<<

The rural informal Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in , timber and

Xiaoxue Weng

Working Paper Keywords: April 2015 , Rural development, Livelihoods, Small-scale farming, , Artisanal and small-scale mining (ASM) About the authors Xiaoxue Weng, Researcher, Natural Resources Group, IIED Acknowledgements The author of this paper is grateful for the invaluable inputs provided by Bill Vorley, Emma Blackmore and Lila Buckley of IIED, the coordination support offered by Kate Lewis and Laura Jenks of IIED as well as the editorial assistance of Nicole Kenton. Produced by IIED’s Sustainable Markets Group The Sustainable Markets Group drives IIED’s efforts to ensure that markets contribute to positive social, environmental and economic outcomes. The group brings together IIED’s on governance, business models, market failure, consumption, investment and the economics of climate change.

Published by IIED, April 2015 Xiaoxue Weng. 2015. The rural informal economy: Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining. IIED Working Paper. IIED, London. http://pubs.iied.org/16590IIED ISBN 978-1-78431-172-8 Printed on recycled paper with vegetable-based .

International Institute for Environment and Development 80-86 Gray’s Inn , London WC1X 8NH, UK Tel: +44 (0)20 3463 7399 Fax: +44 (0)20 3514 9055 email: [email protected] www.iied.org @iied www.facebook.com/theIIED Download more publications at www.iied.org/pubs IIED Working PAPER

The informal economy – broadly defined as economic activity that is not subject to government regulation or taxation – supports some of the most vulnerable in society. In sub-Saharan Africa, it generates 90 per cent of opportunities in some countries, and contributes up to 38 per cent of GDP in others. In rural areas, the informal economy sustains livelihoods of impoverished populations through natural resource and land based economic activities such as farming, logging and mining. The rural informal economy is messy and complex: activities are at times classified as illegal yet are often rooted in traditional resource and land rights. Local may receive significant income, but sustainability of resource use is a pressing concern as informal trade increasingly serves ever-expanding urban and international markets. This paper examines the drivers and livelihood implications of informality in agriculture, logging, and mining in sub-Saharan Africa. It finds commonalities and differences across three areas: rights, regulations and economic factors. Aimed at researchers and practitioners, the paper demonstrates that development interventions in resource governance need to be strongly grounded in the complex reality of the rural informal economy in order to benefit impoverished communities.

Contents

Executive summary 4 4 Timber 15 Rights 15 1 Introduction 5 Regulation 17 What is informality? 5 Economics 17 Rural informality 5 Objective and methodology 7 5 Mining 18 Rights 18 2 A framework for analysis 8 Regulation 19 Spatial scales of inquiry 8 Economics 19 Key areas of inquiry 8 6 Conclusion 21 3 Agriculture 12 Rights 12 References 23 Regulation 14 Economics 14

www.iied.org 3 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining Executive summary

The informal economy is huge and expanding across The main findings of this paper are as follows: sub-Saharan Africa – it generates 90 per cent of • The key drivers of rural informality across the selected employment opportunities in some countries and sectors include persisting customary rights and contributes up to 38 per cent of GDP in others. It norms, exclusionary and costly regulations for rural supports some of the most vulnerable people in society: actors, as well as high economic profits for - women, youth and the rural poor. stricken communities. The rural informal economy (economic activities • Commonalities across the three sectors are performed by rural populations linked to informal trading the concomitance of complex informal rules, and markets) in particular is critical to rural livelihoods. the participation of government officials and Rural informality largely relates to the natural resource informality practiced as a form of resistance against base on which local people rely for their living, i.e. unjust legislation, as well as very few successful agricultural production and the extraction of natural policy interventions. resources (e.g. timber and ). Although at times equated with illegality and thus facing strong • Differences, on the other hand, include the origin pressure to formalise, informal sector activities are in of consumer demand (domestic or international), fact rooted in customary land and resource governance rights granted to rural populations (land norms traditionally practiced by local communities. The rights may be granted but forest and mining rights rural informal economy – in particular its drivers and reserved for the state), as well as varying degrees of livelihood impacts across sectors – has received little illegality (more pronounced in timber and mining). attention to date. The paper also suggests a future research agenda. This paper analyses the drivers and livelihood impacts Ultimately informality is, in fact, the daily reality of natural of informality in agriculture, logging and mining. An resource extraction and production for a large part of analytical framework is presented that focuses on rights, the population in sub-Saharan Africa. Policymakers, regulations and economics as key areas of inquiry. researchers and practitioners should acknowledge its These areas are then examined at three spatial scales: ubiquity and recognise its complexity in research and the political economy, value chains, and rural actors. policy . Future development interventions aiming to reduce poverty need to be strongly grounded in the reality of the rural informal economy.

4 www.iied.org IIED Working paper 1 Introduction

What is informality? Rural informality The informal economy – broadly defined as economic Rural informality, this paper’s focus, is critical to rural activity that is not subject to government regulation, development prospects across sub-Saharan Africa. taxation or observation (Schneider 2002) – has become Studies of the informal economy have on the whole a ‘contemporary governance dilemma’ in international pivoted around urban informality. Both Hart (1973) and development (Benson et al. 2014, p.15). Its scale is de Soto (1979), the field’s progenitors, conceptualised colossal: more than half the global toils in informality against the backdrop of urban and the informal sector; in some African countries such as Peru. The rural informal economy – economic activities Tanzania and Zambia, up to 90 per cent of jobs are performed by rural populations linked to informal unofficial (ILO 2009). The informal economy accounts trading and markets – has in contrast received scant for up to 38 per cent of the GDP in some sub-Saharan attention. Rural informality merits urgent attention African countries (ibid.), and its dimensions are from development researchers, practitioners and expanding across the board (Vorley et al. 2012). The policymakers for at least five reasons: informal sector is not peripheral to the formal economy First, it provides a critical livelihood option for and should thus be examined as a basic component of the rural poor. Most farmers across sub-Saharan the total economy (Chen 2007). Africa rely on informal networks to access their markets. Informality is traditionally associated with undesirable Communities also increasingly diversify their income development outcomes such as , beyond farming; non-farm work, mostly in the informal unregulated enterprises, environmental degradation sector, now accounts for 40–45 per cent of the average and illegal activities (Benson et al. 2014). Some rural household income in the region (Start 2001). As practitioners and researchers now increasingly view it non-farm work is associated with higher income and as a pathway for (Chen 2012). Recent wealth, informal activities may offer ‘a pathway out of studies have substantiated the connection between poverty’ in rural Africa (Barrett et al. 2001, p.2). It also informality and vulnerable populations, showing that presents employment opportunities to the rural youth informal economy participants typically lack legal and among whom is high and livelihood (ibid.). The informal sector draws options scarce (Palmer 2007). women (Barrientos et al. 2003), youth (Proctor & Lucchesi 2012), and rural communities that rely on natural resources and land for their livelihoods (Scoones 1998; Spiegel 2012).

www.iied.org 5 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

Second, sustainability and environmental mercury in ), and the trading of protected degradation are key areas of concern because species. Even within the same sector, the degree of the rural economy hinges on natural resources such as illegality may vary depending on national legislation. For land, timber and minerals (Scoones 2009). Whereas example, while chainsaw loggers in Ghana are illegal government has regulatory power over companies in (both their status and operations), their Cameroonian the formal economy (at least in theory), controlling the counterparts are legal in their status if licensed, but may activities of informal sector enterprises, for instance under-report or trade in protected species. Finally, mercury use in mining and chainsaw use in logging, one may coin the same activity differently according is a formidable task due to the dispersed and at times to one’s interest. The term ‘illegal’ may be used to clandestine nature of their operations. encourage compliance with regulations, which implicitly asserts the legitimacy and appropriateness of the formal Third, communities have long developed informal rules regardless of the needs and customary practices rules to manage resources; this traditional of rural communities. The term ‘informal’, in contrast, informality is now increasingly coalescing with may be used to intimate the decriminalisation of rural regional and global markets. Informality is nothing small-scale farmers, loggers and miners who fail to new to rural populations; they have over centuries comply with the formal rules due to a number of reasons developed customary – today considered ‘informal’ – which are explained later. Therefore it is important not norms and institutions to govern land and resources to equate informality with illegality, or generalise the (Richards 1997; Agrawal & Gibson 1999). A prime relationship between the two so not to criminalise the example is customary land rights, which predate colonial rural poor who undertake these activities. Informality is land titling and allocation. Rural communities engaged sector-, country- and user- specific. in agriculture, or mining, hardly questioned the legitimacy of their activities. But globalisation and Fifth, the informal economy faces strong economic development increasingly link Africa’s remote pressures to formalise from businesses, NGOs, areas with urban and global markets though better donors and policymakers – often without infrastructure, efficient , outside investors sufficient consideration for rural livelihoods. The and demand for cheap products. The increased value mainstream development intervention presupposes that of trades also attracts the state and its governing elites formalising the informal is good for poverty reduction. to sanction, tax and regulate the economic activities The following ILO statement (ILO 2011 in Becker 2004) of the countryside. As a result, the traditional informal epitomises this: practices of rural communities now interface with the “The fundamental challenge posed by the informal rules and regulations of urban and global markets. The economy is how to integrate it into the formal age-old informality rooted in customary norms now co- economy. It is a matter of equity and social solidarity. evolves with formal rules; together they form a resilient Policies must encourage movement away from the rural informal economy parallel to – and interacting with informal economy.” – the formal economy. This has important implications for rural development in sub-Saharan Africa. This orthodoxy has engendered numerous reforms in land, forest and governance in sub-Saharan Fourth, informal is often lumped together with Africa in the last three decades. It has also fuelled ‘illegal’ activities; this requires clarification. In fact, international initiatives including ‘sustainabilising’ large the shades of illegality in informal activities differ across corporations’ agriculture supply chains, advocating sectors and countries. Whereas the term ‘illegality’ in timber legality (e.g. the ’s Forest Law the context of smallholder agriculture may chiefly pertain Enforcement Governance and Trade and Voluntary to the non-declaration of taxes and a lack of registration, Agreements), and promoting conflict-free it may, in the context of informal timber and mining, mineral production (e.g. the Dodd-Frank Act of the US extend to issues such as no license registration, under- government). However some of these initiatives have not reporting, employment without contracts or proper sufficiently accounted for the needs of rural populations registration, the use of banned inputs of production (e.g.

6 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

– if not by design, then in their implementation. This has precipitated the exclusion of already-marginalised Objective and methodology small-scale producers and operators (Putzel et al. This working paper aims to initiate a discussion among 2014; Vorley 2013; Maconachie & Hilson 2011). researchers and practitioners on the rural informal Many of these informal actors continue to have limited economy, particularly its drivers and livelihood impacts access to public infrastructure and are frequently across the agricultural, timber and mining sectors in pestered by the authorities. Advocates of formalisation sub-Saharan Africa. policies also ignore the resilience and dynamism of The paper focuses in particular on: the informal economy in providing low barriers to entry and serving as a buffer against market recessions • exploring commonalities and differences in drivers to these vulnerable populations (Chambwera et al. and livelihood impacts of informality across the 2011; Vorley et al. 2012; Webb et al. 2009). Before selected sectors; policy intervention, it is therefore critical to understand • testing out an analytical framework to examine rural the complex dynamics of the rural informal economy, informality; and particularly how factors such as customary rights, inadequate regulations and economic benefits may • suggesting next steps for development research on drive informality and affect livelihoods. In order to this topic. do this, this paper presents a multi-scale analytical This paper relies on the review and synthesis of framework in Section 2, which is then used to explore academic and grey literature across a range of fields, common drivers of informality and livelihood impacts in including a conceptual exploration of informality within later sections. resource governance, and rural development, as well as in-depth case studies of informality from each of the three sectors.

www.iied.org 7 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining 2 A framework for analysis

The analytical framework (Figure 1) captures three Finally, rural actor-level analysis helps examine areas of inquiry and three spatial scales, which are key motivations, livelihood choices, and responses to understanding the drivers and livelihood impacts of to policy interventions of rural participants in the rural informality in the three sectors reviewed here. The informaleconomy. key areas are rights, regulation and economics. They are to be examined at three spatial levels: political economy (macro-scale), value chain (meso-scale) and rural actors Key areas of inquiry (micro-scale). The three topics (rights, regulation and economics) are examined using the three spatial levels outlined above. Table 1 summarises the main findings regarding drivers Spatial scales of inquiry and livelihood impacts. Note that the listed drivers are The political economy lens allows for analysis of the interdependent; their complex interplay drives rural macro-level context in which rural informal actors are informality in the three sectors. situated and their informal trading occurs – with a particular focus here on rules (formal and informal), Area 1: Rights power of rural actors (vis-à-vis ruling elites), and Customary rights and norms are strong drivers of rural governance of resource access. Value chain analysis informality. Several studies considering the history of helps elucidate the what, who, where and how of norms and property rights in sub-Saharan Africa have informal trading, the agency of rural producers, confirmed the existence and perpetuation of a pluralistic relationships among actors, and linkages to the formal legal system – one formal system determined by the economy. At this meso-level, the diverse character of state, and one informal system created by communities informality manifests itself through various activities – (Benjamin 2008; Meinzen-Dick & Pradhan 2002). economic agents as well as unregistered enterprises Despite numerous legislative reforms, the resource (Hussmanns 2004). It is instructive to conceptualise governance system used in rural Africa has not changed informality’s heterogeneity in terms of value chains (see from the informal to the formal in a linear manner; rather, Figure 2).

8 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

Figure 1: A conceptual framework

Areas of inquiry

Rights Regulation

Economics

Spatial scales of inquiry

Level 1. Political economy (macro)

Level 3. Rural actors (micro) Rural upstream producers (e.g. chainsaw loggers and millers, artisanal miners, Downstream small holder farmers) Level 2. Value chain (meso) buyers/ consumers

Midstream traders/market

Figure 2: A simple model of an informal value chain

Downstream Upstream rural Mid-stream buyers/consumers producers traders/markets (e.g. consumers, trading (e.g. chainsaw loggers and (e.g. timber and mineral companies sourcing timber millers, artisanal miners, intermediaries, agricultural and minerals for regional/ smallholder farmers) products traders) global trade, local supermarkets sourcing food)

www.iied.org 9 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

Table 1: Summary of rural informality examined across three areas and scales

Political Value chain Rural actors economy (meso-level) (micro-level) (macro-level) Rights • Customary rights and norms • Social licence and trust • Informal activities seen as among informal actors legitimate • Legitimacy of the state and its institutions • ‘Resistance’ against the formal rules Regulation • Exclusionary laws and • Agency of informal actors • How formal rules may or may regulations not address needs of rural • Informal rules of trade actors • Elite capture of resource • Link with formal value chains access • Rural actors’ responses to • Process of legalisation policy interventions • Informality perpetuated by government officials Economics • Global, regional and • Demands from low-income • Poverty domestic economic climates consumers • Income diversification • Rural employment • Informal trading more beyond farm work opportunities profitable than formal • Escaping poverty

the informal and formal have coexisted and co-evolved (Manji 2006). Area 2: Regulation Regulation is another cause for informality in the rural The surviving – and thriving in some instances – economy. First, government laws and regulations may informal institutions and customary rights at the value exclude certain players from the formal economy due chain level generate legitimacy and social licenses to to its registration cost, burdensome bureaucracy and operate among rural producers and traders following corruption (Chambwera et al. 2011). Micro-firms do local customs. This pluralist lens also helps at the rural not earn enough profit to justify these costs and so actors’ level to understand why rural populations may take advantage of formal institutions; thus informality question the legitimacy of the state and its institutions in becomes a logical response for smallholder farmers, governing ‘their’ resources. Indeed, informality is most chainsaw loggers and artisanal miners (Perry et al. rampant in countries where rural communities suffer 2007). Exclusion however also occurs along class and from high levels of inequality in income and political ethnic lines, as the ruling elites capture resource access participation (De Ferranti et al. 2003; Perry et al. 2006). regimes and systematically marginalise other groups These countries are often plagued by elite capture (del Pozo-Vergnes 2013 in Benson et al. 2014). exercised by both elites and organised segments of the middle class (ibid.). As Perry et al. (2007) points out: Informal economic participants – excluded by regulations or not – may yet opt to exit the formal “State capture leads to the generalised perception sphere due to the low quality of the services provided that the state is run for the benefit of the few, thus it by the state and its institutions (Perry et al. 2007), reinforces a social norm of non-compliance with taxes with corruption and harassment from government and regulations, what might be dubbed a ‘ of officials being particularly problematic (Bihunirwa et informality’ (p.13).” al. 2012). This exit explanation stands in stark contrast As many case studies illustrate in later sections, elite to the exclusion one for it affirms the agency of the capture of resources has severe repercussions for informal actors and their preference for the informal creating equitable and effective resource governance sector. Instead of painting small informal businesses systems (Putzel et al. 2014). and entrepreneurs as powerless and at the mercy

10 www.iied.org IIED Working paper of factors beyond their control, studies increasingly Area 3: Economics demonstrate that, in spite of the constraints, they may Above all, the economics simply makes sense for rural prefer the informal economy where they can formulate communities and many other parties such as low- their own rules and tailor the market according to their income consumers in African cities. needs (Chambwera et al. 2011). Examining rural actors’ perception of laws and regulations reveals how state First, poverty (and the ensuing desire to diversify legislations and institutions may or may not account income) drives rural farmers, loggers and miners as well for their interests and needs. Later sections in this as local communities to partake in the informal economy. paper show how rural populations may counter formal Informal activities may be seen as a possible escape rules imposed by the government by creating new route out of poverty (Barrett et al. 2001). Later cases informal rules. demonstrate that they provide critical safety nets and an alternative livelihood option for the poor. Jobseekers, It is also useful to note that informal businesses and in particular the rural youth, turn to the informal sector entrepreneurs – whether excluded or exited – may have if they cannot find work in the formal labour market an active link with the formal economy. Ties between (Becker 2004; Palmer 2007). The informal economy, the informal and formal value chains can be strong in some sectors, also offers a cushion for employment for certain . Large companies and their during global downturns (Chambwera et al. 2011) . traders may source agrifood, timber or mineral products produced informally for domestic or international sales– Second, low-income consumers’ demand for affordable in the process, informal produces become ‘legalised’ also spurs informal production and trading of as they feed into formal value chains. In reverse, formal some products, such as cheap food products and actors such as government officials sometimes actively timber. Rural operators and local communities, as participate in informal activities through, for instance, illustrated later, frequently capture higher economic demanding informal ‘taxation’ for timber, food and benefits from informal activities as opposed to minerals produced in rural areas. formal ones. Using the analytical framework, specific cases of drivers and livelihood impacts in these three areas are explored in the following sections.

www.iied.org 11 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining 3 Agriculture

Smallholders represent 80 per cent of all farms in sub- African governments and international donors alike have Saharan Africa and produce up to 90 per cent of food by and large considered rural small-scale agricultural products in some countries (Livingston et al. 2011) . The production as backward, unsanitary, and the remnants overwhelming majority of these operate informally. In of under-development. They have thus sweated to East Africa, smallholder farming accounts for more than integrate small-scale farmers into modern supply 75 per cent of the total employment and produces 75 chains (Vorley 2013). Some gainsay this formalisation per cent of all agricultural (Bihunirwa et al. 2012). prescription, arguing that informal trade should not simply be seen as a market failure, but rather as an Informal small-scale agriculture in sub-Saharan Africa effective and functional link between rural farmers and plays out in three main ways. Rural self-sufficiency the market (Staal et al. 2006) farming continues to be widespread (the first type). More and more small-scale farmers, however, are linking The drivers of informality in small-scale agriculture – and up to rural and urban markets (the second type). Three how they relate to rural livelihoods – are explored below, out of four Ugandan farmers, for example, were selling using the analytical framework presented in Section 2. some or all of their produce either in markets or to Table 2 presents the key findings. traders in 2005 (IFAD 2011). Small-scale farmers sell to informal traders, who may then sell to consumers in informal food markets, supermarkets or, in some Rights instances, export companies. When informal produce The issue of informality in agriculture pivots around reaches the export supply chain, has effectively become customary land ownership. Indeed, some consider part of the formal economy’s food supply chain and smallholder agriculture legitimate because of thus ‘legalised’. Finally, contracted farmers operating in traditional customary claims on land (FAO n.d.a). For the formal sector have also been known to engage in rural communities, informality is therefore the norm; informal activities (the third type). They may choose to governments, in contrast, see it as an illegitimate or side-sell some of their produce informally to traders for inferior arrangement requiring policy interventions. All various reasons outlined below. While some may term this has engendered the pluralistic system of rights (i.e., their actions illegal, and indeed, side-selling breaches co-existence of informal and formal rules), described contracts and is banned in some countries, rural farmers in Section 2. Some land tenure reforms have actually might yet view their behaviours as unproblematic and a attempted to integrate customary rules and ownership logical response to the economic pressures they face, into legislative frameworks, yet implementation has been ultimately capitalising on both the formal and informal problematic (Pacheco et al. 2008; Fitzpatrick 2005). In channels of trade available to them. particular, the titling and land allocation progresses have antagonised rural communities in some countries, who responded by rejecting the new rules and reverting back to informal norms that they consider legitimate (Pacheco et al. 2008).

12 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

Table 2: Summary of findings in agriculture

Political Value chain Rural actors economy Rights • Customary land tenure • Strong social trust among • Informal activities equally producers and traders, or more legitimate form • Co-existence of customary which enables the creation of operation than formal rules and formal rules of informal institutions (the production case of Matooke producers • Unjust regulations and laws in Uganda) imposed by the state without consultation • ‘Resistance’ in the form of deliberate negligence against unjust formal rules Regulation • Global supply chain • Conforming with formal • Policy reforms need to initiatives: upgrade to higher rules – particularly collective support informal actors’ value chains as the motto organisation and registration interests (key to success as but do not focus on markets –challenges traditional in the case of ’s dairy of the poor social hierarchy reform) • Farmers increasingly have one foot in informal and another in formal • Farmers resilient and strong agency in the informal economy • The gender angle often neglected in and producers’ associations Economics • Low global • Demands from urban low- • Poverty prices affect farmers income consumers • A lack of alternative negatively, which • Informal trading more livelihood options encourages side-selling profitable for farmers than formal markets • Informal traders offer various advantages

Informal norms generate trust and social license to diversification’ rather than the principal mode of operate among informal producers and traders. Trust operation to which the farmers need to subscribe obtained from social capital effectively acts as a control (Vorley et al. 2012). In cases where land reform, titling mechanism in the informal market (Benson et al. 2014; and allocation were seen as unjust and lacking local Bihunirwa et al. 2012). In the case of Ugandan matooke consultation in Ghana, studies have observed that (cooking bananas), for example, a complex collective farmers may actively ignore the new rules – a form organisation system forms each harvest season. of resistance against formality imposed by the state Producers and sellers synchronise prices, volumes sold, (Blocher 2006; Kasanga & Kotey 2001). and locations of informal trading centres through their social relations (Bihunirwa et al. 2012). For rural farmers cultivating their customary lands, Regulation informal farming (e.g. without permits or tax Smallholders are generally able to create and shape declarations) is at least equally, if not more, legitimate market rules in the informal economy, making them than state-sanctioned production; formality in this resilient and autonomous economic actors (Vorley regard is best considered as ‘another way of income et al. 2012). But they may struggle when having to

www.iied.org 13 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

organise for selling in the formal markets as required the other in formal institutions’ (Bihunirwa et al. 2012, by regulations. Indeed, collective organisation – most p.2). Side-selling of cotton by smallholders in Malawi commonly in the form of producers’ associations or and Zimbabwe is widespread, for example, in spite cooperatives – poses significant challenges to the of contractual obligations (Minot 2011). Pervasive social structure and power relationships traditionally side-selling typifies the blend of informal-formal practiced among communities (Leahy & Goforth 2014). trading strategies employed by smallholders. Farmers Studies also show that rural unions and cooperatives are continuously assessing the benefits and costs often inadequately represent the interests of women, of informal and formal operations – and possibly a who make up a significant portion of rural farmers combination of the two – to make ‘markets work in their (see e.g. Barrientos et al. 2003). Effective regulations favour’ (Bihunirwa et al. 2012). must also be designed to support the interests of informal actors. Rather than penalising incompliance, Kenya’s dairy reform measures actively supported some Economics 800,000 informal milk vendors, providing incentives for Economic forces are a strong driver of informality in registration (Kaitibie et al. 2010). African governments smallholder agriculture. When low global agricultural intent on formalising smallholder agriculture would need commodity prices diminish rural farmers’ earnings, to take these issues into account in their policy design. contract farmers may be forced to find alternative Global initiatives designed to encourage small sources of income and may engage in side-selling producers to upgrade to high-value supply chains (Minot 2011). A key reason for why rural farmers engage may also affect rural livelihoods (Vorley 2013). Many in informal as opposed to formal trading is the higher of these initiatives work with multinational companies profit margin. Side-selling not only puts more money to integrate small-scale producers into their value into the rural farmers’ pockets (as informal traders offer chains (e.g., Unilever’s fair and sustainable supply better prices), but it also allows them to overcome chain initiative). Schemes tend to work with better constraints such as high levels of repayment and the organised and capitalised producers, however, and lack of information on purchase prices until the harvest not with the poorest of the poor who operate in the (Minot 2011; FAO n.d.b). In addition, as illustrated informal economy (Vorley & Thorpe 2014). Another by the oilseeds trade in Uganda, informal traders line of criticism contends that the emphasis on linking promise timely cash transactions, no costs, small-scale farmers to export markets is only after less strict quality controls, and room for negotiation making ‘markets for the poor’, diverting attention from (Vorley et al. 2015). supporting ‘markets of the poor’, i.e. the domestic The growing numbers of low-income consumers in informal agrifood markets where most small farmers African cities, who demand cheap food products, has make their living (Murphy 2012). also undergirded informality in rural agriculture. Informal This does not mean, however, that the informal and agrifood markets have become the place where poor the formal do not mix. At the value chain level, some producers and consumers’ interests meet (Benson agriproducts link informal smallholders to the formal et al. 2014). In Kenyan cities, for example, informal economy. Many ‘modern’ agriproduct value chains in milk trading has been commonplace in recent years sub-Saharan Africa often start with informal transactions despite the government’s efforts to clamp down. The upstream – farmers selling to local traders – with formal government was unsuccessful in keeping small-scale arrangements only introduced later in the supply chain milk vendors out of the cities because of ‘overwhelming (Vorley et al. 2012). It is common for rural traders to consumer demands’ (Hooton & Omore 2008, p.7). have ‘one foot in informal trading relationships and

14 www.iied.org IIED Working paper 4 Timber

Across the forest-rich African countries in the Congo The legalistic approach turns a blind eye to the Basin rainforests and the miombo woodlands, informal importance of the informal sector to rural livelihoods timber production1 using chainsaws is an important (Cerutti et al. 2013; Mafro 2010). Below, using the livelihood choice for the rural poor. Chainsaw logging analytical framework, we explore why and how rural and milling – defined as the on-site conversion of logs indigents participate in the informal economy, and into for commercial purposes using chainsaws the benefits they receive to make ends meet. Table 3 – carried out in an informal manner may refer to logging, presents the key findings. milling and trading without licenses, or harvesting more than permitted by law (Wit et al. 2010). The legal status of informal loggers and millers varies. Some Rights countries grant them licences for small-scale harvest Customary norms and rights, just as in agriculture, play volumes (e.g. Cameroon), whereas others, such as a central role in driving informality in chainsaw logging Ghana, ban their activities entirely (Hansen et al. 2012; and milling. Cerutti and Lescuyer 2011). Government officials, donors and environmental activists have for the most Forest-dependent communities across sub-Saharan part criminalised small-scale chainsaw operators. Africa have long managed their forest resources using ‘Illegal loggers’, they advocate, should face stricter law traditional norms and rights. Governments started to enforcement and punishments for their informal trading usurp rural communities during the colonial era by (see e.g. UNEP 2012; Environmental Investigation setting up industrial logging operations for timber export Agency 2012). to Europe. Today’s governments continue to hold sway over forest resources (Larson et al. 2010). The creation What escapes their thinking, however, is the staggering of forest laws, some argue, redefined which rules were scale of informal timber production in the region and legal and which were not – in some instances, it was its de facto dominance as the sole supplier for the those customary practices that were non-conforming domestic market. Figure 3 illustrates that informal to the state’s interest that were made illegal (Peluso & production surpassed its formal counterpart in DRC Vandergeest 2001). Customary norms, however, still and Cameroon and rivalled that of the Republic of persist in rural Africa; most sub-Saharan forest-rich the Congo. While industrial formal logging almost regions today are governed by a complex interplay and exclusively serves the export market, most domestic co-existence of informal (customary) and formal rules. demand for timber in the region is met by rural chainsaw loggers and millers who receive strong support Forests ownership rights, in contrast to land rights, from low-income consumers, local communities and remain predominantly in the hands of the state across some government officials (Lescuyer & Cerutti 2013; sub-Saharan Africa (Lawry et al. 2012). Whereas Mafro 2010). customary land titles are often recognised in legal

1 Note that the informal timber production described in this section focuses on chainsaw milling by small-scale rural operators; it should be differentiated from industrial-level production by large companies that commit illegal activities (e.g. a lack of licence, incompliance with management plans, etc.).

www.iied.org 15 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

Figure 3: Informal timber production share in Central Africa

100 1400000 90 87% 1200000 80 70 1000000 ) in 2009 3 60 57% 800000 50 49% 40 600000 34%

Share of informality of Share 30 400000 20 23% 200000 Volume of timber (m 10 0 0 DRC Cameroon Congo Central African gabon Brazzaville Republic

Formal timber production Informal timber production Informal production/total production (%)

Source: Lescuyer and Cerutti, 2013

Table 3: Summary of findings for informal logging

Timber Political Value Chain Rural Actors Economy Rights • Forest tenure conflicts • Informal activities as between the state and rural ‘resistance’ against unjust communities tenure arrangements imposed by the state • Forest ownership belong to the state Regulation • Elite capture of forest • Separation between the • Cost of compliance with resource governance informal and formal timber regulations and policy too sectors – except for high for rural actors • Policies such as revenue selected species for export sharing and that provide significant forestry often do not deliver economic profits the promised benefits Economics • Huge economic benefits to • Demands from the growing • One of the few employment a wide range of stakeholders low-income consumers in opportunities for youth (forest department officials, urban areas • A critical livelihood option police, customs, farmers and • Government officials chiefs) • Significant income participate actively compared to farm work

16 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

frameworks, rural communities can only receive access, The link between informal and formal supply chains use, or in some cases management rights to forest in the timber sector is comparatively weak. The main resources. In reality, governments routinely allocate reason is that the export and domestic markets are wasteland or degraded forests to rural communities, distinct: formal industrial operations serve the export while reserving high-value timber resources suitable for market, which demands stringent product specifications commercial exploitation for the (Bojang 2013). (Cerutti and Lescuyer 2011). Chainsaw millers serve This practice allows governments to generate significant the lax domestic market dominated by low-income income from forest resources and benefits the ruling consumers. There are nonetheless instances when elites (Jones 2004 in Bojang 2013). the informal and formal value chains overlap: export- oriented buyers may purchase logs or sawn timber of Some rural chainsaw loggers and millers may respond high-value species from rural chainsaw millers and/ to tenure arrangements imposed by the state by or in the informal timber markets. Informally harvested intensifying their informal activities. In an interview timber products become legalised in the export process with the author, a Cameroonian chainsaw logger (Weng et al. 2014). Chinese buyers’ scramble for commented, “the government could take away our rosewood species in many African countries is a prime land and trees any moment, so we’d rather sell all the example of this. Despite sustainability concerns, such trees away to the Chinese as soon as we can” (Weng informal trade at times brings substantial economic 2015, p.2). profits to rural communities usually excluded from the lucrative global timber business (ibid.; Asanzi Regulation et al. 2014). Exclusionary regulations and elite-captured formal systems fail to deliver the promised benefits to forest- Economics dependent communities across Africa (Lawry et al. Informal timber production using chainsaws brings 2012), therefore perpetuating informal logging. Policies significant economic benefits to a wide range of such as revenue sharing schemes or community stakeholders. Demand from low-income consumers, forestry commonly fall short of their promises to help as in the case of agriculture, is a key driver. In the communities. Royalty from revenue-sharing schemes domestic markets of Central African countries and rarely reached the hands of community members Ghana, chainsaw milling thrives despite the ban and in Cameroon (Morrison et al. 2009), and were restrictions, because it receives a wide level of public appropriated by local elites for personal gains in Ghana support (Mafro 2010). For example in Ghana, informal (Chapter 5 in Larson et al. 2010). Community forestry payments from chainsaw milling amounted to 33.6 on the other hand has complicated requirements for billion Ghana cedi (approx.US$8.8 billion), which approval. As a result, deft local and at times external benefited government officials, farmers and chiefs elites easily appropriate community forestry permits (Mafro 2010). Indeed, the authorities (police, forestry (ibid.). Community forestry’s new management and customs officials) have partially created the rules structure, which requires formally organised user in the informal sector so that they can ‘tax’ chainsaw groups, also poses challenges to the communities’ timber production by demanding bribes (Mafro 2010; pre-existing rules and institutions. And even if all hurdles Cerutti et al. 2013). Such behaviours are particularly are taken, permits for community forestry are yet often common among increasingly disillusioned officials at the unaffordable for smallholder farmers and communities local level (Cerutti et al. 2013). (Pacheco et al. 2008). Informal timber’s contribution to rural livelihoods The high cost of compliance is also a problem of cannot be overstated. In Ghana, it provides jobs for international initiatives, such as EU’s FLEGT-VPA that about 130,000 people and supports the lives of about promotes timber legality. Research has put a price 650,000 people (Mafro 2010). It is also one of the few tag of US$14.17 per hectare to comply with FLEGT’s viable employment options for the rural youth (ibid.). various requirements – too much for most local In Cameroon, rural populations identify chainsaw producers (Eba’a Atyi et al. 2013). Forest-dependent milling as a key source of income generation (Cerutti communities who are unable to benefit from their and Lescuyer 2011). Research in rural Cameroon surrounding forest resources through formal channels also reveals that farmers often engage in logging and have little choice but to support their livelihoods through milling as an alternative or a supplement to their farm chainsaw logging and milling. work (Weng et al. 2014; Lescuyer 2010 in Cerutti and Lescuyer 2011).

www.iied.org 17 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining 5 Mining

Some communities in the rural informal economy rely on artisanal and small-scale mining (ASM) as a vital Rights livelihood strategy. Artisanal miners use rudimentary Conflicting customary and formal rules, particularly the tools such as shovels and machetes, whereas small- separation of mining rights from land ownership rights, scale mining companies own heavy-duty machines such drive informality in ASM. There are two distinct ‘spheres as bulldozers and trucks. There are more than 30 million of rights’ across sub-Saharan Africa. On the one hand, ASM miners worldwide, excavating various minerals governments separate mining rights from landownership and including gold, diamond, the 3Ts (tin, rights; their post-colonial mining reforms stipulate tantalum, tungsten), bauxite and iron (Hentschel that mining rights belong to the state regardless of et al. 2002). ASM presents huge employment who owns the land. On the other hand, chiefs and opportunities; it is estimated to support more than 10 landowners have traditionally been responsible for times as many people than those directly employed granting mining rights to subsistence artisanal miners in large-scale mining (Buxton 2013). In gold mining, (Nyame & Blocher 2010), leasing land to artisanal which has received most attention, ASM accounts for miners through verbal and simple agreements 90 per cent of the global employment (Hruschka n.d.). (Verbrugge et al. 2015; ibid.). The concomitant exercise Although ASM is critical to rural livelihoods as explained of authority of both governments and local communities below, its environmental impacts (e.g. mercury use in has effectively given rise to the co-existing yet clashing alluvial gold mining) are troublesome. Moreover, it has formal and informal licensing of mining rights. been linked to armed groups and conflict minerals in countries such as Sierra Leone, Angola and the DRC For rural communities, the distinction between (Fisher 2007). landownership and mining rights is inconsequential, thus formal rules matter little to them. Members of While regulations of ASM vary from country to country rural communities see little difference between leasing (thereby its corresponding legal status), artisanal their land to miners or other tenant farmers, willingly miners and small mining companies in all countries engaging in informal negotiations with whoever wants mostly operate in the informal sphere. Their informality to mine on their land including outside financiers (ibid.). manifests in various forms, including; i) they operate When landowners are actually aware of the official outside the legal framework in countries which lack rules, they may still choose to ignore them. They do targeted regulations; ii) they operate without the permits so to ‘resist’ against what they perceive to be unjust required by law; and/or iii) they may underreport arrangements imposed by the state that do not account production volumes to evade taxes (Benson et al. 2014). for their interests (Nyame & Blocher 2010). They are In this section, the analytical framework outlined in also bothered that governments frequently allocate Section 2 is used to analyse the drivers and livelihoods their customary land to large companies for industrial impacts of ASM activities in the informal sector. Table 4 production without consultation and compensation summaries the key findings. (ibid.); this is similar in both agriculture and timber as described earlier.

18 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

Table 4: Summary of findings for ASM in the informal sector

Timber Political Value chain Rural actors economy Rights • Landowning communities • Landowners • Landowners consider and individuals may grant land to artisanal miners leasing land for ASM as mining rights according to through verbal and simple legitimate as leasing land for customary (informal) norms agreements farming • Only the state can grant • ‘Resistance’ against unjust mining rights according to land allocation to large (formal) legislation mining companies by the government • Co-existence of formal and informal ‘licensing’ (the former by the state and the latter by rural landowners) Regulation • Formal laws cater for large • LSM may displace • Stakeholder consultations mining companies and subsistence artisanal gold in policy design the key to exclude interests of the ASM miners success in policy reform (the community case of Peru) • Policy intervention pays little attention to gender Economics • Global recessions induce • Three types of ASM workers • Significant source of income temporary ASM activities – all driven by compared to farming among rural populations • Not all ASM actors are • Lack of alternative livelihood subsistence miners, also options well-capitalised ‘rent seekers’

Finally, a lack of stakeholder consultation in policy Regulation causes informality to persist. Many sub-Saharan The exclusionary nature of regulations is also a governments could learn from Peru’s successful reform, strong driver of informality in ASM. Even those rural for which the government consulted with ASM miners communities and small-scale miners willing to comply in the drafting stage of its new regulatory framework. with the regulations may be deterred by the complex To date, 50 per cent of miners have become formalised and burdensome bureaucratic procedures necessary and 26 cooperatives formed in the ongoing formalisation for compliance (Hilson & Potter 2005; Banchirigah & process (Benson et al. 2014). Hilson 2009). Another reason for informality’s ubiquity is that mining laws are drafted mainly to suit the interests of large companies (Hentschel et al. 2002; Economics Blocher 2006). Financial lures are the main reason why businesses, Many countries have attempted reforms for integrating miners and local communities engage in ASM. ASM artisanal miners and small mining companies into guarantees high profits and thus provides a reliable the formal economy. These reforms have had limited livelihood option in remote areas. Table 5 illustrates success for they tended to ignore the elephant in the three types of miners and their income level in relation to room: the unequal power relationship between rural other economic activities. Note that the first two types communities and the elites as well as large companies (permanent and seasonal) possibly generate a higher (Spiegel 2012; Benson et al. 2014; Fisher 2007). One income than farm work, whereas the shock-push ASM example is when multinational companies displace serves as a safety net in tough times. Poverty, however, artisanal miners (who may have ‘informal’ claims) by is the underlying motivation for rural actors’ participation, obtaining exploration and prospecting licenses using regardless of type. their fast-lane access to the bureaucracy (Hilson & Potter 2005; Dreschler 2001 in Fisher 2007).

www.iied.org 19 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

Various factors may contribute to rural poverty, Binns 2007; Verbrugge et al. 2015). It is not only the including land tenure insecurity, de-agrarianisation, poorest of the poor who participate in ASM, however. global recession, and, in some countries, armed Figure 4 below shows that it may include a cohort of conflicts (Verbrugge 2014; Hentschel et al. 2002). ‘rent seekers’ who are professional and well-capitalised Farmers hoping to diversify their income, in particular, financers (Verbrugge & Buxton 2014). Research look for ASM jobs where available. As Table 5 shows, and policy discussions need to take these complex seasonal ASM workers could be classified as both structures into account when deliberating on the ‘mining farmers’ and ‘farming miners’ (Maconachie & livelihood impacts of ASM.

Table 5: Three types of ASM and their estimated income levels vis-à-vis other local livelihood choices

Type of ASM Description Estimated ratio of ASM income vis- à-vis other local livelihood choices Permanent ASM Generally earn higher income than alternative 1.5–5 occupations Seasonal ASM Consider ASM as an opportunity for additional 0.8–1.5 income during idle periods of other work (e.g. farm work). Similar or slightly higher income than alternative occupations Shock-push ASM People pushed into ASM as a response to 0.5–0.9 disasters or economic shocks. Lower income than previous livelihood option, but best available option as a buffer Source: adapted from Hruschka n.d.

Figure 4: The complex and multi-tiered labour structure in the Philippines’ ASM sector 2

Cooperatives

‘Rent seekers’ Financiers, land claimants, local politicians, armed police, communist rebels

Targeted in current Specialists Carpenters, experts, technicians, portal guards, chemists, engineers formalisation initiatives ‘Miners’ Team leaders

Diggers Corpo

‘Casual Not targeted labour in formalisation force’ initiatives Haulers, packers, processing plant workers

Source: Verbrugge & Buxton 2014

2 Although the example is from the Philippines, we can assume a similar structure for ASM in sub-Saharan Africa.

20 www.iied.org IIED Working paper 6 Conclusion

Informality is widespread and on the rise across sub- • Informal trading is a critical source of income Saharan Africa. The rural informal economy, in particular, for rural communities. Poverty and scant has tremendous implications for livelihoods of indigent employment opportunities prod rural populations communities. This paper has illustrated that rural (especially the youth) into the informal sector. Informal informality is not to be simply equated with illegality; logging and mining are highly profitable income policymakers, researchers and practitioners should diversification strategies beyond farm work. acknowledge its ubiquity and attend to its complexity in • An important commonality across the three sectors their policy design. Any development intervention aiming is the concomitance of complex informal rules, to help the rural poor ultimately needs to be grounded in participation of government officials and informality the reality of the rural informal economy. practiced as a form of resistance against unjust Concretely, this report has found: legislation. Few policy interventions which succeed in integrating informal actors into the formal sector are • Customary rights and norms legitimate another evident similarity. informality in the eyes of rural communities. Farmers, loggers and miners consider their informal • One key difference is that whereas domestic trading rightful due to traditional practices even consumers drive the demand for cheap informal food when it knowingly contradicts existing legislation. and timber products, international demand seems Particularly in the context of rural farming, what to spur informal mining of gold and other precious governments call ‘informality’ is how things have metals. A second difference relates to ownership always been done; anything pertaining to the ‘legal’ rights: legislation across sub-Saharan typically sphere is something smallholders may or may not recognises customary land ownership, but does not choose to follow. In rural informal logging and mining, grant minerals or forest ownership to communities customary rules co-exist and co-evolve together and customary landowners. Finally, illegality in with formal rules, engendering a complex system of informal logging and mining is more pronounced resource access and governance on the ground. than in agriculture, because governments across the region exercise tight control over their prized • Regulations – when exclusionary or poorly natural resources. implemented – drive informality. Byzantine bureaucracy, pervasive corruption and steep The framework used in this paper has allowed for compliance costs deter farmers, loggers and a first comparison of common and different drivers miners from registering and complying with formal of informality and the livelihood implications across rules. Timber and mining laws have long served the the sectors of agriculture, timber and mining. Future interests of large companies and still rarely take into research should further explore the dynamics and consideration the needs of rural operators. Rural complexity of the informal system in and across the farmers often breach contracts and engage in informal three sectors, in particular paying attention to varying trading if the terms of formal agreements seem unfair spatial scales. Key research questions may include: or too costly for them.

www.iied.org 21 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

At the political economy level: One issue beyond the scope of this paper – which has focused on drivers and livelihood implications – is • What are the prevailing legal and customary norms of environmental impacts of informality. Deforestation and resource and land governance? mercury , in particular, are serious concerns. • How have they clashed, co-existed and co-evolved Efforts to mitigate these environmental impacts through historically? global and domestic sustainability-related regulations and initiatives in turn have direct impacts on livelihoods • What is the level of barriers to entry for small firms, (e.g. EU FLEGT-VPA and the Minamata Convention elite capture in decision making, quality of services on Mercury). It is also important to compare the provided as well as corruption in existing regulations? environmental impact of informality vis-à-vis formal At the value chain level: operations (industrial logging vs chainsaw logging and large-scale mining vs artisanal and small-scale • Where and how do rural economic actors participate mining) so that policymakers can weigh the costs in the informal economy? and benefits between livelihood implications and • What are their economic return and relationship with environmental consequences. other actors? • How do they shape the rules of the informal trade? At the rural actor level: • What are the motivations for participating in the informal economy? • What are the livelihoods benefits compared to other economic activities?

22 www.iied.org IIED Working paper References

Agrawal, A. & Gibson, C.C., 1999. Enchantment and Cerutti, P. et al., 2013. Cameroon’s Hidden Harvest: disenchantment: The role of community in natural Commercial Chainsaw Logging, Corruption, and resource conservation. World Development, 27, Livelihoods. Society & Natural Resources, 26(5), pp.629–649. pp.539–553. Asanzi, P. et al., 2014. Rural livelihoods and the Chinese Cerutti, P. et al., 2011. The domestic market for small- timber trade in Zambia’s Western Province. International scale chainsaw milling in Cameroon: present situation, Forestry Review, 16(4), pp.447–458. opportunities and challenges, Bogor, : Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR). Banchirigah, S.M. & Hilson, G., 2009. De- agrarianization, re-agrarianization and local economic Chambwera, M., Macgregor, J. & Baker, A., 2011. development: Re-orientating livelihoods in African The Informal Economy: A primer for development artisanal mining communities. Policy Sciences, 43(2), professionals on the importance of the informal pp.157–180. economy in developing countries, London: IIED (International Institute for Environment and Barrett, C.B., Reardon, T. & Webb, P., 2001. Nonfarm Development). income diversification and household livelihood strategies in rural Africa: Concepts, dynamics, and Chen, M.A., 2007. Rethinking the Informal Economy policy implications. Food Policy, 26, pp.315–331. Linkages with the Formal Economy and the Formal Regulatory Environment, UNU World Institute for Barrientos, S., Dolan, C. & Tallontire, A., 2003. A Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER). Gendered Value Chain Approach to Codes of Conduct in African Horticulture. World Development, 31(9), Chen, M.A., 2012. The Informal Economy : Definitions pp.1511–1526. , Theories and Policies, Cambridge, MA: Women in Informal Employment: Globalizing and Organizing Becker, K.F., 2004. Fact Finding Study: The informal (WIEGO). Available at: http://wiego.org/sites/wiego. economy, Department of Infrastructure and Economic org/files/publications/files/Chen_WIEGO_WP1.pdf. Co-operation (Sida). Available at: http://www.ncbi.nlm. nih.gov/pubmed/19502245. Eba’a Atyi, R. et al., 2013. Impacts of international timber procurement policies on Central Africa’s forestry sector: Benjamin, C.E., 2008. Legal Pluralism and The case of Cameroon. Forest Policy and Economics, : Natural Resource Management in Mali. pp.1–9. World Development, 36(11), pp.2255–2276. Environmental Investigation Agency, 2012. Appetite for Benson, E. et al., 2014. Informal and Green?The Destruction; China’s trade in illegal timber, London: forgotten voice in the transition to a , Environmental Investigation Agency. London: International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). FAO, What is Land Tenure, Rome, Italy: FAO. Available at: http://www.fao.org/docrep/005/y4307e/y4307e05. Bihunirwa, M. et al., 2012. Innovating to compete: htm [Accessed March 29, 2015a]. Smallholder farmers’ agency and markets in East Africa, London/The Hague/: IIED/HIVOS/Mainumby. FAO, Advantags and problems of contract farming, Rome, Italy: FAO. Available at: http://www.fao.org/ Blocher, J., 2006. on Custom : Land Tenure docrep/004/y0937e/y0937e03.htm [Accessed March Policy and Economic Development in Ghana. Yale 2, 2015b]. Human Rights and Development Law Journal, 9, pp.166–202. De Ferranti, D. et al., 2003. Inequality in and the Caribbean: breaking with History, Washington, Bojang, F., 2013. Promoting good governance in natural DC: The International for Reconstruction and resource management in Africa. Nature & Faune, 27(2). Development/the . Available at: http:// Buxton, A., 2013. Responding to the challenge of scholar.google.com/scholar?hl=en&btnG=Search&q artisanal and small-scale mining; how can knowledge =intitle:Inequality+in+Latin+America+and+the+Carib networks help?, London: International Institute for bean:+Breaking+with+History?#1. Environment and Development (IIED).

www.iied.org 23 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

Fisher, E., 2007. Occupying the margins: Labour Leahy, T. & Goforth, M., 2014. Best practice for rural integration and in artisanal mining in food projects in Southern Africa? Development Tanzania. Development and Change, 38(4), pp.735– in Practice, 24(8), pp.933–947. 760. Lescuyer, G. & Cerutti, P., 2013. Taking the Informal Fitzpatrick, D., 2005. “Best Practice” Options for the sector into Account, Paris: CIRAD (Agricultural Legal Recognition of Customary Tenure. Development Research for Development). and Change, 36(3), pp.449–475. Livingston, G., Schonberger, S. & Delaney, S., 2011. Hansen, C.P. et al., 2012. Revisiting illegal logging and Sub-Saharan Africa : The state of smallholders in the size of the domestic timber market: the case of agriculture, Rome, Italy: IFAD. Ghana. International Forestry Review, 14(1), pp.39–49. Maconachie, R. & Binns, T., 2007. “Farming miners” Hart, K., 1973. Informal Income Opportunities and or “mining farmers”?: Diamond mining and rural Urban Employment in Ghana. The Journal of Modern development in post-conflict Sierra Leone. Journal of African Studies, 11(01), pp.61–89. Rural Studies, 23, pp.367–380. Hentschel, T., Hruschka, F. & Priester, M., 2002. Global Maconachie, R. & Hilson, G., 2011. Safeguarding Report on Artisanal & Small-Scale Mining, London: livelihoods or exacerbating poverty? Artisanal mining International Institute for Environment & Development and formalization in West Africa. Natural Resources (IIED). Forum, 35(4), pp.293–303. Hilson, G. & Potter, C., 2005. Structural adjustment and Mafro, E., 2010. Chainsaw Milling in Ghana: Context, subsistence industry: Artisanal gold mining in Ghana. drivers and impacts, Wageningen, the Netherlands: Development and Change, 36(1), pp.103–131. Tropenbos International. Hooton, N. & Omore, A., 2008. Policy in Manji, A., 2006. Legal paradigms in contemporary land small-scale milk markets in Kenya and East Africa reform. Commonwealth & Comparative Politics. markets in Kenya and East Africa, London: International Meinzen-Dick, R.S. & Pradhan, R., 2002. Legal Institute for Environment & Development (IIED). Pluralism and Dynamic Property Rights, Washington Hruschka, F., Artisanal and Small scale Gold Mining ( DC: International Food Policy Research Institute ASGM ) – Challenges and potential for development 20 (IFPRI). Available at: http://www.capri.cgiar.org/pdf/ years of SDC involvement. capriwp22.pdf. Hussmanns, R., 2004. Measuring the informal Minot, N., 2011. Contract farming in Africa: economy: From employment in the informal sector Opportunities and Challenges. In Presentation at to informal employment, Geneva: Policy Integration the AAMP Policy Seminar “Successful Smallholder Department Bureau of Statistics, International Labour Commercialization.” Kigali, Rwanda. Office (ILO). Morrison, K. et al., 2009. Broken Promises: Forest IFAD, 2011. Republic of Uganda; Revenue-Sharing in Cameroon, Washington, DC: Development Project Interim Evaluation, Rome, Italy: World Resources Institute. IFAD office of Evaluation. Murphy, S., 2012. Changing perspectives: Small-scale ILO, 2009. The informal economy in Africa : Promoting farmers, markets and , transition to formality: Challenges and strategies, Nyame, F.K. & Blocher, J., 2010. Influence of land Geneva: International Labour Office. tenure practices on artisanal mining activity in Ghana. Kaitibie, S. et al., 2010. Kenyan Dairy Policy Change: Resources Policy, 35(1), pp.47–53. Influence Pathways and Economic Impacts. World Pacheco, P. et al., 2008. The role of informal institutions Development, 38, pp.1494–1505. in the use of forest resources in Latin America, Bogor, Kasanga, K. & Kotey, N.A., 2001. Land Management in Indonesia: CIFOR (Center for International Forestry Ghana: Building on Tradition and Modernity, London: Research). Available at: http://www.ibcperu.org/doc/ International Institute for Environment & Development isis/9976.pdf [Accessed May 10, 2014]. (IIED). Palmer, R., 2007. Skills for work?: From skills Larson, A.M. et al., 2010. Forests for People development to decent livelihoods in Ghana’s rural Community Rights and Forest Tenure Reform, London: informal economy. International Journal of Educational Earthscan. Development, 27(4), pp.397–420. Lawry, S. et al., 2012. Devolution of Forest Rights and Sustainable Forest Management Volume 1: A Review of Policies and Programs in 16 Developing Countris,

24 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

Peluso, N.L. & Vandergeest, P., 2001. Genealogies of UNEP, 2012. Green Carbon, Black Trade; Illegal the Political Forest and Customary Rights in Indonesia, Logging, Tax Fraud and laundering in the World’s Malaysia, and Thailand. The Journal of Asian Studies, Tropical Forests C. Nellemann & I. E. C. Programme, 60, pp.761–812. eds., United Nations Environment Programme, GRID- Arendal. Perry, G. et al., 2006. Poverty reduction and growth: virtuous and vicious circles, Washington, DC: The Verbrugge, B., 2014. Exploitation and the Persistance International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/ of Informality in Small-Scale Mining: Evidence from the the World Bank. Philippines. Development and Change. Perry, G.E. et al., 2007. Informality: Exit and Verbrugge, B. & Buxton, A., 2014. Artisanal and small- Exclusion, Washington DC: The International Bank for scale mining: protecting those “doing the dirty work,” Reconstruction and Development/the World Bank. London: IIED (International Institute for Environment and Development). Proctor, F. & Lucchesi, V., 2012. Small-scale farming and youth in an era of rapid rural change, London: Verbrugge, B., Cuvelier, J. & Van Bockstael, S., 2015. International Institute for Environment and Development Min(d)ing the land: The relationship between artisanal (IIED). and small-scale mining and surface land arrangements in the southern Philippines, eastern DRC and . Putzel, L. et al., 2014. Formalization of natural resource Journal of Rural Studies, 37, pp.50–60. access and trade Insights from land tenure , mining , fisheries , and Formalization of natural resource Vorley, B. et al., 2015. Growing inclusion? Insights from access and trade, Bogor, Indonesia: CIFOR (Center for value chain development in Ugandan oilseeds, London: International Forestry Research). International Institute for Environment & Development. Richards, M., 1997. Common Property Resource Vorley, B., 2013. Meeting small-scale farmers in their Institutions and Forest Management in Latin America. markets: Understanding and improving the institutions Development and Change, 28, pp.95–117. and governance of informal agrifood trade, London/The Hague/La Paz: IIED/HIVOS/Mainumby. Schneider, F., 2002. Size and Measurement of the Informal Economy in 110 Countries Around the World. Vorley, B., del Pozo-Vergnes, E. & Barnett, A., 2012. In Camberra, Australia: Workshop of Australian national Small producer agency in the globalised market, Tax Centre, ANU. London: International Institute for Environment & Development. Available at: http://pubs.iied. Scoones, I., 2009. Livelihoods perspectives and rural org/16521iied. development. Journal of Peasant Studies, 36(1), pp.171–196. Vorley, B. & Thorpe, J., 2014. Success factors for lead firms to shape inclusive procurement, London: Scoones, I., 1998. Sustainable Rural Livelihoods a IIED (International Institute for Environment and Framework for Analysis. Analysis, 72, pp.1–22. Development). De Soto, H., 1979. Translated by Tim Ennis WHY Webb, J.W. et al., 2009. You say illegal, i say legitimate: DOES THE INFORMAL ECONOMY MATTER ? Entrepreneurship in the informal economy. Academy of Estudios Publicos, 30(otoño 1988). Management Review, 34, pp.492–510. Spiegel, S.J., 2012. Formalisation policies, informal Weng, X., 2015. Recognising informality in the China resource sectors and the de-/re-centralisation of power -Africa natural resource trade, London: International Geographies of inequality in Africa and , Bogor, Institute for Environment and Development (IIED). Indonesia: CIFOR (Center for International Forestry Available at: http://pubs.iied.org/pdfs/17286IIED.pdf? Research). Weng, X. et al., 2014. The Africa – China timber trade Staal, S.J., Pratt, A.N. & Jabbar, M., 2006. Dairy Diverse business models call for specialized policy Development for the Resource Poor; A Comparison of responses, Bogor, Indonesia: Center for International Dairy Policies and Development in South Asia and East Forestry Research (CIFOR). Africa, Rome, Italy: FAO. Available at: http://www.fao. org/ag/againfo/programmes/en/pplpi/docarc/wp44_2. Wit, M. et al., 2010. chainsaw milling:supplier to local pdf. markets — a synthesis, European Tropical Forest Research Network (ETFRN) News. Available at: http:// Start, D., 2001. The Rise and Fall of the Rural Non- www.tropenbos.org/publications/chainsaw+milling:+su farm Economy: Poverty Impacts and Policy Options. pplier+to+local+markets+-+a+synthesis. Development Policy Review, 19(4), pp.491–505.

www.iied.org 25 The rural informal economy | Understanding drivers and livelihood impacts in agriculture, timber and mining

26 www.iied.org IIED Working paper

www.iied.org 27 The informal economy – broadly defined as economic activity that is not subject to government regulation or taxation – supports some of the most vulnerable in society. In sub-Saharan Africa, it generates 90 per cent of employment opportunities in some countries, and contributes up to 38 per cent of GDP in others. In rural areas, the informal economy sustains livelihoods of impoverished populations through natural resource and land based economic activities such as farming, logging and mining. The rural informal economy is messy and complex: activities are at times classified as illegal yet are often rooted in traditional resource and land rights. Local communities may receive significant income, but sustainability of resource use is a pressing concern as informal trade increasingly serves ever- expanding urban and international markets. This paper examines the drivers and livelihood implications of informality in agriculture, logging, and mining in sub-Saharan Africa. It finds commonalities and differences across three areas: rights, regulations and economic factors. Aimed at researchers and practitioners, the paper demonstrates that development interventions in resource governance need to be strongly grounded in the complex reality of the rural informal economy in order to benefit impoverished communities.

IIED is a policy and action research organisation. We promote sustainable development to improve livelihoods and protect the environments on which these livelihoods are built. We specialise in linking local priorities to global challenges. IIED is based in London and works in Africa, Asia, Latin America, the Middle East and the Pacific, with some of the world’s most vulnerable people. We work with them to strengthen their voice in the decision-making arenas that affect them — from village councils to international conventions.

International Institute for Environment and Development 80-86 Gray’s Inn Road, London WC1X 8NH, UK Tel: +44 (0)20 3463 7399 Fax: +44 (0)20 3514 9055 email: [email protected] Knowledge www.iied.org Products

Funded by:

This research was funded by UK aid from the UK Government, however the views expressed do not necessarily reflect the views of the UK Government.