Journal of 96 (2012) 400–416

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Public Economics

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jpube

Optimal fiscal barriers to international economic integration in the presence of havens☆

Niels Johannesen ⁎

Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Øster Farimagsgade 5, building 26, DK-1353 Copenhagen, Denmark article info abstract

Article history: This paper develops a model where firms can shift profits to tax havens by means of intra-firm loans and Received 5 March 2009 countries can protect themselves against profit shifting by taxing cross-border interest flows. The model con- Received in revised form 8 December 2011 siders two countries with a scope for welfare improving economic integration. The first-best tax system has Accepted 24 December 2011 two important characteristics: (i) the on interest flows to the other country is zero to ensure the Available online 30 December 2011 optimal level of economic integration; (ii) the tax rate on interest flows to tax havens is high enough to deter profit shifting to tax havens. In second-best environments, countries face a -off between economic Keywords: integration and protection against tax havens, which causes protection to be suboptimally low. The key to the Profit shifting result is that economic integration makes it easier for multinational firms to circumvent on interest Tax havens payments to tax havens with conduit loans. The paper thus provides an explanation for the empirical puzzle Tax planning that many countries do not tax interest payments to tax havens despite the scope for profit shifting. Withholding taxes © 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Economic integration

1. Introduction capital employed by domestic firms. In this framework, profit shifting allows multinational firms to reduce their effective tax rate and thus Multinational firms face strong incentives to shift profits from improves efficiency by establishing a de facto differentiated capital countries with high corporate taxes to tax havens. A common profit tax with a lower effective rate on mobile capital than on immobile shifting technique uses intra-firm loans from finance subsidiaries in capital.1 tax havens to operating subsidiaries in high-tax countries. Such Interestingly, Mintz (2004) notes that governments have access to loans generate a tax saving because the interest payments shift a tax instrument capable of eliminating the scope for this type of prof- taxable profits from operating subsidiaries facing a high tax rate to it shifting: Withholding taxes on interest payments to foreign entities finance subsidiaries facing a zero tax rate. effectively reduce the tax savings from intra-firm loans and thus con- Recently, an interesting controversy has emerged about the wel- stitute a fiscal barrier to profit shifting. Arguably, a general withhold- fare implications of profit shifting facilitated by tax havens. The con- ing tax on cross-border interest payments would place multinational ventional view that tax havens are harmful is formalized by firms at a disadvantage relative to other firms and therefore also con- Slemrod and Wilson (2009) in a model where tax havens provide stitute a fiscal barrier to economic integration. Under the view that services to firms. In this setting, tax evasion reduces wel- tax havens are harmful, this suggests that optimal withholding fare due to unproductive use of resources by tax havens facilitating taxes should be differentiated with a high rate applying to interest evasion and by tax administrations combating evasion. The alterna- payments to tax havens and a zero rate applying to interest payments tive view that tax havens are beneficial is developed by Hong and to other countries. Intuitively, such a tax system offers protection Smart (2010) in a model where the falls on both per- against profit shifting without impeding economic integration be- fectly mobile capital employed by multinational firms and immobile tween countries. Table 1 reports withholding tax schedules applying to intra-firm interest payments in 28 OECD countries. The first column lists the ☆ I am grateful to Clemens Fuest, Peter Birch Sørensen and participants at the Nordic withholding tax rate stipulated by domestic law, which is the rate Workshop on and Public Economics, the Annual Meeting of the European Doctoral Group in Economics, the Zeuthen Workshop and the Annual Conference of the Association for Public Economic Theory as well as seminar participants at the 1 Johannesen (2010a) points to a positive general equilibrium effect of tax havens. University of Copenhagen for many helpful suggestions. I would also like to thank Joel When tax competition for profits is imperfect in the sense that not all profits are Slemrod (editor) and three anonymous referees for encouraging and insightful comments shifted to the jurisdiction with the lowest tax rate, the tax game between ex ante iden- and suggestions. This research project was initiated during a visit to the Burch Center at UC tical countries may result in an asymmetric equilibrium with an endogenous fraction of Berkeley and I am very grateful for the kind hospitality I was shown there. high-tax and low-tax countries. In this setting, tax havens can potentially improve the ⁎ Tel.: +45 35324415; fax: +45 35323000. welfare of countries by strengthening tax competition for profits, which induces low- E-mail address: [email protected]. tax countries to become high-tax countries.

0047-2727/$ – see front matter © 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jpubeco.2011.12.008 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 401

Table 1 Withholding tax rates on interest flows between related corporations (source country in rows, residence country in columns). Source: PriceWaterhouseCoopers, Global Tax Summaries, Data extract on 2 March 2009.

Domestic law AT BE CZ DK FI FR GE GR HU IE IT LU NL PL PT SP SW UK AU CA JP KO MX NZ NO CH TR US

Austria 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Belgiuma 15 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10 10 10 10 10 10 15 0 15 15 Czech Republic 15 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10 10 10 10 10 10 0 0 20 0 Denmark 30 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Finland 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 France 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Germany 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Greeceb 25 10 10 10 8 10 10 10 X 10 5 10 8 10 10 15 8 10 0 25 25 25 8 10 25 10 10 12 25 Hungary 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Ireland 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Italy 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Luxembourg 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Netherlands 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Polandb 20 10 10 10 5 0 0 5 10 10 10 10 10 5 X 10 0 0 5 10 15 10 10 15 10 0 10 10 0 Portugalb 20 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 X 10 10 10 20 10 20 15 10 20 15 10 15 10 Spain 18 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 10 15 10 10 15 10 10 0 15 10 Sweden 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 United Kingdom 20 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 10 10 10 10 15 10 0 0 15 0 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 X 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 Canada 25 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 25 10 10 10 10 10 15 10 15 10 10 10 X 10 10 10 15 10 10 25 0 Japan 20 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 20 10 10 10 10 10 10 20 10 10 10 10 10 X 10 10 20 10 10 15 10 South Korea 25 10 10 10 15 10 10 10 8 0 0 10 10 10 10 15 10 15 10 15 10 10 X 15 10 15 10 10 12 Mexico 28 10 15 10 15 15 10 15 10 28 10 10 10 15 15 10 15 15 15 15 10 15 15 X 10 15 15 28 15 New Zealand 15 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 15 15 10 10 15 10 10 15 10 10 10 10 15 15 10 10 X 10 10 15 10 Norway 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 X 0 0 0 Switzerland 35 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 10 10 10 10 15 10 0 X 35 0 Turkey 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 X 10 USA 30 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 30 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 15 10 15 10 15 15 15 20 X

Note: Rules are in some cases complex and the rates presented here are the rates that would – according to our judgment – apply to a finance structure as described in the paper. No data were available for Iceland and the Slovak Republic. a Withholding when the Belgium compamny acts as a conduit company for transactions between two non-Belgian companies. b Temporary exemption from Council Directive 2003/49/EC abolishing taxes on intra-firm interest flows within the EU. Rates to EU countries will fall to 5% on 1 July 2009 and 0% on 1 July 2013.

applying to interest flows to tax havens. Subsequent columns list to profit shifting is, seemingly, incompatible with the Slemrod–Wil- withholding tax rates applying to interest flows to other OECD coun- son view of tax havens. If profit shifting to tax havens leads to waste- tries as specified by bilateral treaties and other international agree- ful use of resources, it is puzzling that a large number of countries do ments. Generally, interest flows between OECD countries are subject not set sufficiently high fiscal barriers to eliminate the scope for this to very low tax rates, most notably a zero rate applies to interest type of tax planning. An important contribution of the present flows between EU countries.2 This is consistent with the standard ar- paper is to expose a mechanism that causes fiscal protection against gument that countries benefit from a joint elimination of barriers to tax havens to be suboptimal (or entirely absent) even when tax ha- economic integration. Perhaps more surprisingly, a considerable vens are harmful. This reconciles the Slemrod–Wilson view of tax ha- number of countries, in particular EU countries, do not tax interest vens with observed features of real-world tax systems. payments to entities. Evidently, a zero tax rate on interest This paper analyzes taxation of cross-border interest flows in a payments to tax havens maximizes the benefits associated with tax model of international economic integration. The model considers planning by allowing firms to shift profits to tax havens at no tax two countries, Home and Foreign, with a scope for welfare improving cost.3 economic integration. Each country has access to three tax instru- The absence of fiscal barriers to profit shifting is clearly consistent ments: a corporate tax, a tax on interest payments to entities in the with the Hong–Smart view of tax havens. If profit shifting improves other country, an internal fiscal barrier, and a tax on interest payments efficiency, there is no reason to expect that countries would tax to entities in tax havens, an external fiscal barrier. Firms are heteroge- intra-firm interest payments. Moreover, the absence of fiscal barriers neous with respect to productivity and optimally choose whether to produce only domestically or in both countries.4 Firms also make optimal decisions on the following two interrelated dimensions of 2 Council Directive 2003/49/EC known as the Interest and Royalty Directive abolished financial policies: Firstly, they choose the capital structure of their withholding taxes on interest flows between related EU companies as from 1 January operating subsidiaries including the amount of financing with intra- 2004, however, Portugal, Greece and Poland were conceded transitory arrangements allowing for withholding taxes until 1 July 2013. firm loans. Secondly, they decide whether to provide the intra-firm 3 Admittedly, many countries have rules applying to controlled foreign companies loans through a subsidiary in a tax haven and whether these loans (hereinafter “CFC rules”) under which income earned by a finance subsidiary estab- should be direct loans or conduit loans. For instance, if Home sets a lished in a tax haven could be subject to domestic corporate tax. Such CFC-rules may, fi “ ” high external barrier to deter pro t shifting, it may be optimal for however, be circumvented in a number of relatively simple ways: (i) De-controlling : fi the finance company issues preferred shares to a third party whereby the ownership rms producing in both countries to let the tax haven subsidiary share of the parent company is diluted making the finance company fall outside the grant a loan to the operating subsidiary in Foreign, which passes on scope of the CFC-rules whereas effective control is retained; (ii) “Swamping”: profits from the real activities of the firm are channeled through the finance company where- by the fraction of passive income in the finance company is reduced so it does not fall under the CFC-rules; (iii) “Migration”: the ultimate parent company of the firm is 4 This feature of the model bears some resemblance to Helpman et al. (2004) except established in a tax haven and this parent directly owns the finance company in which that firms can only enter foreign markets by way of direct investment and not by way case the CFC-rules of the countries where the firm operates do not apply. of exporting. 402 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 the loan to the operating subsidiary in Home. In that case, optimal policy involves positive effective internal barriers. Intuitively, interest payments are subject to the internal barrier of Home and raising internal barriers hampers economic integration and reduces the external barrier of Foreign instead of the high external barrier of welfare, however, when raised from an initial level where economic Home. integration is optimal, the welfare loss is second-order. On the other Before turning to the results, we briefly comment on certain im- hand, raising internal barriers increases the tax cost of conduit portant features of the model. Firstly, adding withholding taxes to loans, which is associated with a first-order welfare gain since it mit- the set of tax instruments has the obvious merit that the extent to igates the race-to-the-bottom in external barriers. which tax havens are integrated in the world economy is treated as Under the assumption of the model that tax havens are harmful, a truly endogenous outcome. For instance, if both countries set high these results suggest that policies currently conducted by EU coun- external barriers, there is no scope for profit shifting and tax havens tries are suboptimal. Ideally, EU countries should extend policy coop- are effectively cut off from the world economy. This contrasts the eration and set a common external barrier high enough to deter tax approach of related papers where the presence of tax havens is planning involving tax havens. If this first-best policy is not imple- treated as an exogenous shock (e.g. Hong and Smart, 2010; Slemrod mentable, the EU should allow member countries to raise internal and Wilson, 2009; Johannesen, 2010a). Secondly, introducing conduit barriers above zero. This would enhance welfare by making tax loans into the model of the firm highlights that the effective level of planning more costly and thus increase protection against profit protection against profit shifting in a country depends not only on shifting. its own external barrier but also on the internal barrier and external At a more general level, the integration of conduit finance into a barriers of other countries. Economic integration with other countries model of capital taxation gives rise to two novel insights5: Firstly, and economic integration with tax havens are therefore fundamen- countries face mixed incentives when choosing their policy position tally intertwined. This point has not been made previously in the lit- towards harmful tax havens: On one hand, countries wish to protect erature since existing models of optimal tax policy in the presence of their domestic tax base and therefore have an incentive to use tax in- tax havens are not embedded in models of economic integration. Fi- struments to restrict transactions with tax havens. On the other hand, nally, the model assumes symmetry in the production technologies restrictive policies induce firms to carry out transactions with tax ha- of national and multinational firms and thus rules out that profit vens through affiliated entities in other countries. It follows that a fis- shifting to tax havens improves efficiency as in the Hong–Smart cal environment with imperfect protection against harmful tax framework. This is to focus on the interesting case of harmful tax ha- havens may be the endogenous outcome of tax competition. Second- vens where there is a real tension between the two policy motives, ly, there is an intrinsic tension between economic integration and economic integration and protection against tax havens, and not on protection against harmful tax havens. While international agree- the case of beneficial tax havens where there is no rationale for ments eliminating taxes on cross-country capital flows have been taxes on cross-border interest flows. successful in promoting economic integration, they also constitute The first result relates to optimal tax policies under perfect cooper- powerful tax planning tools in the hands of multinational firms ation where countries cooperate on all dimensions of tax policy. We since they remove the tax cost of conduit structures. This provides show that the two countries optimally eliminate internal barriers an argument for taxes on international capital flows even at the cost and set external barriers so high that no firms shift profits to tax ha- of suboptimal economic integration. vens. This result is very intuitive given the premise that tax havens The remainder of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 de- are harmful. The optimal policy achieves the optimal level of econom- velops the model. Section 3 characterizes the market equilibrium for ic integration between the two countries while providing complete given tax rates. Section 4 derives optimal tax policy under perfect co- protection against tax havens. operation. Section 5 analyzes the equilibrium under EU-style cooper- The second result characterizes the equilibrium of a game where ation. Section 6 characterizes optimal tax policy under imperfect countries are committed not to use internal barriers and set other di- cooperation. Section 7 provides a few concluding remarks. mensions of tax policy non-cooperatively. The motivation for analyz- ing this game is that it mirrors the environment in which EU countries are currently setting capital taxes and we therefore label 2. Model the game EU-style cooperation. We show that the game has a unique equilibrium where the external barrier in both countries is zero. The The model considers two identical countries, Home and Foreign, key to this result is that in the absence of internal barriers, firms use which together constitute a small subset of the world economy. conduit loans to channel interest payments to tax haven entities Both countries are populated by two types of individuals: entrepre- through the country with the lowest external barrier. Countries neurs who own and operate a firm and workers who supply labor to therefore gain no additional protection against profit shifting by hav- the firms. Entrepreneurs are heterogeneous in two orthogonal di- ing external barriers higher than the other country. Moreover, coun- mensions. Firstly, entrepreneurs differ with respect to their ability tries gain from undercutting the other country since this attracts tax as captured by the parameter α, which is uniformly distributed on base in the form of conduit loans. In equilibrium, external barriers the interval [αL ;αH]. Secondly, a fixed fraction λ of the entrepreneurs are competed down to zero and countries suffer from an absolute are avoiders that exploit any profitable tax planning opportunities of- lack of protection against profit shifting. This result reconciles the fered by the presence of tax havens whereas the remaining entrepre- empirical fact that a number of EU countries do not tax interest neurs are compliers that never exploit such opportunities due to payments to tax havens with the Slemrod–Wilson view that tax unspecified informational, ethical or other constraints.6 Workers are havens are harmful. homogenous and inelastically supply one unit of labor. We normalize The final result concerns optimal tax policies under imperfect the mass of workers in each country to one. All individuals are cooperation where countries are unable to cooperate on all dimen- sions of tax policy. The analysis is motivated by the observation that cooperation on certain important policy dimensions, such as enforce- ment efforts and tax base definitions, is very difficult from a practical 5 Conduit finance has largely been neglected in the public finance literature. One ex- perspective. Formally, we assume that effective fiscal barriers are de- ception is Mintz (2004) who computes the cost of capital with and without conduit en- tities but does not analyze optimal tax policy within this framework. termined in two stages, a first stage where nominal barriers are set 6 The assumed heterogeneity in types is consistent with the empirically observable cooperatively and a second stage where another policy dimension, pattern that otherwise comparable firms differ widely in their use of tax haven subsid- say enforcement efforts, is set non-cooperatively. We show that the iaries (Desai et al., 2006). N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 403 endowed with s units of capital and we adopt the standard assumption claimants of firm profits whereas the representative workers, which that capital is perfectly mobile across countries whereas individuals are constitute the local management, receive a fixed salary.7 immobile. Finally, we assume that the world economy comprises at For expositional simplicity, we assume that firms do not have ac- least one tax haven that levies no taxes. cess to external loans. This implies that borrowing by operating sub- sidiaries must be in the form of internal loans from other firm 2.1. Firms entities.8 While this assumption simplifies the analysis considerably, the qualitative results extend to a setting where subsidiaries can Firms optimally choose one of the following production plans: borrow from external investors provided that internal and external (i) not produce at all; (ii) operate a single domestic production borrowing are imperfect substitutes from a non-tax perspective. plant or (iii) operate a single domestic production plant and a single When the entrepreneur is a complier, the capital structure of the foreign production plant. Hence, active firms optimally choose firm is particularly simple: The parent company raises in exter- whether to be national or multinational but are constrained to oper- nal capital markets and passes on the funds to operating subsidiaries ate at most one plant in each country. In terms of organizational in the form of debt and equity. Hence, the financial policy simply structure, each firm is headed by a parent company and comprises specifies the debt–asset ratio θ of each of the two operating subsidi- an operating subsidiary for each of its production plants. The parent aries. This is illustrated in Fig. 1 in the case of a firm that produces company is managed by the entrepreneur whereas operating subsid- in both countries. iaries are managed by a representative worker. When the entrepreneur is an avoider, the firm may choose a more The productivity of a production plant depends partly on the abil- sophisticated financial policy that exploits the tax planning opportu- ity level of the entrepreneur, partly on the location of the plant and nities offered by tax havens. Under the simplest form of tax planning, partly on the capital structure of the operating subsidiary. Specifically, the parent company injects equity into a tax haven subsidiary, which operating a production plant requires a single unit of capital and h passes on the funds to the operating subsidiaries in the form of units of labor. The output of a production plant at these fixed input loans. This tax planning structure reduces the corporate tax bill by levels is given by the following production function: shifting taxable profits to the tax haven, however, there may be an offsetting effect on profits through exposure to the external barrier. α−cðÞθ if the plant is domestic The firm may choose to incorporate an additional element into the FðÞ¼α; θ ð1Þ α−m−cðÞθ if the plant is foreign tax planning structure: If a country, say Home, attempts to deter prof- it shifting to tax havens by means of a high external barrier, the firm where θ is the debt–asset ratio of the subsidiary operating the plant. can resort to conduit loans that channel interest payments through The first part of the production function gives the potential produc- Foreign. Specifically, the tax haven subsidiary grants a loan to the op- tion level of the plant given the ability level of the entrepreneur. erating subsidiary in Foreign, which passes on the loan to the operat- The potential production level is simply α for domestic plants located ing subsidiary in Home. The loan now faces the internal barrier of in the same country as the parent company and α−m for foreign Home and the external barrier of Foreign instead of the external bar- plants located in the other country where m represents inefficiencies rier of Home. The financial structure of a firm engaged in tax planning caused by the distance between the central management and the sub- with conduit loans through Foreign is illustrated in Fig. 2. sidiary. The second part of the production function c(θ) captures the For analytical simplicity, we impose that only firms with operating impact of the capital structure on productivity. While we do not ex- subsidiaries in both countries can implement a tax planning struc- plicitly model this mechanism, the underlying idea is that firms are ture. This assumption is consistent with the empirical pattern docu- plagued by principal–agent problems and that capital structure is a mented by Desai et al. (2006) that large and internationally corporate governance tool allowing entrepreneurs to mitigate ineffi- oriented firms are much more likely to operate tax haven subsidiaries ciencies associated with self-interested managers of the production than small and domestically oriented firms. The assumption is also in plants. In our reduced-form formulation of the principal–agent prob- line with the legal argument by Kleinbard (2011) that purely domes- ~ lem, we simply assume that there exists a debt–asset ratio θ, which tic firms are effectively precluded from engaging in most types of in- ~ maximizes the production of a plant, and that deviations from θ are ternational tax planning. associated with real costs in terms of lower output. We normalize Summing up, all entrepreneurs face a binary choice of firm scale ~ ~ the cost function so that c θ ¼ 0 and assume that c′ðÞθ θ−θ > 0 (national vs multinational) and avoiders furthermore face a binary and c″(θ)>0, which implies that the output loss associated with a choice related to (tax planning vs no tax planning). ~ ~ marginal change in θ away from θ is increasing in the distance θ−θ. There are at most three types of active firms, which we label in the The notion that capital structure affects productivity draws on the following way for future reference: national firms operating a argument of Jensen (1986) that when managers engage in empire fi fl building, debt increases ef ciency by reducing the free cash ow 7 fi fi Other theories of corporate nance conjecture that a pre-commitment to future available for unpro table investment. While the original formulation dividend payments may mitigate the free cash-flow problem in much the same way of the theory is concerned with agency problems at the level of the as the interest payments associated with debt. To model the choice between interest central management, we follow Huizinga et al. (2008) in applying a and dividend payments in a meaningful way, we would need to introduce two addi- similar reasoning to lower levels of management. Within multi- tional tax instruments into the model, namely a tax on dividend payments to the for- eign country and a tax on dividend payments to the tax haven, which would greatly divisional firms local managers conduct business on behalf of the cen- complicate the model. It is therefore assumed that debt is the only tool available to tral management and presuming that the former are concerned with firms to mitigate agency problems. the growth of the specific division they are managing rather than the 8 Recent empirical research shows that internal loans constitute an important com- overall performance of the firm, debt financing of subsidiaries repre- ponent of the capital structure of multinational firms. The Midi dataset collected by the fi sents an instrument to discipline local managers producing a large German Central Bank contains very detailed nancial information on virtually all Ger- fl man inbound and outbound foreign direct investment and thus represent the most cash ow. In the present model, we focus on agency problems at complete source of data on the capital structure of multinational firms. Two recent pa- the subsidiary level and abstract from agency problems at the central pers provide summary statistics from this dataset. Buettner and Wamser (2009) report level, hence the specification of the production function where the an average internal debt–asset ratio of foreign affiliates of German multinational firms subsidiary-level debt–asset ratio rather than the firm-level debt– of around 24% whereas Ramb and Weichenreider (2005) report an average internal debt–asset ratio of German affiliates of non-German firms of around 30%. These asset ratio determines plant productivity. This is consistent with a figures are largely consistent with less complete data available for US multinational model property that will emerge below, namely that entrepreneurs, firms (Desai et al., 2004). See Johannesen (2010b) for a more comprehensive discus- which constitute the central management of firms, are residual sion of the available evidence on internal loans. 404 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416

Equity: 2 Equity: 2

Parent Parent company company (Home) (Home)

θPd θMd Equity: (1- ) Equity: (1-θPf) Equity: (1- ) Equity: (1-θMf) θMd θPd θPf Loans: Loans: θMf Equity: +

Operating Operating Operating Operating θPd Conduit loan: subsidiary subsidiary subsidiary subsidiary (Foreign) (Home) (Foreign) (Home)

Note: θMd and θMf denote the optimal level of debt in the domestic and foreign operating subsidiary of a multinational firm respectively. Direct loan: θPf Conduit loan: θPd Finance Fig. 1. The financial structure of multinational firms. subsidiary (tax haven) domestic plant and not engaging in tax planning; multinational firms θPd θPf operating a plant in each of the two countries and not engaging Note: and denote the optimal level of intra-firm debt in the domestic and foreign operating subsidiary of the planning firm respectively. in tax planning; planning firms operating a plant in each of the two countries and engaging in tax planning. Firms operating a Fig. 2. The financial structure of planning firms. domestic plant and engaging in tax planning are ruled out by assumption. let superscript d and f refer to a subsidiary in the same country as the parent company (d=domestic) and the opposite country of the par- 2.2. Government ent company (f=foreign) respectively. Hence, θf denotes the debt– asset ratio of a subsidiary in Foreign owned by a parent company in The two countries levy taxes to finance a of a fixed Home whereas θf * denotes the debt–asset ratio of a subsidiary in size G. The government objective is to maximize aggregate private Home owned by a parent company in Foreign. Moreover, we let su- disposable income X subject to the constraint that government perscript N denote a national firm, M a multinational firm and P a revenue G satisfies the constraint G ¼ G.9 Revenue is raised with a planning firm. Finally, we introduce the short-hand notation t for a corporate tax tC and withholding taxes on interest payments to vector that fully describes the tax environment in the two countries, foreign entities. The withholding taxes may be differentiated so that i.e. t≡(tC,tI,tE,tC ,tI ,tE ). the applicable rate depends on the country where the foreign entity resides. In particular, the tax rate tI applying to interest payments to 3. Market equilibrium entities in the other country need not coincide with the tax rate tE ap- plying to interest payments to tax haven entities. Since we are con- This section derives the market equilibrium for given tax policies. cerned with optimal tax policy from the perspective of the two The first subsection computes the maximum profits that can be countries, we refer to tI as the internal fiscal barrier and tE as the exter- obtained from each of the three firm types by a given entrepreneur nal fiscal barrier. in a given tax environment. The second subsection uses these expres- We assume that taxes fall directly on capital and not on capital in- sions to show how entrepreneurs choose firm type as a function of come. Hence, the corporate tax base is capital reduced by net borrow- their individual characteristics and derives the allocation of resources ing. Assuming that non-capital inputs of the entrepreneur are between the three firm types for given tax policies and factor prices. correctly classified as labor for tax purposes, this is equivalent to a The third subsection sets up the clearing condition for the labor mar- tax on firm income net of interest expenses and labor costs, i.e. the ket and shows that the wage rate adjusts to determine the equilibri- conventional corporate tax. The withholding tax base is simply the um number of firms of each type. Throughout the section, we amount of outstanding debt to foreign entities, which is equivalent analyze Home, however, everything is perfectly symmetric for to a tax on interest payments to foreign entities. It is assumed that Foreign. both countries apply the exemption principle, which implies that profits generated by foreign subsidiaries are tax exempt at the level 3.1. Optimal financial policies of the parent company. This subsection in turn derives optimal financial policies for 2.3. Notation each of the three firm types, national firms, multinational firms and planning firms, and uses the results to compute maximized profits In order to distinguish between the two countries, we let variables for each of the firm types for a given entrepreneur. associated with Foreign have asterisks. In the case of policy parame- The profit function of a national firm operated by entrepreneur i ters (e.g. tax rates) and factor prices (e.g. wage rates) this is straight- can be stated as: forward. In the case of firm-specific and subsidiary-specific variables fi – Π θ α − θ − − − C (e.g. pro ts and debt asset ratios), we adopt the convention that var- iðÞ¼ i cðÞ hw r t ð2Þ iables have asterisks when the parent company resides in Foreign and where r is the required net-of-tax return to capital exogenously de- termined on the world capital market. The expression merely states

9 fi By assuming that governments maximize aggregate private consumption X,we that pro ts equal production net of labor costs, capital costs and sidestep redistributional issues. taxes. Since debt shifts the tax burden from the domestic subsidiary N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 405 to the parent company, which are both facing the tax rate tC, the subsidiary. Hence, the specification of the profit function takes into tax burden is simply tC regardless of the debt–asset ratio θ. The account that planning firms choose the most tax efficient path for profit-maximizing debt–asset ratio of the sole subsidiary of a national loans granted by tax haven subsidiaries.10 The profit-maximizing firm θN is implicitly defined by the first-order condition: debt–asset ratios of the domestic and foreign subsidiaries of a plan- ning firm, θPd and θPf respectively, are implicitly defined by the first- N c′ θ ¼ 0: ð3Þ order conditions: ′ θPd C − RE It follows directly from the assumptions about the agency cost c ¼ t t ð8Þ θN θ~ fi function that ¼ . Intuitively, a national rm has no – Pf C RE to deviate from the debt asset ratio that is optimal for non-tax c′ θ ¼ t −t : ð9Þ purposes. The profit function of a multinational firm operated by entrepre- fi θPd θPf > θ~ neur i can be stated as: The two rst-order conditions imply that ¼ when tax C E 8 policies are symmetric provided that t >t . Intuitively, when the < α − θd − − − C tax treatment of loans from the tax haven subsidiary is more favor- i c hw r t þ Π ðÞ¼θ ð4Þ able than the tax treatment of equity, planning firms respond by i : α − − θ f − − − −θ f C−θ f C I i m c hw r 1 t t þ t distorting the capital structure of operating subsidiaries toward debt. To summarize, we have derived optimal debt–asset ratios θk for where θd and θf are the debt–asset ratios of the domestic and the for- each of the five plant types, i.e. the domestic plant of a national firm eign subsidiary respectively. The first line reflects the profits of the (k=N), the domestic plant of a multinational firm (k=Md), the domestic subsidiary whereas the second line reflects the profits of foreign plant of a multinational firm (k=Mf), the domestic plant of the foreign subsidiary. As for the domestic subsidiary, debt financing a planning firm (k=Pd) and the foreign plant of a planning firm shifts profits to the parent company in Home, hence the tax burden (k=Pf). is simply tC regardless of the debt–asset ratio θd. As for the foreign We simplify notation by letting ck ≡c(θk) denote agency costs at a subsidiary, equity is subject to the foreign corporate tax whereas plant of type k evaluated at the optimal debt–asset ratio θk. Moreover, debt is subject to the foreign internal barrier and the corporate tax we let Tj denote the tax bill associated with each firm type j evaluated at the level of the parent. The profit-maximizing debt–asset ratios at the optimal debt–asset ratios: of the domestic and foreign subsidiaries of a multinational firm, N C θMd and θMf respectively, are implicitly defined by the first-order T ¼ t ð10Þ conditions: TM ¼ tC þ tC þ θMf tC −tC þ tI ð11Þ c′ θMd ¼ 0 ð5Þ P C C−θPd C − RE −θPf C− RE Mf C C I T ¼ t þ t t t t t ð12Þ c′ θ ¼ t −t −t : ð6Þ

where j=N indicates a national firm, j=M indicates a multinational fi θMd θ~ The former rst-order condition implies that ¼ . Just like the firm and j=P indicates a planning firm. With this notation we can ex- fi fi national rm, the multinational rm has no tax incentive to distort press the maximized profits of each of the firm types in the following the capital structure of its domestic subsidiary because debt merely way: shifts from the domestic subsidiary to the parent. Mf ~ The latter first-order condition implies that θ ≤θ when tax policies ΠN α − − − N i ¼ i hw r T ð13Þ in the two countries are symmetric (with equality when tI =0). no Intuitively, while at symmetric tax policies shifting profits from the ΠM α −hw−r α −m−cMf −hw−r −TM 14 foreign subsidiary to the parent has no effect on the global corporate i ¼ fgþi i ð Þ tax bill, the internal barrier introduces a tax disadvantage of debt over nono equity that induces the multinational to reduce the debt–asset ratio ΠP α − Pd− − α − − Pf − − − P: i ¼ i c hw r þ i m c hw r T ð15Þ below the level that maximizes production. The profit function of a planning firm operated by entrepreneur i can be stated as: 3.2. Firm types 8 < α − θd − − − −θd C −θd RE i c hw r 1 t t Π ðÞ¼θ ð7Þ Entrepreneurs choose to operate the type of firm that yields the i : α − − θ f − − − −θ f C−θ f RE i m c hw r 1 t t highest level of profits given their ability: Compliers choose between operating a national firm and a multinational firm. Avoiders choose where tRE is labeled the real external barrier and defined in the following between operating a national firm, a multinational firm and a plan- way: ning firm. In addition, all entrepreneurs have the option not to pro- duce, in which case profits are zero. no N N The equality Πi =0 defines a threshold ability level α at which RE ≡ E; I E : t min t t þ t entrepreneurs exactly break even if operating a national firm:

N N The real external barrier tRE reflects that debt financing from a tax α ¼ hw þ r þ T : ð16Þ haven subsidiary to the domestic subsidiary may take the form of a direct loan, in which case the tax cost is tE, or a conduit loan through the foreign operating subsidiary, in which case the tax cost is tI +tE *. RE The real external barrier t thus expresses the lowest possible 10 As a tie-breaker, we assume that firms prefer direct loans over conduit loans in tax cost associated with a loan from the tax haven to the domestic cases where the two paths are equally tax efficient. 406 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416

At this ability level, the production of the domestic plant is just P i sufficient to cover the costs of production inputs and taxes. Clearly, α bαN fi entrepreneurs with i would make negative pro ts if operating M a national firm and are therefore better off not producing at all i N N i whereas entrepreneurs with αi >α are able to derive positive profits from a national firm. We refer to a national firm operated by an entre- N preneur with αi =α as a marginal national firm. M N M The equality Πi =Πi defines a threshold ability level α at which entrepreneurs are exactly indifferent between operating a na- αN αP αM α fi fi i tional rm and a multinational rm: D -{r+hw}-T

M Mf M N α m hw r c T −T : 17 PD ¼ þ þ þ þ ð Þ -{r+hw+c } PF P -{r+hw*+m+c }-T Since the domestic subsidiary of a multinational firm is identical to -{r+hw} fi fi MF M the domestic subsidiary of a national rm in terms of nancial policy -{r+hw*+m+c } -T and tax liability, TM −TN is the tax bill associated with the foreign M operating subsidiary of a multinational firm. It follows that α is the Fig. 3. The allocation of resources between firm types. ability level at which the foreign operating subsidiary of a multina- M tional firm exactly breaks even. Entrepreneurs with αi bα would de- rive negative profits from a foreign plant and are therefore better off as the tax saving associated with tax planning although, strictly only producing domestically whereas entrepreneurs with α >αM are i speaking, it includes differences in tax bills as well as corporate gov- able to derive positive profits from the foreign operating subsidiary. ernance related output losses. We refer to a multinational firm operated by an entrepreneur with Finally, the equality ΠP =ΠN implicitly defines a threshold ability α =αM as a marginal multinational firm. i i i level αP at which avoiders are exactly indifferent between operating a In any symmetric equilibrium, it holds that αM >αN. Intuitively, national firm and a planning firm: domestic subsidiaries have advantages over foreign subsidiaries in terms of technology since the potential output of a foreign plant is lower than that of a domestic plant operated by the same entrepre- αP ¼ m þ hw þ r þ TP þ cPd þ cPf −TN: ð19Þ neur and in terms of taxation since loans from the parent to the for- eign subsidiary are subject to the internal barrier. Hence, it requires Avoiders with α bαP are better off operating a national firm than a a higher ability level to break even with a foreign subsidiary than a i planning firm whereas the reverse is true for avoiders with α >αP. domestic subsidiary. This implies the existence of an intermediate i We refer to a planning firm operated by an avoider with α =αP as a range of ability levels α ∈[αN ;αM] at which entrepreneurs prefer to i i marginal planning firm. operate a national firm over a multinational firm and a high range It is easy to see that if Γ>0, it holds that αP bαM, which implies a of ability levels α ∈[αM ;αH] at which entrepreneurs prefer to operate i wedge between the abilities of entrepreneurs operating marginal a multinational firm over a national firm. 11 Intuitively, the most pro- planning firms and marginal multinational firms. As the tax saving ductive entrepreneurs are able to derive positive profits from foreign approaches zero, the ability wedge closes and αP approaches αM. subsidiaries despite the technological and fiscal disadvantage of for- For entrepreneurs that are avoiders, αN, αM, αP and Γ jointly char- eign operations.12 acterize choices over firm types. Avoiders with α bαN do not produce For entrepreneurs that are compliers, αN and αM fully characterize i at all. When Γ>0 avoiders with αN ≤α bαP operate a national firm choices over firm types. Compliers with ability level α bαN do not i i whereas avoiders with α ≥αP operate a planning firm. When Γ≤0 produce at all, compliers with αN ≤α bαM operate a national firm i i avoiders with αN ≤α bαM operate a national firm whereas avoiders and compliers with α ≥αM operate a multinational firm. i i with α ≥αM operate a multinational firm. For entrepreneurs that are avoiders and thus use tax havens i Fig. 3 illustrates the profit functions of the three types of firms and whenever this is profitable, we also need to consider the possibility the allocation of resources between them.13 The line ΠN illustrates of a planning firm. We first define Γ as the difference in profits be- i the maximized profits of a national firm as a function of the ability tween a planning and a multinational firm Γ≡ΠP −ΠM and rearrange i i level of the entrepreneur. The intersection with the vertical axis to obtain: gives the minimized costs of operating a national firm and the inter- nono section with the horizontal axis gives the threshold ability level αN Γ M Mf − P Pd Pf : ¼ T þ c T þ c þ c ð18Þ at which a national firm breaks even. The slope of the line is 1 reflect- ing that a unit increase in ability yields a unit increase in profits. The ΠM fi fi For a given avoider with ability level α , a multinational firm and a line i illustrates the maximized pro ts of a multinational rm. The i fi planning firm are identical in terms of inputs and potential output, minimized costs of operating a multinational rm are more than fi fi hence Γ>0 if and only if the minimized sum of tax payments and cor- twice that of a national rm due to the technological and scal disad- porate governance related output losses is smaller for a planning firm vantages of foreign plants relative to domestic plants. The slope of the fl (second bracket) than for the multinational firm (first bracket). Clear- line is 2 re ecting that a unit increase in ability yields a unit increase fi ly, avoiders prefer a planning firm to a multinational firm if Γ>0 and a in pro ts at each of the two plants. The intersection between the lines ΠN ΠM αM multinational firm to a planning firm if Γ≤0. We shall later refer to Γ i and i gives the threshold ability level at which a multina- P tional firm earns the same profits as a national firm. The line Πi illus- trates the maximized profits of a planning firm. The line is drawn under the assumption that the use of a tax haven subsidiary generates M a tax saving, hence it is parallel to the line Πi but shifted up by the 11 αH fi Formally, this requires that is suf ciently large. amount of the tax saving Γ. The intersection between the lines ΠN 12 The property of the model that more productive firms become multinational i through foreign direct investment whereas less productive firms remain national mir- rors the finding by Helpman et al. (2004). 13 Fig. 3 is based on a similar illustration in Helpman et al. (2004). N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 407

P P and Πi gives the threshold ability level α at which a planning firm that apply symmetrically in the two countries while anticipating earns the same profits as a national firm. that tax policies shape financial policies at the firm level and the equi- Using the definitions of αN, αM, αP and Γ, it is straightforward to librium allocation of resources between the three firm types.14 The compute the mass of national firms, EN, multinational firms, EM, and optimal policy maximizes private disposable income subject to the planning firms, EP, respectively in a given tax environment: revenue requirement. Private disposable income in each of the two hi hi countries is the sum of profits earned by domestic entrepreneurs, EN ¼ λγ αP−αN þ ðÞ1−λ γαM−αN ð20Þ labor income earned by domestic workers and capital income: no hi αP N αH P M H M X ¼ λγ ∫αN Π dα þ ∫αP Π dα E ¼ ðÞ1−λ γα−α ð21Þ noi i i i αM N αH M þ ðÞ1−λ γ ∫αN Π dα þ ∫αM Π dα þ w þ Sr ð24Þ hi i i i i EP ¼ λγ αH−αP ð22Þ where S is the total capital endowment of residents. Government rev- enue in each of the two countries may be written as the sum of the where γ is the density of the ability distribution and λ is defined as total tax payments of resident firms: follows:λ≡λ when Γ>0 and λ≡0 when Γ≤0 where we recall that λ is the exogenous fraction of entrepreneurs that are avoiders. Hence, N N M M P P: in cases where Γ>0, the mass of national firms EN equals the mass G ¼ E T þ E T þ E T ð25Þ of avoiders with ability between αN and αP and the mass of compliers with ability between αN and αM, the mass of multinational firms EM We are now prepared to present a proposition characterizing the equals the mass of compliers with ability above αM and the mass of optimal tax system under perfect cooperation: planning firms EP equals the mass of avoiders with ability above αP. Proposition 1. The optimal tax system involves zero internal barriers, In cases where Γ≤0, the mass of national firms equals the mass of en- tI =0, and external barriers high enough to deter avoiders from engaging trepreneurs with ability between αN and αM, the mass of multination- in tax planning, tE ≥tC. The corporate tax is at the lowest level that allows al firms equals the mass of entrepreneurs with ability above αM and financing of the public good given that there is no revenue from internal the mass of planning firms equals zero. and external barriers, tC ¼ hG.

3.3. Labor market equilibrium Proof. See Appendix. ■

The fixed mass of workers together with the assumption that each Intuitively, there are two possible sources of inefficiency in the production plant uses h workers restricts the number of production model. Firstly, taxes may reduce the total output of the economy plants that may be operated in Home in equilibrium. Specifically, below its potential level by distorting the financial policies of firms. labor market clearance in Home requires: Specifically, positive internal barriers induce multinational firms to Mf ~ finance the foreign subsidiary with too little debt ( θ bθ) because N M P M P 1 ¼ hE þ E þ E þ E þ E : ð23Þ debt from the parent company is taxed more heavily than equity whereas a wedge between the corporate tax rate and the external bar- rier induces planning firms to finance subsidiaries with too much debt The left-hand side of Eq. (23) is the fixed labor supply whereas the Pf Pd ~ (θ ¼ θ > θ) because debt from the haven subsidiary is taxed less right-hand side is labor demand. All firms in Home (EN +EM +EP)as heavily than equity. Secondly, taxes may reduce the total output of well as multinational and planning firms in Foreign (EM * +EP *) oper- the economy below its potential level by distorting the allocation of ate a production plant in Home and hire h workers. Since the margin- resources between firm types. Specifically, positive internal barriers al ability levels vary positively with the wage rate w, the labor raise the tax bill paid by two plants forming a multinational firm demand curve is downward sloping. Intuitively, at higher wage levels, above the tax cost of two plants forming two individual national firms it requires a higher ability to generate profits from production, (TM >2TN) causing too little economic integration among compliers hence fewer firms choose to produce and labor demand is lower. whereas a wedge between the corporate tax rate and the external bar- The combination of a downward sloping labor demand curve and a rier lowers the tax bill of two plants forming a planning firm below the fixed labor supply ensures the existence of a unique equilibrium tax bill of two plants forming two individual national firms (TP b2TN) wage rate. causing too much economic integration among avoiders. It should be noted that tax policies are transmitted through the It is easy to see that a tax system with zero internal barriers and labor market. Generally, tax increases cause profits to fall and induce prohibitive external barriers raises the required revenue while realiz- marginal firms to close production plants and shed workers. Unem- ing the full potential output of the economy. The fact that external ployment drives down wages, which, in turn, causes profits to rise barriers are prohibitive implies that only national and multinational and induce firms to open new production plants and hire workers firms exist in equilibrium. In the absence of internal barriers, firms until a new equilibrium is reached. Clearly, tax policy may change face the same tax cost of financing subsidiaries with debt and equity, the allocation of resources between the three firm types. For instance, namely the corporate tax rate, hence financial policies of both firm the initial impact of an increase in internal barriers is to reduce profits N Md Mf ~ types are undistorted (θ ¼ θ ¼ θ ¼ θ) and all production plants of multinational firms while leaving profits of other firms unaffected achieve their potential output. Moreover, in the absence of internal thus causing only multinational firms to close. The resulting wage barriers, the total tax bill paid by two plants forming a multinational pressure benefits all firms and causes firms of all types to open. The firm equals the total tax bill of two plants forming two individual na- net effect is therefore a reallocation of resources from multinational tional firms (TM =2TN) so that the optimal tax system leaves the allo- firms to national firms and planning firms. cation of resources between national and multinational firms undistorted. In other words, the output of the foreign plant of a 4. Perfect cooperation

14 We focus on symmetric policy vectors since they give rise to symmetric outcomes This section analyzes tax policy under perfect cooperation where in the two countries in terms of X and G. This allows us to abstract from the bargaining governments cooperate on all policy dimensions. We assume that problem arising if we would allow for asymmetric policy vectors with asymmetric C I E governments cooperatively choose a vector of tax rates (t ,t ,t ) outcomes. 408 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 marginal multinational firm (αM −m) equals the output of the do- It is instructive to inspect the efficiency properties of the equilibrium. mestic plant of a marginal national firm (αN), which implies that no By the arguments invoked in the previous section, the absence of internal increase in output can be achieved by reallocating entrepreneurial re- barriers implies that financial policies of multinational firms are undis- sources between the national and the multinational sectors. torted and that the foreign plant of a marginal multinational firm and The formal proof developed in the Appendix derives the marginal the domestic plant of a marginal national firm are equally productive cost of funds (the ’MCF’) associated with each of the three tax instru- (αM−m=αN) so that the allocation of entrepreneurial resources be- ments. External barriers always improve efficiency and the MCF asso- tween national and multinational firms is undistorted. However, the ab- ciated with this instrument is therefore below unity whereas the sence of external barriers introduces several inefficiencies. Firstly, MCFs associated with internal barriers and the corporate tax are at planning firms face different tax costs of financing with debt and least unity. This shows that external barriers should optimally be equity and the financial policies of planning firms are therefore dis- Pd Pf ~ raised all the way to prohibitive levels where no planning firms torted ( θ ¼ θ > θ). This implies that planning firms do not exist. In the absence of planning firms, the corporate tax does not af- achieve their potential output. Secondly, the tax saving generated by fect efficiency and is thus associated with a unit MCF whereas internal tax planning introduces a wedge between the productivity of a marginal barriers reduce efficiency and are associated with a MCF exceeding planning firm and a marginal multinational firm (αP bαM). This implies unity. This shows that internal barriers should optimally be zero. that total output could be increased by reallocating entrepreneurial re- sources from planning firms to national and multinational firms. 5. EU-style cooperation The main lessons from this analysis are the following: When coun- tries remove internal barriers in order to remove the obstacles to eco- This section analyzes a non-cooperative policy game where the nomic integration, it triggers a race-to-the-bottom in external two countries are not allowed to use internal barriers. This game re- barriers because governments endeavor to prevent conduit financing sembles the current institutional framework for tax setting in the of plants located on its territory or to attract conduit loans financing EU in the sense that the Interest and Royalty Directive has eliminated plants located outside its territory. In the resulting equilibrium, exter- internal barriers within the EU whereas there is no binding coopera- nal barriers are entirely absent and tax planning is profitable for tion on external barriers and corporate taxes. We therefore label this avoiders. This is inefficient because planning firms use too much institutional setting EU-style cooperation. debt relative to the socially optimal level and because the de facto Formally, we consider a game with the following two-stage struc- differential tax treatment of avoiders and compliers causes firms ture: (i) governments set corporate tax rates and external barriers non- operated by more able compliers to be crowded out by firms operated cooperatively under the constraint that tI =tI * =0 and (ii) entrepreneurs by less able avoiders. decide on financial policies and production plans. We immediately char- As noted earlier, the structure of the game analyzed in this section re- acterize the equilibrium properties in the following proposition: sembles the institutional framework for tax setting in the EU where in- ternal barriers have been abolished and countries set corporate taxes Proposition 2. Consider an environment where countries are commit- and external barriers non-cooperatively. Interestingly, the equilibrium I I * ted not to use internal barriers, t =t =0, and set other dimensions of of the game reproduces the puzzling feature of observed tax structures tax policy non-cooperatively. In the unique Nash equilibrium, external in many EU countries, namely the absence of external barriers. The anal- E E * barriers are competed down to zero, t =t =0, and the public good is ysis thus takes us some way towards understanding why many EU coun- fi C C τ entirely nanced with the corporate tax, t ¼ t ¼ hG where tries have no external barriers. A limitation of the analysis, however, is the fact that it treats the institutional framework for tax setting as exog- N M P enously given. The question thus remains why this particular type of co- E þ 2E þ 2E τ≡ > 1 operation has prevailed in the EU rather than perfect cooperation. EN þ 2EM þ 2−θPd−θPf EP A possible explanation revolves around political feasibility. Argu- ably, cooperation on internal barriers involves a smaller political for EN,EM,EP, θPd and θPf evaluated at the equilibrium. cost than cooperation on external barriers since the former only af- fects transactions with specific partner countries whereas the latter Proof. See Appendix. ■ affects transactions with all third countries. To explore the implica- tions of the hypothesis that only cooperation on internal barriers is The key to the result that external barriers are competed down to politically feasible, it would be useful to analyze a variant of EU- zero lies in the fact that in the absence of internal barriers the real ex- style cooperation where countries set a common internal barrier in fi ternal barrier faced by rms is simply given by the lowest of the ex- a first stage whereas external barriers and corporate tax rates are fi ternal barriers in the two countries. Planning rms therefore set non-cooperatively in a second stage. To the extent that the opti- channel all loans from the tax haven subsidiary through the country mal common internal barrier was found to be zero, EU style coopera- with the lowest external barrier. Starting from external barriers tion could be rationalized as a second-best policy under the E E * fi t >t where planning rms channel all loans from the tax haven constraint that cooperation on external barriers involves a prohibitive fi subsidiary through Foreign, Home can induce planning rms to in- political cost. Unfortunately, this policy game has no policy equilibri- E stead channel loans through Home by setting t marginally below um in pure strategies.16 In principle, one could attempt to compute a tE *. This gives rise to a discrete increase in be- cause loans from tax haven subsidiaries now become subject to 16 To see this, note that with a common internal barrier tI =tI * >0, Home can set tE as the external barrier in Home rather than in Foreign. It follows that high as tE * +tI >0 without inducing firms to use conduit finance through Foreign. Sim- the best response of any individual country is always to undercut ilarly, Foreign can set tE * as high as tE +tI * without inducing firms to use conduit fi- the external barrier of the other country. Countries thus engage in a nance through Home. Up to a certain point, this creates a race-to-the-top in external Bertrand style tax competition for the mobile tax base comprised by barriers since raising external barriers allows countries to increase protection against fi E * loans from tax havens, which drives external barriers to zero.15 tax havens without triggering a loss of tax base through conduit nancing. When t is high enough, however, it becomes optimal for Home to undercut the external barrier of Foreign by just enough to make firms undertake conduit finance through Home, that 15 The game may be interpreted along the lines of Janeba and Peters (1999): The two is tE btE * −tI. Given this low value of tE, it is no longer optimal for Foreign to set a high countries compete for a perfectly mobile tax base and may choose to give preferential value of tE *. By the same argument, the fully non-cooperative policy game has no equi- treatment to the perfectly mobile base over less mobile bases by setting tE btC. In the librium in pure strategies either. The absence of a pure strategy equilibrium in tax pol- unique equilibrium, the tax rate applying to the perfectly mobile base (i.e. tE) is com- icy games with a perfectly mobile tax base is fairly common in the literature (see for peted down to zero. instance Marceau et al., 2010) N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 409 policy equilibrium in mixed strategies but given the complexity of the liquidation proceeds rather than dividends. This administrative prac- model we do not pursue this avenue. tice does not rest on a firm legal basis and must be confirmed by the Another possible explanation for the fact that the actual form of administration in confidential advance tax agreements in each sepa- cooperation in the EU does not conform to the socially optimal poli- rate case. The example illustrates the important role of obscure legal cies derived in Proposition 1 emphasizes the role of commitment. If details and opaque administrative practices for effective taxation countries were to agree to implement a zero internal barrier and a and thus the potential difficulties of defining all policy dimensions prohibitive external barrier in the absence of a commitment mecha- exhaustively in international agreements. nism, the reasoning underlying Proposition 2 tells us that the external This section analyzes optimal tax policies in a setting where inter- barrier would be subject to the same race-to-the-bottom as under national cooperation is plagued by the imperfection described above EU-style cooperation. If Foreign complies with the agreement, Home and the main result is that optimal tax policy involves strictly positive has an incentive to deviate by lowering the external barrier in order internal barriers. Intuitively, raising internal barriers above zero is in to induce avoiders to finance subsidiaries in Foreign with conduit itself undesirable since it places multinational firms at a disadvantage loans through Home and given this deviation by Home, it is optimal relative to other types of firms and thus distorts the allocation of re- for Foreign to deviate by setting the external barrier even lower. It sources. However, by raising the cost of conduit finance, internal bar- is therefore a priori conceivable that EU-style cooperation is a riers also serve as a tool to implement effective external barriers. second-best policy under the constraint that there is no mechanism Clearly, the race-to-the-bottom in external barriers explored in the by which governments can commit to implementing high external previous section was caused by the absence of internal barriers, barriers. The next section provides a formal analysis of optimal poli- which induced planning firms to channel loans from tax haven sub- cies in a setting where cooperation is limited by an imperfect com- sidiaries through the country with the lowest external barrier. Raising mitment mechanism. The results, however, do not support the internal barriers introduces an additional tax cost of conduit finance, hypothesis that EU-style cooperation is a second-best policy but which reduces the incentive to compete on external barriers. In par- rather suggest that the EU countries could improve the outcome by ticular, since the tax cost of financing production plants in Home raising internal barriers above zero. with conduit loans through Foreign amounts to tI +tE *, Home can raise its external barrier tE at least up to tI without inducing planning fi fi E * 6. Imperfect cooperation rms to resort to conduit nance regardless of t . By showing that positive external barriers can only be enforced at the cost of also Effective taxation is determined by a host of policy dimensions, enforcing positive internal barriers, the analysis highlights the inter- for instance the nominal tax rate, the broadness of the tax base, esting trade-off between economic integration and protection against fi the scope for avoidance and the enforcement efforts exerted by pro t shifting, which we conjecture is generally present in second- tax administrations. While it is relatively easy to specify a common best environments. nominal tax rate in an international agreement, coordination on In the formal analysis, we assume that tax policy has two dimen- fi other dimensions of tax policy is considerably more difficult. Most sions. The rst policy dimension is directly observable and can be obviously, any attempt to specify enforcement efforts in an interna- interpreted as nominal tax rates. The second policy dimension is not tional agreement would face very significant measurement prob- directly observable and can be interpreted as either enforcement ef- lems.17 Arguably, international cooperation on the complex of legal forts or as the broadness of tax bases, however, for ease of reference details that defines a tax base faces similar difficulties since it almost we shall use the label enforcement levels. The relevant tax rates for fi inevitably leaves some scope for idiosyncratic administrative prac- rm behavior and revenue considerations are effective tax rates, fi tices and legal interpretations that affect effective taxation. These which are affected by both policy dimensions. Speci cally, we assume considerations suggest that even if international agreements con- that the enforcement level associated with a given tax instrument is a strain individual governments in some policy dimensions, govern- continuous variable z scaled to the interval [0,1] where 0 is no en- ments are likely to retain flexibility in other policy dimensions forcement and 1 is full enforcement. Letting t denote the nominal that have a bearing on effective taxation. rate of a given tax, we assume that the effective tax rate is given by The empirical relevance of these considerations for the withhold- t ¼ zt. This formulation implies that nominal tax rates place upper ing taxes studied in this paper is confirmed by the following anecdot- limits on effective tax rates while different degrees of imperfect al evidence: Luxembourg is a leading player in the fierce international enforcement can be used to achieve any level of effective taxation be- competition for holding companies. Like most other countries, tween zero and the nominal tax rate. Luxembourg levies a high withholding tax on dividend payments to We consider an institutional setting, which we label imperfect co- tax havens, however, if enforced strictly the tax could make tax plan- operation, where the two governments cooperate on nominal internal ning involving Luxembourg holding companies owned by offshore and external barriers but are unable to commit to enforcement levels. funds unattractive since repatriation of profits would not be tax effi- We thus analyze the following sequence: (i) governments choose I E cient. While Luxembourg is not explicitly bound by an international nominal internal barriers t and nominal external barriers t cooper- agreement to levy the withholding tax, abolishing it would likely en- atively; (ii) governments choose nominal corporate tax rates and en- tail a political cost by exposing the role Luxembourg plays in harmful forcementno levels non-cooperatively,no that is Home chooses C ; I; E; C C; I; E; C international tax planning. Instead of abolishing the tax, the Luxem- t z z z and Foreign chooses t z z z ; and (iii) entre- I E bourg tax administration thus allows multinational firms to circum- preneurs make optimal decisions given the effective tax rates {t ,t , C I * E * C * vent it. Holding companies issue several classes of shares each t ,t ,t ,t }. This game structure implies that governments effective- fi fi fi ly choose effective tax rates non-cooperatively but subject to upper linked to the pro ts of a speci c scal year. When the holding compa- I E ny needs to pay a dividend to the offshore fund by which it is owned, limits on internal and external barriers t and t decided cooperatively fi it liquidates a class of shares and the repatriated profits are free in the rst stage. fi of withholding tax since the tax administration considers them The following lemma con rms the intuition outlined in the previ- ous section that under imperfect cooperation where countries can only agree on nominal tax rates due to the lack of a commitment mechanism, complementing a zero common internal barrier with a positive common external barrier leads to the same equilibrium 17 Cremer and Gahvari (2000) emphasize the practical obstacles associated with co- ordination of enforcement efforts and show that international coordination of tax rates outcome as EU style cooperation, namely zero effective internal and may lead governments to compete for mobile tax bases by reducing audit probabilities external barriers. 410 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416

Lemma 1. Any first-stage policy vector with zero nominal internal Proof. See Appendix. ■ I E barriers, t ¼ 0, and positive nominal external barriers, t ≥0, leads to a symmetric equilibrium policy vector in the non-cooperative second The proof of Lemma 3 shows that from a social perspective the stage where effective internal and external barriers are zero, tI =tE =0, marginal cost of public funds associated with the combined use of and the public good is entirely financed with the corporate tax, tC ¼ τhG. effective internal and external barriers is smaller than the marginal cost of public funds associated with the corporate tax rate when eval- Proof. See Appendix. ■ uated at tI =tE =0. This implies that increasing effective internal and external barriers marginally while reducing the corporate tax rate to As noted above, the role of nominal tax rates chosen in the coop- leave government revenue unchanged raises the level of private dis- fi erative rst stage is to constrain the effective tax rates that can be posable income and thus welfare. chosen in the non-cooperative second stage. The zero nominal inter- I To see the intuition for this result, note that we analyze a neigh- nal barrier t ¼ 0 effectively imposes a zero effective internal barrier I E borhood around a market equilibrium with the following properties: t =0 whereas the positive nominal external barrier hit > 0 allows E On one hand, the absence of internal barriers implies that the debt E∈ ; Mf ~ countries to choose any effective external barrier t 0 t . Hence, level of multinational firms is socially optimal (θ ¼ θ) and that the the non-cooperative subgame is identical to EU-style cooperation allocation of entrepreneurial resources between national and multi- except that tE has an upper limit and clearly the same tax competition national firms is undistorted in the sense that the foreign plant of a mechanism emerges: external barriers are competed down to zero marginal multinational firm and the domestic plant of a marginal na- through a race-to-the-bottom in enforcement levels. tional firm are equally productive (αM −m=αN). On the other hand, While the equilibrium outcome of EU style cooperation is not the absence of effective external barriers implies that the debt level of Pd Pf ~ changed simply by adding a positive external barrier to the zero inter- planning firms is too high (θ ¼ θ > θ) and that there is a wedge nal barrier, this does not imply that the equilibrium cannot be chan- between the productivity of a marginal planning firm and a marginal ged at all. The following lemma shows that by raising nominal multinational firm (αP bαM) so that total output could be increased by internal barriers above zero, an equilibrium can be obtained where reallocating entrepreneurial resources from planning firms to nation- both effective internal and effective external barriers are positive. al and multinational firms. Starting from this market equilibrium, a combined increase in ef- λ fi Lemma 2. Provided that is not too large, a rst-stage policy vector fective internal and external barriers affects welfare through several where nominal internal and external barriers are marginally positive, channels. Firstly, increasing external barriers raises welfare by reduc- I E ρ ρ→ t ¼ t ¼ for 0, leads to a symmetric equilibrium in the non- ing the extent to which financial policies of planning firms are dis- cooperative second stage where effective internal and external barriers torted whereas increasing internal barriers reduces welfare by I E ρ are marginally positive, t =t = , and the remainder of the public introducing a distortion of the financial policies of multinational fi C τ′ − good is nanced with the corporate tax, t ¼ h G Q where firms. The welfare gain is first-order but the welfare loss is only no second-order because the financial policies of multinational firms Q EMθMf EP θPd θPf ρ ¼ þ þ are initially undistorted. Secondly, increasing external barriers raises N M P fi fi τ′≡ E þ 2E þ 2E welfare by reducing the after-tax pro ts of planning rms and caus- EN þ 2EM þ 2−θPd−θPf EP ing a reallocation of resources from marginal planning firms to more productive marginal national and multinational firms whereas for EN,EM,EP, θMf, θPd and θPf evaluated at the equilibrium. increasing internal barriers reduces welfare by eroding the after-tax profits of multinational firms and causing a reallocation of resources Proof. See Appendix. ■ from marginal multinational firms to marginal national firms. Again, When nominal internal and external barriers are set at ρ>0 in the the welfare gain is first-order but the welfare loss is only second- first stage, countries can choose any level of effective internal and ex- order because marginal national firms and marginal multinational ternal barriers up to ρ in the second stage by adjusting enforcement firms are initially equally productive. levels. In the proof, we derive the MCF associated with each of the Proposition 3 builds on Lemmas 1–3 to characterize the optimal three tax instruments tC, tI and tE from the perspective of an individ- tax policy in the cooperative first stage: ual government, which only takes into account the private disposable λ income of its own residents and its own . We show that Proposition 3. Provided that is not too large, the optimal tax policy in fi the MCF associated with both tI and tE is lower than the MCF associ- the cooperative rst-stage must be one that gives rise to strictly positive ated with tC when evaluated at tI =tE =0. It follows that when nom- effective internal barriers in the non-cooperative second stage. fi fi inal scal barriers are raised marginally above zero in the rst stage, Proof. See Appendix. ■ countries fully enforce these taxes in the second stage in order to fully exploit the opportunity to raise revenue with tI and tE at a low The result implies that EU-style cooperation cannot be rational- marginal cost while lowering tC so as to reduce the revenue raised ized as a second-best policy in the institutional environment that at a higher marginal cost. In the equilibrium, revenue Q is raised we refer to as imperfect cooperation. Rather, the result suggests with internal and external barriers and revenue G−Q is raised with that if cooperation between EU countries is limited by commitment the corporate tax. Lemma 2 thus shows that starting from an initial problems, starting from the current policy equilibrium welfare could situation with zero effective fiscal barriers, a socially desirable in- be improved by sacrificing some measure of economic integration in crease in effective external barriers can be achieved at the cost of a so- order to obtain better protection against international tax planning. cially undesirable increase in effective internal barriers. An obvious limitation of the results presented in this section is the Lemma 3 compares the welfare levels in the equilibria character- particular institutional assumptions under which they are derived. ized by Lemma 1 and Lemma 2 respectively and shows that the net We believe, however, that the mechanisms are fairly general and welfare effect of raising both internal and external barriers marginally that the result would extend to many other institutional settings above zero is positive. where the first-best policy is not implementable. Generally, when a group of countries only imperfectly controls effective external bar- Lemma 3. Welfare in a symmetric equilibrium with tI =tE =ρ for ρ→0 riers in a cooperative stage, there is a scope for harmful tax competi- ′ and tC ¼ τ h G−Q is higher than welfare in a symmetric equilibrium tion, which may be mitigated by internal barriers. Applying a with tI =tE =0 and tC ¼ τhG. standard second-best argument, no dimensions are undistorted in N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 411 the optimum, hence internal barriers should be positive even at the constraint, the first-order conditions characterizing the optimal tax cost of suboptimal economic integration. policy may be stated as:

7. Concluding remarks dX=dtk − ¼ μ for k ¼ C; I; E: ð26Þ This paper has analyzed optimal taxation of cross-border interest dG=dtk flows from the perspective of two countries. The main findings were the following: If governments cooperate on all policy dimensions, op- Optimality thus requires that the marginal cost of public funds is timal tax policy is characterized by a zero internal barrier and a pro- 18 hibitive external barrier. While the absence of internal barriers equalized across tax instruments. allows the two countries to achieve the optimal degree of economic The proof proceeds in the following way. First, we derive the effect of integration, high external barriers provide protection against profit small tax changes on private disposable income and government reve- shifting to tax havens. Assuming that tax policy has dimensions on nue respectively. Secondly, we use these expressions to compute the which governments are unable to cooperate, optimal tax policy in- marginal cost of public funds associated with each of the three tax in- volves effective internal barriers above zero. In the absence of internal struments on the basis of which we characterize the optimal tax system. k fi barriers, firms may circumvent external barriers by means of conduit We differentiate Eq. (24) with respect to t using the de nitions of ΠN ΠM ΠP loans at no tax cost, which triggers a race-to-the-bottom in external i , i and i to obtain: barriers leaving countries without protection against profit shifting. 8 () () N N While increasing internal barrier is in itself undesirable, it enhances > P ∂ M ∂ > λγ∫α T dw α −λ γ∫α T dw α > αN þ h d þ ðÞ1 αN þ h d welfare by raising the tax cost of conduit loans, which allows coun- > ∂tk dtk i ∂tk dtk i > () ! ! > P P Pd Pd P Pf Pf tries to implement effective external barriers. > H ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂θ ∂ ∂ ∂θ > λγ∫α T T c T c dw α > þ αP þ þ þ þ þ 2h d i The results relate to a recent controversy between Hong and > ∂tk ∂θPd ∂θPd dtk ∂θPf ∂θPf dtk dtk > () ! Smart (2010) and Slemrod and Wilson (2009) about the welfare im- > M M Mf Mf > αH ∂T ∂T ∂c ∂θ dw fi < þðÞ1−λ γ∫αM þ þ þ 2h dα plications of pro t shifting to tax havens. We documented that a con- dX ∂ k ∂θMf ∂θMf k k i − ¼ ()t dt dt siderable number of countries, in particular EU countries, do not tax dtk > N P P > dα N P dα P P dα > þλγ ΠN αN −Π α þ Π α interest payments to tax haven entities, which maximizes the scope > k k k > ()dt dt dt for profit shifting. This is clearly consistent with the Hong–Smart > > dαN dαM dαM fi > 1−λ γΠN αN −ΠN αM ΠM αM view that tax havens are bene cial whereas it is, seemingly, at odds > þðÞ k k þ k > dt dt dt – > with the Slemrod Wilson view that tax havens are harmful. By show- > dw fi fi : − ing that scal barriers to pro t shifting may be absent even when tax dtk – havens are harmful, our model reconciles the Slemrod Wilson view ð27Þ of tax havens with the observed features of real-world tax systems. Although our results are derived in a model where firms use a Πj α fi fi particular tax planning structure, we believe that the mechanism where we have introduced the notation ( i)forthepro ts of a rm α would carry over to other related settings, for instance optimal tax- of type j operated by an entrepreneur with ability i. It follows from the ation of cross-border dividends and royalties. In the case of dividend first-order conditions for optimal financial policies that indirect effects taxes, note that some multinational firms have a tax haven entity as on firm profits through changes in financial policies are zero. Moreover, N M P N N M the ultimate parent company and eventually need to repatriate by the definitions of α , α and α , it holds that Π (α )=0, that Π M N M P P N P profits to this entity. Based on the intuition developed above, we (α )=Π (α ) and that Π (α )=Π (α ). This implies that the effect conjecture that first-best dividend taxes are characterized by zero of changes in the allocation of entrepreneurial resources between na- taxes on dividend payments between countries and prohibitive tional, multinational and planning firms (fourth and fifth line) is zero. taxes on dividend payments to tax haven entities. However, firms Finally, it follows from Eq. (23) that the effects working through may circumvent high external barriers of any individual country changes in the wage rate sum to zero. We may thus rewrite Eq. (27) by means of holding structures. We thus conjecture that eliminating as the sum of the mechanical effects on firm profits: internal barriers would trigger a tax competition for intermediate holding companies driving external barriers to zero and that () () () dX ∂TN ∂TM ∂TP second-best dividend taxation involves positive internal barriers. A − ¼ EN þ EM þ EP : ð28Þ k ∂ k ∂ k ∂ k very similar argument applies to royalty taxes. International tax dt t t t planning may consist of a contribution of patents to a tax haven en- tity, which subsequently licenses the right to use the patents back to k operating subsidiaries against the payment of royalties. The royalty We differentiate Eq. (25) with respect to t to obtain: payments erode the corporate tax base of the operating subsidiaries 8 while being taxed at a zero rate at the level of the tax haven entity. > ∂ N ∂ M ∂ P > N T M T P T > E þ E þ E Obviously, firms may circumvent high external barriers of any indi- > ()()∂ k ∂ k ∂ k () <> t t t vidual by means of conduit structures whereby the right to use the dG ∂TN ∂θN ∂TM ∂θMd ∂TM ∂θMf ∂TP ∂θPd ∂TP ∂θPf ¼ EN þ EM þ þ EP þ : k > ∂θN ∂ k ∂θMd ∂ k ∂θMf ∂ k ∂θPd ∂ k ∂θPf ∂ k patent is licensed to a conduit entity which subsequently sub- dt > t t t t t > N M P licenses the patent to the plant. This triggers a tax competition dy- > dE N dE M dE P : T þ T þ T namics, which is identical to the one we have analyzed in the con- dtk dtk dtk text of interest taxes and we conjecture that second-best taxation ð29Þ of royalty payments involves positive internal barriers.

Appendix 18 We note, however, that the marginal cost of public funds cannot be computed for tax instruments that do not apply to a tax base. This is the case, for instance, when tE is prohibitively high so that no planning firms exist. Clearly, setting tE at prohibitive Proof of Proposition 1. Governments maximize X subject to G ¼ G. levels is optimal if the marginal cost of public funds is lower than for alternative tax in- Letting μ denote the Lagrange multiplier associated with the revenue struments at all non-prohibitive levels. 412 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416

We then use definitions of EN, EM, EP, αN, αM and αP to restate the The inverse MCF for the external barrier may be stated as: third line in the following way: N P M P E 2T −T þ ðÞ1−λ T −T −dG εP γλ ¼ 1 þ þ P ð33Þ 8 !0 1 9 dX 2E > N ∂ P− N > > ∂T dw T T dw > > þ h TN þ λ@ þ h A TP−TN > εP θPd C − E <> ∂ k k ∂ k k => where is the of with respect to t t or equivalently t dt t dt θPf C * − E * −γ 0 1 : ð30Þ the elasticity of with respect to t t . The three terms represent > M N > > ∂ T −T > the mechanical effect, the behavioral effect and the general equilibri- > @ dwA M N > :> þðÞ1−λ þ h T −T ;> εP ≥ ∂tk dtk um effect respectively. It is easy to see that 0 so that the behavior- al effect is positive: raising tE reduces the tax saving associated with internal debt in planning firms and the latter respond by bringing ~ the debt–asset ratio closer to the efficient level θ. Moreover, the gen- We differentiate Eq. (23) to derive the following equation relating eral equilibrium effect is unambiguously positive: raising tE increases changes in tax policies to changes in wages: the tax burden on marginal planning firms, which are replaced by 0 1 more productive marginal national and multinational firms in the E N ∂ TP−TN ∂ TM−TN new equilibrium. In sum, the MCF associated with t is below unity. dw 1 @∂T A ¼ − þ λ þ ðÞ1−λ The inverse MCF for the internal barrier may be stated as: dtk 2h ∂tk ∂tk ∂tk ð31Þ ! M N M P P M I T −2T þ λ T −T 1 ∂T ∂T dG M ¼ − λ þ ðÞ1−λ − ¼ 1 þ ε −γðÞ1−λ ð34Þ 2h ∂tk ∂tk dX 2EM

where εM is the elasticity of θMf with respect to tI. It is easy to see that where the second equality uses symmetry to eliminate asterisks. We εM ≤0 so that the behavioral effect is negative: raising tI adds to the insert the latter expression into Eq. (30), insert the resulting expres- tax disadvantage of internal debt in multinational firms and the latter ~ sion back into Eq. (29) and rearrange to obtain: respond by bringing the debt–asset ratio further away from θ. More- 8 over, the general equilibrium effect is unambiguously negative: rais- > ∂ N ∂ M ∂ P I > N T M T P T ing t increases the tax burden on marginal multinational firms, > E þ E þ E þ > ()()∂tk ∂tk ∂tk ()which are replaced by less productive marginal national and planning > N N M Md M Mf P Pd P Pf > ∂T ∂θ ∂T ∂θ ∂T ∂θ ∂T ∂θ ∂T ∂θ > EN þ EM þ þ EP þ firms in the new market equilibrium. In sum, the MCF associated with > ∂θN ∂ k ∂θMd ∂ k ∂θMf ∂ k ∂θPd ∂ k ∂θPf ∂ k > t t ()t t t I > 2 3 t is above unity. < ∂ M ∂ N dG M N T T ¼ 6 ðÞ1−λ T −2T −2 þ 7 : The inverse MCF for the corporate tax may be stated as: k > 6 ∂tk ∂tk 7 dt > 6 ()7 > γ 6 ∂ N ∂ P 7 > 6 N P T T 7 N P M P > − 6 λ 2T −T 2 − þ 7 C 2T −T þ ðÞ1−λ T −T > 2 6 ∂tk ∂tk 7 dG P > 6 ()7 − ¼ 1−ψε −γλψ ð35Þ > 6 M P 7 dX 2EP > 4 M P ∂T ∂T 5 :> λðÞ1−λ T −T − ∂tk ∂tk where: ð32Þ θPd þ θPf EP Tax changes affect government revenue through three distinct ψ≡ : EN þ 2EM þ 2−θPd−θPf EP channels: a mechanical effect represented by the first line; a behavioral – effect working through changes in the debt asset ratios represented C by the second line; and a general equilibrium effect working through The behavioral effect is negative: raising t adds to the tax advan- tage of debt in planning firms and the latter respond by bringing the a reallocation of resources between firm types represented by the ex- – fi θ~ pression in square brackets. The general equilibrium effect should be debt asset ratio away from the ef cient level . Moreover, the general equilibrium effect is unambiguously negative: an increase in tC re- interpreted in the following manner: If a policy change reduces the fi fi fi total profits of two plants forming a multinational firm more than duces the pro ts of national rms and multinational rms by more than the profits of planning firms and therefore causes marginal the total profits of two plants forming two individual national firms, fi that is if ∂TM/∂tk>2∂TN/∂tk, there is a net reallocation of resources national and multinational rms to be replaced by less productive fi fi fi marginal planning rms in the new equilibrium. In sum, the MCF as- from multinational rms to national rms causing a loss of govern- C M − N sociated with t is above unity. ment revenue proportional to T 2T . Similarly, if a policy change E fi Since the MCF associated with t is below unity and the MCFs reduces the total pro ts of two plants forming two individual national I C firms more than the total profits of two plants forming a planning associated with t and t are above unity, the optimal tax policy fi ∂ N ∂ k ∂ P ∂ k must involve a prohibitive external barrier. We thus compare the rm, that is if 2 T / t > T / t , there is a net reallocation of re- I C E sources from national firms to planning firms causing a loss in gov- inverse MCFs associated with t and t given that t is prohibitively N P high. Evaluating Eqs. (34) and (35) at λ=0 yields: ernment revenue proportional to 2T −T . Finally, if a policy change reduces the total profits of two plants forming a multinational firm M N I T −2T more than the total profits of two plants forming a planning firm, dG E M − t prohibitive ¼ 1 þ ε −γ ð36Þ that is if ∂TM/∂tk>∂TP/∂tk, there is a net reallocation of resources f dX g 2EM from multinational firms to planning firms causing a loss of govern- M P ment revenue proportional to T −T . dGC We use Eqs. (28) and (32) to derive the marginal cost of public − E : t prohibitive ¼ 1 ð37Þ funds (the ‘MCF’) for each of the three tax instruments. For exposi- f dX g tional convenience, we report the inverse MCFs, that is the govern- ment revenue raised with a given tax instrument for each unit of In the absence of planning firms, the inverse MCF is below unity private income foregone. for tI and exactly unity for tC. Intuitively, tI distorts the capital N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 413 structure of multinational firms and introduces a productivity wedge financed with direct loans from tax haven subsidiaries and operating between multinational and national firms. On the other hand, tC subsidiaries in Foreign are financed with conduit loans from tax leaves both the capital structure of multinational firms and the over- haven subsidiaries through Home. This leads to the following tax all allocation of resources between multinational and national firms bills payable in Home: undistorted. It follows that the optimal tax system involves a zero in- ternal barrier. DP ¼ 1−θPd tC þ θPdtE þ θPf tE It is easy to verify that for tI =0, the tax saving from tax planning Γ P −θPf C θPf E θPd E: equals zero exactly when tE =tC, hence the external barrier is prohib- D ¼ 1 t þ t þ t itive if and only if it exceeds the corporate tax rate (tE ≥tC). Finally, note that since internal barriers and external barriers raise no reve- As tE approaches tC from below, the debt levels chosen by planning ~ nue, the entire public good must be financed with the corporate tax. firms approach θ, hence Home experiences a discrete revenue gain of P ~ The size of the labor force constrains the number of production plants approximately 2E θtC reflecting that the debt of multinational firms to 1/h. Under the optimal tax policy, each plant pays taxes tC. It fol- operated by avoiders in Foreign, which was subject to corporate tax in lows that tC ¼ Gh satisfies the revenue constraint with equality. Foreign prior to the reform, is subject to the external barrier of Home after the reform. This discrete revenue gain dominates revenue Proof of Proposition 2. Private disposable income in Home under changes caused by changes in the optimal debt–asset ratio θ and gen- asymmetric policies is given by Eq. (24). Differentiating Eq. (24) eral equilibrium effects since these effects are proportional to the dis- k with respect to a tax rate t yields the non-cooperative analogue to tance tC −tE and therefore become infinitely small as tE approaches tC Eq. (28), i.e. an equation relating tax changes in Home to changes in from below. Turning to the effect on X, note that starting from tE =tC, P P ~ private disposable income in Home: it holds that ∂T =∂tE ¼ ∂T =∂tE ¼ θ. It follows from Eqs. (38)–(40) E C E b N M P that starting at t =t , a small change dt 0 increases X by ∂T ∂T ∂T P ~ E EN EM EP −2E θdt > 0. In sum, the proposed reform increases X without dX k þ k þ k − ∂t ∂t ∂t : 38 violating the budget constraint, hence the initial policy vector is not k ¼ nono ð Þ dt dw M P dw −hEM EP hE E consistent with equilibrium. þ k þ þ k dt dt (B) An initial policy vector with tC * >tE * >0 and tE >tE *. Planning firms use conduit loans through Foreign to finance subsidiaries in The first line represents the direct effect of the tax change on Home, hence profits. The second line represents the indirect effect through wage changes: Increases in w (w*) increase (decrease) private consumption DP ¼ 1−θPd tC by transferring rents from multinational and planning firms resident in Foreign (Home) to workers in Home (Foreign). We use Eq. (31) to DP ¼ 1−θPf tC : derive the following equations relating tax changes to wage changes:

! E E * C Consider a reform in Home that reduces t to t and adjusts t to dw 1 ∂TN ∂TP ∂TM ¼ − þ λ þ ðÞ1−λ ð39Þ satisfy the revenue requirement with equality. The reduction in tE k 2h ∂ k ∂ k ∂ k dt t t t induces planning firms to finance subsidiaries in Home with direct 0 1 loans, hence ∂ P− N ∂ M− N dw 1 T T T T − @λ 1−λ A 40 P Pd C Pd E k ¼ k þ ðÞ k ð Þ D ¼ 1−θ t þ θ t dt 2h ∂t ∂t DP ¼ 1−θPf tC þ θPftE: where we have used that ∂TN */∂tk =0 since taxes in Home do not fall fi on national rms in Foreign. The reduction in tE thus causes a discrete increase in G equal to j fi Let D denote the tax bill paid to Home by a rm of type j. The (EPθPd +EP *θPf *)tE * reflecting that the debt of operating subsidiaries in government revenue of Home may thus be stated as follows: Home, which was previously subject to the external barrier of Foreign, is now subject to the external barrier of Home. Setting tE =tE * does N D M M P P M M P P: G ¼ E D þ E D þ E D þ E D þ E D ð41Þ not affect tRE and therefore leaves X unchanged. Reducing tE to tE * thus increases G and leaves X unchanged. This allows for a small reduc- Home collects revenue from all firms in Home as well as multina- tion in tC, which increases X without violating the budget constraint. It tional and planning firms in Foreign. follows that the initial policy vector is not consistent with equilibrium. In order to prove Proposition 2, we consider five cases (A)–(E) (C) An initial policy vector with tE =tE * >0. Planning firms use that cover all possible policy vectors given the absence of internal direct loans to finance operating subsidiaries, hence: barriers and show that only (E) is an equilibrium. E ≥ C E * ≥ C * P Pd C Pd E (A) An initial policy vector with t t and t t . External D ¼ 1−θ t þ θ t barriers are prohibitive and no planning firms exist, hence domestic M P −θPf C θPf E: and foreign avoiders with αi >α operate multinational firms with D ¼ 1 t þ t the following tax bills payable in Home: Consider a reform in Home that reduces tE marginally. The reduc- M C C θ~ E D ¼ t þ t tion in t induces planning firms to finance subsidiaries in Foreign M ~ C with conduit loans through Home, hence D ¼ 1−θ t : DP ¼ 1−θPd tC þ θPdtE þ θPf tE Corporate tax rates are at the level that satisfies the revenue con- P −θPf C θPf E θPd E: straints with equality, that is tC ¼ tC ¼ hG. Consider a reform in D ¼ 1 t þ t þ t Home that reduces tE to a level marginally below tC. The reduction E M M * P Pf P * Pd E in t induces avoiders with αi >α =α to replace multinational Home thus experiences a discrete revenue gain of (E θ +E θ )t firms with planning firms where operating subsidiaries in Home are reflecting that the debt of operating subsidiaries in Foreign, which was 414 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 subject to the external barrier of Foreign prior to the reform, is subject government revenue is twice as large as the reduction in private con- to the external barrier of Home after the reform. This discrete revenue sumption. The behavioral effect of tE on government revenue is posi- gain dominates revenue changes caused by changes in the optimal tive since it reduces the of shifting profits to tax havens debt–asset ratio θ and general equilibrium effects since these effects and thus induces planning firms to reduce their debt–asset ratio. The are proportional to the distance tE −tE * and therefore become infinite- general equilibrium effect of tE on government revenue is also posi- ly small as tE approaches tE * from below. It follows from Eqs. (38)–(40) tive since the workers in Home initially shed by planning firms are that starting at tE =tE *, a small change dtE b0 increases X by −EP(θPd absorbed by national firms and foreign multinational firms both con- +θPf)dtE >0. In sum, the proposed reform increases X without violating tributing more to the government revenue in Home. Likewise, the budget constraint, hence the initial policy vector is not consistent workers in Foreign initially shed by planning firms are partly with equilibrium. absorbed by multinational firms contributing more to the govern- (D) An initial policy vector with tE =0 and tE * >0. Planning firms ment revenue in Home. Dividing Eqs. (43) and (44), one obtains: fi use conduit loans through Home to nance subsidiaries in Foreign. E P C Both countries earn zero revenue from the external barrier and cor- dG P γðÞ1−λ ðÞ1 þ λ θ t − ¼ 2 þ ε þ : ð45Þ porate tax rates are at the level that satisfies the revenue constraints dX EP with equality, that is tC ¼ tC ¼ τhG. Consider a reform in Home that increases tE marginally and adjusts tC to satisfy the revenue require- Clearly, the inverse MCF associated with tE is strictly larger than ment with equality. unity since the first term (the mechanical effect) is larger than unity As a first step of the analysis, we use Eqs. (39) and (40) to derive and the second and third terms (the behavioral and general equilibri- the following non-cooperative analogue to Eq. (32), i.e. an equation um effects) are strictly positive. relating tax changes in Home to changes in government revenue in We then evaluate Eqs. (38) and (42) for tk =tC at tI =tI * =tE =0 Home: and tE * >0: 8 > ∂ N ∂ M ∂ P ∂ M ∂ P dX N M P P > N D M D P D M D P D − ¼ E þ 2E þ 2E 1−θ > E E E E E C > k þ k þ k þ k þ k dt no > ∂t ()∂t ∂()t ∂t ∂t M Mf P P Mf > M Mf P Pd P Pf þ E λθ þ E θ −ðÞ1−λ θ ð46Þ > ∂D ∂θ ∂D ∂θ ∂D ∂θ > þEM þ EP þ > ∂θMf ∂ k ∂θPd ∂ k ∂θPf ∂ k > t t t 8 > ()() N M P P > ∂ M ∂θMf ∂ P ∂θPd ∂ P ∂θPf > E þ 2E þ 2E 1−θ > M D P D D > > þE þ E þ < > ∂θMf ∂ k ∂θPd ∂ k ∂θPf ∂ k dG − MθMf εMf−εMf − PθP εPf εPd > t ()t t E E þ 47 > 2 3 C ¼ ð Þ > N M dt > > ∂T ∂T > 2 2 > 6 ðÞ1−λ DN−DM − þ 7 : −γλðÞ2−λ θP þ ðÞ1−λ ðÞ1 þ λ θMf tC > 6 ∂ k ∂ k 7 > 6 ()t t 7 > 6 7 < 6 ∂ N ∂ P 7 dG 6 N P T T 7 Mf * Mf Pf * Pd Mf * Mf Pf * Pd ¼ λ D −D − þ : ð42Þ where ε , ε , ε and ε are the elasticities of θ , θ , θ and θ k > 6 ∂ k ∂ k 7 dt > 6 ()t t 7 C > 6 7 with respect to t . It is straightforward to show that the behavioral ef- > 6 ∂TM ∂TP 7 C > 6 λðÞ1−λ DM−DP − þ 7 fect of t on government revenue (second line) is unambiguously > 6 k k 7 C > γ 6 ∂t ∂t 7 negative. Intuitively, an increase in t induces firms to erode the cor- > − 6 ()7 > 2 6 ∂ N ∂ P 7 porate tax base in Home by increasing loans to operating subsidiaries > 6 −λ N− P T − T 7 > 6 ðÞ1 D D þ 7 εMf * εPf * εPd > 6 ∂tk ∂tk 7 in Home, that is >0, >0 and >0, and reducing loans from > 6 () 7 Mf > 6 M 7 parent companies in Home, that is ε b0. Finally, the general equilib- > 6 ∂T 7 > 6 λ DM þ 7 rium effect of tC is negative. Intuitively, an increase in tC causes a net > 6 k 7 > ∂t fi > 6 ()7 shift of entrepreneurial resources from rms with large corporate tax > 6 ∂ M ∂ P 7 > 4 M P T T 5 bases in Home to firms with smaller corporate tax bases in Home. :> λðÞ1−λ D −D − ∂tk ∂tk Since the corporate tax is the only tax that generates revenue, this shift of entrepreneurial resources unambiguously reduces tax reve- nue in Home. To determine whether the contemplated reform increases X,we Dividing Eqs. (46) and (47), one could obtain an expression for the use Eqs. (38) and (42) to compute the MCF associated with each of C E C inverse MCF associated with t from the perspective of an individual the two tax instruments t and t from the perspective of Home. country, i.e. {−dGC/dX}. For the present purposes, it is, however, Since the initial market equilibrium is symmetric, we simplify the ex- sufficient to note that {−dGC/dX}b1 since the mechanical effect is pressions by dropping asterisks. Moreover, since all planning firms E smaller than unity and the behavioral and general equilibrium effects face the same real external barrier, that is t , and therefore choose – are strictly negative. the same debt asset ratio of operating subsidiaries, we can use the E P Pd Pf Pd * Pf * In sum, the MCF associated with t is unambiguously smaller simplifying notation θ ≡θ =θ =θ =θ . than the MCF associated with tC, hence the proposed reform increases We evaluate Eqs. (38) and (42) for tk =tE at tI =tI * =tE =0 and E * X. It follows that the initial policy vector is not consistent with t >0: equilibrium. (E) An initial policy vector with tE =tE * =0. Both countries earn dX P P − ¼ 2E θ ð43Þ zero revenue from the external barrier and corporate tax rates are dtE at the level that satisfies the revenue constraints with equality, that is tC ¼ tC ¼ τhG. This implies that tRE =0 and that dG P P P P P P 2 C ¼ 4E θ þ 2E θ ε þ 2γðÞ1−λ ðÞ1 þ λ θ t ð44Þ dtE DP ¼ 1−θPd tC where εP >0 is the elasticity of θPd and θPf * with respect to the tax P −θPf C : saving associated with internal lending tC −tE. The external barrier D ¼ 1 t falls on the debt of all planning firms, however, only in the case of planning firms resident in Home does it directly reduce private con- An increase in tE induces planning firms to finance subsidiaries sumption in Home. This explains that the mechanical effect of tE on Home with conduit loans through Foreign, hence tRE is unchanged N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416 415 at zero and X remains the same. Moreover, DP and DP * are unchanged revenue as possible with the corporate tax at a higher marginal and G remains the same. For tE * =0, any tE ≥0 therefore gives rise to cost. It follows that Home's best response to full enforcement in For- the same X and the same G for an unchanged level of tC. Since each eign is full enforcement and, by symmetry, Foreign's best response to country, given the policies of the other country, is unable to change full enforcement in Home is full enforcement, hence full enforcement its own policies in a way that increases X while still satisfying the is a Nash equilibrium. revenue constraint, the proposed policy vector is a Nash equilibrium. Since we consider small changes to a symmetric market equilibri- Finally, we compute the corporate tax rate that satisfies the reve- um, we simplify subsequent expressions by dropping asterisks on EJ nue requirement given that internal and external barriers are zero for J=N ,M ,P and applying the definition θP ≡θPd =θPf =θPd * =θPf *. and raise no revenue. Using symmetry, government revenue from Evaluating Eqs. (38) and (42) for tk =tE at tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0 yields: the corporate tax can be written as: no − dX PθP N M P P C E ¼ E ð48Þ G ¼ E þ 2E þ 2E 1−θ t : dt dG P P P P P P 2 C Using Eq. (23), this expression may be restated as: ¼ 2E θ þ 2E θ ε þ γλðÞ2−λ θ t : ð49Þ dtE 8 9 < N M P −θP = 1 E þ 2E þ 2E 1 The intuition for these expressions is identical to the intuition un- G ¼ tC h : EN þ 2EM þ 2EP ; derlying Eqs. (43)–(44) derived in the Proof of Proposition 2 with the sole difference that in the current context with no conduit financing, tE only falls on subsidiaries in Home so that −dX/dtE as well as the where 1/h is the number of operating subsidiaries in Home and the mechanical part of dG/dtE is halved. Dividing Eqs. (48) and (49),we expression in curly brackets is the average corporate tax base in obtain the following expression for the inverse MCF associated with Home for these subsidiaries. Inserting the revenue requirement G ¼ tE from the perspective of an individual country: G and rearranging, one obtains: ( ) () P C N M P dG E P γλðÞ2−λ θ t C E þ 2E þ 2E − t ¼ 2 þ 2ε þ : ð50Þ t ¼ hG: dX EP EN þ 2EM þ 2EP 1−θP

Clearly, the inverse MCF associated with tE is strictly larger than unity since the first term (the mechanical effect) is strictly larger Proof of Lemma 1. Without loss of generality, we can interpret the than unity and the second and third terms (the behavioral and general subgame comprised by stages two and three as a non-cooperative equilibrium effects) are strictly positive. game where Home sets tE and tC subject to tE≤t E and Foreign sets Similarly, we evaluate Eqs. (38) and (42) for tk =tI at tI =tI * = tE * and tC * subject to tE≤t E given that tI =tI * =0. This game is iden- tE =tE * =0 and find: tical to EU-style corporation except for the constraints on tE and tE *. −λ Cases (B)–(E) of the Proof of Proposition 2 apply and imply that dX 1 Mf M P − ¼ θ E þ E ð51Þ tE =tE * =0 in the unique Nash equilibrium. The corporate tax rate dtI 2 fi that satis es the revenue requirement given that effective internal no dG M Mf M Mf Mf 1−λ Mf P Mf C and external barriers are zero is also derived in the Proof of ¼ E θ þ E θ ε þ γθ −λθ−θ t ð52Þ Proposition 2. dtI 2

Proof of Lemma 2. We first note that when nominal internal and ex- where εMf * is the elasticity of θMf * with respect to the tax cost of debt ternal barriers are set at strictly positive levels in the first stage, coun- finance, tC * +tI, which is strictly negative. The internal barrier falls on tries can choose strictly positive levels of effective internal and the internal debt of foreign multinational firms and thus only affects external barriers in the second stage by choosing non-zero enforce- private consumption through its negative effect on wages. The behav- ment levels. Hence, all tax instruments represent possible sources of ioral effect of tI on government revenue is positive since it induces revenue and countries optimally choose to use the revenue sources foreign multinational firms to reduce internal loans to operating sub- that maximize private disposable income while satisfying the reve- sidiaries in Home. The general equilibrium effect of tI on government nue constraint. We also note that when Foreign fully enforces the revenue may be positive or negative. The ambiguity stems from the nominal barriers, that is zI * =zE * =1, planning firms never choose fact that workers initially shed by marginal foreign multinational to finance plants in Foreign with conduit loans through Home since firms following an increase in tI may be absorbed by domestic nation- the tax cost of conduit finance tI * +tE is at least as high as the tax al firms (generating a revenue gain proportional to θMf *) or foreign cost of direct finance tE * regardless of the policy choices made by planning firms (generating a revenue loss proportional to θP −θMf *) Home. Moreover, planning firms never choose to finance plants in in the new equilibrium. Dividing these two equations, we obtain the Home with conduit loans through Foreign since the tax cost of con- following expression for the inverse MCF associated with tI from the duit finance tI +tE * is at least as high as the tax cost of direct finance perspective of an individual country: E t regardless of the policy choices made by Home. Similarly, when 8 hi ) Mf P F C Home fully enforces nominal barriers, planning firms do not engage < M M γθ −λθ−θ t dG I 2 E 2 E Mf in conduit financing. − t ¼ − ε þ : : dX 1−λ EM þ EP 1−λ EM þ EP EM þ EP We proceed by deriving the MCF associated with each of the three tax instruments from the perspective of Home under the assumption ð53Þ that Foreign fully enforces fiscal barriers, that is zI * =zE * =1. In order to prove that zI =zI * =zE =zE * =1 is an equilibrium in the second It is straightforward to verify that when λ is not too large, the stage, it suffices to show that the MCFs associated with tE and tI re- inverse MCF associated with tI is strictly larger than unity since the spectively are smaller than the MCF associated with tC. When this mechanical effect (first term) is larger than unity and the behavioral holds, Home optimally sets zI =zE =1 so as to raise as much revenue effect (second term) and general equilibrium effect (third term) are as possible with fiscal barriers at a low marginal cost and as little strictly positive. 416 N. Johannesen / Journal of Public Economics 96 (2012) 400–416

As shown in the Proof of Proposition 2, the MCF associated with tC productive marginal national firms (reflected by the first part of the from the perspective of Home exceeds unity at tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0 third term) and to more productive marginal multinational firms and thus exceeds the MCF associated with tI and tE provided that λ (reflected by the second part of the third term). There is also a reallo- is not too large. It follows that full enforcement zI =zI * =zE =zE * =1 cation of entrepreneurial resources from marginal multinational is a Nash equilibrium in the second stage. firms to marginal national firms, however, evaluated at a point Finally, we characterize the corporate tax rate necessary to satisfy where the allocation of resources between these two types of firms the revenue requirement. Government revenue may be written as is undistorted, the associated efficiency loss is only second-order. no The MCF associated with combined increase in internal and external G ¼ EN þ 2EM þ 2EP 1−θP tC þ Q barriers is therefore below unity. By comparison, it was shown in the Proof of Proposition 1 that the MCF associated with the corporate where tax is above unity as long as external barriers are not prohibitive. It no follows directly that increasing internal and external barriers margin- Q ¼ EMθMf þ 2EPθP ρ ally from an initial level of zero and reducing the corporate tax to hold government revenue constant allows governments to increase pri- is the revenue derived from internal and external barriers. Using Eq. vate disposable income and thus welfare. (23) and the revenue requirement G G, one may rearrange to ob- ¼ Proof of Proposition 3. Without loss of generality, we can interpret tain the following expression for the corporate tax rate the subgame comprised by stages two and three as a non-cooperative () I E C I≤ I N M P game where Home sets {t ,t ,t } subject to the constraints that t t C E þ 2E þ 2E E t ¼ h G−Q and tE≤t and Foreign sets {tI *,tE *,tC *} subject to the constraints N M P −θP I E E þ 2E þ 2E 1 thatnotI≤t and tE≤t . In the first stage, countries optimally choose t I; t E so as to pick out the best feasible non-cooperative equilibri- N M P θP where E , E , E and are evaluated at the equilibrium. um in the second stage. It follows from the Proof of Proposition 2 that an equilibrium with zero effective internal barriers tI =tI * =0 Proof of Lemma 3. The proof proceeds by showing that from a social and positive effective external barriers tE >0 or tE * >0 does not perspective the MCF associated with the combined use of effective in- exist. Hence, the only feasible equilibrium with zero effective internal ternal and external barriers is smaller than the MCF associated with barriers is tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0 and tC tC τhG. It follows from the corporate tax rate when evaluated at tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0. This ¼ ¼ Lemma 1 that an equilibrium with positive effective barriers implies that increasing effective internal and external barriers and tI =tI * =tE =tE * =ρ for ρ→0 and tC tC τ′hG is feasible and at the same time reducing the corporate tax rate to leave government ¼ ¼ from Proposition 3 that this equilibrium is superior to the equilibrium revenue unchanged raise the level of private disposable income and tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0 and tC tC τhG. thus welfare. ¼ ¼ Use Eqs. (28) and (32) to derive the following expression for the inverse MCF associated with a combined increase in internal and ex- References ternal barriers evaluated at tI =tI * =tE =tE * =0: Buettner, T., Wamser, G., 2009. Internal Debt and Multinationals’ Profit Shifting — dGE¼I Empirical Evidence from Firm-Level Panel Data. Oxford University Centre for − ¼ 1 þ ξεP dX Business Taxation, Working Paper no. 09/18. fi θPd θPf 2TN−TP 1−λ θPd θPf −θMf TM−TP Cremer, H., Gahvari, F., 2000. Tax evasion, scal competition and economic integration. þ þ ðÞþ – þγξλ European Economic Review 44, 1633 1657. 2EP θPd þ θPf Desai, M., Foley, F., Hines, J., 2004. A multinational perspective on capital structure choice and internal capital markets. Journal of Finance 59 (6), 2451–2487. ð54Þ Desai, M., Foley, F., Hines, J., 2006. The demand for tax haven operations. Journal of Public Economics 90, 513–531. where Helpman, E., Melitz, M., Yeaple, S., 2004. versus FDI with heterogenous firms. American Economic Review 94 (1), 300–316. P θPd θPf Hong, Q., Smart, M., 2010. In praise of tax havens: international tax planning and E þ foreign direct investment. European Economic Review 54 (1), 82–95. ξ ¼ : EMθMf EP θPd θPf Huizinga, H., Laeven, L., Nicodème, G., 2008. Capital structure and international debt þ þ shifting. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 80–118. Janeba, E., Peters, W., 1999. Tax evasion, tax competition and the gains from nondiscrimi- The second term represents the behavioral effect, which is unam- nation: the case of interest taxation in Europe. The Economic Journal 109 (January), 93–101. biguously positive. The increase in external barriers induces planning ~ Jensen, M.C., 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. firms to bring debt levels closer to θ, which represents a first-order American Economic Review 76 (2), 323–329. welfare gain. The increase in internal barriers induces multinational Johannesen, N., 2010a. Tax competition for profits, asymmetric equilibrium and bene- Mf ~ ficial tax havens. Journal of International Economics 81, 253–264. firms to bring θ below θ, however, since the finance structure of Johannesen, N., 2010b. Taxing the financially integrated multinational firm. EPRU multinational is initially undistorted, the efficiency loss is second- Working Paper No. 2010-12. order. The third term represents the general equilibrium effect, Kleinbard, E.D., 2011. Stateless Income. Florida Tax Review 11, 699. Marceau, N., Mongrain, S., Wilson, J.D., 2010. Why do most countries set high tax rates which is also unambiguously positive. The increase in external bar- – fi fi on capital? Journal of International Economics 80, 249 259. riers reduces pro ts of planning rms whereas the increase in inter- Mintz, J., 2004. Conduit entities: implications of -efficient financing struc- nal barriers reduces profits of multinational firms. The loss of profits tures for real investment. International Tax and Public Finance 11, 419–434. is larger for planning firms than for multinational firms due to higher Ramb, F., Weichenreider, A.J., 2005. Taxes and the financial structure of German Inward – θPd θPf θMf FDI. Review of World Economics 141 (4), 670 692. cross-border lending ( + > ). Hence, there is a reallocation of Slemrod, J., Wilson, J.D., 2009. Tax competition with parasitic tax havens. Journal of entrepreneurial resources from marginal planning firms to more Public Economics 93 (11–12), 1261–1270.