Karl Marx and the Marxist School

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Karl Marx and the Marxist School See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/321255666 Karl Marx and the Marxist School Working Paper · November 2017 DOI: 10.13140/RG.2.2.27320.03847 CITATIONS READS 0 15,446 1 author: Scott Carter University of Tulsa 19 PUBLICATIONS 59 CITATIONS SEE PROFILE Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects: From Pool of Profits to Surplus and Deficit Industries View project All content following this page was uploaded by Scott Carter on 23 November 2017. The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. 1 Karl Marx and the Marxist School Scott Carter, The University of Tulsa ([email protected])1 • Marx was a working class revolutionary thinker whose economic theories were designed for a mass working class audience • Marx’s economic thought developed as a sustained critique of Classical Political Economy and addressed many of the short-comings in the labor theory of value of that approach • Marx’s method of historical materialism considers social formations as evolving and developing from earlier forms often through revolutionary struggle • Marx’s contribution to the Classical labor theory of value includes the notion of the value of labor power and theory of surplus-value defined as the exploitation of the unpaid labor of workers • Marx’s theory of surplus value expresses itself in an understanding of the division of the working-day into necessary and surplus labor time which serves as the foundation upon which his economic theories are built • Marx’s economic theories are rich and includes among other things theories of accumulation, circuits of revenue and capital, schemes of social reproduction, crisis theory and the falling rate of profit, the reserve army of labor, and the transformation of values into prices of production 0. Introductory Few figures in the history of economic thought have been the source of more controversy, ranging from complete scorn and vilification to sanctification and adulation, than Karl Heinrich Marx (1818- 1883). Marx was a philosopher, profoundly deep social thinker, political economist, and working- class intellectual and revolutionary. Marx was a mighty thinker with a very fertile mind of immense prowess and intellectual stature upon whose work the Marxist School is founded. But Marx’s impact is not limited to the School that bears his name, as many Schools of thought - friend and foe alike - owe a tremendous debt of gratitude to the Old Moor, as Marx was affectionately called by his friends, ostensibly due to his dark complexion and coarse hair. Marx’s economic theory as devised by the Master himself was intended to be revolutionary and written from the historical perspective of a class-conscious revolutionary proletariat and working- class. Whether or not this necessarily matters in terms of the analytics of Marx’s economic theory strictly-speaking is a subject of some debate, as there are certain authors that argue the “partisan political revolutionary” elements need to be separated from the “objective economic” in appraisals of Marx’s overall merit in terms of an economic theoretician (see for example Morishima 1973, pp.4-5). But for Marx the theory was explicitly developed through active struggle as a working-class 1 Associate Professor, Department of Economics, The University of Tulsa, Oklahoma, USA. Chapter to appear in Hassan Bougrine and Louis-Philippe Rochon A Short History Of Economic Thought: Major Contributions since Adam Smith, (forthcoming Edward Elgar). 2 perspective on, and understanding of, the capitalist mode of production. One commentator writes that: “Marx wrote his political economy for what he hoped would be a mass working-class audience; whatever its actual reception, it was intended as a weapon in the class struggle” (King 1980, p. 370). Marx considered his approach advancing the mantle of political economy as a science beyond what, in the Afterward to the Second German Edition of Das Kapital, he called the “bourgeois horizon” that had confounded the Classical Political Economy of his predecessors, namely Adam Smith (1723-90), David Ricardo (1772-1823), Thomas Robert Malthus (1766-1834), and John Stuart Mill (1806-73) to name some of the most important figures in that approach (MECW, Vol. 35, p. 14; Fowkes. p. 96). 2 It is important also to understand that although Marx is most associated with theories of socialism and communism, in fact the overwhelming majority of his inquiries concerned only capitalism. Marx and the school of thought he inspired approaches the study of capitalism through the lens of historic-specificity, by which is meant that capitalism as a mode of production has a lifespan of its own: it was born at a specific historical juncture, has matured since that time in ways that have often been remarkably transformative, and eventually it will die and give way to post-capitalist socio-economic formations. This is a unique feature of the Marxist School that as discussed below relies heavily on the Marxian method of historical materialism. 1. Marx in the history of economic thought The history of economic thought is unlike the history of most other sciences in that the development of ideas does not proceed in a linear fashion where early notions once shown to be “wrong” are jettisoned in favor of newer ones that are shown to be “right”. Economic thought instead proceeds zig-zag like, with starts and stops such that many years later (sometimes decades and/or centuries), ideas thought to be long dead are revived and given modern polish and relevance. This attribute arises because some of the most fundamental foundational building blocks of economic science still to this day remain unresolved. Nowhere is this more obvious than the theory of value and price, and it is from that perch the present study of Marx and the Marxist school begins. By theory of value we mean the theory or explanation that underlies the exchange relation observed in social formations governed by the market mechanism, where goods and services are produced for 2 To facilitate study of the original material which readers are strongly encouraged to do, quotes by Marx from Capital Volume I are cited from two alternative sources: (i) Marx-Engels Collected Works (MECW) Vol. 35 where Volume I falls; and (ii) citation from the Ben Fowkes translation originally published in 1976 by Vintage Press and later picked up by Penguin Classics. The Fowkes translation is the edition studied by the present writer in graduate school, etc., although the trend lately is to cite from the Collected Works so as to facilitate study across the corpus the writings of Marx and Engels. All citations in the present essay are from MECW. The Marx-Engels Collected Works (complied between 1975 and 2005) is a 50-volume set of the works of Marx and Engels translated from original German Marx-Engels-Gesamtausgabe (MEGA) into English originally arranged by the Institute of Marxism-Leninism in Moscow and published by Lawrence & Wishart in the UK in collaboration with International Publishers in the USA under the auspice of an international commission of scholars from the then-USSR and later Russian Republic, USA, and UK. Interested readers can find freely available online versions and transcriptions of the entire MECW as well as a plethora of other resources at the Marxist Internet Archive (https://www.marxists.org/). 3 exchange thereby fetching a unit-price, and whose allocation is garnered through exchange of commodities for money (“buying”) and money for commodities (“selling”). It is important to emphasize that the exchange relation is an objective condition faced in market societies, and the role of economic science is (or at least should be) to provide cogent, logically-consistent, and robust explanations for this objective fact. To illustrate consider the following heuristic example. Let there be two different goods, A and B. Suppose that in the market it is observed that 2 units of A (2A) costs the same as 1 unit of B (1B), and that for simplicity that cost is $1. This says that for one dollar buyers can purchase 2 units of A and for the same dollar they can alternatively purchase 1 unit of B. The question any theory of value must try to answer is, why? What is it about 2A that makes it equal in value to 1B, such that for the same $1 buyers can purchase these very different quantities of these very different things? To this question economic thought has forwarded broadly speaking at least two different underlying mechanisms. For the earlier Classical Political Economy approach beginning around the 1700s until 1870, it was posited that 2A = 1B due to equal expenditure in production for the different quantities of the different goods, with that cost being reduced to labor-time objectively expended or bestowed in production according to the socially average level of technology of the day. For the later approach of Neoclassical Economics beginning in 1870 until the present, the selfsame exchange relation is explained as a function of the equal amounts of utility or satisfaction the subjective individual receives when consuming 2A as he/she does when consuming 1B, with the further caveat that this occurs at the margin of constrained choice. Both theories contain a similar methodological character in that sought for in explaining the exchange between any two objects for sale is a “common third” (Kurz 2013, p. 46). In the early labor theory of value (LTV) this “common third” is commensurable quantities of socially-necessary labor time in production, and in the later marginal utility theory of value (MUTV) the “common third” is commensurable quantities of utility at the margin of constrained choice. To illustrate this, a brief account of the history of thought is shown in Figure 1 below.
Recommended publications
  • Keynes's Investment Theory As a Micro-Foundation for His Grandchildren
    Vol. 14, 2020-24 | July 03, 2020 | http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2020-24 Keynes's investment theory as a micro-foundation for his grandchildren Sergio Nisticò Abstract In contrast with the ‘missing micro-foundations’ argument against Keynes’s macro- economics, the paper argues that it is the present state of microeconomics that needs more solid ‘Keynesian foundations’. It is in particular Keynes’s understanding of investors’ behaviour that can be fruitfully extended to consumption theory, in a context in which consumers are considered as entrepreneurs, buying goods and services to engage in time- consuming activities. The paper emphasizes that the outcome in terms of enjoyment is particularly uncertain for those innovative and path-breaking activities, which Keynes discussed in his 1930 prophetic essay about us, the grandchildren of his contemporaries. Moreover, the Keynes-inspired microeconomics suggested in the paper provides an explanation of why Keynes’s prophecy about his grandchildren possibly expanding leisure did not materialize yet. The paper finally points at the need for appropriate economic policies supporting consumers’ propensity to enforce innovative forms of time use. JEL B41 D11 D81 Keywords Keynesian microeconomics; consumption; time use; uncertainty; Keynes’s grandchildren Authors Sergio Nisticò, Creativity and Motivations Economic Research Center, Department of Economics and Law, University of Cassino and Southern Lazio, Italy, [email protected] Citation Sergio Nisticò (2020). Keynes's investment theory as a micro-foundation for his grandchildren. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, 14 (2020-24): 1–15. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2020-24 Received January 22, 2020 Published as Economics Discussion Paper February 14, 2020 Revised June 8, 2020 Accepted June 18, 2020 Published July 3, 2020 © Author(s) 2020.
    [Show full text]
  • A History of Economic Thought Isaac Ilych Rubin
    H. H. P y B M H A History of Economic Thought MCTOPMJI. by 3K0H0MMHECK0R Isaac Ilych Rubin MblC/IM Translated and edited by Donald Filtzei K30AHHE TPETbS co Bioporo aono^HEHHoro Poc/dapimatHHQio Ytewto Coatma Afterword tonyu&HO 4 xanetmu jr*t6noto MCOOUM 9M tyso* by Catherine Colliot-Thelene LINKS rOCyflAPCTBEHHOE H3^ATE^bCTBO MOCKBA * 1 9 2 9 * /lEHHHfPAJl Isaac Ilych Rubin was born in Russia in 1886 In 1905 he became an active participant in the 75 Russian revolutionary movement After the Bolshevik seizure of power he worked as a .^7/3 professor of Marxist economics and in 1926 became research associate at the Marx-Engels Institute In 1930 he was airested. An official Soviet philosopher wrote that: 'The followers First published as htoriya ekonomicheskoi of Rubin and. the Menshevizing Idealists. mydi (Gosizdat RSFSR) This translation treated Marx's revolutionary method in the taken, with the permission of the New York spirit.,, of Hegelianism The Communist Public Library, from a copy of the second Party has smashed these trends alien to Marx- printing of the second, revised Russian edition ism'. (Rosenthal, quoted by Rornan Rozdolsky (1929) in that library's possession in The Making of Marx's Capital?) Rubin was Ihis edition first published in 1979 by imprisoned, accused of belonging to an organi- Ink Links Ltd., zation that never existed, forced to 'confess' to 271, Kentish Town Road participating in events that never took place, London NW5 2JS and finally removed from among the living Between 1924 and 1930 Rubin completed Translation
    [Show full text]
  • Thomas Hodgskin and Economic Progress; a Radical Reconstruction of His Endogenous Growth Theory
    THOMAS HODGSKIN AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS; A RADICAL RECONSTRUCTION OF HIS ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY F.G. Day PhD 2009 THOMAS HODGSKIN AND ECONOMIC PROGRESS; A RADICAL RECONSTRUCTION OF HIS ENDOGENOUS GROWTH THEORY Frederick George Day A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements of the Manchester Metropolitan University for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Department of Economics The Manchester Metropolitan University June 2009 1 Declaration I confirm that no part of this thesis has been submitted for the award of a qualification at this or any other university. 2 Abstract By means of a close reading of early 19th century economic works, and by reconstructing aspects of Thomas Hodgskin‘s political economy, this thesis presents an exposition of those parts of his work that contributed to his position on growth. Rather than concentrating on his ideas on capital, we have centred on his concept of political economy as a science concerned with labour as the sole creator of wealth. We present his political economy as having labour as its focal point within a hypothetical pure market economy. From here he sought a foundation to economic growth derived from human action rather than capital or other material circumstances. Hodgskin saw human knowledge and the use of technology as the starting point that would, from his perspective, lead inevitably to those economic conditions that produce improvements in economic welfare and by doing so allow for an increase in population. In order to demonstrate his ideas on growth, we reconstruct his concepts of what was natural and artificial to equate to the modern notions of endogenous and exogenous.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Marginal Revolution
    MARGINAL REVOLUTION It took place in the later half of the 19th century Stanley Jevons in England, Carl Menger in Austria and Leon walras at Lausanne, are generally regarded as the founders of marginalist school Hermann Heinrich Gossen of Germany is considered to be the anticipator of the marginalist school The term ‘Marginal Revolution’ is applied to the writings of the above economists because they made fundamental changes in the apparatus of economic analysis They started looking at some of the important economic problems from an altogether new angle different from that of classical economists Marginal economists has been used to analyse the single firm and its behavior, the market for a single product and the formation of individual prices Marginalism dominated Western economic thought for nearly a century until it was challenged by Keynesian attack in 1936 (keynesian economics shifted the sphere of enquiry from micro economics to macro economics where the problems of the economy as a whole are analysed) The provocation for the emergence of marginalist school was provided by the interpretation of classical doctrines especially the labour theory of value and ricardian theory of rent by the socialists Socialists made use of classical theories to say things which were not the intention of the creators of those theories So the leading early marginalists felt the need for thoroughly revising the classical doctrines especially the theory of value They thought by rejecting the labour theory of value and by advocating the marginal utility theory of value, they could strike at the theoretical basis of socialism Economic Ideas of Marginalist School This school concentrated on the ‘margin’ to explain economic phenomena.
    [Show full text]
  • Evolution and Refinement of the Concept of Supply and Demand from Cournot to Marshall Ray Mcdermott
    Evolution and Refinement of the Concept of Supply and Demand from Cournot to Marshall Ray McDermott Table of Contents Page Introduction 1 John Stuart Mill 2 Augustin Cournot 5 J. H. von Thunen 7 Hermann Heinrich Gossen 8 Fleeming Jenkin 10 William Stanley Jevons 13 Carl Menger 19 Leon Walras 21 Aspects of Marginal Theory as set by Jevons, Menger and Walras 28 Rudolf Auspitz and Richard Lieben 47 Alfred Marshall 52 Conclusion 66 Bibliography 67 ALUMNI MEMORIAL LIBRARY Creighton University Omaha; Nebraika 65178 fc v 385843 “ *** '••v.i-fii. Evolution and Refinement of the Concept of Supply and Demand from Cournot to Marshall The law of supply and demand can be restated in mathematical language. Fleeming Jenkin did this. As one looks at the correspondence between the economists of an eighty year period (Cournot to Marshall), thinking can be clarified on the discussion of supply and demand. Relationships are shown between these economists. There are similar­ ities as well as differences in their thinking. Disagreements on terminology pertaining to utility theory is evident between Jevons, Walras, and Menger. Priority on thoughts about utility was claimed and disputed between Jevons and Walras. Marshall was annoyed by Jevons* theory. Marshall, Walras, and Mill were all directed by their fathers in the classics. Lecturing at various universities was common for Jevons, Marshall, Walras, and Menger. Some however were not trained economists. Examples of these were Jenkin, Cournot, and von Thunen. Jevons, Menger, and Walras were the founders of the Marginal Utility School. The economists are not discussed according to the chronological time in which they lived.
    [Show full text]
  • Why to Worry About the Wealth of Nations: Technological Unemployment, Unequal Distribution and Secular Stagnation
    Why to Worry about the Wealth of Nations: Technological Unemployment, Unequal Distribution and Secular Stagnation Timon Scheuer October 14, 2016 Abstract Persistent unemployment challenges politics of today. The cure commonly prescribed is economic growth. While technological progress should still provide the necessary productivity gains, their interdepen- dency to the role allocation of private capitalism may also be an ori- gin or at least a magnifier of stagnation in the first place. In order to investigate these interdependencies the paper takes a system per- spective. Within a correspondingly aggregate model technical change affects needs of consumers, expectations of producers and productivity in different ways. Applying a corresponding set of equations in discrete time steps then allows for simulations of exemplary scenarios. In ab- sence of public interventions and institutions the stability of the system and its growth path strongly depends on the mixture of process and product innovation. If the latter fails to overcome temporary limita- tions of needs and expectations, the lack of demand may induce a loop of unemployment and stagnation. This risk increases with disparity, which itself may be triggered by certain forms of technical change in the first place. PROCEEDING OF A PRELIMINARY PRESENTED AT THE YOUNG ECONOMIST CONFERENCE 1 1 Introduction Social scientists know the name of Adam Smith (1776, [2006]) and his fa- mous `Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations`. He may even be seen as the father of economic liberalism emphasizing the role of spreading market interactions, the division of labour and the accumula- tion of capital in order to achieve productivity gains and boost economic growth (Sturn, 2008, pp.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Economic Thought: Its Evolution and Its Contribution to Consumer Behavior
    A Great Revolution in Economics –Vienna 1871 and after Austrian economic thought: its evolution and its contribution to consumer behavior Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen A great REVOLUTION In economics —VIENNA 1871 and after AUSTRIAN ECONOMIC THOUGHT: ITS EVOLUTION AND ITS CONTRIBUTION TO CONSUMER BEHAVIOR Lazaros Th. Houmanidis Auke R. Leen The letter type on the cover is of Arnold Böcklin (Basel 1827-1901 Fiesole). It is a typical example of the Art Nouveau (Jugendstil) style—the fashionable style of art in Vienna at the end of the 19th century (the time older Austrianism came in full swing). In a sense, Böcklin’s work represents the essence of Austrianism: “Never was he interested in the accidental; he wanted the everlasting”. Cereales Foundation, publisher Wageningen University P.O. Box 357, 6700 AJ Wageningen, The Netherlands E [email protected] Printed by Grafisch Service Centrum Van Gils B.V. Cover design by Hans Weggen (Art Director Cereales) © 2001 Lazaros Th. Houmanidis and Auke R. Leen ISBN 90-805724-3-8 In the memory of our beloved colleague JACOB JAN KRABBE PREFACE A Great Revolution in Economics—Vienna 1871 and after is about the revolution in economic thought that started in Vienna in the last quarter of the nineteenth century. After a time of trying to save the objective value theory the time was there for a new awakening of economic thought. In Vienna, for the first time by the 1871 publication of Menger’s Grundsätze, value become subjective, and the market a process with a sovereign consumer. This book is about this awakening that proved to be more than a plaisanterie viennoise.
    [Show full text]
  • Georgescu-Roegen on Gossen. Paola Tubaro
    A tale of two destinies: Georgescu-Roegen on Gossen. Paola Tubaro To cite this version: Paola Tubaro. A tale of two destinies: Georgescu-Roegen on Gossen.. History of Political Economy, Duke University Press, 2014, 46 (1), pp.33-54. 10.1215/00182702-2398921. hal-01354924 HAL Id: hal-01354924 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01354924 Submitted on 20 Aug 2016 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. A tale of two destinies: Georgescu-Roegen on Gossen Paola Tubaro Abstract Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen edited the English translation of Gossen’s book The Laws of Human Relations (1983), and wrote a lengthy introduction to it. His highly appreciative, thoroughly documented study has become a major reference on an otherwise little known early writer. It suggests that Gossen was unjustly ignored by his contemporaries, just as Georgescu-Roegen felt that his own contributions to economics were insufficiently recognized. Yet it was not only a personal motive that inspired Georgescu-Roegen’s editorial enterprise: I show that his original plan was to build a model of consumer choice, with support of hints found in Gossen, to address what he saw as essential theoretical issues.
    [Show full text]
  • Regional Foreign Direct Investment Review
    PROMOTING INDUSTRIAL ZONES AND INVESTMENT MOBILIZATION USAID WB/G SO1: EXPANDING ECONOMIC OPPORTUNITIES CONTRACT NO. 294-C-00-00-00071-00 Regional Foreign Direct Investment Review SUBMITTED ON MAY 20, 2002 TO THE USAID MISSION TO THE WEST BANK AND GAZA MARGOT ELLIS, CTO BY THE SERVICES GROUP (TSG) SUTHERLAND MILLER III, SENIOR CONSULTANT 2300 CLARENDON BOULEVARD 1110 ARLINGTON, VIRGINIA 22201 USA WWW.TSGINC.COM USAID PRIZIM Project Regional Foreign Direct Investment Review Table of Contents Executive Summary i Chapter 1: Introduction and Methodology 1 Chapter 2: Regional Foreign Direct Investment Overview 7 Chapter 3: Sectoral Focus on Information Technology 24 Chapter 4: Sectoral Focus on Apparel and Textiles 48 Chapter 5: Sectoral Focus on Stone and Marble 59 Chapter 6: Conclusion 69 Annex A.1: Top 1,000 Companies in Pre-packaged Software A1-1 Annex A.2: Top 1,000 Companies in Computer Programming A2-1 Annex A.3: Top 1,000 Companies in Apparel Manufacturing A3-1 Annex A.4: Top Companies in Dimension Stone A4-1 The Services Group USAID PRIZIM Project Regional Foreign Direct Investment Review Executive Summary This report summarizes the available data on foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows into the Middle East region, and provides information that can help the Palestinian Investment Promotion Agency (PIPA) target firms for investment promotion. The goal of this document is to better inform PIPA about regional FDI trends and guide their strategic planning for active and successful investment promotion activities. For this analysis regional investment activity was reviewed in detail for three sectors - information technology (IT), apparel manufacturing, and stone and marble - based on the previously completed Investor Targeting Strategy (ITS) completed by The Services Group in 1999.
    [Show full text]
  • Divinization and Neoclassical Economics
    9 Neoclassical economics as a logic of subversion Arpad Szakolczai Subversion is an activity associated with radical politics and art. It means an effort – usually combined with plotting and similar secret, underground activities – to undermine established powers and authorities. However, this paper, in line with the general orientation of the volume, starts from the presumption that we today, all of us, inside the ‘advanced’ world, live in- side subversion. Thus, as the activity of subversion is only apparently self- evident, so better start by exploring the meanings of the word. Dictionary definitions of subversion, and of related terms like ‘under- mine’ and ‘overthrow’, contain three points of interest. Most evidently, such an activity involves a degree of violence; though this is combined with secrecy, a link that will prove to be particularly important. Furthermore, such activities aim with particular vigour not directly at the prevailing pow- ers, trying to avoid a direct – and usually hopeless – confrontation; rather they aim at the foundations. In one reading, subversion tries to inflict blows below the belt; in another, particularly clear in the term ‘undermine’, it op- erates by generating a void,1 into which the entity falls due to its own weight. Finally, all this involves a fundamental reversal of the vertical perspective or order of things: whatever previously was high is brought down, and what- ever was low consequently moves up. Such an idea was central to the Tabula Smaragdina (Linden 2003), a key piece of hermetic writings, while on dif- ferent note ‘turning the world upside down’ also for the activity of circus clowns.
    [Show full text]
  • The Routledge Handbook of Heterodox Economics Theorizing, Analyzing, and Transforming Capitalism Tae-Hee Jo, Lynne Chester, Carlo D'ippoliti
    This article was downloaded by: 10.3.98.104 On: 27 Sep 2021 Access details: subscription number Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: 5 Howick Place, London SW1P 1WG, UK The Routledge Handbook of Heterodox Economics Theorizing, Analyzing, and Transforming Capitalism Tae-Hee Jo, Lynne Chester, Carlo D'Ippoliti The social surplus approach Publication details https://www.routledgehandbooks.com/doi/10.4324/9781315707587.ch3 Nuno Ornelas Martins Published online on: 28 Jul 2017 How to cite :- Nuno Ornelas Martins. 28 Jul 2017, The social surplus approach from: The Routledge Handbook of Heterodox Economics, Theorizing, Analyzing, and Transforming Capitalism Routledge Accessed on: 27 Sep 2021 https://www.routledgehandbooks.com/doi/10.4324/9781315707587.ch3 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR DOCUMENT Full terms and conditions of use: https://www.routledgehandbooks.com/legal-notices/terms This Document PDF may be used for research, teaching and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproductions, re-distribution, re-selling, loan or sub-licensing, systematic supply or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The publisher shall not be liable for an loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material. 3 The social surplus approach Historical origins and present state Nuno Ornelas Martins Introduction For classical political economists, the social surplus is the part of production that is not necessary for the reproduction of the existing social system.
    [Show full text]