Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum Presenting a live 90-minute webinar with interactive Q&A Resale Price Maintenance and Minimum Advertised Pricing: Structuring to Minimize Antitrust Scrutiny State, Federal, and International Treatment of RPM Agreements and MAP Policies THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 28, 2019 1pm Eastern | 12pm Central | 11am Mountain | 10am Pacific Today’s faculty features: Michael A. Lindsay, Partner, Dorsey & Whitney LLP, Minneapolis William L. Monts, III, Partner, Hogan Lovells US, Washington, D.C. The audio portion of the conference may be accessed via the telephone or by using your computer's speakers. Please refer to the instructions emailed to registrants for additional information. If you have any questions, please contact Customer Service at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 1. Tips for Optimal Quality FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY Sound Quality If you are listening via your computer speakers, please note that the quality of your sound will vary depending on the speed and quality of your internet connection. If the sound quality is not satisfactory, you may listen via the phone: dial 1-866-961-8499 and enter your PIN when prompted. Otherwise, please send us a chat or e-mail [email protected] immediately so we can address the problem. If you dialed in and have any difficulties during the call, press *0 for assistance. Viewing Quality To maximize your screen, press the F11 key on your keyboard. To exit full screen, press the F11 key again. Continuing Education Credits FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY In order for us to process your continuing education credit, you must confirm your participation in this webinar by completing and submitting the Attendance Affirmation/Evaluation after the webinar. A link to the Attendance Affirmation/Evaluation will be in the thank you email that you will receive immediately following the program. For additional information about continuing education, call us at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 2. Program Materials FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY If you have not printed the conference materials for this program, please complete the following steps: • Click on the ^ symbol next to “Conference Materials” in the middle of the left- hand column on your screen. • Click on the tab labeled “Handouts” that appears, and there you will see a PDF of the slides for today's program. • Double click on the PDF and a separate page will open. • Print the slides by clicking on the printer icon. U.S. Antitrust Rules for Unilateral Price Policies and Minimum Advertised Price Policies Michael A. Lindsay DORSEY & WHITNEY LLP February 28, 2019 Some Terminology • “Resale Price Maintenance” (RPM) describes a range of practices by which a manufacturer tries to influence a reseller’s pricing of the manufacturer’s products – Vertical relationship – “Vertical Price Fixing” is what you say if you don’t like it! • Two significant distinctions to bear in mind – Distinction 1: Actual selling price vs. advertised price – Distinction 2: Agreement vs. unilateral policy • “RPM Agreement” typically applies to actual selling price 6 Terminology, cont’d • Minimum Advertised Price Policy (MAP) – Applies only to advertised price, not to actual selling price • Gray area as to where advertising ends and selling price begins – In-store advertising in bricks & mortar stores – “Shopping cart” prices in online world • Unilateral Pricing Policy (UPP) – Applies to both advertised price and actual selling price – Conceptual distinction between advertised price and actual selling price becomes irrelevant – Sometimes referred to as “RPM Policy” or as “Colgate Policy” 7 Terminology, cont’d • Both UPP and MAP policies are unilateral policies – Reseller is free to disregard, but manufacturer can terminate or limit relationship – Inadvertence can convert a policy into an agreement • MAP can be implemented by agreement, rather than through unilateral policy – Debatable whether a contractual right is valuable for manufacturer – More value to legal enforceability insofar as MAP applies to “coop” advertising 8 U.S. Federal Law 9 RPM Agreements • Under federal law, resale price agreements that are truly vertical agreements are judged under the rule of reason – This was not the case when many of us went to law school! – You will still find counsel and business people who remember the old rules – And US law is an outlier on the global stage • The rule of reason approach results from the gradual removal of vertical agreements from the per se category – 1997’s State Oil v. Khan abandoned per se rule for maximum resale price agreements – 2007’s Leegin abandoned per se rule for minimum resale price agreements 10 Leegin Rationale • Economics does not justify a per se prohibition of minimum RPM agreements – RPM is not “always or almost always” anticompetitive – RPM can • Promote inter-brand competition by reducing intra-brand competition • Encourage provision of services by reducing “free-rider” problem of “discounting” resellers • Facilitate market entry by new brands, products, or firms • Administrative convenience does not justify a per se prohibition • But Leegin did not establish a rule of per se legality – Rule of Reason applies 11 When RPM Agreements Might Be Illegal • Enforcement mechanism for manufacturer cartel – “An unlawful cartel will seek to discover if some manufacturers are undercutting the cartel's fixed prices. Resale price maintenance could assist the cartel in identifying price-cutting manufacturers who benefit from the lower prices they offer” • Enforcement mechanism for retailer cartel – “A group of retailers might collude to fix prices to consumers and then compel a manufacturer to aid the unlawful arrangement with resale price maintenance” • Protecting a dominance of manufacturer or retailer – “A dominant retailer . might request resale price maintenance to forestall innovation in distribution that decreases costs” – “A manufacturer with market power . might use resale price maintenance to give retailers an incentive not to sell the products of smaller rivals or new entrants” 12 MAP Policies and Agreements • Rationale in Leegin applies to MAP as well as RPM • Even some pre-Leegin cases suggested rule of reason treatment – In re Nissan Antitrust Litig., 577 F.2d 910, 915–17 (5th Cir.1978) – FTC in CD Music found MAP programs illegal under rule of reason where programs adopted by music manufacturers with collective 85%+ market share, each of whom had must-carry recordings – In Re Compact Disc Minimum Advertised Price Antitrust Litig., 216 F.R.D. 197 (D. Me. 2003) (citing lack of precedent for holding MAP policies or agreements illegal per se) 13 State Law 14 State Antitrust Law • States can and do have their own antitrust laws • Federal antitrust laws do not pre-empt state law – California v. ARC America Corp., 490 U.S. 93 (1989) • States are free to use antitrust laws to regulate markets somewhat differently than federal laws – Some states have broad principles or requirements (in statutes or in case law) to construe state law consistent with federal law • States have not uniformly embraced Leegin for interpretation of state antitrust laws 15 State Laws, cont’d • Resale pricing agreements (on actual reselling price) – Are judged under the rule of reason in most states, but – Remain per se illegal in several states (notably California and Maryland) • 50-state survey of state laws relating to RPM is available on Antitrust Source – https://www.americanbar.org/content/dam/aba/publishing/antitrus t_source/lindsay_chart.authcheckdam.pdf (last updated April 2017) – Send comments to [email protected] 16 California Statute • A “trust” is a combination – To “increase the price of merchandise or any commodity” • CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 16720(b) (2009) – To “fix at any standard or figure, whereby its price to the public or consumer shall be in any manner controlled or established, any article or commodity” • CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 16720(d) – To “agree in any manner to keep the price of such article . at a fixed or graduated figure” • CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 16720(e) – To “establish . the price of any article . between them . and others, so as directly or indirectly to preclude a free and unrestricted competition . .”) • CAL. BUS. & PROF. CODE § 16720(e) 17 California State Enforcement • California state AG filed a series of enforcement actions in early part of this decade, taking position that RPM agreements continue to be per se violations of state law • People v. DermaQuest (2010) – “Distributor may not resell Product in a price structure that yields a Product price at ultimate retail sale below Dermaquest's Suggested Retail Price (DSRP)” – Consent order for injunction, $70,000 in civil penalties, and $50,000 in costs • People v. BioElements (2011) – Consent order for injunction, $15,000 in civil penalties, and $36,000 in costs 18 California Private Litigation • Darush MD APC v. Revision LP – UPP policy, but coupled with multiple in-person and telephone efforts to secure compliance – Applies per se rule under Cartwright Act • No. 12-cv-10296, 2013 WL 1749539 (C.D. Cal. Apr. 10, 2013) • Alsheikh v. Superior Court – Applies per se rule under Cartwright Act • 2013 WL 5530508, at *3 (Cal. App. 2 Dist. Oct. 7,2013) • In re Online Travel Co. (OTC) Hotel Booking Antitrust Litig. – “lower courts have diverged” on whether RPM agreements are per se unlawful in California post-Leegin, “leaving the law in California unclear” • No. 3:12-cv-3515-B, 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 152428, at *47 (N.D. Tex. Oct. 27, 2014) 19 Maryland • Any agreement “that establishes a minimum price below which a retailer, wholesaler, or distributor may not sell a commodity or service” is an unreasonable restraint of trade Md. Code Ann., Com. Law § 11-204(b) • In 2016, Maryland AG sued J&JVC for UPP that allegedly included terms negotiated with Costco – For UPP to be legal in MD, policy “must result from the purely unilateral decision of a manufacturer, without negotiation as to its terms, and must be enforced unilaterally” • No substantive rulings, and case settled in 2017 with J&JVC Assurance of Discontinuance and payment of $50,000 Complaint, State of Maryland v.
Recommended publications
  • Competition Law
    COMPETITION LAW SIBERGRAMME 2/2012 ISSN 1606-9986 21 August 2012 Senior Editor ROBERT LEGH Head of the Competition Law Unit of Bowman Gilfillan Inc, Johannesburg This issue by LAUREN RICHARDS and KHOFOLO KRUGER Candidate Attorneys: Bowman Gilfillan Inc Siber Ink Published by Siber Ink CC, B2A Westlake Square, Westlake Drive, Westlake 7945. © Siber Ink CC, Bowman Gilfillan Inc This Sibergramme may not be copied or forwarded without permission from Siber Ink CC Subscriptions: [email protected] or fax (+27) 086-242-3206 To view Competition Tribunal judgments, see: http://www.comptrib.co.za/ Page 2 ISSN 1606-9986 COMPETITION LAW SG 2/2012 IN THIS ISSUE: ESSENTIAL MATTERS: A COMPARATIVE ASSESSMENT OF DIFFERENT APPROACHES TO THE ESSENTIAL FACILITIES DOCTRINE............................. 2 Introduction..............................................................................................................................2 South Africa .............................................................................................................................3 The United States (US).............................................................................................................10 The European Union (EU).......................................................................................................13 Comparison of the US and EU positions .................................................................................15 Conclusion ...............................................................................................................................17
    [Show full text]
  • Ruling Within Reason: a Reprieve for Resale Price Maintenance
    Agenda Advancing economics in business Ruling within reason: a reprieve for resale price maintenance As a result of the US Supreme Court’s recent overturning of the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles decision, which deemed minimum resale price maintenance unlawful per se, this practice is to be judged under the ‘rule of reason’ in the USA, as has been the case with other vertical restraints. Is it therefore time to change the European approach to vertical price fixing? In its June 2007 judgement in Leegin Creative Leather purposes of applying Article 81(1) to demonstrate Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc, the US Supreme Court ruled any actual effects on the market.5 that resale price maintenance (RPM) should be judged under the ‘rule of reason’.1 The Leegin ruling overturned In line with the Commission’s approach, in the UK the long-standing 1911 Dr Miles precedent, which held minimum RPM is considered a hard-core practice that that it is per se unlawful under Section 1 of the Sherman ‘almost inevitably’ infringes Article 81 or the Chapter I Act for firms to fix the minimum retail price at which prohibition under the Competition Act 1998.6 Indeed, the retailers may sell goods or services on.2 Office of Fair Trading (OFT) has brought a number of high-profile vertical price fixing cases in recent years, as The outcome of the Leegin case has relieved those who discussed below. support the view that, although under certain circumstances minimum RPM may result in sub-optimal In light of the Leegin judgement, is this the time for market outcomes, this risk is not sufficient to make the European competition policy to move towards an effects- practice illegal per se.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance After Monsanto: a Doctrine Still at War with Itself*
    RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE AFTER MONSANTO: A DOCTRINE STILL AT WAR WITH ITSELF* TERRY CALVANI** AND ANDREW G. BERG*** In this article, two enforcement officials at the Federal Trade Com- mission reexamine resale price maintenance in light of the Supreme Court's recent decision in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp. Commissioner Calvani and Mr. Berg consider both antitrust law and economic policy in their review of the history of resale price mainte- nance; they point out the chronic inconsistencies to which this antitrust regime has been subject, and identify these same inconsistenciesat work in Monsanto. The authorsset forth three theses with respect to Mon- santo: first, that the Court intimated a willingness to reconsiderat some future time the per se standardof illegalityfor resale price maintenance; second, that the Court recognized the continuing vitality of the Colgate doctrine, which had been seriously questionedin recent years; and, third, that the Monsanto Court unsuccessfully attempted to delineate a work- able evidentiary standard applicable to communications between sellers and resellers when it is alleged that such communications constitute an illegal contract, combination, or consiracy under section one of the Sherman Act. The authorssuggest that, taken together, these elements in Monsanto display a doctrine at war with itself The authorsconclude by examining the possible implications of the Monsanto decisionfor the future direction of the law of resale price maintenance. Typically, antitrust issues do not generate widespread public inter- est; there is, however, a considerable amount of such interest in resale price maintenance,' as evidenced by numerous articles on the subject in newspapers and periodicals of general circulation.2 This high level of © 1984 Terry Calvani & Andrew G.
    [Show full text]
  • Resale Price Maintenance: Economic Theories and Empirical Evidence
    "RESALE PRICE MAINTENANCE: ECONOMIC THEORIES AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission November 1983 RESALF. PRICE INTF.NANCE: ECONO IC THEORIES AND PIRICAL EVIDENCE Thomas R. Overstreet, Jr. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commiss ion November 1983 . FEDERAL TRDE COM~ISSION -f. JAMES C. ~ILLER, III, Chairman MICHAEL PERTSCHUK, Commissioner PATRICIA P. BAILEY, Commissioner GEORGE W. DOUGLAS, Commissioner TERRY CALVANI, Commi S5 ioner BUREAU OF ECONO~ICS WENDY GRA~, Director RONALD S. BOND, Deputy Director for Operations and Research RICHARD HIGGINS, Deputy Director for Consumer Protection and Regulatory Analysis JOHN L. PETE , Associate Director for Special Projects DAVID T. SCHEFF N, Deputy Director for Competition and Anti trust PAUL PAUTLER, Assistant to Deputy Director for Competition and Antitrust JOHN E. CALFEE, Special Assistant to the Director JAMES A. HURDLE, Special Assistant to . the Director THOMAS WALTON, Special Assistant to the Director KEITH B. ANDERSON, Assistant Director of Regulatory Analysis JAMES M. FERGUSON, Assistant Director for Antitrust PAULINE IPPOLITO, Assistant Director for Industry Analysis WILLIAM F. LONG, ~anager for Line of Business PHILIP NELSON, Assistant Director for Competition Analysis PAUL H. RUBIN, Assistant Director for Consumer Protection This report has been prepared by an individual member of the professional staff of the FTC Bureau of Economics. It rsfle cts solely the views of the author, and is not intended to represent the position of the Federal Trade Commission, or necessarily the views of any individual Commissioner. -ii - fI. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank former FTC Commissioner David A.
    [Show full text]
  • Per Se Treatment: an Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation Adam Weg
    Hastings Law Journal Volume 60 | Issue 6 Article 14 1-2009 Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation Adam Weg Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Adam Weg, Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation, 60 Hastings L.J. 1535 (2009). Available at: https://repository.uchastings.edu/hastings_law_journal/vol60/iss6/14 This Note is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Hastings Law Journal by an authorized editor of UC Hastings Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Per Se Treatment: An Unnecessary Relic of Antitrust Litigation ADAM WEG* INTRODUCTION Over the past thirty years, the Supreme Court's test for finding a violation of the Sherman Act for certain types of business agreements has changed significantly.' Prior to that time, several types of agreements were illegal "per se,"2 while others were judged by a "rule of reason. ' Per se treatment is based solely on the existence of the offending agreements in the marketplace.' An agreement violates the Sherman Act if it falls into one of the per se illegal categories Conversely, a rule-of- reason analysis (which has recently been supplemented with "quick- look" analysis) allows a court to delve further into the intricacies of an agreement by examining the purpose, power, and effect of the agreement. As the complexity of products and the need for cooperation by market competitors has increased in recent years, the Court has moved several types of agreements from the per se category to the rule- * J.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance
    DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS JOHANNES KEPLER UNIVERSITY OF LINZ Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance by Matthias HUNOLD Johannes MUTHERS Working Paper No. 2006 March 2020 Johannes Kepler University of Linz Department of Economics Altenberger Strasse 69 A-4040 Linz - Auhof, Austria www.econ.jku.at [email protected] Manufacturer Cartels and Resale Price Maintenance Matthias Hunold∗ and Johannes Muthers† February 2021 Abstract In a model with manufacturer and retailer competition, we show that RPM facilitates manufacturer cartels when retailers have an outside option to selling the manufacturer’s product. Because retailers have an effective outside option, the manufacturer can only ensure contract acceptance by leaving a sufficient margin to the retailers. This restricts the wholesale price level even when manufacturers collude. In this context, collusion can only become profitable for manufacturers if they use resale price maintenance. We thus provide a novel theory of harm for resale price maintenance when manufacturers collude and illustrate the fit of this theory in competition policy cases. JEL classification: D43, K21, K42, L41, L42, L81. Keywords: resale price maintenance, collusion, retailing. ∗We thank participants at the 2020 annual meeting of the Verein für Socialpolitik as well as seminar participants at the University of Siegen, and in particular Hanna Hottenrott, Sebastian Kessing, Dieter Pennerstorfer, Frank Schlütter and Nicolas Schutz for valuable comments and suggestions. Corresponding author. University of Siegen, Unteres Schloß 3, 57068 Siegen, Germany; e-mail: [email protected]. †Johannes Kepler University Linz, Altenberger Straße 69, 4040 Linz, Austria; e-mail: jo- [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Resale price maintenance (RPM) has been used by colluding manufacturers of beer, gummi bears, chocolate, and coffee.1 The case reports contain indications that RPM indeed helped to make manufacturer collusion successful.
    [Show full text]
  • The Resale Price Maintenance Two-Step
    COMMERCIAL LITIGATION Controlling Retail Prices The Resale Price Maintenance By Pat Pascarella, Anne Swoboda Cruz, Two-Step and Stephanie Rzepka Until anti-Leegin states permit companies simply to enter into pro- competitive resale price agreements, properly implemented and monitored policies can In 2007, the U.S. Supreme Court abolished the per se rule provide a fair amount against minimum resale price agreements and held that of price discipline, and they were to be judged instead under the more lenient rule pose marginal risk. of reason standard. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 877 (2007). ance has placed manufacturers competing But 10 years later, the combined effect in nationwide markets in the unenviable of a disconnect between Leegin and cer- position of weighing the benefits of ratio- tain states’ laws and a lack of dispositive nalizing their retail distribution channels court decisions providing substantive guid- against unpredictable litigation risks. ■ Pat Pascarella is the chair the Tucker Ellis’ Antitrust Group. Before joining Tucker Ellis, he served with the U.S. Department of Justice, Antitrust Division in Washington D.C. and as chief in-house antitrust counsel to a Fortune-10 company. Anne Swoboda Cruz, a partner in Tucker Ellis’ Los Angeles office, is a trial attorney specializing in commercial litigation and antitrust. Ms. Cruz also is an active member of DRI, including the DRI Women in the Law Com- mittee. Stephanie Rzepka is an associate in Tucker Ellis’ Houston office. She represents businesses in antitrust, class action, and complex commercial litigation before state and federal courts and antitrust enforcement agencies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rule of Reason
    University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law 2018 The Rule of Reason Herbert J. Hovenkamp University of Pennsylvania Carey Law School Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Business Law, Public Responsibility, and Ethics Commons, Courts Commons, Economic History Commons, Industrial Organization Commons, Intellectual Property Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Law and Society Commons, Legal History Commons, Legal Remedies Commons, Litigation Commons, Public Economics Commons, and the Social Welfare Law Commons Repository Citation Hovenkamp, Herbert J., "The Rule of Reason" (2018). Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law. 1778. https://scholarship.law.upenn.edu/faculty_scholarship/1778 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship at Penn Law by an authorized administrator of Penn Law: Legal Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE RULE OF REASON Herbert Hovenkamp* Abstract Antitrust’s rule of reason was born out of a thirty-year Supreme Court debate concerning the legality of multi-firm restraints on competition. By the late 1920s the basic contours of the rule for restraints among competitors was roughly established. Antitrust policy toward vertical restraints remained much more unstable, however, largely because their effects were so poorly understood. This Article provides a litigation field guide for antitrust claims under the rule of reason—or more precisely, for situations when application of the rule of reason is likely.
    [Show full text]
  • A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance Thom Lambert University of Missouri School of Law, [email protected]
    University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository Faculty Publications 2010 A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance Thom Lambert University of Missouri School of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.missouri.edu/facpubs Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons, Courts Commons, and the Litigation Commons Recommended Citation Thomas A. Lambert, A Decision-Theoretic Rule of Reason for Minimum Resale Price Maintenance, 55 Antitrust Bull. 172 (2010) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of University of Missouri School of Law Scholarship Repository. THE ANTITRUST BULLETIN: Vol. 55, No. 1/Spring 2010 : 167 A decision-theoreticrule of reason for minimum resale price maintenance BY THOMAS A. LAMBERT* In holding that minimum resale price maintenance (RPM) is not per se illegal but should instead be evaluated under the rule of reason, the Leegin Court directed lower courts to craft a structured liability analysis that will separate pro- from anticompetitive instances of the practice. Thus far, courts, regulators, and commentators have proposed four types of approaches for evaluating instances of RPM: (1) approaches focused on the effects on consumer prices; (2) approaches focused on the identity of the party initiating the RPM (i.e., manufacturer or dealer(s)); (3) approaches focused on whether the product at issue is sold along with dealer services that are susceptible to free-riding; and (4) an approach, favored by the Federal Trade Commission, that mechanically applies factors the Leegin Court deemed to be relevant to the liability question.
    [Show full text]
  • Comment Per Se Antitrust Presumptions in Criminal
    TAFT – HENRY (COMMENT) 6/11/2021 1:56 PM COMMENT PER SE ANTITRUST PRESUMPTIONS IN CRIMINAL CASES Roxann E. Henry* The 2020 William Howard Taft Lecture’s focus on the per se concept in Sherman Act Section One antitrust cases came at a timely point given the recent interest in antitrust jurisprudence. This Comment looks at perspectives from each of the three branches of government in the development of current per se practice in criminal prosecutions, tracing from the sparse legislative text through the convoluted judicial history of per se illegality to its current use by the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice in criminal cases. Recognizing that much of the development occurred in the context of a misdemeanor statute and before clarity on relevant constitutional requirements, I demonstrate that the Constitution proscribes the current use of per se illegality in criminal cases because—in the guise of a presumption of illegality—the per se concept substitutes judicial fact-finding using ever-changing and difficult-to-apply standards for fact- finding by a jury in derogation of the right to trial by jury, the separation of powers, and various aspects of the right to due * Roxann E. Henry is a solo practitioner of antitrust law focusing on consulting, compliance, monitoring, opinions and representing individuals. A former Chair of the Antitrust Section of the American Bar Association, she has handled all aspects of competition law, including criminal defense, treble damage litigation, compliance advice, and merger and other civil investigations and, as lead counsel, won a rare corporate criminal antitrust jury acquittal.
    [Show full text]
  • Greg Shaffer, Theories of Harm from Resale Price Maintenance
    Theories of Harm from Resale Price Maintenance Greg Sha¤er University of Rochester FTC Hearings on Resale Price Maintenance February 19, 2009 Introduction Resale price maintenance is a practice in which an upstream …rm (manufacturer) restricts the price at which a downstream …rm (retailer) can resell its product. It has been used by …rms with market power and without market power, in markets where competition is vigorous, and in markets where competition is not so vigorous. RPM can take di¤erent forms. It can be a price ‡oor (min RPM), a price ceiling (max RPM), or a …xed price (…xed-price RPM). Introduction Resale price maintenance is a practice in which an upstream …rm (manufacturer) restricts the price at which a downstream …rm (retailer) can resell its product. It has been used by …rms with market power and without market power, in markets where competition is vigorous, and in markets where competition is not so vigorous. RPM can take di¤erent forms. It can be a price ‡oor (min RPM), a price ceiling (max RPM), or a …xed price (…xed-price RPM). Introduction RPM must be analyzed in the market context in which it occurs. In the past, when it was legal, RPM was commonly observed on products such as aspirin, pens, pencils, toothpaste, …ne china, soap, cigars, baby powder, deodorant, shaving cream, milk, electronic equipment, skiing equipment, hearing aids, refrigerators, and toasters. Introduction My assignment Discuss strategic theories of harm Leave RPM cartel theories to others Leave e¢ ciency rationales to others Strategic Theories of Harm Mitigating the E¤ects of Bargaining/Opportunism Manufacturer Retailer Retailer Mitigating the E¤ects of Bargaining/Opportunism Suppose an upstream …rm with market power sells to competing downstream …rms who also have market power.
    [Show full text]
  • Retail Price Maintenance
    Resale Price Maintenance: A Competitive Assessment Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Resale Price Maintenance Panel on Anticompetitive Effects Warren S. Grimes Professor, Southwestern Law School February 19, 2009 If one sat in on a marketing class at any reputable business school, the business reason for imposing resale price maintenance (RPM)1 would likely be described in straightforward fashion. A brand seller imposes RPM for one fundamental reason – it helps the seller win and retain retailers that will carry and promote the product. It does this by guaranteeing the retailer a high margin. That’s it. Of course, not all brand sellers will find it advantageous to impose RPM. An efficient, low cost producer can compete on favorable terms without RPM. If consumers widely recognize the superiority of a brand – an example might be Procter & Gamble’s Tide -- that seller too will likely see no need to employ RPM – retailers will want to carry the strong brand to attract customers. Under these circumstances, the brand seller will probably resist retailer pressure to impose RPM because it will prefer to take advantage of the vigorous intrabrand competition among retailers, bringing down the end price to consumers and increasing overall sales.2 The brand seller most likely to find RPM attractive is one who is selling a mid to high- priced brand whose inherent superiority is not readily evident to consumers. For such a manufacturer, RPM can give retailers a needed incentive not only to stock the brand but to actively promote it. Still, a competitive assessment of RPM is not complete without recognizing that even the brand seller with a relatively weak and relatively high priced brand has alternatives to RPM for widening distribution and sales.
    [Show full text]