The Informal Economy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Informal Economy sustainable markets The Informal Economy A primer for development professionals on the importance of the informal economy in developing countries Muyeye Chambwera, James MacGregor and Antonia Baker International Institute for Environment and Development 3 Endsleigh Street, London WC1H 0DD Tel:-+44(0)207 3882117 Fax:+44(0)207 3882826 www.iied.org For further information please contact Muyeye Chambwera [email protected] Could the informal economy be the route to deliver the big sustainable development ideals such as the Green Economy, Millennium Development Goals and Poverty Reduction Strategies, given that its share is rapidly increasing and that the poor mostly operate here? In some developing countries, the share of the informal economy is greater than that of the formal economy. Government planners, donors and NGOs could use the informal or the formal economy to help lift up the wellbeing of the poor and address global challenges such as climate change, but choosing one over the other could lead to most efforts missing the mark. Planning food security, agricultural development, climate adaptation, low-carbon development, and housing requires a careful consideration of the current and future role of the informal economy. In attempting to answer questions about whether or not the informal economy is an impediment to development, whether it should be eliminated or promoted, we realise that the informal economy is not fully understood, is not clearly separated from the formal economy, is difficult to measure and does not necessarily imply illegality. These are among the 10 key messages that this paper raises for development professionals operating in any sector, in developed and developing countries. First published by International Institute for Environment and Development (UK) in 2011 © International Institute for Environment and Development. All rights reserved International Institute for Environment and Development 3 Endsleigh Street London, WC1H 0DD www.iied.org [email protected] Designed by Eileen Higgins [email protected] Printed by Park Communications www.parkcom.co.uk Cover image © Chris Stowers / Panos ISBN: 978-1-84369-822-7 Product code: 15515IIED Please recycle Disclaimer: This paper represents the view of the author and not necessarily of IIED. The International Institute for Environment and Development is one of the world’s top policy research organisations working in the field of sustainable development. With its broad based network of partners, IIED is helping to tackle the biggest issues of our times — from climate change and cities to the pressures on natural resources and the forces shaping global markets. Introduction On first hearing the phrase ‘informal economy’ (IE), most people think of illegal activities, such as trading in drugs or prostitution, paying bribes or avoiding taxes. As such, it is often regarded as something that should be eliminated in pursuit of a formal economy (FE). Without much analysis, one can even assume that the IE is a transitional route to formality as economies grow and regulation becomes stronger. Yet, reality seems to confound these expectations, at least in the short- to medium-term. The IE currently accounts for over half of global employment and as much as 90 per cent of employment in some of the poorer developing countries. Due to its flexible nature, the IE is in some ways better able to adapt to difficulties such as the current global recession, providing some measure of support to those most in need. Since it provides employment and income for the most impoverished – particularly women – it is a key route to achieving the millennium development goals (MDGs) of eradicating extreme poverty and hunger, promoting gender equality and empowering women. As such, some governments are beginning to become more aware of the vital role the IE plays, especially for the most vulnerable. Because of this awareness, some now look to policies that support the IE to © Muyeye Chambwera 1 The informal economy currently become more productive, provide a better voice in governance accounts for over and a better quality of life for those dependent on it. half of global Failure to fully grasp the nature, dynamics and drivers of the IE employment presents a dilemma for the sustainable development agenda. and as much Some of the questions may include: (1) Does development entail as 90 per cent eliminating the IE or working with it? (2) Should it be suppressed of employment or promoted, given its predominance? While this paper does not in some of the seek to answer these questions directly, it highlights key features and realities of the IE, providing a context for planning and poorer developing pursuing sustainable development initiatives. Indeed the delivery countries. and outcomes of ideals (such as the MDGs, poverty reduction, climate change adaptation, low carbon development, the green economy, housing for all and agricultural development) depend on the assumptions society makes today about the future economic scenarios which shape rural-urban dynamics, the use of natural resources, and the way in which product and labour markets operate, among other things. The IE can hardly be measured directly. Even though some individual countries have attempted comprehensive studies, there is little global analysis. The most recent analysis, including World Bank studies, use International Labour Organization (ILO) estimates from 1994 to 2000 and Schneider’s estimates for 110 countries over the period 1999 to 2004, to provide a global cross-section of data. A more up-to-date study is clearly needed to illustrate the changes in the size and nature of the IE, particularly in response to the recent recession. 2 Key messages 1. The global poor and the developing world earn their livelihoods in the informal economy The informal sector currently accounts for over half the global employment, involving an estimated 1.8 billion people as compared to the 1.2 billion of the formal sector (ILO 2002). In developed countries, the IE predominates as a livelihood activity for poorer people. In developing countries, the IE predominates for all but the richer, urban populations. It is of particular importance for people in poor urban and rural areas, and for women and farmers. The size of a nation’s IE is strongly correlated with levels of economic development (see Figure 1). The average size of the IE as a percentage of the Gross National Income (GNI) is 41 per cent in developing countries, 38 per cent in transition economies and 18 per cent in Organization for Economic Development (OECD) countries, according to average estimates from 1999 to 2004 (Schneider 2002). Estimates for 110 countries1 Figure 1 1. Sources: Schneider 2007; World Bank Development Indicators. Informal share of GDP using multiple indicator measures, average of observations available for 1999 to 2004, GDP per capita average for 1999 to 2006. 3 In the developing world, nation size appears to be an irrelevant factor (Lal and Raj 2006). For example the Small Island Developing States (SIDS) show self-employment (a proxy for informal employment) ranging from 5 per cent of non-agricultural employment in 1990 to 2000 in Bahrain to 65 per cent in Haiti (ILO 2002). 2. Globally, the informal economy appears to be growing in both developed and developing countries The main reason for this growth appears to be that formal labour markets have not been able to generate sufficient jobs to absorb a continuously- growing workforce, particularly for unskilled labour (Flodman Becker 2004). In the 15 countries forming part of EU before the expansion in 1995, the share of IE employment2 to total employment increased from 25 to 33 per cent between 1988 and 1998. The corresponding share of IE employment in the US was 25 per cent, where it increased strongly in the 1980s, but did not increase between 1995 and 2001 (ILO 2002). Developing countries also show high growth in the IE. In 1990 21 per cent of the sub-Saharan African (SSA) labour force of 227 million was working in the IE. However, by 1998 40 to 60 per cent of urban employment was estimated to be in the IE (Charmes 1998 in: Xaba et al. 2002). For example, in Kenya, the IE grew at a rate of an estimated 9 per cent a year between 1985 and 1990, and 16.1 per cent between 1991 and 1994. This is 10 times that of the formal sector, which only grew at 1.6 per cent during that period (Xaba et al. 2002). In the 1990s, Swaziland’s urban IE accounted for 10 per cent of national employment. The IE was growing at an average annual rate of 15 per cent, contrasting sharply with the decline of formal wage employment of 1 per cent annually. By the 1990s, the urban IE was contributing 22 per cent to national employment (ibid.). 2. Part time and temporary work and self-employment. 4 Effects of recession 1 Box Growth in the IE appears to have increased during the recession. Estimates show that globally in 2009 there were over 200 million more informal sector workers displaced from formal work, due to rising unemployment. In some cases, the IE can act as a temporary ‘cushion’ against the recession. For instance in Peru, where the IE is estimated at 60 to 70 per cent, the ILO describes the flexibility between sectors as a primary factor in keeping total unemployment down during the current recession. People took on extra part time or full time work to make ends meet (Slater 2010). Dennis Causso, a street vendor in Peru explains ‘I usually work in construction, but when there isn’t any work, like right now, I sell candy on the street and to people on the buses’ (ibid.). However, many of the sectors having high concentrations of informal workers (particularly women) such as export commodities, export manufacturing, and waste recycling are also the ones that have been badly affected by the current global recession.
Recommended publications
  • Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: the Role of Economic Factors
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Crossref Hindawi Publishing Corporation ISRN Economics Volume 2013, Article ID 954071, 14 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/954071 Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: The Role of Economic Factors Natalia Melgar,1 Juliette Milgram-Baleix,2 and Máximo Rossi1 1 Department of Economics, University of the Republic, Constituyente 1502, 11200 Montevideo, Uruguay 2 Department of Economic eory and History, University of Granada, Campus Cartuja, 18071 Granada, Spain Correspondence should be addressed to Natalia Melgar; [email protected] Received 8 November 2012; Accepted 26 November 2012 Academic Editors: T. M. Dall and D. Mitra Copyright © 2013 Natalia Melgar et al. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. We �nd that individuals’ opinions concerning protectionist policies match with how their revenue could be affected in the medium or long term by trade liberalisation in line with predictions of the comparative advantage models. An adverse macroeconomic context (large increase in the unemployment rate or in�ation rate) increases protectionist attitudes, thus re�ecting that people do not trust that free trade will lead to lower prices or create jobs despite trade theory optimism. People share a mercantilist view of trade since more imports increase protectionism support, while people positively value exports, especially in small countries. Regarding policy measures, while protectionist measures do not in�uence protectionism support in general, easy access to exports reduces people’s support for protectionism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers
    Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 7 July 2019 The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers Jenna Demeter The University of Tennessee, Knoxville, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit Part of the Business Administration, Management, and Operations Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Economic History Commons, Gender and Sexuality Commons, Growth and Development Commons, Income Distribution Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Inequality and Stratification Commons, International and Comparative Labor Relations Commons, International Economics Commons, International Relations Commons, International Trade Law Commons, Labor and Employment Law Commons, Labor Economics Commons, Latin American Studies Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Macroeconomics Commons, Political Economy Commons, Politics and Social Change Commons, Public Economics Commons, Regional Economics Commons, Rural Sociology Commons, Unions Commons, and the Work, Economy and Organizations Commons Recommended Citation Demeter, Jenna (2019) "The Oppressive Pressures of Globalization and Neoliberalism on Mexican Maquiladora Garment Workers," Pursuit - The Journal of Undergraduate Research at The University of Tennessee: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 7. Available at: https://trace.tennessee.edu/pursuit/vol9/iss1/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Size and Debt Sustainability Against Piketty's
    Economic Size and Debt Sustainability against Piketty’s Capital Inequality Hyejin Cho To cite this version: Hyejin Cho. Economic Size and Debt Sustainability against Piketty’s Capital Inequality. ACRN Journal of Finance and Risk Perspectives, ACRN Oxford Publishing House, 2015, 4 (2), pp.21-42. hal-01009465v2 HAL Id: hal-01009465 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01009465v2 Submitted on 24 May 2017 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. ACRN Journal of Finance and Risk Perspectives Vol. 4, Issue 2, March 2015, p. 21-42 ISSN 2305-7394 ECONOMIC SIZE AND DEBT SUSTAINABILITY AGAINST PIKETTY’S “CAPITAL INEQUALITY” Hye-jin Cho1 1Department of Economics, University of Paris 1, Pantheon-Sorbonne, PARIS, FRANCE Abstract. This article presents a methodology designed to facilitate alternative variables measuring economic growth. A capital-labor split of Cobb-Douglas function is adapted for use in the context of economic growth. A capital/income ratio and two fundamental laws of capitalism originated by Thomas Piketty illustrate capital inequality undervalued with respect to labor inequality. In addition, the article includes export and external debt as strong alternatives. Empirical data of the World Bank are analyzed to demonstrate broad differences in economic sizes.
    [Show full text]
  • Inclusive Capitalism for the American Workforce Reaping the Rewards of Economic Growth Through Broad-Based Employee Ownership and Profit Sharing
    AP PHOTO/STEVE PHOTO/STEVE AP H ELBER Inclusive Capitalism for the American Workforce Reaping the Rewards of Economic Growth through Broad-based Employee Ownership and Profit Sharing Richard B. Freeman, Joseph R. Blasi, and Douglas L. Kruse March 2011 WWW.AMERICANPROGRESS.ORG Inclusive Capitalism for the American Workforce Reaping the Rewards of Economic Growth through Broad-based Employee Ownership and Profit Sharing Richard B. Freeman, Joseph R. Blasi, and Douglas L. Kruse March 2011 Contents 1 Introduction and summary 5 The problem and the reform 5 The problem 7 The reform 11 The tax consequences 15 The consequences of our reform 15 Broad-based incentive systems work 18 Narrow incentive pay systems don’t work 22 The implications of reform 22 Taxes 23 Company responses 26 Worker responses and risk 28 Conclusion 29 Endnotes 32 About the authors and acknowledgements Introduction and summary The American model of capitalism needs major institutional reforms to regain its economic health and do what it has failed to do for the past three to four decades—ensure that the benefits of economic progress reach the bulk of our citizens. Well before the recent housing and financial crises, the Great Recession of 2007-2009, and the ensuing jobless recovery, the U.S. economy was not deliv- ering the benefits of sustained economic growth to the vast bulk of workers. From the mid-1970s through the 2000s the earnings of most American workers increased more slowly than the rate of productivity growth. Real median earnings barely rose even as gross domestic product per employed worker grew substan- tially.1 This contrasts with the nearly equal rates of real earnings growth and pro- ductivity growth from the turn of the 20th century through the early 1970s, which created a large prosperous middle class.
    [Show full text]
  • The Informal Sector and Economic Growth of South Africa and Nigeria: a Comparative Systematic Review
    Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity Review The Informal Sector and Economic Growth of South Africa and Nigeria: A Comparative Systematic Review Ernest Etim and Olawande Daramola * Department of Information Technology, Cape Peninsula University of Technology, P.O. Box 652, South Africa; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Received: 17 August 2020; Accepted: 10 October 2020; Published: 6 November 2020 Abstract: The informal sector is an integral part of several sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries and plays a key role in the economic growth of these countries. This article used a comparative systematic review to explore the factors that act as drivers to informality in South Africa (SA) and Nigeria, the challenges that impede the growth dynamics of the informal sector, the dominant subsectors, and policy initiatives targeting informal sector providers. A systematic search of Google Scholar, Scopus, ResearchGate was performed together with secondary data collated from grey literature. Using Boolean string search protocols facilitated the elucidation of research questions (RQs) raised in this study. An inclusion and exclusion criteria became necessary for rigour, comprehensiveness and limitation of publication bias. The data collated from thirty-one (31) primary studies (17 for SA and 14 for Nigeria) revealed that unemployment, income disparity among citizens, excessive tax burdens, excessive bureaucratic hurdles from government, inflationary tendencies, poor corruption control, GDP per capita, and lack of social protection survival tendencies all act as drivers to the informal sector in SA and Nigeria. Several challenges are given for both economies and policy incentives that might help sustain and improve the informal sector in these two countries.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 (PDF)
    CHAPTER 3 Growing Apart or Moving Together? Synchronization of Informal- and Formal-Economy Business Cycles Given its relative large size and the potential to dampen formal-economy business cycles, the informal economy needs to be factored into macroeconomic policy decisions. This chapter provides empirical evidence that informal output moves in the same direction as formal output, but in a more muted manner, with the direction of causality running from the formal economy to the informal economy. Informal employment, in contrast, does not co-move with the formal economy. Hence, the informal sector can provide a short-term buffer to formal- economy labor market disruptions even if, in the long run, it can act as a poverty trap. Policies that aim to curtail informal employment therefore need to be complemented with interventions that provide other buffers to short-term adverse shocks. Introduction In an average emerging market and developing economy (EMDE), the informal sector accounts for about one third of GDP, compared with about 18 percent of GDP in advanced economies (figure 3.1). Its large size makes the informal economy a potential amplifier or dampener of business cycles that policy makers need to take into account when deciding on countercyclical macroeconomic policies. If the informal economy expands while the formal economy contracts, it may support household incomes and consumer demand during economic downturns and serve as a safety net (Loayza and Rigolini 2011). If the informal economy behaves procyclically (that is, grows during expansions in the formal economy), it could function as an auxiliary “growth engine” during economic expansions (Chen 2005; Dell’Anno 2008; Meagher 2013).
    [Show full text]
  • Workforce Composition, Productivity and Pay: the Role of Firms in Wage Inequality
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 13212 Workforce Composition, Productivity and Pay: The Role of Firms in Wage Inequality Chiara Criscuolo Ryo Kambayashi Alexander Hijzen Timo Leidecker Cyrille Schwellnus Oskar Nordström Skans Erling Barth Capucine Riom Wen-Hao Chen Duncan Roth Richard Fabling Balazs Stadler Priscilla Fialho Richard Upward Katarzyna Grabska Wouter Zwysen MAY 2020 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 13212 Workforce Composition, Productivity and Pay: The Role of Firms in Wage Inequality Chiara Criscuolo Ryo Kambayashi OECD Hitotsubashi University Alexander Hijzen Timo Leidecker OECD and IZA OECD Cyrille Schwellnus Oskar Nordström Skans OECD Uppsala University and IZA Erling Barth Capucine Riom Institute for Social Research Oslo and IZA LSE Wen-Hao Chen Duncan Roth Statcan IAB Richard Fabling Balazs Stadler MOTU OECD Priscilla Fialho Richard Upward OECD University of Nottingham Katarzyna Grabska Wouter Zwysen Maastricht University OECD MAY 2020 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society.
    [Show full text]
  • Estimating the Size of Shadow Economy with Electricity Consumption Method
    Estimating the size of Shadow Economy with Electricity Consumption Method OLYMPIA MISSIOUa and DIMITRIOS PSYCHOYIOSb a International Hellenic University. b Assistant Professor of the Department of Industrial Management, University of Piraeus. Abstract Shadow Economy (SE) is an undesirable attribute not only for developing countries but also for developed ones and it is caused by a range of factors such as tax burden, tax morality, quality of institutions and corruption. (Schneider and Enste,2000; Schneider and Williams, 2013) Although the size and structure of the informal sector differ substantially among countries, significant distortions such as tax revenue losses, ineffective macroeconomic policies and lower quality and quantity of public goods are caused in real economy in all cases. (Markellos et al, 2016) As a result, the measurement of SE is a crucial procedure. In this framework, a range of methods is suggested by bibliography. Direct methods, indirect methods or macroeconomic approaches and model approach are the main categories. In the present analysis, the size of SE of 19 European Union (EU) countries over the 2008-2013 period is estimated through a macroeconomic approach called Electricity Consumption Method (ECM) or physical input method due to its accuracy and reliability of energy data. The model improves simple ECM approach taking into account other factors affecting the growth rate of electricity consumption. The results indicate that SE is decreased on unweighted average by 3% over the period 2008- 2013. In general, both Southern and Eastern Europe countries present a greater size of the informal sector (%of official GDP) in comparison with Western Europe countries such as France and Austria.
    [Show full text]
  • The Optimal Size of Government in Australia
    THE OPTIMAL SIZE OF GOVERNMENT IN AUSTRALIA Anthony J Makin Griffith Business School Griffith University Gold Coast 4222 [email protected] Julian Pearce Economics and Finance School Advisory Committee QUT Brisbane 4000 [email protected] Shyama Ratnasiri Griffith Business School Griffith University Gold Coast 4222 [email protected] Paper presented at 2018 Australian Conference of Economists, Canberra, 10-13 July. 1 THE OPTIMAL SIZE OF GOVERNMENT IN AUSTRALIA Abstract In the extensive literature on the role of government in the economy scant attention has been paid to the influence of the relative size of government on an economy’s rate of growth. This paper canvasses perspectives on why the size of government has grown, how this affects the wider economy, and why a trade-off exists between increased government size and economic growth beyond some optimal level, as conveyed by the so-called BARS curve. The paper next examines in-depth trends in government spending in Australia which has grown to a historically high level of 37 per cent of national income post GFC before econometrically estimating the optimal size of government on Australia’s BARS curve using the ARMAX approach. The results suggest the share of government spending in Australia consistent with maximising economic growth is 31 per cent of national income, significantly below the current level of 37 per cent. JEL: H6 E62 Contents 1. Introduction 2. Perspectives on Government Size and Growth 3. The Growth of Government in Australia 4. Estimating Optimal Government Size for Australia 5. Conclusion 2 THE OPTIMAL SIZE OF GOVERNMENT IN AUSTRALIA 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The Neoliberal Rhetoric of Workforce Readiness
    The Neoliberal Rhetoric of Workforce Readiness Richard D. Lakes Georgia State University, Atlanta, USA Abstract In this essay I review an important report on school reform, published in 2007 by the National Center on Education and the Economy, and written by a group of twenty-five panelists in the USA from industry, government, academia, education, and non-profit organizations, led by specialists in labor market economics, named the New Commission on the Skills of the American Workforce. These neoliberal commissioners desire a broad overhaul of public schooling, ending what is now a twelve-year high school curriculum after the tenth-grade with a series of state board qualifying exit examinations. In this plan vocational education (also known as career and technical education) has been eliminated altogether in the secondary-level schools as curricular tracks are consolidated into one, signifying a national trend of ratcheting-up prescribed academic competencies for students. I argue that college-for-all neoliberals valorize the middle-class values of individualism and self-reliance, entrepreneurship, and employment in the professions. Working-class students are expected to reinvent themselves in order to succeed in the new capitalist order. Imperatives in workforce readiness Elected officials in state and national legislatures and executive offices share a neoliberal perspective that public school students are academically deficient and under-prepared as future global workers. Their rhetoric has been used to re-establish the role of evidence-based measurement notably through report cards of student's grade-point-averages and test-taking results. Thus, states are tightening their diploma offerings and consolidating curricular track assignments.
    [Show full text]
  • Study on Informal Sector Linkages Within the Tourism Value Chain
    Study on Informal Sector linkages within the Tourism Value Chain Table of Contents Executive Summary 2 Policy Recommendations 4 1. Introduction 7 1.1. Brief overview 7 1.2. Objectives of the study 9 1.3. Justification 10 1.4. Outline of the report 10 2. Key issues in the literature 11 2.1. Key Findings 11 3. Context 16 3.1. Size and Characteristics of the Informal sector 16 3.2. Informal Sector Contribution to GDP 17 3.3. Policy Framework Supporting Informal Sector 17 4. Methodology and Data 22 4.1. Methodology 22 5. Characteristics and Nature of the Informal Sector 25 5.1. Key Findings 25 6. Tourism Value Chain Analysis 30 6.1. Ampara District 30 6.2. Batticaloa District 35 6.3. Polonnaruwa District 39 6.4. Trincomalee District 45 7. Policy Orientated Recommendations 46 Reference 59 Annex 1: Methodology for Estimating the Informal Sector Contribution to GDP 61 Annex 2: Changes in Economic and Tourism Industry Policy Framework 63 Annex 3: Characteristics and Nature of the Informal Sector – Tables 66 Annex 4: Value Chain Analysis Tables 71 Annex 5: Supply Chain Analysis Figures 75 Annex 6: Case Study Profile Tables 87 Annex 7: Summary of Case Study Findings 91 Executive Summary The Tourism Industry has been identified as one of the key drivers of growth and development in Sri Lanka by the successive governments. The Tourism Strategic Plan 2017 was formulated to transform the sector and support move towards achieving sustainable development goals. In contrast to more advanced countries, the Tourism Industry in Sri-Lanka is largely driven by the informal sector in Sri Lanka.
    [Show full text]
  • World Employment and Social Outlook Trends 2020 World Employment and Social Outlook
    ILO Flagship Report World Employment and Social Outlook Outlook and Social Employment World – Trends 2020 Trends X World Employment and Social Outlook Trends 2020 World Employment and Social Outlook Trends 2020 International Labour Office • Geneva Copyright © International Labour Organization 2020 First published 2020 Publications of the International Labour Office enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention. Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to ILO Publications (Rights and Licensing), International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland, or by email: [email protected]. The International Labour Office welcomes such applications. Libraries, institutions and other users registered with a reproduction rights organization may make copies in accordance with the licences issued to them for this purpose. Visit www.ifrro.org to find the reproduction rights organization in your country. World Employment and Social Outlook: Trends 2020 International Labour Office – Geneva: ILO, 2020 ISBN 978-92-2-031408-1 (print) ISBN 978-92-2-031407-4 (web pdf) employment / unemployment / labour policy / labour market analysis / economic and social development / regional development / Africa / Asia / Caribbean / Europe / EU countries / Latin America / Middle East / North America / Pacific 13.01.3 ILO Cataloguing in Publication Data The designations employed in ILO publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the International Labour Office concerning the legal status of any country, area or territory or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers.
    [Show full text]