NYNEX Corp. V. Discon, Inc

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

NYNEX Corp. V. Discon, Inc No. 96-1570 In the Supreme Court of the United States OCTOBER TERM, 1997 __________ NYNEX CORPORATION, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. DISCON, INCORPORATED, RESPONDENT __________ On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit __________ MOTION FOR LEAVE TO FILE BRIEF AND BRIEF FOR THE AMERICAN AUTOMOBILE MANUFACTURERS ASSOCIATION AS AMICUS CURIAE SUPPORTING PETITIONERS __________ PHILLIP D. BRADY STEPHEN M. SHAPIRO MARK SLYWYNSKY ROY T. ENGLERT, JR. American Automobile Counsel of Record Manufacturers Association DONALD M. FALK 1401 H Street, N.W. MICHAEL E. LACKEY, JR. Suite 900 Mayer, Brown & Platt Washington, D.C. 20005 2000 Pennsylvania Ave., N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006 (202) 463-2000 Counsel for Amicus Curiae In the Supreme Court of the United States OCTOBER TERM, 1997 __________ No. 96-1570 NYNEX CORPORATION, ET AL., PETITIONERS v. DISCON, INCORPORATED, RESPONDENT __________ On Writ of Certiorari to the United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit __________ MOTION OF THE AMERICAN AUTOMOBILE MANUFACTURERS ASSOCIATION FOR LEAVE TO FILE BRIEF AS AMICUS CURIAE SUPPORTING PETITIONERS __________ Pursuant to Sup. Ct. R. 37.3, the American Automobile Manufacturers Association (“AAMA”) respectfully moves for leave to file the accompanying brief as amicus curiae in support of petitioner.1 Petitioners have consented to the filing of the brief; counsel for respondent has consented orally to the filing of this brief, but AAMA had not received written consent by the time the brief was sent to be printed. See Sup. Ct. R. 37.3(a). The American Automobile Manufacturers Association (“AAMA”) is a non-profit national trade organization. Its member companies — General Motors Corporation, Ford Motor Company, and Chrysler Corporation — are the largest automobile manufactur- ers in the United States. The AAMA has often represented its members before this Court. 1 This brief was funded entirely by the AAMA and was authored entirely by its counsel. 3 The first question presented in this case provides two important and related opportunities to clarify the antitrust laws. First, this case calls for an evaluation of the vitality and proper scope of the per se prohibition of “group boycotts.” Second, the Court can and should continue to clarify the status of vertical nonprice restraints. The AAMA wishes to present its views on these issues because they are of exceptional significance to its members. Vertical restraints — agreements between firms at different levels of distribu- tion — are important competitive tools for all manufacturers that face intense interbrand competition. Manufacturers use a variety of vertical agreements to obtain inputs with the greatest efficiency and at the lowest price. Vertical agreements are particularly important to manufacturers that, like AAMA members, distribute their products to the public through a network of independent local dealers. The AAMA addresses these issues from the perspective of the domestic automobile industry to assist the Court in its assessment of the real-world consequences of the resolution of this case. The AAMA supports its views with examples from its members’ experience competing in an industry marked by intense interbrand competition at the producer level. That experience has shown the importance of flexibility in commercial arrangements with parties at different levels of distribution. AAMA members can produce automobiles more efficiently if they are able to deal with sole-source or limited numbers of suppliers who have strong incentives to satisfy the standards of the industry. Similarly, manufacturers have pro- moted the efficient distribution of vehicles to consumers by imposing limits both on the number of authorized distributors and on their conduct. The possibility is remote that these vertical restraints could have any adverse effect on interbrand competition. By contrast, hostility to such arrangements — whether it takes the form of the per se condemnation suggested by the Second Circuit in this case, or the condemnation after cursory analysis that the government suggested in its amicus brief at the certiorari stage 4 — threatens the efficiencies resulting from exclusive or limited supply and distribution agreements. Such arrangements should continue to be subject to full rule-of-reason review, with the accompanying pre- sumption of legality. For the foregoing reasons, the motion of the AAMA to file the accompanying brief as amicus curiae in support of petitioners should be granted. Respectfully submitted. PHILLIP D. BRADY STEPHEN M. SHAPIRO MARK SLYWYNSKY ROY T. ENGLERT, JR. American Automobile Counsel of Record Manufacturers Association DONALD M. FALK 1401 H Street, N.W. MICHAEL E. LACKEY, JR. Suite 900 Mayer, Brown & Platt Washington, D.C. 20005 2000 Pennsylvania Ave., N.W. Washington, D.C. 20006 (202) 463-2000 Counsel for Amicus Curiae JUNE 1998 QUESTION PRESENTED This brief addresses the first question presented: Whether, by dealing with one supplier, a purchaser engages in a “group boycott” of the supplier’s disappointed competitors, and thus may be subjected to per se liability under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. (i) iii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page INTEREST OF THE AMICUS CURIAE .............. 1 INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT . 1 ARGUMENT .................................... 3 I. VERTICAL ARRANGEMENTS INVOLVING A SINGLE MANUFACTURER OR CUSTOMER SHOULD NOT BE CONDEMNED PER SE AS “GROUP BOYCOTTS” .. 4 A. Two-Firm Vertical Agreements Are Not “Group Boycotts” Of Either Firm’s Competitors ................... 6 B. The Rationale Of Klor’s and General Motors Conflicts With Later Decisions Of This Court ............. 8 C. This Court Should Make Clear That Nonprice Agreements Between A Supplier and its Distributor or Customer Are Presumptively Legal ......................... 17 D. Conduct Undertaken Within The Supply And Distribution Arrangements Of A Single Manufacturer Should Be Analyzed Under The Full Rule Of Reason, Not A Trun- cated And Hostile Mode of Analysis ............ 20 iv TABLE OF CONTENTS — Continued Page II. UNCERTAINTY REGARDING “GROUP BOYCOTTS” IMPEDES PROCOMPETITIVE CONDUCT IN THE AUTOMOBILE INDUSTRY .................... 22 A. The Continuing Confusion Surrounding “Group Boycotts” Impedes The Ability Of Automobile Manufacturers To Preserve The Quality And Integrity Of Their Dealership Networks .................................. 23 B. The Confusion Surrounding “Group Boycotts” Impedes The Ability Of Automobile Manufacturers To Contract Efficiently With Suppliers .................... 25 III. FACIALLY DEFECTIVE ANTITRUST ACTIONS ARE APPROPRIATELY DISMISSED UNDER RULE 12(b)(6) ................................... 27 CONCLUSION ................................. 29 v TABLE OF AUTHORITIES Page Cases Adaptive Power Solutions, LLC v. Hughes Missile Systems Co., ___ F.3d. ___, 1998 WL 172774 (9th Cir. Apr. 15, 1998) ........................ 7 Anderson v. United States, 171 U.S. 604 (1898) ........................... 7 Arnold Pontiac-GMC, Inc. v. General Motors Corp., 786 F.2d 564 (3d Cir. 1986) .................... 25 Associated General Contractors v. California State Council of Carpenters, 459 U.S. 519 (1983) .......................... 28 Barry Wright Corp. v. ITT Grinnell Corp., 724 F.2d 227 (1st Cir. 1983) ..................... 7 BMI v. CBS, 441 U.S. 1 (1979) ...................... 5 Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993) ........ 4, 11, 22 Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977) .......................... 18 Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 485 U.S. 717 (1988) ....................... passim Chicago Professional Sports Ltd. Partnership v. NBA, 95 F.3d 593 (7th Cir. 1996) .............. 15 Continental TV, Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) ........................ passim Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984) .......................... 16 vi TABLE OF AUTHORITIES — Continued Pages Dial A Car, Inc. v. Transportation, Inc., 82 F.3d 484 (D.C. Cir. 1996) ................... 28 Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers’ Ass’n v. United States, 234 U.S. 600 (1914) ........ 6 FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447 (1986) ....................... passim FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass’n, 493 U.S. 411 (1990) ....................... 2, 5, 9 Hartford Fire Ins. Co. v. California, 509 U.S. 764 (1993) ........................... 7 Interface Group, Inc. v. Massachusetts Port Authority, 816 F.2d 9 (1st Cir. 1987) ...................... 28 Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984) ............................. 8 Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 340 U.S. 211 (1951) ........................ 9, 16 Klor’s, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207 (1959) ....................... passim Loewe v. Lawlor, 208 U.S. 274 (1908) ................ 7 Lovett v. General Motors Corp., 998 F.2d 575 (8th Cir. 1993), cert. denied, 510 U.S. 1113 (1994) ......................... 25 Monsanto v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752 (1984) ................. 11, 15, 17, 21 vii TABLE OF AUTHORITIES — Continued Pages National Society of Professional Engineers v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978) .............. 12 NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984) ......................... 5, 20 Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985) ...................... 3, 5, 13 Parsons v. Ford Motor Co., 669 F.2d 308 (5th Cir.), cert. denied, 459 U.S. 832 (1982) .........................
Recommended publications
  • Ruling Within Reason: a Reprieve for Resale Price Maintenance
    Agenda Advancing economics in business Ruling within reason: a reprieve for resale price maintenance As a result of the US Supreme Court’s recent overturning of the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles decision, which deemed minimum resale price maintenance unlawful per se, this practice is to be judged under the ‘rule of reason’ in the USA, as has been the case with other vertical restraints. Is it therefore time to change the European approach to vertical price fixing? In its June 2007 judgement in Leegin Creative Leather purposes of applying Article 81(1) to demonstrate Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc, the US Supreme Court ruled any actual effects on the market.5 that resale price maintenance (RPM) should be judged under the ‘rule of reason’.1 The Leegin ruling overturned In line with the Commission’s approach, in the UK the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles precedent, which held minimum RPM is considered a hard-core practice that that it is per se unlawful under Section 1 of the Sherman ‘almost inevitably’ infringes Article 81 or the Chapter I Act for firms to fix the minimum retail price at which prohibition under the Competition Act 1998.6 Indeed, the retailers may sell goods or services on.2 Office of Fair Trading (OFT) has brought a number of high-profile vertical price fixing cases in recent years, as The outcome of the Leegin case has relieved those who discussed below. support the view that, although under certain circumstances minimum RPM may result in sub-optimal In light of the Leegin judgement, is this the time for market outcomes, this risk is not sufficient to make the European competition policy to move towards an effects- practice illegal per se.
    [Show full text]
  • Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives
    USDA Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: United States Department of Agriculture The Story of the Capper- Rural Business- Volstead Act Cooperative Service Cooperative Information Report 59 Abstract The Capper-Volstead Act provides a limited exemption from antitrust liability for agricultural producers who market the products they produce on a cooperative basis. Without Capper-Volstead, farmers who agree among themselves on the pric es they'll accept for their products and other terms of trade would risk being held in violation of antitrust law. Even with the exemption, agricultural producers are not free to unduly enhance the prices they charge, consolidate with or collaborate in anticompetitive conduct with nonproducers, or engage in conduct with no legitimate business purpose that is intended to reduce competition. Keywords: cooperative, antitrust, Capper-Volstead Act, law ________________________________________ Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: The Story of the Capper-Volstead Act Donald A. Frederick Program Leader Law, Policy & Governance Rural Business-Cooperative Service U.S. Department of Agriculture Cooperative Information Report 59 September 2002 RBS publications and information are available on the Internet. The RBS w eb site is: http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/rbs Preface Antitrust law poses a special challenge to agricultural marketing associations. Certain conduct by independent business people-- agreeing on prices, terms of sale, and whom to sell to--violates the Sherman Act and other antitrust statutes. And these are the very types of collaborative activities that agricultural producers conduct through their marketing cooperatives. Since 1922, the Capper-Volstead Act has provided a limited antitrust exemption for agricultural marketing associations. Producers, through qualifying associations, can agree on prices and other terms of sale, select the extent of their joint marketing activity, agree on common marketing practices with other cooperatives, and achieve substantial market share and influence.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum
    Presenting a live 90-minute webinar with interactive Q&A Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum Advertised Pricing: Structuring to Minimize Antitrust Scrutiny State, Federal, and International Treatment of RPM Agreements and MAP Policies THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 28, 2019 1pm Eastern | 12pm Central | 11am Mountain | 10am Pacific Today’s faculty features: Michael A. Lindsay, Partner, Dorsey & Whitney LLP, Minneapolis William L. Monts, III, Partner, Hogan Lovells US, Washington, D.C. The audio portion of the conference may be accessed via the telephone or by using your computer's speakers. Please refer to the instructions emailed to registrants for additional information. If you have any questions, please contact Customer Service at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 1. Tips for Optimal Quality FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY Sound Quality If you are listening via your computer speakers, please note that the quality of your sound will vary depending on the speed and quality of your internet connection. If the sound quality is not satisfactory, you may listen via the phone: dial 1-866-961-8499 and enter your PIN when prompted. Otherwise, please send us a chat or e-mail [email protected] immediately so we can address the problem. If you dialed in and have any difficulties during the call, press *0 for assistance. Viewing Quality To maximize your screen, press the F11 key on your keyboard. To exit full screen, press the F11 key again. Continuing Education Credits FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY In order for us to process your continuing education credit, you must confirm your participation in this webinar by completing and submitting the Attendance Affirmation/Evaluation after the webinar.
    [Show full text]
  • In the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh
    Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 1 of 74 [PUBLISH] IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT ________________________ No. 15-14160 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06012-GAP-TBS QUALITY AUTO PAINTING CENTER OF ROSELLE, INC., Traded as Prestige Auto Body, Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14162 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06013-GAP-TBS ULTIMATE COLLISION REPAIR, INC., Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 2 of 74 Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14178 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06018-GAP-TBS CAMPBELL COUNTY AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14179 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 2 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 3 of 74 6:14-cv-06019-GAP-TBS LEE PAPPAS BODY SHOP, INC., DAVID C. BROSIUS, d.b.a. Martins Auto Body Works, Inc., ART WALKER AUTO SERVICES, INC., WHITEFORD COLLISION AND REFINISHING, INC., Plaintiffs-Appellants, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14180 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:15-cv-06022-GAP-TBS CONCORD AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, 3 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 4 of 74 Defendants-Appellees.
    [Show full text]
  • Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly?
    COVER STORIES Antitrust , Vol. 33, No. 2, Spring 2019. © 2019 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly? BY DEBBIE FEINSTEIN AND ALBERT TENG OR A NUMBER OF YEARS, exists—or only when it can also be shown to harm consumer commentators have debated whether the United welfare; (2) historical case law on monopsony; (3) recent States has a monopoly problem. But as part of the cases involving monopsony issues; and (4) counseling con - recent conversation over the direction of antitrust siderations for monopsony issues. It remains to be seen law and the continued appropriateness of the con - whether we will see significantly increased enforcement Fsumer welfare standard, the debate has turned to whether the against buyer-side agreements and mergers that affect buyer antitrust agencies are paying enough attention to monopsony power and whether such enforcement will be successful, but issues. 1 A concept that appears more in textbooks than in case what is clear is that the antitrust enforcement agencies will be law has suddenly become mainstream and practitioners exploring the depth and reach of these theories and clients should be aware of developments when they counsel clients must be prepared for investigations and enforcement actions on issues involving supply-side concerns. implicating these issues. This topic is not going anywhere any time soon.
    [Show full text]
  • Per Se Treatment: an Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation Adam Weg
    Hastings Law Journal Volume 60 | Issue 6 Article 14 1-2009 Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation Adam Weg Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Adam Weg, Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation, 60 Hastings L.J. 1535 (2009). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal/vol60/iss6/14 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation ADAM WEG* INTRODUCTION Over the past thirty years, the Supreme Court's test for finding a violation of the Sherman Act for certain types of business agreements has changed significantly.' Prior to that time, several types of agreements were illegal "per se,"2 while others were judged by a "rule of reason. ' Per se treatment is based solely on the existence of the offending agreements in the marketplace.' An agreement violates the Sherman Act if it falls into one of the per se illegal categories Conversely, a rule-of- reason analysis (which has recently been supplemented with "quick- look" analysis) allows a court to delve further into the intricacies of an agreement by examining the purpose, power, and effect of the agreement. As the complexity of products and the need for cooperation by market competitors has increased in recent years, the Court has moved several types of agreements from the per se category to the rule- * J.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Protest Boycotts As Restraints of Trade Under the Sherman Act: a Proposed Standard
    Cleveland State Law Review Volume 30 Issue 2 Article 7 1981 Protest Boycotts as Restraints of Trade under the Sherman Act: A Proposed Standard Francis M. Allegra Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! Recommended Citation Francis M. Allegra, Protest Boycotts as Restraints of Trade under the Sherman Act: A Proposed Standard, 30 Clev. St. L. Rev. 221 (1981) available at https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev/vol30/iss2/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cleveland State Law Review by an authorized editor of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PROTEST BOYCOTTS AS RESTRAINTS OF TRADE UNDER THE SHERMAN ACT: A PROPOSED STANDARD FRANCIS M. ALLEGRA* I. INTRODUCTION T HE SHERMAN ANTI-TRUST ACT' WAS ORIGINALLY ENACTED to combat trusts'- powerful business combinations, capable of wielding con- centrated economic power-created when individual shareholders from various corporations transferred their shares to a single trustee or governing board.' In pertinent part, section 1 of the Sherman Act states that "[elvery contract, combination . .. , or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States .... is declared to be il- legal."' The comprehensive language of section 1, though subsequently limited in its scope,5 evinces a congressional intent to utilize the plenary power of the Commerce Clause to its fullest extent.' Yet, while the broad language was designed to preserve economic freedom and unfet- * Judicial Clerk, United States Court of Claims, Washington, D.C.; Assoc.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rule of Reason
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 2018 The Rule of Reason Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Courts Commons, Economic History Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Law and Society Commons, Legal History Commons, Legal Remedies Commons, Litigation Commons, Public Economics Commons, and the Social Welfare Law Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "The Rule of Reason" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1778. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1778 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE RULE OF REASON Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract Antitrust’s rule of reason was born out of a thirty-year Supreme Court debate concerning the legality of multi-firm restraints on competition. By the late 1920s the basic contours of the rule for restraints among competitors was roughly established. Antitrust policy toward vertical restraints remained much more unstable, however, largely because their effects were so poorly understood. This Article provides a litigation field guide for antitrust claims under the rule of reason—or more precisely, for situations when application of the rule of reason is likely.
    [Show full text]
  • Application of Noerr-Pennington and the First Amendment to Politically Motivated Economic Boycotts: Missouri V
    Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review Volume 13 Number 1 Article 2 12-1-1979 Application of Noerr-Pennington and the First Amendment to Politically Motivated Economic Boycotts: Missouri v. NOW Charles P. Cockerill Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.lmu.edu/llr Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Charles P. Cockerill, Application of Noerr-Pennington and the First Amendment to Politically Motivated Economic Boycotts: Missouri v. NOW, 13 Loy. L.A. L. Rev. 85 (1979). Available at: https://digitalcommons.lmu.edu/llr/vol13/iss1/2 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Reviews at Digital Commons @ Loyola Marymount University and Loyola Law School. It has been accepted for inclusion in Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons@Loyola Marymount University and Loyola Law School. For more information, please contact [email protected]. APPLICATION OF NOERR-PENNINGTON AND THE FIRST AMENDMENT TO POLITICALLY MOTIVATED ECONOMIC BOYCOTTS: MISSOURI V NOW By Charles P. Cockerill* I. INTRODUCTION Boycotts' or concerted refusals to deal historically have been held to be combinations that restrain trade in violation of section one of the Sherman Act.2 Courts have predicated antitrust liability, not on the quantum of impact on interstate trade or the reasonableness of the methods used by the combination but, rather, on the fact that the com- bination was formed with the express or implied purpose of effecting a 3 boycott in restraint of trade or competition. * J.D., 1979 (California Western School of Law); B.A., 1972 (University of California); Member, State Bar of California.
    [Show full text]
  • ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT and INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition
    ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition ISSUED BY THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION APRIL 2007 ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: Promoting Innovation and Competition ISSUED BY THE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE AND THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION APRIL 2007 This Report should be cited as: U.S. DEP’T OF JUSTICE & FED. TRADE COMM’N, ANTITRUST ENFORCEMENT AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS: PROMOTING INNOVATION AND COMPETITION (2007). This Report can be accessed electronically at: www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/hearings/ip/222655.pdf www.ftc.gov/reports/index.shtm TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ................................................................. 1 CHAPTER 1: THE STRATEGIC USE OF LICENSING: UNILATERAL REFUSALS TO LICENSE PATENTS ................................................. 15 I. Introduction ......................................................... 15 II. The Kodak and CSU Decisions .......................................... 16 A. The Basic Facts and Holdings of the Cases .................. 16 B. Panelist Views on Kodak .................................. 17 C. Panelist Views on CSU ................................... 18 D. Ambiguity as to the Scope of the Patent Grant .............. 19 III. Policy Issues Relating to Unilateral Refusals to License ................... 20 A. Should Antitrust Law Accord Special Treatment to Patents? .. 21 B. Should Market Power Be Presumed with Patents? ........... 22 C. If an Antitrust Violation Were Found, Would There Be Workable Remedies for Unconditional, Unilateral Refusals to License Patents? .............................. 22 D. What Would Be the Effect of Liability for Refusals to License Patents on Incentives to Innovate? .................. 23 E. Competitive Effects of Refusals to License Patents ........... 24 IV. Legal Analysis of Unilateral Refusals to License Patents ................... 25 A. Does Section 271(d)(4) of Title 35 of the U.S. Code Create an Immunity for Unilateral Refusals to License Patents? .....
    [Show full text]
  • Comment Per Se Antitrust Presumptions in Criminal
    TAFT – HENRY (COMMENT) 6/11/2021 1:56 PM COMMENT PER SE ANTITRUST PRESUMPTIONS IN CRIMINAL CASES Roxann E. Henry* The 2020 William Howard Taft Lecture’s focus on the per se concept in Sherman Act Section One antitrust cases came at a timely point given the recent interest in antitrust jurisprudence. This Comment looks at perspectives from each of the three branches of government in the development of current per se practice in criminal prosecutions, tracing from the sparse legislative text through the convoluted judicial history of per se illegality to its current use by the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice in criminal cases. Recognizing that much of the development occurred in the context of a misdemeanor statute and before clarity on relevant constitutional requirements, I demonstrate that the Constitution proscribes the current use of per se illegality in criminal cases because—in the guise of a presumption of illegality—the per se concept substitutes judicial fact-finding using ever-changing and difficult-to-apply standards for fact- finding by a jury in derogation of the right to trial by jury, the separation of powers, and various aspects of the right to due * Roxann E. Henry is a solo practitioner of antitrust law focusing on consulting, compliance, monitoring, opinions and representing individuals. A former Chair of the Antitrust Section of the American Bar Association, she has handled all aspects of competition law, including criminal defense, treble damage litigation, compliance advice, and merger and other civil investigations and, as lead counsel, won a rare corporate criminal antitrust jury acquittal.
    [Show full text]
  • Guide Forcompliance with Federal Antitrust Laws
    Guide forCompliance with Federal Antitrust Laws October 2020 1 North Second Street, Hartsville, SC 29550 US I 843 383 7000 I sonoco.com October 2020 Dear Teammate: Since its founding in 1899, it has been Sonoco’s policy to comply fully with all applicable legal and regulatory requirements. To ensure Companywide compliance, each of us needs to understand these laws and regulations, including today’s complex antitrust laws. A number of companies have recently received severe punishments—hefty fines and hundreds of millions of dollars in damages—for antitrust law violations. Employees of these companies, too, have also been charged, tried, convicted, fined and jailed for their participation in violations of antitrust laws. Please read this Guide for Compliance with Federal Antitrust Laws carefully. It will help you understand current antitrust laws, their enforcement, and the serious criminal penalties and civil liabilities antitrust law violators face. Inappropriate actions by just one team member can cause significant damage to Sonoco and its team members. It is the responsibility of every Sonoco director, officer and team member to know the law and comply. Please contact our Company counsel if you need additional advice. Sincerely, Howard Coker President and Chief Executive Officer Table of Contents I. Purpose of Antitrust Laws and Consequences of Violation ..............................1 Purpose .........................................................................................................................................1 Consequences
    [Show full text]