The Limits of Market Organization

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Limits of Market Organization The Limits of Market Organization The Limits of Market Organization RICHARD R. NELSON EDITOR Russell Sage Foundation ⏐ New York The Russell Sage Foundation The Russell Sage Foundation, one of the oldest of America’s general purpose foundations, was established in 1907 by Mrs. Margaret Olivia Sage for “the improvement of social and liv- ing conditions in the United States.” The Foundation seeks to fulfill this mandate by fostering the development and dissemination of knowledge about the country’s political, social, and economic problems. While the Foundation endeavors to assure the accuracy and objectivity of each book it publishes, the conclusions and interpretations in Russell Sage Foundation pub- lications are those of the authors and not of the Foundation, its Trustees, or its staff. Publica- tion by Russell Sage, therefore, does not imply Foundation endorsement. BOARD OF TRUSTEES Robert E. Denham, Chair Alan S. Blinder Larry V. Hedges Alan B. Krueger Christine K. Cassel Jennifer L. Hochschild Cora B. Marrett Thomas D. Cook Timothy A. Hultquist Eric Wanner Christopher Edley Jr. Kathleen Hall Jamieson Mary C. Waters John A. Ferejohn Melvin Konner Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data The limits of market organization / edited by Richard Nelson. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-87154-626-4 1. Comparative economics. 2. Mixed economy. 3. Government ownership. 4. Capitalism. 5. Free enterprise. 6. Economic policy. I. Nelson, Richard R. HB90.L535 2005 330.12′2—dc22 2004058806 Copyright © 2005 by Russell Sage Foundation. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher. Reproduction by the United States Government in whole or in part is permitted for any purpose. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials. ANSI Z39.48-1992. Text design by Suzanne Nichols. RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION 112 East 64th Street, New York, New York 10021 10987654321 Contents Contributors vii Chapter 1 Introduction 1 Richard R. Nelson PART I INFRASTRUCTURE, NATURAL MONOPOLY, 25 AND EQUITABLE ACCESS Chapter 2 Electric Power 27 Kira Fabrizio Chapter 3 Telecommunications Regulation: An Introduction 48 Nicholas Economides Chapter 4 Passenger Rail 77 Elliott D. Sclar Chapter 5 Financial Clearing Systems 114 John A. James and David F. Weiman PART II HUMAN SERVICES 157 Chapter 6 The Role of Markets in American K–12 Education 161 Richard J. Murnane Chapter 7 Early Childhood Education and Care 185 Sheila B. Kamerman and Jane Waldfogel Chapter 8 Market Versus State in Health Care and Health Insurance: False Dichotomy 213 Dahlia K. Remler, Lawrence D. Brown, and Sherry A. Glied PART III SCIENCE AND TECHNOLOGY 231 Chapter 9 Basic Scientific Research 233 Richard R. Nelson CONTENTS Chapter 10 The Internet 259 David C. Mowery and Timothy Simcoe Chapter 11 Satellite Data 294 Roberta Balstad PART IV PROTECTING THE PUBLIC AND THE STATE 319 Chapter 12 Public Health 321 Kristine M. Gebbie Chapter 13 Campaign Finance 335 Richard Briffault Chapter 14 Conclusion 371 Richard R. Nelson Index 377 vi Contributors RICHARD R. NELSON is George Blumenthal Professor of International and Public Affairs, Business, and Law, Emeritus, at Columbia University. ROBERTA BALSTAD is director of Columbia University’s Center for Interna- tional Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN). RICHARD BRIFFAULT is vice-dean and Joseph P. Chamberlain Professor of Legislation at Columbia Law School. LAWRENCE D. BROWN is professor in the Department of Health Policy and Management in the Mailman School of Public Health at Columbia University. NICHOLAS ECONOMIDES is professor of economics at Stern School of Busi- ness at New York University. KIRA FABRIZIO is a doctoral candidate at the Haas School of Business at the University of California, Berkeley, and is currently a visiting scholar at the Boston University School of Management. KRISTINE M. GEBBIE is Elizabeth Standish Gill Associate Professor and Director of the Center for Health Policy at the Columbia University School of Nursing. SHERRY A. GLIED is professor and chair of the Department of Health Policy and Management in the Mailman School of Public Health at Columbia University. JOHN A. JAMES is professor of economics at the University of Virginia. CONTRIBUTORS SHEILA B. KAMERMAN is Compton Foundation Centennial Professor for the Prevention of Children and Youth Problems at the Columbia University School of Social Work, director of the Columbia Institute on Child and Fam- ily Policy (ICFP), and codirector of the ICFP Clearinghouse on International Developments in Child and Family Policies. DAVID C. MOWERY is the William A. and Betty H. Hasler Professor of New Enterprise Development in the Haas School of Business at the University of California, Berkeley. RICHARD J. MURNANE is Thompson Professor of Education and Society at the Harvard University Graduate School of Education. DAHLIA K. REMLER is associate professor in the School of Public Affairs at Baruch College, City University of New York. ELLIOTT D. SCLAR is professor of urban planning and public affairs at Columbia University and holds appoints in the Graduate School of Architec- ture, Planning, and Preservation and the School of International Affairs. TIMOTHY SIMCOE is assistant professor of management in the Rotman School of Management at the University of Toronto. JANE WALDFOGEL is professor of social work and public affairs at Columbia University School of Social Work and research associate at the Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion at the London School of Economics. DAVID F. WEIMAN is Alena Wels Hirschorn ’58 Professor and chair of the Department of Economics at Barnard College. viii 1 INTRODUCTION Richard R. Nelson HE CLOSE of the twentieth century saw a virtual canonization of mar- ket organization as the best, indeed the only effective, way to structure Tan economic system.1 This phenomenon, though strongest in the United States and, to a somewhat lesser extent, the United Kingdom, was widespread. The conception of market organization being canonized was simple and pure, along the lines of the standard textbook model in econom- ics. For-profit firms are the vehicles of production. They decide what to pro- duce and how, on the basis of their assessments about what is most profitable. Given what suppliers offer, free choice by customers, who decide on the basis of their own knowledge and preferences where they will spend their own money, determines how much of what is bought by whom. Competition among firms assures that production is efficient and tailored to what users want, and prices are kept in line with costs. The role of government is lim- ited to establishing and maintaining a body of law to set the rules for the mar- ket game and assuring the availability of basic infrastructure needed for the economy to operate. Economists of an empirical bent and political scientists and sociologists who have studied actual modern economies recognize the oversimplifications involved in this folk theory. If intended as a positive theory of how modern economies are actually structured, it misses the complexity of market organi- zation in many spheres of economic activity and ignores the wide range of ac- tivities involving major investments of resources where markets play a limited role. The theory represses the extensive roles of government in modern economies. More generally, it misses the institutional complexity and varie- gation of modern economies.2 The folk theory clearly is intended more as a normative statement than as a positive one. In this role, it has been highly successful in recent years. 1 THE LIMITS OF MARKET ORGANIZATION While the broad ideological argument is focused on the economy as a whole, it is at the sectoral or activity level that the details of economic organi- zation are worked out. At this level, discussion today about the way a sector or activity should be structured almost always starts with the presumption that market organization, of a relatively simple kind, is the right solution. This is the “default” solution. In recent years, sectors and activities that were previ- ously regulated have been subject to strong pressures for deregulation. Where there is a major public sector role, the pressures are toward privatization. Under this view, competition is always something to be fostered, and arguments for public support of any kind are viewed with suspicion. Propositions to the ef- fect that perhaps market organization is not appropriate for the activity in ques- tion tend to be rejected out of hand. There is a strong preference to use the market as much as possible and to keep nonmarket elements to a minimum. A case can be made that this apparent bias in favor of simple market or- ganization at a sectoral level is, on net, a plus. It points policy discussion right from the start toward a mode of organization that, in fact, has served effec- tively as a central part of the governing structure over a wide range of activi- ties and sectors. It is associated with bias against governing structures that rely heavily on central planning and top-down command and control, which often have proved problematic or worse in contexts in which they have been em- ployed. However, the case for markets can be pushed too far. If the presumption in favor of market organization is accompanied by blindness to the complex- ity and variegation of modern economies, an ideological resistance to mixed forms of governance, and hostility to structures that make little use of markets, this can be a real problem. Modern societies face a number of challenging and often contentious choices regarding how to organize and govern a variety of activities that together employ a large and growing share of their resources.
Recommended publications
  • Virtual Currencies in the Eurosystem: Challenges Ahead
    STUDY Requested by the ECON committee Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Authors: Rosa María LASTRA, Jason Grant ALLEN Directorate-General for Internal Policies EN PE 619.020 – July 2018 Virtual currencies in the Eurosystem: challenges ahead Monetary Dialogue July 2018 Abstract Speculation on Bitcoin, the evolution of money in the digital age, and the underlying blockchain technology are attracting growing interest. In the context of the Eurosystem, this briefing paper analyses the legal nature of privately issued virtual currencies (VCs), the implications of VCs for central bank’s monetary policy and monopoly of note issue, and the risks for the financial system at large. The paper also considers some of the proposals concerning central bank issued virtual currencies. This document was provided by Policy Department A at the request of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. This document was requested by the European Parliament's Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs. AUTHORS Rosa María LASTRA, Centre for Commercial Law Studies, Queen Mary University of London Jason Grant ALLEN, Humboldt-Universität zu Berlin Centre for British Studies, University of New South Wales Centre for Law Markets and Regulation ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Dario PATERNOSTER EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support EP committees
    [Show full text]
  • The Cases of the Liberty Dollar and E-Gold Lawrence H
    The Troubling Suppression of Competition from Alternative Monies: The Cases of the Liberty Dollar and E-gold Lawrence H. White Proposals abound for reforming monetary policy by instituting a less-discretionary or nondiscretionary system (“rules”) for a fiat- money-issuing central bank to follow. The Federal Reserve’s Open Market Committee could be given a single mandate or more gener- ally an explicit loss function to minimize (e.g., the Taylor Rule). The FOMC could be replaced by a computer that prescribes the mone- tary base as a function of observed macroeconomic variables (e.g., the McCallum Rule). The role of determining the fiat monetary base could be stripped from the FOMC and moved to a prediction mar- ket (as proposed by Scott Sumner or Kevin Dowd). Alternative pro- posals call for commodity money regimes. The dollar could be redefined in terms of gold or a broader commodity bundle, with redeemability for Federal Reserve liabilities being reinstated. Or all Federal Reserve liabilities could actually be redeemed and retired, en route to a fully privatized gold or commodity-bundle standard (White 2012). All of these approaches assume that there will con- tinue to be a single monetary regime in the economy, so that the way to institute an alternative is to transform the dominant regime. Cato Journal, Vol. 34, No. 2 (Spring/Summer 2014). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights reserved. Lawrence H. White is Professor of Economics at George Mason University, a member of the Mercatus Center Financial Markets Working Group, and a Senior Fellow at the Cato Institute. 281 Cato Journal A different approach to monetary reform is to think about ways that alternative monetary standards might arise in the marketplace to operate in parallel with the fiat dollar, perhaps gradually to displace it.
    [Show full text]
  • Queens Frederick]
    Dean Alvord house, Albermarle Road , Prospect Park South, Brooklyn. Dean Alvord house, Albermarle Road, Prospect Park South, Brooklyn. John J. Petit, 1902. eu John J. Petit. 1902. Plans of first and second fl oors. eu Queens Frederick]. Lancaster bought a nearby sandy waste with Queens developed much more slowly than Brooklyn. two or three houses and promoted it as New Venice.585 Its ocean shore was considerably further than Brooklyn's The largest development was made by two brothers, coast from the business districts of Brooklyn and Manhat­ Newbold and Alfred Lawrence. Naming the project after tan, while northern Queens, before the development of mid­ themselves, they provided land for the Lawrence railroad town Manhattan, was even more isolated. One of the earli­ station and built the Lawrence Association, which can· est sections to attract attention from New York City was tained a school and a public ha11. 586 The new town was so Far Rockaway, which had a large seaside hotel called the successful that the Rockaway Hunting Club decided to Marine Pavilion.579 Built in 1833, it was famous enough by move there from Bayswater and hired Bruce Price to design 1850 to have attracted Henry Wadsworth Longfellow and a new c1ubhouse.587 Washington Irving. A small suburban-style resort called By 1898, when Queens was incorporated into New Wavecrest, similar to those on Coney Island, developed near York, the Long Island Railroad had started its own service to the hotel in the 1870s.58O Rockaway Beach, the Ocean Electric Railway, and the In 1863 a developer named Dr.
    [Show full text]
  • Universita' Degli Studi Di Padova
    UNIVERSITA’ DEGLI STUDI DI PADOVA DIPARTIMENTO DI SCIENZE ECONOMICHE ED AZIENDALI “M.FANNO” CORSO DI LAUREA MAGISTRALE / SPECIALISTICA IN BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION TESI DI LAUREA “The American banking system before the FED” RELATORE: CH.MO PROF. GIANFRANCO TUSSET LAUREANDO: CARLO RUBBO MATRICOLA N. 1121213 ANNO ACCADEMICO 2016 – 2017 ANNO ACCADEMICO 2016 – 2017 Il candidato dichiara che il presente lavoro è originale e non è già stato sottoposto, in tutto o in parte, per il conseguimento di un titolo accademico in altre Università italiane o straniere. Il candidato dichiara altresì che tutti i materiali utilizzati durante la preparazione dell’elaborato sono stati indicati nel testo e nella sezione “Riferimenti bibliografici” e che le eventuali citazioni testuali sono individuabili attraverso l’esplicito richiamo alla pubblicazione originale. Firma dello studente _________________ INDEX INTRODUCTION ........................................................ 2 CHAPTER ONE ........................................................... 4 THE INDEPENDENCE WAR AND THE BANK OF NORTH AMERICA .... 5 THE FIRST BANK OF THE UNITED STATES 1791 – 1811 ........................... 8 THE SECOND BANK OF THE UNITED STATES 1816-1833 ....................... 13 THE DECENTRALIZED BANKING SYSTEM 1837 – 1863 .......................... 17 CIVIL WAR FINANCING AND THE NATIONAL BANKING SYSTEM ... 23 PANICS OF THE END OF THE CENTURY AND ROAD TO THE FED .... 27 CHAPTER TWO ........................................................ 39 THE ROLE OF THE U.S. SUPREME COURT ................................................ 40 THE SUFFOLK SYSTEM: A “FREE MARKET CENTRAL BANK” .......... 45 DO THE U.S. NEED A CENTRALIZED BANKING SYSTEM? ................... 49 FINAL REFLECTIONS ............................................ 64 BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................... 69 1 INTRODUCTION The history of the American banking system is not well-known but it is very important, since it has shaped the current financial market of the country. The U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Rockoff, Hugh Working Paper Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking Working Paper, No. 2010-04 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Rutgers University Suggested Citation: Rockoff, Hugh (2010) : Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking, Working Paper, No. 2010-04, Rutgers University, Department of Economics, New Brunswick, NJ This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/59460 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu February, 2010 Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking Hugh Rockoff Rutgers University and NBER Department of Economics 75 Hamilton Street New Brunswick NJ 08901 [email protected] 1 Abstract Adam Smith and Milton Friedman are famous for championing Laissez Faire, yet both supported government regulation of the banking system.
    [Show full text]
  • Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis
    Centre for Risk & Insurance Studies enhancing the understanding of risk and insurance Moral Hazard and the Financial Crisis Kevin Dowd CRIS Discussion Paper Series – 2008.VI MORAL HAZARD AND THE FINANCIAL CRISIS Kevin Dowd* “It’s like not being invited to a party and then being given the bill.” (Comment by a Wall Street passer-by on the bank bailout.) There is no denying that the current financial crisis – possibly the worst the world has ever seen and not over yet – has delivered a major seismic shock to the policy landscape. In country after country, we see governments panicked into knee-jerk responses and throwing their policy manuals overboard: bailouts and nationalizations on an unprecedented scale, fiscal prudence thrown to the winds and the return of no-holds-barred Keynesianism. Lurid stories of the excesses of ‘free’ competition – of greedy bankers walking away with hundreds of millions whilst taxpayers bail their institutions out, of competitive pressure to pay stratospheric bonuses and the like – are grist to the mill of those who tell us that ‘free markets have failed’ and that what we need now is bigger government. To quote just one writer out of many others saying much the same, “the pendulum will swing – and should swing – towards an enhanced role for government in saving the market system from its excesses and inadequacies” (Summers, 2008). Free markets have been tried and failed, so the argument goes,1 now we need more regulation and more active macroeconomic management. Associated with such arguments is the claim that the problem of moral hazard is overrated.
    [Show full text]
  • Antebellum Banking Regulation: a Comparative Approach
    ANTEBELLUM BANKING REGULATION: A COMPARATIVE APPROACH DISSERTATION Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Doctor of Philosophy in the Graduate School of The Ohio State University By Alka Gandhi, M.A. ***** The Ohio State University 2003 Dissertation Committee: Approved by Professor Richard H. Steckel, Advisor Professor Paul Evans ________________________ Advisor Professor J. Huston McCulloch Economics Graduate Program ABSTRACT Extensive historical and contemporary studies establish important links between financial systems and economic development. Despite the importance of this research area and the extent of prior efforts, numerous interesting questions remain about the consequences of alternative regulatory regimes for the health of the financial sector. As a dynamic period of economic and financial evolution, which was accompanied by diverse banking regulations across states, the antebellum era provides a valuable laboratory for study. This dissertation utilizes a rich data set of balance sheets from antebellum banks in four U.S. states, Massachusetts, Ohio, Louisiana and Tennessee, to examine the relative impacts of preventative banking regulation on bank performance. Conceptual models of financial regulation are used to identify the motivations behind each state’s regulation and how it changed over time. Next, a duration model is employed to model the odds of bank failure and to determine the impact that regulation had on the ability of a bank to remain in operation. Finally, the estimates from the duration model are used to perform a counterfactual that assesses the impact on the odds of bank failure when imposing one state’s regulation on another state, ceteris paribus. The results indicate that states did enact regulation that was superior to alternate contemporaneous banking regulation, with respect to the ability to maintain the banking system.
    [Show full text]
  • American Foundations for Social Welfare
    STATEMENT CONCERNING PUBLICATIONS OF RUSSELL SAGE FOUNDATION The Russell Sage Foundation was established in 1907 by Mrs. Russell Sage "for the improvement of social and living conditions in the United States of America." In carrying out its purpose the Foundation maintains a staff which, among other duties, conducts studies of social conditions, author- ized by the General Director, where new information, its analysis and interpretation seem necessary in order to formu- late and advance practicable measures aimed at improvement. From time to time the Foundation publishes the results of these studies in book or pamphlet form. In formulating the problem for study, in mapping out a plan of work on it, in collecting facts, in drawing conclu- sions, and in the presentation of findings, authors of Foun- dation studies, who are always either members of the staff or specially commissioned research workers, have the benefit of the criticism and advice of their colleagues in the organi- zation. Full freedom is given research workers for the final decision on all of these steps, and in presenting and inter- preting both factual material and conclusions in their own way. While the general responsibility for management of the Foundation is vested in the board of trustees, the respon- sibility for facts, conclusions, and interpretations rests with the research workers alone and not upon the Foundation, its trustees, or other members of the staff. Publication under the imprint of the Foundation does not imply agreement by the organization or its members with opinions or interpretations of authors. It does imply that care has been taken that the research on which a book is based has been thoroughly done.
    [Show full text]
  • 19Th Century NYC Spatial History
    NINETEENTH-CENTURY NEW YORK CITY: A SPATIAL HISTORY Sophomore seminar – Spring 2017 Weekly seminars – W 10:10-12:00 GIS labs – M 10:30-12:00 Course number: BC3504 Instructor: Prof. Gergely Baics ([email protected]) Office hours: Th 12-2PM ERC fellow: Fatimazohra Koli ([email protected]) Office hours: TBA Course description (short): History of 19th-century New York City with a focus on spatial history. We explore three major themes, including the city’s rapidly changing built environment, its social environment, and urban metabolism. Methodologically, we focus on spatial analysis, especially historical Geographic Information Systems. Course description (long): Thematically, this seminar introduces students to key issues of 19th-century New York City history. We examine the economic, social, and spatial processes that propelled Gotham’s rise from a major Atlantic port to America’s first metropolis, with weekly readings focusing on three consecutive themes: the city’s rapidly changing built environment, its social environment, and basic metabolic functions that sustained residents. Methodologically, we approach each of these themes through the lens of spatial historical analysis, interrogating how the physical and social geography of 19th-century New York transformed under the pressures of modern urbanization. The class therefore includes a significant methodological component: in addition to weekly seminars, students attend four lab sessions at the Empirical Reasoning Center (ERC) to learn basic methods of Geographic Information Systems (GIS) mapping. Assignments focus on acquiring essential GIS skills and performing spatial historical analysis. As their final project, students write an original research paper with a significant mapping component. Prerequisites: None Learning objectives: Students who complete this class will be able to: 1) Demonstrate a well-rounded understanding of the key problems and debates of 19th- century New York City history.
    [Show full text]
  • The Suffolk Bank and the Panic of 1837: How a Private Bank Acted As a Lender-Of-Last-Resort*
    The Suffolk Bank and the Panic of 1837: How a Private Bank Acted as a Lender-of-Last-Resort* Arthur J. Rolnick Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Bruce D. Smith University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Warren E. Weber Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and University of Minnesota Abstract Before the establishment of federal deposit insurance, the U.S. experienced periodic banking panics, during which banks suspended specie payments and reduced lending. There was often a corresponding economic slowdown. The Panic of 1837 is considered one of the worst banking panics, and it coincided with a slowdown that lasted for almost five years. The economic disruption was not uniform across the country, however. The slowdown in New England was substantially less severe than elsewhere. Here we suggest that the Suffolk Bank, a private bank, was one reason for New England’s relative success. We argue that the Suffolk Bank’s provision of note-clearing and lender-of-last-resort services (via the Suffolk Banking System) lessened the effects of the Panic of 1837 in New England relative to the rest of the country, where no bank provided such services. * The authors thank the Baker Library, Harvard Business School for the materials provided from its Suffolk Bank Collection. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. 484 Arthur J. Rolnick, Bruce D. Smith, and Warren E. Weber Before the establishment of federal deposit insurance in 1935, the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • By:Bill Medley
    By: Bill Medley Highways of Commerce Central Banking and The U.S. Payments System By: Bill Medley Highways of Commerce Central Banking and The U.S. Payments System Published by the Public Affairs Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 1 Memorial Drive • Kansas City, MO 64198 Diane M. Raley, publisher Lowell C. Jones, executive editor Bill Medley, author Casey McKinley, designer Cindy Edwards, archivist All rights reserved, Copyright © 2014 Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without the prior consent of the publisher. First Edition, July 2014 The Highways of Commerce • III �ontents Foreword VII Chapter One A Calculus of Chaos: Commerce in Early America 1 Chapter Two “Order out of Confusion:” The Suffolk Bank 7 Chapter Three “A New Era:” The Clearinghouse 19 Chapter Four “A Famine of Currency:” The Panic of 1907 27 Chapter Five “The Highways of Commerce:” The Road to a Central Bank 35 Chapter Six “A problem…of great novelty:” Building a New Clearing System 45 Chapter Seven Bank Robbers and Bolsheviks: The Par Clearance Controversy 55 Chapter Eight “A Plump Automatic Bookkeeper:” The Rise of Banking Automation 71 Chapter Nine Control and Competition: The Monetary Control Act 83 Chapter Ten The Fed’s Air Force: A Plan for the Future 95 Chapter Eleven Disruption and Evolution: The Development of Check 21 105 Chapter Twelve Banks vs. Merchants: The Durbin Amendment 113 Afterword The Path Ahead 125 Endnotes 128 Sources and Selected Bibliography 146 Photo Credits 154 Index 160 Contents • V ForewordAs Congress undertook the task of designing a central bank for the United States in 1913, it was clear that lawmakers intended for the new institution to play a key role in improving the performance of the nation’s payments system.
    [Show full text]
  • The United States' Experience with State Bank Notes: Lessons for Regulating E-Cash*
    • The United States' Experience with State Bank Notes: Lessons for Regulating E-Cash* Arthur J. Rolnick Bruce D. Smith Warren E. Weber Revised version January 1997 • Preliminary, do not cite or quote Comments invited The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System. We thank Stacey Schreft and Ed Stevens for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. • • Right of regulating coin given to Congress for two reasons: For sake of uniformity; and to prevent fraud in States towards each other or foreigners. Both these reasons hold equally as to paper money. James Madison, 1786 We do not pretend, that a National Bank can establish and maintain a sound and uniform state of currency in the country, in spite of the National Government; but we do say that it has established and maintained such a currency, and can do so again, by the aid of that Government; and we further say, that no duty is more imperative on that Government, than the duty it owes the people, of furnishing them a sound and uniform currency. Abraham Lincoln, 1839 1. Introduction For well over a hundred years, the United States has benefited from having a safe and uniform currency. Since 1863, banks have been essentially prohibited from issuing notes that do not have the full backing of the federal government, and since 1879 virtually all currency has circulated at par. The possible introduction of privately-issued electronic monies has some people concerned that the situation could change, however.
    [Show full text]