Sherman Act Section 1 Fundamentals
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives
USDA Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: United States Department of Agriculture The Story of the Capper- Rural Business- Volstead Act Cooperative Service Cooperative Information Report 59 Abstract The Capper-Volstead Act provides a limited exemption from antitrust liability for agricultural producers who market the products they produce on a cooperative basis. Without Capper-Volstead, farmers who agree among themselves on the pric es they'll accept for their products and other terms of trade would risk being held in violation of antitrust law. Even with the exemption, agricultural producers are not free to unduly enhance the prices they charge, consolidate with or collaborate in anticompetitive conduct with nonproducers, or engage in conduct with no legitimate business purpose that is intended to reduce competition. Keywords: cooperative, antitrust, Capper-Volstead Act, law ________________________________________ Antitrust Status of Farmer Cooperatives: The Story of the Capper-Volstead Act Donald A. Frederick Program Leader Law, Policy & Governance Rural Business-Cooperative Service U.S. Department of Agriculture Cooperative Information Report 59 September 2002 RBS publications and information are available on the Internet. The RBS w eb site is: http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/rbs Preface Antitrust law poses a special challenge to agricultural marketing associations. Certain conduct by independent business people-- agreeing on prices, terms of sale, and whom to sell to--violates the Sherman Act and other antitrust statutes. And these are the very types of collaborative activities that agricultural producers conduct through their marketing cooperatives. Since 1922, the Capper-Volstead Act has provided a limited antitrust exemption for agricultural marketing associations. Producers, through qualifying associations, can agree on prices and other terms of sale, select the extent of their joint marketing activity, agree on common marketing practices with other cooperatives, and achieve substantial market share and influence. -
Competition and Monopoly : Single-Firm Conduct Under Section
CHAPTER 8 EXCLUSIVE DEALING I. Introduction prohibiting one party from dealing with 5 Exclusive dealing describes an arrangement others, or the exclusive-dealing arrangement whereby one party’s willingness to deal with can take other forms, as when a seller enacts another is contingent upon that other party (1) policies effectively requiring customers to deal dealing with it exclusively or (2) purchasing a exclusively with it. large share of its requirements from it.1 Exclusive dealing is frequently procom- Exclusive dealing is common and can take petitive, as when it enables manufacturers and many forms.2 It often requires a buyer to deal retailers to overcome free-rider issues exclusively with a seller. For example, a misaligning the incentives for these vertically- manufacturer may agree to deal with a related firms to satisfy the demands of distributor only if the distributor agrees not to consumers most efficiently. For example, a carry the products of the manufacturer’s manufacturer may be unwilling to train its competitors.3 And many franchise outlets agree distributors optimally if distributors can take to buy certain products exclusively from a that training and use it to sell products of the franchisor.4 But it also may involve a seller manufacturer’s rivals. Other benefits can occur dealing exclusively with a single buyer. as well, as when an exclusivity arrangement assures a customer of a steady stream of a Exclusive dealing also occurs between necessary input. sellers and consumers, as when a consumer agrees to purchase all its requirements of a But exclusive dealing also can be particular product from a single supplier. -
In the United States Court of Appeals for the Eleventh
Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 1 of 74 [PUBLISH] IN THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE ELEVENTH CIRCUIT ________________________ No. 15-14160 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06012-GAP-TBS QUALITY AUTO PAINTING CENTER OF ROSELLE, INC., Traded as Prestige Auto Body, Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14162 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06013-GAP-TBS ULTIMATE COLLISION REPAIR, INC., Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 2 of 74 Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM INDEMNITY COMPANY, STATE FARM GUARANTY INSURANCE COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14178 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:14-cv-06018-GAP-TBS CAMPBELL COUNTY AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al., Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14179 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 2 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 3 of 74 6:14-cv-06019-GAP-TBS LEE PAPPAS BODY SHOP, INC., DAVID C. BROSIUS, d.b.a. Martins Auto Body Works, Inc., ART WALKER AUTO SERVICES, INC., WHITEFORD COLLISION AND REFINISHING, INC., Plaintiffs-Appellants, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, Defendants-Appellees. ________________________ No. 15-14180 ________________________ D.C. Docket Nos. 6:14-md-02557-GAP-TBS, 6:15-cv-06022-GAP-TBS CONCORD AUTO BODY, INC., Plaintiff-Appellant, versus STATE FARM MUTUAL AUTOMOBILE INSURANCE COMPANY, STATE FARM FIRE & CASUALTY COMPANY, et al, 3 Case: 15-14160 Date Filed: 03/04/2019 Page: 4 of 74 Defendants-Appellees. -
Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly?
COVER STORIES Antitrust , Vol. 33, No. 2, Spring 2019. © 2019 by the American Bar Association. Reproduced with permission. All rights reserved. This information or any portion thereof may not be copied or disseminated in any form or by any means or stored in an electronic database or retrieval system without the express written consent of the American Bar Association. Buyer Power: Is Monopsony the New Monopoly? BY DEBBIE FEINSTEIN AND ALBERT TENG OR A NUMBER OF YEARS, exists—or only when it can also be shown to harm consumer commentators have debated whether the United welfare; (2) historical case law on monopsony; (3) recent States has a monopoly problem. But as part of the cases involving monopsony issues; and (4) counseling con - recent conversation over the direction of antitrust siderations for monopsony issues. It remains to be seen law and the continued appropriateness of the con - whether we will see significantly increased enforcement Fsumer welfare standard, the debate has turned to whether the against buyer-side agreements and mergers that affect buyer antitrust agencies are paying enough attention to monopsony power and whether such enforcement will be successful, but issues. 1 A concept that appears more in textbooks than in case what is clear is that the antitrust enforcement agencies will be law has suddenly become mainstream and practitioners exploring the depth and reach of these theories and clients should be aware of developments when they counsel clients must be prepared for investigations and enforcement actions on issues involving supply-side concerns. implicating these issues. This topic is not going anywhere any time soon. -
Reconciling the Harvard and Chicago Schools: a New Antitrust Approach for the 21St Century
Indiana Law Journal Volume 82 Issue 2 Article 4 Spring 2007 Reconciling the Harvard and Chicago Schools: A New Antitrust Approach for the 21st Century Thomas A. Piraino Jr. Parker-Hannifin Corporation Follow this and additional works at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons Recommended Citation Piraino, Thomas A. Jr. (2007) "Reconciling the Harvard and Chicago Schools: A New Antitrust Approach for the 21st Century," Indiana Law Journal: Vol. 82 : Iss. 2 , Article 4. Available at: https://www.repository.law.indiana.edu/ilj/vol82/iss2/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law School Journals at Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Indiana Law Journal by an authorized editor of Digital Repository @ Maurer Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Reconciling the Harvard and Chicago Schools: A New Antitrust Approach for the 21st Century THOMAS A. PIRAINO, JR.* INTRODUCTION: A NEW APPROACH TO ANTITRUST ANALYSIS ............................... 346 I. THE BATTLE FOR THE SOUL OF ANTITRUST .................................................. 348 A . The Harvard School ........................................................................... 348 B. The Chicago School ........................................................................... 350 II. THE PRINCIPAL CASES REFLECTING THE HARVARD/CHICAGO SCHOOL C ON FLICT .................................................................................................... -
Recent Development of Indonesian Competition Law and Agency
The Contribution of Competition Policy to Improving Regulatory Performance Ahmad Junaidi Bureau of Policy 1 Indonesia Competition Law • Competition is regulated by The Law No.5 Year 1999 Concerning Prohibition on Monopolistic Practices and Unfair Business Practices • The Law has been implemented for almost 11 year to enhance fair competition, since Indonesia economic policy and structure changes after crisis 1998. 2 PRINCIPLES AND PURPOSES The Principle (Article 2) Business activities of business actors in Indonesia must be based on economic democracy, with due observance of the equilibrium between the interests of business actors and the interests of the public The Purposes (Article 3) The purpose of enacting this Law shall be as follows: a. to safeguard the interests of the public and to improve national economic efficiency as one of the efforts to improve the people’s welfare; b. to create a conducive business climate through the stipulation of fair business competition in order to ensure the certainty of equal business opportunities for large-, middle- as well as small-scale business actors in Indonesia c. to prevent monopolistic practices and or unfair business competition that may be committed by business actors; and d. the creation of effectiveness and efficiency in business activities. 3 Structure of The Law Prohibited Agreements: Prohibited Dominant (rule of reason’s approach) Activities Position: (rule of reason’s (rule of reason’s Agreement with Foreigner approach) approach) Exclusive Dealing Monopoly Dominant Oligopsony Monopsony Position Trusts Share Ownership Vertical Intregation Market Control Cartel Conspiracy Interlocking Boycott Merger and Oligopoly Acquition Price Fixing 4 The Commission: KPPU • The Commission for the Supervision of Business Competition (KPPU) was established in 2000 with the authority mandated by the Law No. -
Exclusive Dealing: Before, Bork, and Beyond
Exclusive Dealing: Before, Bork, and Beyond The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation J. Mark Ramseyer & Eric B. Rasmusen, Exclusive Dealing: Before, Bork, and Beyond, 57 J. L. & Econ. S145 (2014). Published Version http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.1086/680347;10.1086/680347 Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:16952765 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA 1 October 6, 2013 Address correspondence to: [email protected] [email protected] Goal: 5000-7500 words Currently: 6,465 words (including everything) Exclusive Dealing: Before Bork, and Beyond J. Mark Ramseyer and Eric B. Rasmusen* Abstract: Antitrust scholars have come to accept the basic ideas about exclusive dealing that Bork articulated in The Antitrust Paradox. Indeed, they have even extended his list of reasons why exclusive dealing can promote economic efficiency. Yet they have also taken up his challenge to explain how exclusive dealing could possibly cause harm, and have modelled a variety of special cases where it does. Some (albeit not all) of these are sufficiently plausible to be useful to prosecutors and judges. *J. Mark Ramseyer, Mitsubishi Professor, Harvard Law School, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138, 617-496-4878; Eric B. Rasmusen, Dan R. and Catherine M. Dalton Professor, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana 47405-1701, [email protected], 812-855-9219. -
Some Canadian Thoughts on Exclusive Dealing
Some Canadian Thoughts on Exclusive Dealing ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group Teleseminar July 17, 2012 James Musgrove McMillan LLP with assistance from Devin Anderson Document # 6003961 LEGISLATION A. Section 77(1): For the purposes of this section, “exclusive dealing” means (a) any practice whereby a supplier of a product, as a condition of supplying the product to a customer, requires that customer to (i) deal only or primarily in products supplied by or designated by the supplier or the supplier’s nominee, or (ii) refrain from dealing in a specified class or kind of product except as supplied by the supplier or the nominee, and (b) any practice whereby a supplier of a product induces a customer to meet a condition set out in subparagraph (a)(i) or (ii) by offering to supply the product to the customer on more favourable terms or conditions if the customer agrees to meet the condition set out in either of those subparagraphs; 2 LEGISLATION B. Section 77(2): Where … the Tribunal finds that exclusive dealing ... because it is engaged in by a major supplier of a product in a market or because it is widespread in a market, is likely to (a) impede entry into or expansion of a firm in a market, (b) impede introduction of a product into or expansion of sales of a product in a market, or (c) have any other exclusionary effect in a market, with the result that competition is or is likely to be lessened substantially, the Tribunal may make an order directed to all or any of the suppliers against whom an order is sought prohibiting them from continuing to engage in that exclusive dealing … and containing any other requirement that, in its opinion, is necessary to overcome the effects thereof in the market or to restore or stimulate competition in the market. -
Exclusive Dealing and Competition: a US FTC View Alden F
Exclusive Dealing and Competition: A US FTC View Alden F. Abbott General Counsel, U.S. Federal Trade Commission ICN Workshop, Stellenbosch, South Africa, November 2, 2018 1 Introduction: Exclusive Dealing Basics • “An exclusive dealing contract is a contract under which a buyer promises to buy its requirements of one or more products exclusively from a particular seller.” Hovenkamp, Federal Antitrust Policy (2016) • Variations on “full scale” exclusive dealing (partial, de facto) • Loyalty discounts, discounts tied to percentage of purchases from a seller • Slotting allowances, supplier pays fee for preferred or exclusive shelf space • Requirements contracts, agreements to buy all needed units from one seller, also de facto agreements under which firms won’t buy from other sellers • Exclusive dealing may confer substantial procompetitive benefits but also may pose significant anticompetitive risks • case-specific analysis is key • Exclusive dealing assessed by most authorities under antitrust “rule of reason” 2 Evaluating Exclusive Dealing – ICN Review • 2013 ICN Unilateral Conduct Workbook, Chapter 5 – Exclusive Dealing • Outlines elements for flexible rule of reason analysis, focus on evidence • Potential exclusive dealing efficiencies include: • Encouraging distributors to promote a manufacturer’s products more vigorously • Encouraging suppliers to help distributors by providing key services of information • Addressing problems of free riding between suppliers • Addressing “hold up” problems for customer-specific investments • Allowing suppliers to control distribution quality more easily • Potential harms related to market foreclosure (including raising rivals’ costs) • Price increases due to output reduction, also overall reduction in market output • Increase in dominant firm’s market share unexplainable by quality, supply/demand • Exit of existing competitors due to an exclusive dealing arrangement • Entry deterrence (preventing deterrence by potential competitors) 3 Evaluating Exclusive Dealing – U.S. -
Exclusive Contracts and Market Dominance!
Exclusive contracts and market dominance Giacomo Calzolari University of Bologna and CEPR Vincenzo Denicolò University of Leicester, University of Bologna and CEPR November 7th, 2014 Abstract We propose a new theory of exclusive dealing. The theory is based on the assumption that a dominant …rm has a competitive advantage over its rivals, and that the buyers’willingness to pay for the product is private information. In this setting, we show that the dominant …rm can impose contractual restrictions on buyers without having to compensate them. This implies that exclusive dealing contracts can be both pro…table and anticompetitive. We discuss the general implications of the theory for competition policy and illustrate by example how it applies to real world antitrust cases. Keywords: Exclusive dealing; Non-linear pricing; Antitrust; Dominant …rm J.E.L. numbers: D42, D82, L42 We thank Glenn Ellison, Paolo Ramezzana, Helen Weeds, Chris Wallace, Mike Whinston, Piercarlo Zanchettin and seminar participants at MIT, Boston University, Essex, Leicester, Stavanger, Pittsburgh, Bocconi, University of Washington, CEMFI, the Economics of Con‡ict and Cooperation workshop at Bergamo, the SAET conference in Paris, the IIOC conference in Chicago, the CEPR applied industrial organization conference in Athens, the US DoJ, and the European Commission (DG Comp) for useful discussion and comments. The usual disclaimer apply. 1 1 Introduction Exclusive dealing contracts have long raised antitrust concerns. However, ex- isting anticompetitive theories rely on assumptions that do not always …t real antitrust cases. In this paper, we propose a new theory of competitive harm, which is arguably more broadly applicable than existing ones. -
Exclusive Dealing Session
1 1 UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION 2 and 3 UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF JUSTICE 4 5 6 7 SHERMAN ACT SECTION 2 JOINT HEARING 8 UNDERSTANDING SINGLE-FIRM BEHAVIOR: 9 EXCLUSIVE DEALING SESSION 10 WEDNESDAY, NOVEMBER 15, 2006 11 12 13 14 15 HELD AT: 16 UNITED STATES FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION 17 601 NEW JERSEY AVENUE, N.W. 18 WASHINGTON, D.C. 19 9:30 A.M. TO 4:00 P.M. 20 21 22 23 24 Reported and transcribed by: 25 Susanne Bergling, RMR-CLR For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 2 1 MODERATORS: 2 DAN O'BRIEN 3 Chief, Economic Regulatory Section 4 Antitrust Division, Department of Justice 5 and 6 MICHAEL G. VITA 7 Assistant Director 8 Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission 9 10 PANELISTS: 11 12 Morning Session: 13 Jonathan M. Jacobson 14 Howard P. Marvel 15 Richard M. Steuer 16 Mary W. Sullivan 17 Joshua D. Wright 18 19 Afternoon Session: 20 Stephen Calkins 21 Joseph Farrell 22 Benjamin Klein 23 Abbott (Tad) Lipsky 24 25 For The Record, Inc. (301) 870-8025 - www.ftrinc.net - (800) 921-5555 3 1 C O N T E N T S 2 3 MORNING SESSION: 4 Introduction.................................... 4 5 Presentations: 6 Jonathan M. Jacobson.................... 52 7 Howard P. Marvel........................ 40 8 Richard M. Steuer....................... 7 9 Mary W. Sullivan........................ 19 10 Joshua D. Wright........................ 29 11 Moderated Discussion............................ 63 12 Lunch Recess....................................105 13 14 AFTERNOON SESSION: 15 Introduction....................................106 16 Presentations: 17 Stephen Calkins.........................108 18 Joseph Farrell..........................133 19 Benjamin Klein..........................145 20 Abbott (Tad) Lipsky.....................120 21 Moderated Discussion............................161 22 Conclusion......................................202 23 24 25 For The Record, Inc. -
Protest Boycotts As Restraints of Trade Under the Sherman Act: a Proposed Standard
Cleveland State Law Review Volume 30 Issue 2 Article 7 1981 Protest Boycotts as Restraints of Trade under the Sherman Act: A Proposed Standard Francis M. Allegra Follow this and additional works at: https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! Recommended Citation Francis M. Allegra, Protest Boycotts as Restraints of Trade under the Sherman Act: A Proposed Standard, 30 Clev. St. L. Rev. 221 (1981) available at https://engagedscholarship.csuohio.edu/clevstlrev/vol30/iss2/7 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Journals at EngagedScholarship@CSU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cleveland State Law Review by an authorized editor of EngagedScholarship@CSU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PROTEST BOYCOTTS AS RESTRAINTS OF TRADE UNDER THE SHERMAN ACT: A PROPOSED STANDARD FRANCIS M. ALLEGRA* I. INTRODUCTION T HE SHERMAN ANTI-TRUST ACT' WAS ORIGINALLY ENACTED to combat trusts'- powerful business combinations, capable of wielding con- centrated economic power-created when individual shareholders from various corporations transferred their shares to a single trustee or governing board.' In pertinent part, section 1 of the Sherman Act states that "[elvery contract, combination . .. , or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States .... is declared to be il- legal."' The comprehensive language of section 1, though subsequently limited in its scope,5 evinces a congressional intent to utilize the plenary power of the Commerce Clause to its fullest extent.' Yet, while the broad language was designed to preserve economic freedom and unfet- * Judicial Clerk, United States Court of Claims, Washington, D.C.; Assoc.