David Ricardo Vs. Gottfried Haberler: When an Austrian Mind Matches an English Classic Mind

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

David Ricardo Vs. Gottfried Haberler: When an Austrian Mind Matches an English Classic Mind LIV REUNIÓN ANUAL| NOVIEMBRE DE 2019 David Ricardo Vs. Gottfried Haberler: When an Austrian Mind Matches an English Classic Mind Poinsot, Flavia Gabriela ISSN 1852-0022 / ISBN 978-987-28590-7-7 David Ricardo vs. Gottfried Haberler: When an Austrian mind matches an English classic mind Flavia G. Poinsot1 Abstract In many textbooks of international trade we read that the theory of comparative advantage, of Ricardo, determines its relative prices in function of the labor-cost theory. This approach, actually, emerges with Haberler by 1930s. For Haberler, the Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage is robust, but not the labor-cost doctrine which, he assumes, Ricardo applies. Haberler, then, reformulates the theory from the Austrian outlook which rejects the classical labor theory of value. The process, epistemologically speaking, resembles that of a Lakatosian “research program”, because while the hard core, the theory of comparative advantage, does not change, the assumptions and the labor-cost theory are eliminated. However, would Ricardo agree with Haberler in that he based the theory of comparative advantage in the labor-cost hypothesis? And, why Haberler thinks, without doubt, that Ricardo adheres to the labor-cost theory? This paper is an attempt to answer these questions. JEL classification: B31 - B53 – B25 – B12 - F10 Key words: David Ricardo – Gottfried Haberler – theory of value – theory of comparative advantage – Austrian school of thoughts – epistemology Introduction Gottfried Haberler, “the best horse in the Viennese stables” (Schumpeter, 2000, in Boehm, 2015), publishes Die Theorie der komparativen Kosten und ihre Auswertung für die Begründung des Freihandels in 1930, translate as The theory of international trade with its implications to commercial policy in 1933. The “known treatise of the professor von Haberler” (Schumpeter, 1954, 1971, p. 676), more than a century later of the David Ricardo’s Principles of Political Economy, makes famous the law of 1 [email protected] Universidad Nacional del Sur – Bahía Blanca – Argentina 1 comparative advantages of the latter. From here on, the idea that Ricardo puts forward his model in terms solely of labor is almost the norm in the most textbooks of foreign trade. Haberler develops the analysis of international trade in two parts, the theory and the trade policy. He divides the theory into the monetary theory of international trade in the first place, and the pure theory of international trade in the second place. In the former, Haberler considers the monetary aspects of the foreign trade. The theory of comparative advantage is in the latter and “dealt with the phenomena which result from the immobility of labor and capital, i.e. with the theory of comparative cost and all that follows from it” (pp. 8-9). Although it was linked to Ricardo by 1930s, and perhaps Torrens was the first in establishing the idea, Haberler stresses that Ricardo is the first in state his ideas systematically. We can read in the introduction that “the only really systematic theory of international trade we possess is the so-called classical theory” and all its component parts “were worked out by such early writers as Hume, Adam Smith and Ricardo” (Haberler, 1933, 1950, pp. 3). The doctrine of comparative costs is its “real” components, as opposed to the monetary aspects of the foreign trade. The problem, in Haberler view, is that Ricardo constructs the theory with the labor-cost theory, which supposes a set of unreal assumptions. Then, he argues, the theory is correct, but neither the assumptions nor the labor-cost theory is adequate. Then, he proceeds to disentangle the comparative advantage ideas of the chapter seven of the Principles (1817) of Ricardo from its assumptions, which, in turn, imply to eliminate the labor-cost theory. The picture of the theory that emerges from these considerations, “the solid theory” in Haberler’s words, resembles, I would suggest, that of a Lakatosian “research program”. We can state that the essentials underlying Ricardo explanation, his logical postulates, are the hard core of the theory, while the assumptions which support the labor-cost theory, and this theory itself, forms the protective belt. With this picture in mind, we can observe that Haberler unquestionably accepts the logical postulates of the law of comparative advantages. However, he rejects as unreal or false the assumptions, which support the labor-cost theory. He, then, reconsider the logical structure of this protective belt. In the first place, he changes the assumption and drops the labor-cost theory. In the second place, he substitutes those structures with the 2 principles of the marginal utility principles and the general equilibrium theory, in an Austrian way. However, does Ricardo state the theory of the international trade in terms of the labor theory of value? This question brings us to reconsider whether he adheres to the labor- cost theory because, if this is so, we can expect also that he would develop the trade theory in terms of this. Another question related is why Haberler thinks, without doubt, that Ricardo adheres to the labor-cost theory. This paper is an attempt to answer these questions. So that, the first section of this essay briefly displays the biography of Gottfried Haberler. In order to answer the addressed questions, the next section develops the key elements in the transformation of the theory Haberler does. In his own words, he takes the “only really systematic theory of international trade” to transform it in the theory he described as a “solid” one. So then, in the third and fourth section I give some probable answers to those questions. A final section contains some concluding thoughts. Gottfried Haberler, “the best horse in the Viennese stables”: His biography in a few lines Gottfried Haberler born on 20 July 1900 in Purkesdorf near Vienna. At the University of Vienna, where he studies, Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich von Wieser are his professors of economics and, since that, he belongs to the Austrian School of Economics. He is a member of the Mises circle. What’s more, with Hans Kelse, they are the witnesses of the marriage of Ludwing von Mises with Margit Sereny-Herzfeld in Geneva in 1958. This event was something strange for these two friends because Mises, of fifty-seven years old, lived with his mother until she dies a while ago, and Margit was not known for over a decade. Really, Kelse “could hardly believe he was seeing his friend at the office of the county clerk” (Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011, p. 115-16). Haberler gains his doctorate in law in 1923 and in political science in 1925, after that he works in the chamber of commerce. In 1927 he graduates from postdoctoral studies in London, and, when returns to Vienna, he obtains his Habilitation with Der Sinn der Indexzahlen, or The Meaning of the Index Numbers, in 1928, with Friedrich Hayek and Oskar Morgenstern. A year later, he graduates from postdoctoral studies, now from 3 Harvard, where he gives guest lectures in 1931-32. At the University of Vienna, Haberler, with Hayek and Morgenstern, have his lectures and participates in the Mises- Privatseminar (Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011). Haberler, Hayek and Morgenstern, “serve as a quantitative counterbalance to Spann and his circle of students for the first time in many years” with their courses alongside those of Mayer, Mises, and Strigl. In the Mayer’s circle, its students question the foundations of the “Austrian monetary business cycle theory” (Vorlesungsverzeichnis, 1929-1930, p. 12; Weber, 1966, p. 2, in Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011, p. 109), a theme that Haberler writes about and debates in the Mises’ circle. In this line of investigation, the combined contributions of Haberler, Machlup, Morgenstern and Strigl makes possible that the Austrian School presents itself in Zurich in 1928 “as the authoritative research group in monetary and business cycle theory” (Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011, p. 71). On 1934, Haberler writes a compilation of all current business cycle theories and two years later, when many of them were living outside of Austria, he completes his work on business cycle theories, “a monument to the “Austrian” contribution” (Haberler, 1937, pp. 33- 72). In the spite of the fact that the Austrian School is paralyzed by the political events of the time, its exiled members join the neoclassical mainstream, like Fritz Machlup in information economics; Oskar Morgenstern with his works on game theory, economic forecasting, and methodology; and Paul Rosestein-Rodan with his work in developing countries. Hayek points out that it is possible to have the impression that the Austrian School theories have entered into mainstream economics (Hayek, 1973, p. 13; Boettke, 1994b, p. 1, in Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011, p. 168). At this time, when many members of the Austrian School are politically undesirable, Haberler, whose Prosperity and Depression (1937) makes possible his contacts with the most world’s well-known economists, accepts, shortly after its publication, an appointment at Harvard. Therefore, he is abroad when Hitler determines the annexation in 1938, when many lectures and professors, who were either Jewish or dislike of the Nazis, among them Schüller, Morgenstern and Winkler, loss their teaching certification. But, in spite of his situation, he “uses his excellent contacts and his organizational talents to help emigrants and exiles in many ways” (Feichtinger, 2001, p. 202-3, in Schulak & Unterköfler, 2011, p. 132). Once more, in the United States, Haberler gains an excellent reputation, became advisor to the Board of Governors of the American 4 central banking system and later is elected president of the American Economic Association in 1963. While n 1971 Fritz Machlup became an honorary senator of the University of Vienna, Gottfried Haberler receives honorary Ph. D.s from the University of Innsbruck in 1970 and the Vienna University of Economics and Business in 1980.
Recommended publications
  • HLA MYINT 105 Neoclassical Development Analysis: Its Strengths and Limitations 107 Comment Sir Alec Cairn Cross 137 Comment Gustav Ranis 144
    Public Disclosure Authorized pi9neers In Devero ment Public Disclosure Authorized Second Theodore W. Schultz Gottfried Haberler HlaMyint Arnold C. Harberger Ceiso Furtado Public Disclosure Authorized Gerald M. Meier, editor PUBLISHED FOR THE WORLD BANK OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS Public Disclosure Authorized Oxford University Press NEW YORK OXFORD LONDON GLASGOW TORONTO MELBOURNE WELLINGTON HONG KONG TOKYO KUALA LUMPUR SINGAPORE JAKARTA DELHI BOMBAY CALCUTTA MADRAS KARACHI NAIROBI DAR ES SALAAM CAPE TOWN © 1987 The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank 1818 H Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior permission of Oxford University Press. Manufactured in the United States of America. First printing January 1987 The World Bank does not accept responsibility for the views expressed herein, which are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World Bank or to its affiliated organizations. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Pioneers in development. Second series. Includes index. 1. Economic development. I. Schultz, Theodore William, 1902­ II. Meier, Gerald M. HD74.P56 1987 338.9 86-23511 ISBN 0-19-520542-1 Contents Preface vii Introduction On Getting Policies Right Gerald M. Meier 3 Pioneers THEODORE W. SCHULTZ 15 Tensions between Economics and Politics in Dealing with Agriculture 17 Comment Nurul Islam 39 GOTTFRIED HABERLER 49 Liberal and Illiberal Development Policy 51 Comment Max Corden 84 Comment Ronald Findlay 92 HLA MYINT 105 Neoclassical Development Analysis: Its Strengths and Limitations 107 Comment Sir Alec Cairn cross 137 Comment Gustav Ranis 144 ARNOLD C.
    [Show full text]
  • Productivity Trends: Capital and Labor
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Productivity Trends: Capital and Labor Volume Author/Editor: John W. Kendrick Volume Publisher: NBER Volume ISBN: 0-87014-367-0 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/kend56-1 Publication Date: 1956 Chapter Title: Productivity Trends: Capital and Labor Chapter Author: John Kendrick Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c5596 Chapter pages in book: (p. -3 - 23) Productivity Trends Capital and Labor JOHN W. KENDRICK OCCASIONAL PAPER 53 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH, INC. 1956 Reprinted from the Review of Economics andStatistics Libraryof Congresscatalogcard number: 56-9228 PRIcE 8.50 Thestudy upon which this paper is based was made possible by funds granted to the National Bureau of Economic Research by the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation, Inc. The Foundation, however, is not to be understood as approving or disapproving by ofits grant any of the statements made or views expressed in this publication. NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1956 OFFICERS Harry Scherman, Chairman Gottfried Haberler, President George B. Roberts, Vice-President and Treasurer W. J. Carson, Executive Director DIRECTORS AT LARGE Wallace J.Campbell, Director, Cooperative League of the USA Solomon Fabricant, New York University Albert J. Hettinger, Jr., Lazard Frères and Company Oswald W. Knauth, Beau fort, South Carolina H. W. Laidler, Executive Director, League, for Industrial Democracy Shepard Morgan, Norfolk, Connecticut George B.Roberts, Vice-President, The First National City Bank of New York Beardsley Rumi, New York City Harry Scherman, Chairman, Book-of-the-Month Club George Soule, Bennington College N.
    [Show full text]
  • Gottfried Haberler: a Century Appreciation*
    __________________________________________________________________________________________________ Gottfried Haberler: A Century Appreciation* Richard M. Ebeling* _____________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________________________________________ ________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________ During the first week of July in 1936, an inter- work. Indeed, "Haberler-like methods" became a national conference on the "Problems of Economic catch phrase of the entire conference.1 Change" was held in Annecy, France. It brought Haberler had spent two years carefully together such notable economists as Ludwig von researching and consulting on the various Mises, Wilhelm Ropke, Oskar Morgenstern, Bertil competing theories
    [Show full text]
  • Alvin Hansen As a Creative Economic Theorist Author(S): Paul A
    Alvin Hansen as a Creative Economic Theorist Author(s): Paul A. Samuelson Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 90, No. 1 (Feb., 1976), pp. 24-31 Published by: Oxford University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1886083 Accessed: 18-07-2015 20:54 UTC Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/ info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly Journal of Economics. http://www.jstor.org This content downloaded from 132.72.138.1 on Sat, 18 Jul 2015 20:54:30 UTC All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions ALVIN HANSEN AS A CREATIVE ECONOMIC THEORIST PAUL A. SAMUELSON Early syntheses, 27. - The scholar reborn, 29. - Conclusion, 31. Much has been written about Alvin Hansen, the teacher and scholar - by others in this symposium and by me elsewhere.' My purpose here is to describe his contributions to the corpus of eco- nomic analysis: when all personal influences decay exponentially through time as they must, there remains imperishably locked in the developed corpus of a subject the value-added contributions of a scholar. Men are mortal.
    [Show full text]
  • Lionel Robbins on Economic Generalizations and Reality in the Light of Modern Econometrics
    Economica (2009) 76, 873–890 doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00805.x Robbins on Economic Generalizations and Reality in the Light of Modern Econometrics By ROGER E. BACKHOUSEw and STEVEN N. DURLAUFz wUniversity of Birmingham and Erasmus University Rotterdam zUniversity of Wisconsin–Madison Final version received 27 February 2009. This paper examines Lionel Robbins’ critical attitude towards formal empirical work from the standpoint of modern econometrics. It argues that his attitude towards empirical work rested on indefensible assumptions and that he failed to realise that the role he saw for empirical work undermined his belief in the primacy of economic theory. This matters because Robbins’ attitudes are echoed in modern economics, best exemplified by the calibration methodology of Kydland and Prescott, which is vulnerable to similar criticisms. INTRODUCTION Economists take widely different positions on the role that empirical evidence should play in the development of substantive propositions. Contemporary macroeconomics is split between those who give primacy to theory, whether they employ calibration methods to link theory to data (Edward Prescott) or regard theory and econometrics as complementary (Lars Hansen and Thomas Sargent), and those who regard atheoretical analyses as fundamental (Christopher Sims).1 Similar disagreements exist within microeconomics. On the microeconometrics side, one finds competing paradigms between James Heckman, whose work focuses on the use of economic assumptions to account for self-selection and heterogeneity, those who adopt the essentially statistical assumptions employed in Donald Rubin’s causal model, and Charles Manski’s emphasis on asking what may be learned under minimal assumptions of any type. Other microeconomic research, for example Steven Levitt’s work on crime, focuses on the identification of natural experiments, so that econometric analysis is reduced to a trivial role.
    [Show full text]
  • Front Matter, Table of Contents, Acknowledgments
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Individual and Social Responsibility: Child Care, Education, Medical Care, and Long-Term Care in America Volume Author/Editor: Victor R. Fuchs, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-26786-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fuch96-1 Conference Date: October 7-8, 1994 Publication Date: January 1996 Chapter Title: Front matter, table of contents, acknowledgments Chapter Author: Victor R. Fuchs Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c6555 Chapter pages in book: (p. -11 - 0) This Page Intentionally Left Blank Individual and Social Responsibility A National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report Individual and Social Responsibility Child Care, Education, Medical Care, and Long-Term Care in America Edited by Victor R. Fuchs The University of Chicago Press Chicago and London VICTORR. FUCHSis the Henry J. Kaiser, Jr., Professor Emeritus at Stanford University and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 60637 The University of Chicago Press, Ltd., London 0 1996 by The National Bureau of Economic Research All rights reserved. Published 1996 Printed in the United States of America 05040302010099989796 12345 ISBN: 0-226-26786-5 (cloth) Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Individual and social responsibility : child care, education, medical care, and long-term care in America / edited by Victor R. Fuchs. p. cm.-(National Bureau of Economic Research conference report) Includes bibliographical references and index. 1. Human services-United States-Congresses. 2.
    [Show full text]
  • Reacting to Samuelson: Early Development Economics and the Factor-Price Equalization Theorem
    1 Reacting to Samuelson: Early Development Economics and the Factor-Price Equalization Theorem Mauro Boianovsky (Universidade de Brasilia) [email protected] Abstract. Paul Samuelson’s famous 1948 “factor price equalization theorem” was his main contribution to international trade theory. He demonstrated conditions under which trade in goods only would lead to full equalization of the remuneration of productive factors across countries. In practice, general factor-price equalization has not been a feature of the international economy, as Samuelson acknowledged. His theorem came out when development economics was starting to emerge as a new field of research and policy, largely based on the observed international income asymmetries between poor and rich countries. The paper investigates how development economists reacted mostly (but not always) critically to that theorem, with attention to the methodological issues involved and to Samuelson’s own perception of the theorem’s relevance. Key words. Samuelson, factor-price equalization, development economics, trade theory JEL codes. B20, B27, B30 Resumo. O famoso teorema de 1948 da “equalização dos preços dos fatores” de Paul Samuelson foi sua principal contribuição à teoria do comércio internacional. Ele demonstrou condições sob as quais o comércio de bens iria conduzir à plena equalização das remunerações dos fatores entre os países. Na prática, a equalização dos preços dos fatores não tem ocorrido em geral, como Samuelson reconheceu. O seu teorema veio à tona quando a economia do desenvolvimento estava começando a emergir como nova área de pesquisa e política, baseada largamente nas assimetrias internacionais de renda observadas. O trabalho investiga como economistas do desenvolvimento reagiram em geral (mas não sempre) de forma crítica àquele teorema, com atenção às questões metodológicas envolvidas e à própria percepção de Samuelson da relevância do seu teorema.
    [Show full text]
  • Gottfried Haberler Papers
    http://oac.cdlib.org/findaid/ark:/13030/tf0k4000k6 No online items Register of the Gottfried Haberler papers Finding aid prepared by Hoover Institution Library and Archives staff and Sally DeBauche Hoover Institution Library and Archives © 1998, 2014 434 Galvez Mall Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-6003 [email protected] URL: http://www.hoover.org/library-and-archives Register of the Gottfried Haberler 95048 1 papers Title: Gottfried Haberler papers Date (inclusive): 1900-1998 Collection Number: 95048 Contributing Institution: Hoover Institution Library and Archives Language of Material: English Physical Description: 113 manuscript boxes, 1 cubic foot box, 9 oversize box(70.8 Linear Feet) Abstract: Correspondence, speeches and writings, printed matter, photographs, slides, and memorabilia relating to economic theory, and especially to laissez-faire economics and associated concepts of liberty. Creator: Haberler, Gottfried, 1900-1995 Hoover Institution Library & Archives. Access Box 122 restricted; use copies available in Box 73. The remainder of the collection is open for research; materials must be requested at least two business days in advance of intended use. Publication Rights For copyright status, please contact the Hoover Institution Library & Archives. Acquisition Information Materials were acquired by the Hoover Institution Library & Archives in 1995. Preferred Citation [Identification of item], Gottfried Haberler papers, [Box no., Folder no. or title], Hoover Institution Library & Archives. Biographical
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction: Continuity and Change in Theory, Behavior,And Methodology
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change Volume Author/Editor: Robert J. Gordon, ed. Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-30452-3 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/gord86-1 Publication Date: 1986 Chapter Title: Introduction: Continuity and Change in Theory, Behavior,and Methodology Chapter Author: Robert J. Gordon Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10017 Chapter pages in book: (p. 1 - 34) Introduction: Continuity and Change in Theory, Behavior, and Methodology Robert J. Gordon For well over a century business cycles have run an unceasing round. They have persisted through vast economic and social changes; they have withstood countless exp(~riments in industry, agriculture, banking, industrial relations, and public policy; they have confounded forecasters without number, belied repeated prophecies of a "new era of prosperity" and outlived repeated forebodings of "chronic depression." Arthur F. Bums (1947, 27) Analyzing business cycles means neither more nor less than analyzing the economic process of the (;apitalist era.... Cycles are not like tonsils, separable things that might be treated by themselves, but are, like the beat of the heart, of the essenc~: of the organism that displays them. Joseph A. Schumpeter (1939, 5) The postwar era has not surprised Arthur Burns, for business cycles have continued their "unceasing round." l~lthough the United States recession of 1981-82 was the eighth since ~lorld War II and the deepest postwar slump by almost any measure, the 1983-84 recovery displayed an upward momentum sufficient to befuddle forecasters and delight incumbent politicians.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes and References
    Notes and References Note: The term 'loc. cit.' is used when a text has just been mentioned and the term 'op. cit.' is used when a text has been referenced some distance back. 1 The Classical Legacy 1. For a recent critical survey of classical trade theory, including the debate on the Corn Laws and the BuUionist and Banking/Currency school controversies, see Leonard Gomes, Foreign Trade and the National Economy: Mercantilist and Classical Perspectives (London: Macmillan, 1987) part II. Part I of the same book surveys the foreign trade doctrines of the mercantilists. 2. Joan Robinson, 'Reflections on the Theory of International Trade', in her Collected Economic Papers, vol. 5 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1979) p. 130. 2 Early Neoclassical Contributions 1. A. A. Cournot, Recherches sur les Principes Mathematiques de la Theorie des Richesses (Paris: Hachette, 1838). Translated by Nathaniel T. Bacon as Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth (London: Macmillan, 1897) p. 117. 2. Cournot's arithmetical example is in Principes, pp. 314-15. 3. See Edgeworth, 'The Theory of International Values', Economic Jour­ nal, 1894, p. 627. 4. Researches, p. 157. 5. Researches, p. 156. 6. Ibid. pp. 162-3. 7. The 1844 criticism was by Carl Heinrich Hagen, in his book, Die Nothwendigkeit der Handelsfreiheit fur das Nationaleinkommen, mathe- matisch nachgewiesen (Konigsberg, 1844) pp. 30-1. Samuelson praises Cournot's treatment of interspatial price equilibrium as being 'marvel­ lously modern and fruitful', but adds, 'his analysis of tariff protection appears to be ambiguous and of doubtful validity'. P. A. Samuelson, The Way of An Economist', in Paul Samuelson (ed.), International Economic Relations (London: Macmillan, 1969) p.
    [Show full text]
  • Universidade Federal De Minas Gerais Faculdade De Ciências Econômicas Centro De Desenvolvimento E Planejamento Regional
    Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional V Ciclo de Seminários em Metodologia e História do Pensamento Econômico HISTORICISMO E SOCIALISMO DE ESTADO NA ALEMANHA Luiz Felipe Bruzzi Curi Pós-Doutorando, Cedeplar/UFMG Doutor em História Econômica (USP) O texto é o capítulo 4 da tese Nationalökonomie nos trópicos: pensamento econômico alemão no Brasil (1889-1945), defendida em fevereiro de 2018 e disponível para consulta na íntegra no repositório da USP. Belo Horizonte 27 de setembro de 2018 Capítulo 4 Historicismo e socialismo de Estado Se não trilhou exclusivamente um Sonderweg, um caminho particular, uma “via prussiana” das ideias econômicas como apressadamente se pode pensar ao generalizar o nacionalismo da jovem escola histórica para um conjunto diverso de pensadores, o pensamento econômico produzido nos Estados germânicos durante o “longo século XIX”, em alguma medida tributário da Nationalökomie, teve traços decisivos de especificidade. Não ficou isolado dos ventos e “fantasmas” – como o que Marx sinalizou no início do Manifesto Comunista de 1848 – que rondavam a Europa nesse período, pois foi influenciado pelo liberalismo britânico e pelo socialismo francês, para citar apenas dois exemplos, mas estruturou-se num ambiente intelectual, político e social peculiar. Um dos principais desafios que se colocam a quem deseja dizer algo sobre as ideias econômicas na Alemanha oitocentista é justamente relacionado com a questão que acabou “contaminando” todas as demais nesse período da história germânica: o que é ser alemão? Seria a mescla de tradições que resultou na Nationalökonomie a expressão de um pensamento especificamente “alemão”? A pergunta é de difícil resposta, mas vale expor algumas intuições nortedoras deste capítulo, que busca situar linhagens de pensamento alemãs, apropriadas no Brasil, no contexto de sua formação e desenvolvimento.
    [Show full text]
  • Reconsidering Value and Labour in the Digital Age
    Reconsidering Value and Labour in the Digital Age Edited by Eran Fisher Open University of Israel Christian Fuchs University of Westminster, UK vi Contents Contents 8 Advertising on Social Media: The Reality behind the Ideology of “Free Access”: The Case of Chinese Social Media Platforms 133 Yuqi Na List of Figures and Tables vii Part IV Rent and the Commons Series Preface viii 9 Mapping Approaches to User Participation and Digital Labour: A Critical Perspective 153 Notes on Contributors x Thomas Allmer, Sebastian Sevignani, and Jernej Amon Prodnik 10 Is the Concept of Rent Relevant to a Discussion of Surplus Part I Foundations Value in the Digital World? 172 Olivier Frayssé 1 Introduction: Value and Labour in the Digital Age 3 Christian Fuchs and Eran Fisher 11 The Demise of the Marxian Law of Value? A Critique of Michael Hardt and Antonio Negri 188 2 The Digital Labour Theory of Value and Karl Marx in the Jakob Rigi Age of Facebook, YouTube, Twitter, and Weibo 26 Christian Fuchs Part V Productivity in Reproduction 3 The Hands and Brains of Digital Culture: Arguments for 12 Devaluing Binaries: Marxist Feminism and the Value of an Inclusive Approach to Cultural Labour 42 Consumer Labour 207 Marisol Sandoval Kylie Jarrett 13 The Concept of Subsumption of Labour to Capital: Part II Labour and Class Towards Life Subsumption in Bio-Cognitive Capitalism 224 4 A Contribution to a Critique of the Concept Playbour 63 Andrea Fumagalli Arwid Lund 14 Form-Giving Fire: Creative Industries as Marx’s “Work of 5 Marx in Chinese Online Space: Some Thoughts on the Combustion” and the Distinction between Productive and Labour Problem in Chinese Internet Industries 80 Unproductive Labour 246 Bingqing Xia Frederick H.
    [Show full text]