing)): Zhongguo fazhi chubanshe. Minzner, Carl F. 2009. Riots and Cover-Ups: Counterproductive Control of Local Agents in China. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Law 31:72. Miranda, Rowan, and Allan Lerner. 1995. Bureaucracy, Organizational Redundancy, and the Privatization of Public Services. Public Administration Review 55 (2):193-200. Mittal, Sonia. 2008. A Necessary Precaution: The Separation of Powers and Political Stability in America. In Midwest Political Science Association Conference. Chicago, IL. Montinola, Gabriella, Yingyi Qian, and Barry R. Weingast. 1995. Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political Basis for Economic Success in China. World Politics 48 (1):50-81. Morgan, Maria Chan. 1981. Controlling the Bureaucracy in Post-Mao China. Asian Survey 21 (12):1223-1236. Munro, Donald J. 1971. The Malleability of Man in Chinese Marxism. The China Quarterly (48):609-640. Nathan, Andrew. 1973. A Factional Model For CCP Politics. China Quarterly 53:98-114. Naughton, Barry. 1992. Hierarchy and the Bargaining Economy: Government and Enterprise in the Reform Process. In Bureaucracy, Politics, and Decision Making in Post-Mao China, edited by K. G. Lieberthal and D. M. Lampton. Berkeley: University of California Press. Naughton, Barry. 2007. The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth. Cambridge and London: MIT Press. Naughton, Barry J., and Dali L. Yang, eds. 2004. Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nee, Victor, and Peng Lian. 1994. Sleeping with the Enemy: A Dynamic Model of Declining Political Commitment in State Socialism. Theory and Society 23 (2):253-296. Niskanen, William A. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago and New York: Aldine Atherton, Inc. North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

250 O'Brien, Kevin J., and Lianjiang Li. 1999. Campaign Nostalgia in the Chinese Countryside. Asian Survey 39 (3):375-393. O'Donnell, Guillermo, and Philippe C. Schmitter. 1986. Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Tentative Conclusions about Uncertain Democracies. Baltimore and London: Johns Hopkins University Press. Oi, Jean C. 1992. Fiscal Reform and the Economic Foundations of Local State Corporatism in China. World Politics 45 (1):99-126. Oi, Jean C. 1998a. The Collective Foundation for Rapid Rural Industrialization. In Cooperative and Collective in China's Rural Development, edited by E. B. Vermeer, F. N. Pieke and W. L. Chong. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Oi, Jean C. 1998b. The Evolution of Local State Corporatism. In Zouping in Transition: The Process of Reform in Rural North China, edited by A. G. Walder. Cambridge and London: Harvard University Press. Oi, Jean C. 1999. Rural China Takes Off: Institutional Foundations of Economic Reform. Berkeley: University of California Press. Oi, Jean C. 2004. Realms of Freedom in Post-Mao China. In Realms of Freedom in Modern China, edited by W. C. Kirby. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Oi, Jean C., and Scott Rozelle. 2000. Elections and Power: The Locus of Decision- Making in Chinese Villages. The China Quarterly:513-539. Olson, Mancur. 1993. Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development. The American Political Science Review 87 (3):567-576. Pearl, Judea. 2000. Causality: Models, Reasoning, and Inference. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Pei, Minxin. 2002. China's Governance Crisis. Foreign Affairs 81 (5):96-109. Pei, Minxin. 2008. Fighting Corruption: A Difficult Challenge for Chinese Leaders. In China's Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by C. Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Pfeffer, Jeffrey, and Gerald Salancik. 1978. The External Control of Organizations. New York: Harper & Row. Pieke, Frank N. 2008. Marketization and centralization of cadre education and training. In Reinventing the Chinese party-state. Shenyang Normal University. Pieke, Frank N. 2009a. The Good Communist: Elite Training and State Building in Today's China. Pieke, Frank N. 2009b. Marketization, Centralization and Globalization of Cadre Training in Contemporary China. China Quarterly 200 (1):953-971. Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Punyaratabandhu-Bhakdi, Suchitra. 1983. Individual Values, Organizational Structure, and the Problem of Performance: Thailand as a Case Study. Public Administration Review 43 (6):510-519. Putnam, Robert D. 1976. The Comparative Study of Political Elites. Edited by J. LaPalonbara, Prentice-Hall Contemporary Comparative Politics Series. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.

251 Qian, Yingyi. 2003. How Reform Worked in China. In In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, edited by D. Rodrik. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press. Qian, Yingyi, and Barry R. Weingast. 1997. Federalism as a Commitment to Preserving Market Incentives. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11:83-92. Rawski, Thomas G. 1994. Chinese Industrial Reform: Accomplishments, Prospects, and Implications. The American Economic Review 84 (2):271-275. Rodden, Jonathan. 2004. Comparative Federalism and Decentralization: On Meaning and Measurement. Comparative Politics 36 (4):481-500. Rostow, W.W. 1960. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schoenhals, Michael. 1991. The 1978 Truth Criterion Controversy. The China Quarterly (126):243-268. Scholz, John T., Jim Twombly, and Barbara Headrick. 1991. Street-Level Political Controls Over Federal Bureaucracy. The American Political Science Review 85 (3):829-850. Schubert, Gunter. 2002. Village Elections in the PRC: A Trojan Horse of Democracy? Discourses on Political Reform and Democratization in East and Southeast Asian in the Light of New Processes fo Regional Community Building (19). Schurmann, Franz. 1970. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. 2nd ed. Berkeley: University of California Press. Selznick, Philip. 1960. The Organizational Weapon: A Study of Bolshevik Strategy and Tactics. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Shambaugh, David. 2008a. China's Communist Party: Atrophy and Adaptation. Washington, DC: Woodrow Wilson Center Press and University of California Press. Shambaugh, David. 2008b. Learning from Abroad to Reinvent Itself: External Influences on Internal CCP Reforms. In China's Changing Political Landscape: Prospects for Democracy, edited by C. Li. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Shi, Li. 2000. Efficiency and Redistribution in China's Revenue Sharing System. In Governance, Decentralization and Reform in China, India and Russia, edited by J.-J. Dethier. Boston and London: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Shi, Taifeng, ed. 2006. Compilation of CCP Central Party School Teaching Scripts 6: Studies of Current Important Theory, Hot Issues, and Difficult Issues (zhonggong zhongyang dangxiao jianggaoxuan 6: dangqian zhongda lilun yu redian nandian wenti yanjiu). Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The Political Logic of Economic Reform. Berkeley: University of California Press. Shirk, Susan L. 2006. China: Fragile Superpower. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press. Shirk, Susan L. 2007. Changing Media, Changing Foreign Policy in China. Japanese Journal of Political Science 8 (01):43-70. Simon, Herbert A. 1979. Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations. The American Economic Review 69 (4):493-513. Smith, Benjamin B. 2005. Life of the Party: The Origins of Regime Breakdown and Persistence under Single-Party Rule. World Politics 57 (3):421-51.

252 Smith, Peter H. 1979. Labyrinths of Power: Political Recruitment in Twentieth-Century Mexico. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Solnick, Steven L. 1996. The Breakdown of Hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: A Neoinstitutional Perspective. World Politics 48 (2):209-238. Solnick, Steven L. 1998. Stealing the State: Control and Collapse in Soviet Institutions. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Spence, Jonathan D. 1999. The Search for Modern China. 2nd ed. New York and London: W.W. Norton and Company. Spence, Michael. 1973. Job Market Signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (3):355-374. Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1975. The Theory of "Screening," Education, and the Distribution of Income. American Economic Review 65 (3):283-300. Stockmann, Daniela, and Mary Elizabeth Gallagher. 2009. Remote Control: How the Media Sustains Authoritarian Rule in China. Streeter, Calvin L. 1992. Redundancy in Organizational Systems. The Social Service Review 66 (1):97-111. Suleiman, Ezra N. 1977. The Myth of Technical Expertise: Selection, Organization, and Leadership. Comparative Politics 10 (1):137-158. Tang, Tsou. 1976. Prolegomena to the Study of Informal Groups in CCP Politics. China Quarterly 65:98-114. Tezcur, Bunes Murat. 2008. Intra-Elite Struggles in Iranian Elections. In Political Participation in the Middle East, edited by E. Lust-Okar and S. Zerhouni. Boulder and London: Lynne Rienner. Ting, Michael M. 2003. A Strategic Theory of Bureaucratic Redundancy. American Journal of Political Science 47 (2):274-292. Townsend, James R. 1969. Political Participation in Communist China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Tran, Emilie. 2003. From Senior Official to Top Civil Servant: An Enquiry into the Shanghai Party School. Perspectives Chinoises (46):27. Tsai, Kellee S. 2005. Capitalists Without a Class: Political Diversity Among Private Entrepreneurs in China. Comparative Political Studies 38 (9):1130-58. Tucker, Robert C., ed. 1975. The Lenin Anthology. New York: W.W. Norton and Company. U, Eddy. 2007. Disorganizing China: Counter-Bureaucracy and the Decline of Socialism. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Vogel, Ezra F. 1967. From Revolutionary to Semi-Bureaucrat. China Quarterly:36-60. Walder, Andrew G. 1995. Career Mobility and the Communist Political Order. American Sociological Review 60 (3):309-328. Walder, Andrew G., Bobai Li, and Donald J. Treiman. 2000. Politics and Life Chances in a State Socialist Regime: Dual Career paths into the Urban Chinese Elite, 1949- 1996. American Sociological Review 65 (2):191-209. Walder, Andrew G., and Litao Zhao. 2006. Political Office and Household Wealth: Rural China in the Deng Era. China Quarterly (186):357-76. Wang, Changjiang. 2002. Historical Lessons of Party Building from the Soviet Communist Party. In Compilation of CCP Central Party School Teaching Scripts: Important Issues of the World (zhonggong zhongyang dangxiao jianggaoxuan:

253 guanyu dangdai shijie zhongda wenti), edited by Y. Yu and C. Yang. Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Wang, Huanchao. 2006. Social Development Theory and Several Major Issues in China's Social Development (shehui fazhan lilun yu woguo shehui fazhan zhong de jige zhongda wenti). In Compilation of CCP Central Party School Teaching Scripts 6: Studies of Current Important Theory, Hot Issues, and Difficult Issues (zhonggong zhongyang dangxiao jianggaoxuan 6: dangqian zhongda lilun yu redian nandian wenti yanjiu), edited by T. Shi. Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Wang, Zhongqing, ed. 1992. General Description of Party School History (dangxiao jiaoyu lishi gaishu), 1921-1947. Beijing: Party School Publishing House. Wedeman, Andrew. 2004. The Intensification of Corruption in China. China Quarterly 180:895-921. Wedeman, Andrew. 2005. Anticorruption Campaigns and the Intensification of Corruption in China. Journal of Contemporary China 14 (42):93-116. Wedeman, Andrew. 2010. Guilt and Punishment in China's War on Corruption. In Growing Pains: Tensions and Opportunity in China's Transformation, edited by J. C. Oi, S. Rozelle and X. Zhou. Stanford: Walter H. Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center. White, Tyrene. 1990. Postrevolutionary Mobilization in China: The One-Child Policy Reconsidered. World Politics 43 (1):53-76. Whitford, Andrew B. 2002. Decentralization and Political Control of the Bureaucracy. Journal of Theoretical Politics 14 (2):167-193. Whiting, Susan H. 2004. The Cadre Evaluation System at the Grass Roots: The Paradox of Party Rule. In Holding China Together: Diversity and National Integration in the Post-Deng Era, edited by B. J. Naughton and D. L. Yang. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Whiting, Susan H. 2006. Growth, Governance, and Institutions: The Internal Institutions of the Party-State in China. World Bank Research Project on the Rise of China and India (Governance). Whyte, Martin King. 1974. Small Groups and Political Rituals in China. Berkeley: University of California Press. Wibowo, Ignatius, and Lye Liang Fook. 2006. China's Central Party School: A Unique Institution Adapting to Changes. In The Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by K. E. Brodsgaard and Z. Yongnian. London and New York: Routledge. William A. Niskanen, Jr. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago and New York: Aldine Atherton, Inc. Williams, Oliver. 1993. An Outsider's Perspective. In Public Administration in China, edited by M. K. Mills and S. S. Nagel. Westport and London: Greenwood Press. Williamson, Oliver E. 1989. Transaction cost economics. In Handbook of Industrial Organization, edited by R. Schmalensee and R. D. Willig. Amsterdam: North- Holland. Wolfe, Bertram D. 1984. Lenin and the Twentieth Century: A Bertram D. Wolfe Retrospective. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press. World Bank. 2002. National Development and Sub-National Finance: A Review of Provincial Expenditures. Washington, DC.

254 Wright, Tim. 2004. The Political Economy of Coal Mine Disasters in China: "Your Rice Bowl or Your Life". China Quarterly:629-646. Xiao, Guishu. 2002. Experiences and Lessons from the Socialist Construction in the Soviet Union. In Compilation of CCP Central Party School Teaching Scripts: Important Issues of the World (zhonggong zhongyang dangxiao jianggaoxuan: guanyu dangdai shijie zhongda wenti), edited by Y. Yu and C. Yang. Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Xie, Chunhong. 2009. Research on Contemporary CCP’s Building of a Learning Party- State (dangdai zhongguo gongchandang jianshe xuexi xing zhengdang yanjiu): People's Publishing House. Yang, Chungui. 2002. On Party School Education (dangxiao jiaoxue lun). Beijing: Central Party School Publishing House. Yang, Dali. 2006. Economic Transformation and its Political Discontents in China: Authoritarianism, Unequal Growth, and the Dilemmas of Political Development. Annual Review of Political Science 9:143-64. Zhang, Bailin, ed. 2005. PRC Civil Servant Law. Beijing: Zhongguo renshi chubanshe, Dangjian duwu chubanshe. Zhang, Le-Yin. 1999. Chinese Central-Provincial Fiscal Relationships, Budgetary Decline and the Impact of the 1994 Fiscal Relations in China: An Evaluation. China Quarterly (157):115-141. Zhang, Tao, and Heng-fu Zou. 1996. Fiscal Decentralization, Public Spending, and Economic Growth in China: World Bank. Zhao, Wei, and Xueguang Zhou. 2004. Chinese Organizations in Transition: Changing Promotion Patterns in the Reform Era. Organization Science 15 (2):186-199. Zheng, Shiping. 1997. Party vs. State in Post-1949 China: The Institutional Dilemma. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. Zheng, Yongnian. 2006. The Party, Class, and Democracy in China. In The Chinese Communist Party in Reform, edited by K. E. Brodsgaard and Z. Yongnian. London and New York: Routledge. Zheng, Yongnian. 2010. The Chinese Communist Party as Organizational Emperor: Culture, reproduction and transformation. London and New York: Routledge. Zhou, Xueguang. 2010. The Institutional Logic of Collusion among Local Governments in China. Modern China 36 (1):47-78.

255