Distrust – the Hidden Cost of Control

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Distrust – the Hidden Cost of Control IZA DP No. 1203 Distrust – The Hidden Cost of Control Armin Falk Michael Kosfeld DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DISCUSSION PAPER July 2004 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Distrust – The Hidden Cost of Control Armin Falk IZA Bonn, University of Bonn Michael Kosfeld University of Zurich Discussion Paper No. 1203 July 2004 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 Email: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the institute. Research disseminated by IZA may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit company supported by Deutsche Post World Net. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its research networks, research support, and visitors and doctoral programs. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available on the IZA website (www.iza.org) or directly from the author. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1203 July 2004 ABSTRACT ∗ Distrust – The Hidden Cost of Control We show experimentally that a principal’s distrust in the voluntary performance of an agent has a negative impact on the agent’s motivation to perform well. Before the agent chooses his performance, the principal in our experiment decides whether he wants to restrict the agents’ choice set by implementing a minimum performance level for the agent. Since both parties have conflicting interests, restriction is optimal for the principal whenever the latter expects the agent to behave opportunistically. We find that most principals in our experiment do not restrict the agent’s choice set but trust that the agent will perform well voluntarily. Principals who trust induce, on average, a higher performance and hence earn higher payoffs than principals who control. The reason is that most agents lower their performance as a response to the signal of distrust created by the principal’s decision to limit their choice set. Our results shed new light on dysfunctional effects of explicit incentives as well as the puzzling incompleteness of many economic contracts. JEL Classification: C7, C9, M5 Keywords: trust, distrust, motivation, incentives, control, incomplete contracts, fairness Corresponding author: Armin Falk IZA Bonn P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Email: [email protected] ∗ Financial support by the MacArthur Foundation (Network on the Evolution of Individual Preferences and Social Norms), the Ludwig Boltzmann Institute for the Analysis of Economic Growth, and the Swiss National Science Foundation (Project No 12-67751.02) is gratefully acknowledged. Principal-agent relations are typically characterized by a conflict of interest. Therefore, principals often use control and incentive devices to eliminate agents' most opportunistic actions. This paper analyzes how the agent perceives the principal's decision to control and how this a®ects the agent's behavior. We conducted an experiment in which a principal can decide either to trust or to control the agent, where controlling rules out the agent's most opportunistic actions. Our results show that the decision to control signi¯cantly reduces the agents' willingness to act in the principal's interest. Explicit incentives back¯re and performance is lower if the principal controls compared to if he trusts. We analyze the interaction of motivation and control in a simple and parsimonious set- up. In the game under study, an agent chooses a productive activity x which is costly to him but which increases the principal's payo®. The distinguishing feature of our experiment is the principal's decision. Before choosing x, the principal determines the agent's choice set. He can either leave the choice of x completely to the agent's discretion, in which case the lowest possible choice of x is zero. Alternatively, the principal can force the agent to choose at least a minimum level x > 0. The de¯nition of the agent's choice set can be interpreted as the degree of control implemented in the agent's work environment. For example, making it impossible for the agent to choose below x is the equivalent of implementing various control or monitoring devices which restrain the agent from his most opportunistic choices. Not restricting the choice set, on the other hand, represents the absence of such control mechanisms. Alternatively, the restriction of the choice set can also be interpreted as the outcome of a corresponding employment contract. For example, if x represents the amount of working hours, x captures a minimum presence requirement. Similarly, if x stands for the quality of a produced good or service, x is the minimum quality the agent has to deliver. Since x is costly to the agent, standard economic theory predicts that the agent will choose the lowest possible x, which is zero if the principal does not restrict the agent's choice set and x > 0 if he does. Since the principal's payo® is increasing in x, he will therefore always be better o® controlling the agent than not limiting the agent's choice set. However, if there are agents who are intrinsically motivated to perform in the principal's interest, controlling may actually decrease performance. A potential reason is that agents do not like to be restricted and perceive control as a negative signal of distrust. In addition, these agents might also assume that the principal has low expectations. Our main results, in fact, con¯rm the hypothesis that control has an adverse e®ect on agents' performance. We ¯nd that a majority of the agents in our experiment choose a lower x if the principal restricts rather than trusts them. We vary the level of x in di®erent treatments. While we ¯nd evidence for the hidden costs of control in all treatments, the net e®ect on pro¯ts turns out to be non-monotonic. For low levels of x, control generates signi¯cantly lower pro¯ts than trust; as x rises, however, control eventually breaks even. In a detailed analysis of agents' motives behind control aversion, we ¯nd that agents seem to believe that principals 1 who control expect to receive less than those who don't, and that agents' beliefs correlate positively with their behavior. When asked for their perception of control, most agents indicate that they perceive the decision to control as a signal of distrust and a limitation of their choice autonomy. Given the hidden costs of control, principals earn more if they trust their agents than if they control. Most of the principals in our experiment seem to understand the adverse e®ect of control. The majority decides not to restrict the agent's choice set but to trust that the agent will perform well voluntarily. Principals who control hold more pessimistic beliefs about the agent's performance than principals who trust. As agents' behavior roughly con¯rms both types of beliefs, our results nicely support the so-called \self-ful¯lling prophecy of distrust" (Niklas Luhmann, 1968).1 We conducted several control treatments both to test the robustness of our results as well as to isolate the precise impact of control on agents' motivation. In one of these treatments, the constraint x is given exogenously, i.e., the agent's choice set is identical to that in the main experiment when the principal decides to control. However, since it is not the principal who implements x, distrust and control are not at issue in this treatment. If the principal's controlling decision is behaviorally relevant to the agent, x should therefore be lower if the principal decides to control in the main treatment than in the control treatment. This is what we ¯nd. In a further treatment, we embed the principal's control decision in a standard gift-exchange game. A principal in this treatment not only decides whether to control his agent but also determines his agent's wage. In line with previous studies, we ¯nd that agents' x-choices are generally increasing in the wage payment, i.e., agents act reciprocally to the principal's wage choice. Yet, if the principal controls, the agent's reciprocal inclination is lower than if the principal does not control. The result shows that even if the principal can use additional instruments to motivate the agent, control continues to have a negative impact on agents' performance. To further test the robustness of our ¯ndings, we conducted a questionnaire where subjects were asked to state their work motivation in various everyday workplace scenarios. Similar to our lab evidence, we ¯nd that self-reported work motivation varies signi¯cantly with the extent to which agents are exposed to control. Taken together, our results show that the use of control and explicit incentives entails 1The intuition of our results is neatly captured by an example reported by David Packard, one of the founders of the computer company Hewlett-Packard (HP). Packard notes in his memoirs: \In the late 1930s, when I was working for General Electric ..., the company was making a big thing of plant security. ... GE was especially zealous about guarding its tool and parts bins to make sure employees didn't steal anything.
Recommended publications
  • Introduction to Psychological Disorders Defining Disorder Psychological Disorder
    Introduction to Psychological Disorders Defining Disorder Psychological Disorder • A “harmful dysfunction” in which behaviors are maladaptive, unjustifiable, disturbing, and atypical Maladaptive • An exaggeration of normal, acceptable behaviors • Destructive to oneself or others Unjustifiable • A behavior which does not have a rational basis Disturbing • A behavior which is troublesome to other people Atypical • A behavior so different from other people’s behavior that it violates a norm • Norms vary from culture to culture MUDA • A mnemonic device used to remember the four attributes of a psychological disorder –Maladaptive –Unjustifiable –Disturbing –Atypical Understanding Disorders Early Views of Mental Illness • In ancient times, mental illness was usually explained through a supernatural model; the person was possessed or a sinner • During the Middle Ages treatment methods were inhumane and cruel Philippe Pinel (1745-1826) • French physician who worked to reform the treatment of people with mental disorders • Encouraged more humane treatment Understanding Disorders: The Medical Model The Medical Model • Concept that mental illnesses have physical causes that can be diagnosed, treated, and in most cases, cured. • Psychological disorders can be diagnosed based on their symptoms and treated or cured through therapy. • Psychological disorders are similar to a physical illness. Understanding Disorders: The Bio-Psycho-Social Model Bio-Psycho-Social Model • Contemporary perspective that assumes biological, psychological, and sociocultural
    [Show full text]
  • Econ 771.001
    ECON 771: Political Economy of Race and Gender Spring 2018 Dr. Elissa Braunstein Department of Economics, Colorado State University [email protected] Office: C327 Clark Office hours: T 1:00 – 2:00 (or by appointment) Overview I define political economy as “the study of the impact of group identity and collective conflict on the organization of economic activity and its consequences.” Political economy traditions tend to focus on class as a source of identity and group conflict. In this course, we will expand that focus to incorporate other sources of group membership, giving you a broad background in economic approaches to inequality and identity based on race/ethnicity and gender. We will focus primarily on the neoclassical, Marxian political economy and feminist literatures. In addition to learning more about the relationship between group membership and economic structures, we will use the prisms of race and gender to better understand and critique various approaches to economic analysis. And while much of the literature focuses on the U.S. context, I will try to broaden the discussion as often as possible, and encourage students to do the same. I welcome students from other social science disciplines. Although we will cover some advanced material that may be difficult for those who have not completed graduate economics courses, the emphasis will be on the main points, rather than the technical detail. The syllabus includes both required readings (*starred) and supplemental readings/sections as I wanted to give you a more complete sense of the literature if you are interested in looking further into a particular topic.
    [Show full text]
  • The Pandemic Exposes Human Nature: 10 Evolutionary Insights PERSPECTIVE Benjamin M
    PERSPECTIVE The pandemic exposes human nature: 10 evolutionary insights PERSPECTIVE Benjamin M. Seitza,1, Athena Aktipisb, David M. Bussc, Joe Alcockd, Paul Bloome, Michele Gelfandf, Sam Harrisg, Debra Liebermanh, Barbara N. Horowitzi,j, Steven Pinkerk, David Sloan Wilsonl, and Martie G. Haseltona,1 Edited by Michael S. Gazzaniga, University of California, Santa Barbara, CA, and approved September 16, 2020 (received for review June 9, 2020) Humans and viruses have been coevolving for millennia. Severe acute respiratory syndrome coronavirus 2 (SARS-CoV-2, the virus that causes COVID-19) has been particularly successful in evading our evolved defenses. The outcome has been tragic—across the globe, millions have been sickened and hundreds of thousands have died. Moreover, the quarantine has radically changed the structure of our lives, with devastating social and economic consequences that are likely to unfold for years. An evolutionary per- spective can help us understand the progression and consequences of the pandemic. Here, a diverse group of scientists, with expertise from evolutionary medicine to cultural evolution, provide insights about the pandemic and its aftermath. At the most granular level, we consider how viruses might affect social behavior, and how quarantine, ironically, could make us susceptible to other maladies, due to a lack of microbial exposure. At the psychological level, we describe the ways in which the pandemic can affect mating behavior, cooperation (or the lack thereof), and gender norms, and how we can use disgust to better activate native “behavioral immunity” to combat disease spread. At the cultural level, we describe shifting cultural norms and how we might harness them to better combat disease and the negative social consequences of the pandemic.
    [Show full text]
  • Distrust, Fear and Emotional Learning: an Online Auction Perspective Glenn Robert Bewsell
    Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research This paper is available online at ISSN 0718–1876 Electronic Version www.jtaer.com VOL 7 / ISSUE 2 / AUGUST 2012 / 1-12 DOI: 10.4067/S0718-18762012000200002 © 2012 Universidad de Talca - Chile Distrust, Fear and Emotional Learning: An Online Auction Perspective Glenn Robert Bewsell University of Wollongong, School of Information Systems and Technology, Wollongong, Australia, [email protected] Received 19 December 2011; received in revised form 12 April 2012; accepted 27 April 2012 Abstract This exploratory research explores the emotional perspective of online distrust, where distrust is a fear. Fear is one of the negative emotions where the situational state is motive-inconsistent and uncertainty is present. A review of literature explores distrust as a fear, emotions, emotional learning and identifies cognitive dimensions consistent with fear. These cognitive dimensions are motive-inconsistent situational state, uncertainty, goal-path obstacle, effort, and agency/control. Textual data is collected from an online auction community website to support this research. The dimensions consistent with fear are identified within the data collected and analyzed using qualitative analysis. Goal-path obstacles are identified within the data as; value incongruence, user isolation, user inefficacy, and financial. The goal-path obstacles identified are consistent with types of fear. The research findings are discussed in terms of the theory and offers suggestions to practitioners to improve
    [Show full text]
  • Kranton Duke University
    The Devil is in the Details – Implications of Samuel Bowles’ The Moral Economy for economics and policy research October 13 2017 Rachel Kranton Duke University The Moral Economy by Samuel Bowles should be required reading by all graduate students in economics. Indeed, all economists should buy a copy and read it. The book is a stunning, critical discussion of the interplay between economic incentives and preferences. It challenges basic premises of economic theory and questions policy recommendations based on these theories. The book proposes the path forward: designing policy that combines incentives and moral appeals. And, therefore, like such as book should, The Moral Economy leaves us with much work to do. The Moral Economy concerns individual choices and economic policy, particularly microeconomic policies with goals to enhance the collective good. The book takes aim at laws, policies, and business practices that are based on the classic Homo economicus model of individual choice. The book first argues in great detail that policies that follow from the Homo economicus paradigm can backfire. While most economists would now recognize that people are not purely selfish and self-interested, The Moral Economy goes one step further. Incentives can amplify the selfishness of individuals. People might act in more self-interested ways in a system based on incentives and rewards than they would in the absence of such inducements. The Moral Economy warns economists to be especially wary of incentives because social norms, like norms of trust and honesty, are critical to economic activity. The danger is not only of incentives backfiring in a single instance; monetary incentives can generally erode ethical and moral codes and social motivations people can have towards each other.
    [Show full text]
  • I Am an African
    I Am An African Favourite Africa Poems By Wayne Visser Fifth Edition Fifth paperback edition published in 2016 by Kaleidoscope Futures, Cambridge, UK. First and second paperback editions published in 2008 and 2010 by Your P.O.D. Ltd. Third and fourth paperback edition published in 2012 and 2014 by Wayne Visser. First and second electronic editions published in 2011 by Wayne Visser and in 2016 by Kaleidoscope Futures. Copyright © 2016 Wayne Visser. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, except as permitted by the UK Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, without the prior permission of the publisher. Cover photography and design by Wayne Visser. Cover photograph of the author by Indira Kartallozi. Printing and distribution by Lulu.com. ISBN 978-1-908875-22-8 Dedication Dedicated to the people of Africa, who never cease to amaze and inspire with their colourful diversity, their warm humanity, their unquenchable hope, their tireless resilience and their indomitable spirit. Fiction Books by Wayne Visser I Am An African: Favourite Africa Poems Wishing Leaves: Favourite Nature Poems Seize the Day: Favourite Inspirational Poems String, Donuts, Bubbles and Me: Favourite Philosophical Poems African Dream: Inspiring Words & Images from the Luminous Continent Icarus: Favourite Love Poems Life in Transit: Favourite Travel & Tribute Poems Non-fiction Books by Wayne Visser Beyond Reasonable
    [Show full text]
  • Integrating Animal-Assisted Interventions with Counseling Theory
    Article 14 Fido and Freud Meet: Integrating Animal-Assisted Interventions With Counseling Theory Paper based on a program presented at the 2011 American Counseling Association Conference, March 27, New Orleans, LA. Laura Bruneau and Amy Johnson Bruneau, Laura, is an associate professor of Counselor Education at Adams State University. Her primary research area is creativity in counseling, which includes therapeutic reading and animal-assisted interventions. She and her dog are a Pet Partners Team and a Reading Education Assistance Dog Team. Johnson, Amy, is the executive director of Teacher’s Pet, an organization that pairs troubled youth with hard-to-adopt shelter dogs. She is also the director of the Center for Human-Animal Interventions at Oakland University. Abstract Current research on animal-assisted interventions (AAI) is expansive and rapidly growing, affirming a host of physical, physiological, and psychological benefits when integrated into the counseling process. This modality harnesses the power of the human-animal bond, providing benefit to the client and the counselor- client relationship. Given the mental health needs of the juvenile justice population, the use of innovative, creative modalities is needed. By integrating counseling theory and AAI, this manuscript grounds the practice of AAI while highlighting examples with adjudicated youth. Keywords: animal-assisted interventions, human-animal bond, counseling theory, adjudicated youth Animal-assisted intervention (AAI) is an umbrella term for modalities such as animal-assisted therapy and animal-assisted activities. AAI is goal-oriented, designed to improve client functioning, and delivered by a practitioner with specialized expertise and training (Animal Assisted Interventions International, 2013). The scholarly literature on AAI is expansive and rapidly growing, supporting positive results with using AAI for persons with emotional or behavior difficulties (Nimer & Lundahl, 2007) and children and adolescents with psychiatric disorders (Prothman, Bienert, & Ettrich, 2006).
    [Show full text]
  • Behavioral Economics As Applied to Firms: a Primer1
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Behavioral economics as applied to firms: a primer Armstrong, Mark and Huck, Steffen University College London (UCL) January 2010 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/20356/ MPRA Paper No. 20356, posted 02 Feb 2010 03:16 UTC Behavioral Economics as Applied to Firms: A Primer1 Mark Armstrong and Steffen Huck Department of Economics University College London January 2010 Abstract We discuss the literatures on behavioral economics, bounded rationality and experimental economics as they apply to firm behavior in markets. Topics discussed include the impact of imitative and satisficing behavior by firms, outcomes when managers care about their position relative to peers, the benefits of employing managers whose objective diverges from profit-maximization (including managers who are overconfident or base pricing decisions on sunk costs), the impact of social preferences on the ability to collude, and the incentive for profit-maximizing firms to mimic irrational behavior. 1. Introduction In recent years there has been a good deal of research investigating how poor or non-standard decision making by consumers might affect market outcomes. In much of this work, the assumption is that firms are fully rational and aim to maximize their profits (and sometimes they do this by exploiting the behavioral biases of consumers). Some of this work points to situations where there is a role for policy which protects consumers from their own failings and from exploitative firms.2 In this article we focus instead on non-standard approaches to firm behavior. Consumers are kept in the background, and are present merely to generate in some fashion a demand curve for the firms' products.
    [Show full text]
  • Two Stories of Distrust in America
    May 2021 Two Stories of In America Two Stories of in America About More in Common The report was conducted by More in Common, a new international initiative to build societies and communities that are stronger, more united, and more resilient to the increasing threats of polarization and social division. We work in partnership with a wide range of civil society groups, as well as philanthropy, business, faith, education, media and government to connect people across lines of division. Principal Authors Dan Vallone — U.S. Director Stephen Hawkins — Director of Research Noelle Malvar, PhD — Senior Researcher Paul Oshinski — Research Fellow Taran Raghuram — Research Fellow Daniel Yudkin, PhD — Associate Research Director More in Common www.moreincommon.com 115 Broadway, New York, NY 10006 Acknowledgements More in Common appreciates the valuable input and advice relating to this study received from a wide range of experts and friends. We would like to thank the Charles Koch Institute, the Knight Foundation, and Democracy Fund for their philanthropic support for this project. For their assistance with many elements of this work we would like to thank our colleague Coco Xu and Amanda Fuchs Miller, Ranit Schmelzer, and Marla Viorst. The execution and analysis of this project was conducted in close partnership with YouGov. For their efforts across our polling projects, we thank the following members of the YouGov research team in particular: Samantha Luks, Rebecca Phillips, and Marissa Shih. The report, data visualizations, and other aesthetic considerations were designed and created by Michelle Ng and Alane Marco. Copyright © 2021 More in Common Version 1.0.3 All Rights Reserved To request permission to photocopy or reprint materials, email: [email protected] Contents Foreword –––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––– 5 Executive Summary ––––––––––––––––––––––––––– 7 Methodology –––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––– 10 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Medical Education and Distrust Modulate the Response of Insular-Cingulate 2 Network and Ventral Striatum in Pain Diagnosis
    1 Medical education and distrust modulate the response of insular-cingulate 2 network and ventral striatum in pain diagnosis. 3 Giada Dirupoa,b,c, Sabrina Totaroa, Jeanne Richardc,d and Corrado Corradi-Dell’Acquaa,b 4 5 a Theory of Pain Laboratory, Department of Psychology, Faculty of Psychology and 6 Educational Sciences (FPSE), University of Geneva, Geneva, Switzerland. 7 b Geneva Neuroscience Center, University of Geneva, Geneva, Switzerland. 8 c Swiss Center for Affective Sciences, University of Geneva, Geneva, Switzerland. 9 d Department of Psychology, Swiss Distance University Institute, Brig, Switzerland. 10 11 Corresponding author: Giada Dirupo, University of Geneva – Campus Biotech, Ch. des Mines 12 9, CH-1211, Geneva, Switzerland. Tel: +41223790966. E-mail: [email protected] 13 14 Keywords: Medical Students, Negative Feedback, Social Conformity, Medial Prefrontal 15 Cortex, Insula. 16 1 Abstract 2 Healthcare providers often underestimate patients’ pain, sometimes even when aware of 3 their reports. This could be the effect of experience reducing sensitivity to others pain, or 4 distrust towards patients’ self-evaluations. Across multiple experiments (375 participants), we 5 tested whether senior medical students differed from younger colleagues and lay controls in 6 the way they assess people’s pain and take into consideration their feedback. We found that 7 medical training affected the sensitivity to pain faces, an effect shown by the lower ratings 8 and highlighted by a decrease in neural response of the insula and cingulate cortex. Instead, 9 distrust towards the expressions’ authenticity affected the processing of feedbacks, by 10 decreasing activity in the ventral striatum whenever patients’ self-reports matched 11 participants’ evaluations, and by promoting strong reliance on the opinion of other doctors.
    [Show full text]
  • Gender Differences*
    PERFORMANCE INCOMPETITIVE ENVIRONMENTS: GENDER DIFFERENCES* URI GNEEZY MURIEL NIEDERLE ALDO RUSTICHINI Eventhough the provision of equal opportunities for men and women has beena priorityin manycountries, large gender differences prevail in competitive high-rankingpositions. Suggested explanations include discrimination and dif- ferencesin preferencesand human capital. In this paper we present experimental evidencein support of anadditionalfactor: women may be lesseffective than men incompetitive environments, even if they are able to perform similarly in non- competitiveenvironments. In a laboratoryexperiment we observe, as we increase thecompetitiveness of theenvironment, a signicant increasein performancefor men,but not for women. This results in a signicant gendergap inperformance intournaments, while there is no gap whenparticipants are paid according to piecerate. This effect is stronger when women have to compete against men than insingle-sex competitive environments: this suggests that women may be ableto performin competitiveenvironments per se. I. INTRODUCTION Allocationsacross genders of high prole jobs remain largely favorableto men, and area majorfactor in thegender gap in earnings.For example, Bertrand and Hallock[2001] found that only2.5 percentof the vehighestpaid executivesin alargedata setof U.S.rmsare women (for areviewon genderdifferences in wages,see Blau and Kahn [2000]). Thenumerous attempts to explain this fact can beclassi ed intotwo broad categories.The rstexplanation restson gender differences in abilities and pref- erencesand hencein occupationalself-selection [Polachek 1981]. Thesecond class ofexplanations relatesto discrimination in the workplace,which leads todifferential treatmentof men and womenwith equal preferencesand abilities [Black and Strahan 2001; Goldin and Rouse2000; Wennerås and Wold1997]. In this paper wepropose and experimentallytest an addi- tional explanation:women may be less effective than menin competitiveenvironments.
    [Show full text]
  • Blog Addition Gneezy and List
    Women and the Competition Gap By Uri Gneezy and John List You think you know why less than 4% of Fortune 500 CEOs are women? Scholars have theorized for decades about the reasons why women can’t seem to make faster progress in breaking through the glass ceiling. The sad fact is that while women are doing better than men in some areas, such as higher education, men still occupy the highest ranks of society in the United States and around the world. The proportion of women in the U.S. workforce rose from 48 percent in 1970 to 64 percent in 2011,1 but today, only one in five senior management positions are held by women. Some consider these facts as an achievement, since they are the highest in U.S. history. Yet, women are still paid less than men for equivalent jobs. Even in public positions women still have not achieved parity. They still hold fewer than 17 percent of Congressional seats, and about the same percentage of corporate board seats. We’ll try to convince you that an important contributor to this gap in labor market outcomes is the different ways in which men and women react to incentives. In particular, women tend to avoid competitive settings and jobs in which salary is determined by relative rankings. But why do women and men react differently to incentives? And how important is the culture we’re born into in making us more or less competitive? We couldn’t just take for granted, in the absence of data, that women were innately less competitive than men.
    [Show full text]