Ocean Governance and the Marine Fisheries Crisis: Two Decades of Innovation - and Frustration

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Ocean Governance and the Marine Fisheries Crisis: Two Decades of Innovation - and Frustration OCEAN GOVERNANCE AND THE MARINE FISHERIES CRISIS: TWO DECADES OF INNOVATION - AND FRUSTRATION Harry N. Scheiber" I. IN T R O DU C T IO N ............................................................................................ 119 II. T HE U .N. R ESPO NSE ...................................................................... ........ 123 III. T HE U .S. D EBAT E .................................................................................... 127 IV.APPROACHES TO FISHERIES MANAGEMENT ..... ...................................... 129 A. The PrecautionaryPrinciple ........................................................ :.130 B. The Preservationist Approach ........................................................... 131 C. Protection of biodiversity and ecosystem integrity ............................... 133 D. Privatizationofproperty rights infisheries ........................................ 134 V . C O N C LU SIO N ............................................................................................ 137 I. INTRODUCTION Twenty years ago, many well-regarded marine biologists and fishery-management experts objected to the notion that marine fish stocks could actually be "depleted" or "exhausted."' Policy makers and even many scientists persistently resisted the idea that a marine fish population or species could be wiped out despite large-scale changes in the marine fishing' situation in modern times, including the modernization of fishing fleets. The industrialization of fishing vessels began with the introduction of steam-trawler fishing in the late nineteenth century. This was followed by other innovations in gear and vessel technology, such as the introduction of giant factory ships that began operating in distant waters in the 1930s. The impact of this industrialization and modernization of fleets, which accelerated Harry N. Scheiber is the Stefen Riesenfeld Professor of Law and History at the Boalt Hall School of Law, University of Califbrnia, Berkeley. He is director of the Ocean Law and Policy Program in U.C. Berkeley's Center fin the Study of Law and Society, and also teaches in Boalt Hill's Jurisprudence and Social Policy )octoral Program. Acknowledgemenbt. This article is based on research partly stipported by a grant from the Calitbrnia Sea Grant Program of federal fiunds (Sea Grant Program, NOAA) and state funds, under Grant R/MA,-IO. U.S. (;overnment agencies have permission to duplicate or circulate fbr official use. The author wishes to express his thanks to his colleagues in teachingand research, Proft l)avid Caron, and Christopher Carr, J.I)., of U.C. Berkeley, for a generous sharing, in all oIur collaborations, of their learning on the Law of the Sea and on international fisheries law. I To be sure, the utopian notion of inexhaustibility continued to be voiced, despite the manif stly devastating etlects, tir example, of whaling activity on whale stocks in some ocean areas even in the old age of sail. HeinOnline -- 20 Va. Envtl. L.J. 119 2001 120 Virginia Environmental Law Journal [Vol. 20:119 dramatically after World War II, was magnified by the relentless expansion of fishing effort. As a consequence of this expanded effort, the harvest of fish grew from 17 million tons to 69 million between 1950 and 1974. By 1990 it had risen to almost 90 million.2 In 1900, the world landings of marine fisheries had been only an estimated 3 million tons. However, When collapses of commercial fisheries occurred - such as the dramatic crash of the Monterey-based sardine fishery, once one of the world's most intensive fisheries, after 1948 - the fishermen tended to argue that the stocks had simply migrated elsewhere. Marine scientists debated whether the loss of the Monterey fishery was due to overfishing or instead was due to some natural process. Through the late 1970s, it remained a respectable scientific and policy position to view as unfounded and alarmist the idea that actual loss of fisheries on a long-term basis might be the result of overfishing. There was also a widely-held view among fishery oceanographers and biologists that the harvestable volume of marine fisheries, called the "latent" volume of the biomass, was many times the already inflated tonnage levels that were then being harvested." These views have changed radically in the last twenty years. Today, the accepted premises of debate on ocean fishery issues include as axiomatic the possibility that severe and possibly fatal damage can be done to such resources by excessive fishing. To be sure, there is deep and lasting controversy as to what measures need to be taken in response to the possibility of such damage. But now it is universally understood that the clock has been ticking; today, we have a serious crisis in marine fisheries and ocean environment, and consequently a crisis in ocean resources governance. 2 U.N. Foot & AciiIc. OR;., Tiii: S'I'AVF O1. Woiti,) FISI iRII.S AND AQUACUI'I'LURI., passimn (1. fr), available at http://www.fto.org/dwcrep/wf).i00e/w99ot(eoo.htm [hereinafter STAlE UOF WO)i.II) FisIitIEI'S]. : On the example of' the sardine fishery's crash, see Harry N. Scheiher, Success and Failure in Science-Policy Interactions: Cases.from the Histor q/'Calfbrnia Coastal and Ocean Studies, 1915,-1)73, in iMI'ROVING INTiERIAC'iONS BI,'TWI.:EN COASTAL,SCIENCE AND POLICY 97, 98-105 (National Academy of Science ed., 19)5). See generally ARTIUR F. MCEVOY, Till FiSihERMAN'S PIROBiEM: EcoI,OY;Y AND LAW IN TIIE CAIVFORNIA FisI :imI:s i SO-198O ( 196). For example, Wilbert M. Chapman, internationally recognized in his day as an authority on fisheries science and policy, predicted marine fishery harvests at an tippet- bound of' I.(X) million tons in the year '2(XX. Wilbert M. Chapman, Seatbod and World Famine - A Positive Approach, Address in the Symposium on Food fi'om the Sea (Sept. 23 196.9)(transcript available in the Milner Schaefer Papers, Scripps Institution of Oceanography Archives, U.C. San I)iego). This was an exceptionally optimistic estimate fbr the day, but others who estimated lower latent resotirces in fisheries took a positive view of the long-run potential and certainly (lid not worry much about depletion, if'they even admitted that word to discussion. HeinOnline -- 20 Va. Envtl. L.J. 120 2001 2001] Ocean Governance and the Marine Fisheries Crisis 121 The data published annually in the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization ("FAO") reports have told the story vividly. Ever larger and more powerful fishing vessels, increasingly efficient gear, and-most ominously-a rapidly increasing tonnage of fishing vessels, impelled by large governmental subsidies for construction and operation, pushed the catch levels up five-fold between 1950 and 1990." Then, after 1989, catch levels began to slump. Several long- established deepwater and coastal fisheries collapsed altogether, among them a once-giant fishery for Northwest Atlantic cod that had been working for centuries. Moreover, the yield per unit of effort also began to show a decline, a sure indication that stocks were being reduced in numbers and that their reproductive potential was being damaged. The FAO data since the mid-1990s have shown that some 60% of the world's fisheries are at risk at different orders of magnitude. Now some 44% are assessed as being "fully exploited." This means that they may already be at the tipping point of overfishing and progressive depletion. In addition, the pressure on fisheries may be higher now that the ecological balance may be adversely affected with only slight variations in either environmental conditions or fishing effort. The truly shocking datum, however, is that one in six of the world's ocean fisheries is now evaluated as "overexploited" or at the point where commercial use will soon be no longer feasible.- Excluded from current assessments in the FAO reports are some once-important fisheries that have already been so fully depleted that they are left out of the calculations. Among the fisheries located within the United States' 200-mile Exclusive Economic Zone, where foreign fishing is not permitted, more than one third of the stocks are deemed over- utilized, and another 44% fully-utilized.' Consumers have felt the effects of the fishing decline, as the global catch of fish on a per capita basis fell by some 10% between 1988 and The data here and fbllowing on catch levels and assessments are from various FAO sources. See OF WORII) FISIIEIlS. suprauAE note 2 at 8-I I and tables passie; R. (irainger & S. M. (;arcia, Chronicles q Marine Fishery Landings, (19.'0-1994): Trend Analysis and Fisheries Potential, in U.N. FAO FISiIERIES TEClINICAL PAI'ER No. .59 (1996); R. Grainger, Global Trends in Fisheries and Agriculture, in TRENIDS AN) FUTIURE' CI IALLENGES FOR U.S. NATIONAl. OCEAN AND COASTAl. POLICY 23h(B. Cicin-Sain et al. eds., 19!9!9). 6 STATE OF WOhI.I) FisIhIEIIES, supra note 2, at 8-1. Ild. U.S. NATIONAL MARINI. FisiiEiliES SERVICE, PUll No. NMFS-F/SPO-22, OUi LIVIN(; OCEANs: Til: ECONOMIC STATUS OF: U.S. Fisiii:,IEii. S (NOAA, U.S. l)ep't of Commerce ed., 1()9(). HeinOnline -- 20 Va. Envtl. L.J. 121 2001 122 Virginia Environmental Law Journal [Vol. 20:119 1992." Moreover, a large proportion of the volume rise in catches of the previous decade consisted of fish species not used for table food, but rather only for animal feed or other secondary products. This put further pressure on the per-capita food fish supply globally. The consumer price index for fish products in the U.S. market accordingly was pushed steadily upward in the 1980s; far exceeding the rates of price increase for poultry or meats."' More recently, prices for certain fish species have risen far out of the reach of ordinary middle-class consumers in developed countries. Some of the once-popular species have disappeared from markets altogether because of fishery closings imposed by coastal state governments or international regulatory bodies.'' All of this evidence sounded the alarm so urgently that even the popular media finally began io give the fisheries crisis some attention. Attention had already been drawn to the environmental issues facing the oceans by the damaging oil spills occurring in several parts of the world.
Recommended publications
  • Ecological Economics and Sustainable Forest Management: Developing a Transdisciplinary Approach for the Carpathian Mountains
    ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS AND SUSTAINABLE FOREST MANAGEMENT: DEVELOPING A TRANSDISCIPLINARY APPROACH FOR THE CARPATHIAN MOUNTAINS Edited by I.P. Soloviy and W.S. Keeton Ukrainian National Forestry University Press, Lviv © Ihor P. Soloviy and William S. Keeton © Ukrainian National Forestry University Press All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Ukrainian National Forestry University Press Gen. Chuprynky 103 Lviv 79057 Ukraine E-mail: [email protected] Ecological economics and sustainable forest management: developing a transdisciplinary approach for the Carpathian Mountains. Edited by I.P. Soloviy, W.S. Keeton. – Lviv : Ukrainian National Forestry University Press, Liga-Pres, 2009. − 432 p. – Statistics: fig. 28, tables 67 , bibliography 686 . The modern scientific conceptions and approaches of ecological economics and sustainable forestry are presented in the book. The attention is given especially to the possibility of the integration of these concepts towards solving the real ecological and economic problems of mountain territories and its sustainable development. The ways of sustainability of forest sector approaching have been proposed using the Ukrainian Carpathian Mountains as a case study. The book will be a useful source for scientists and experts in the field of forest and environmental policies, forest economics and management, as well as for the broad nature conservation publicity. Printed and bound in Ukraine by Omelchenko V. G. LTD Kozelnytska 4, Lviv, Ukraine, phone + 38 0322 98 0380 ISBN 978-966-397-109-0 ЕКОЛОГІЧНА ЕКОНОМІКА ТА МЕНЕДЖМЕНТ СТАЛОГО ЛІСОВОГО ГОСПОДАРСТВА: РОЗВИТОК ТРАНСДИСЦИПЛІНАРНОГО ПІДХОДУ ДО КАРПАТСЬКИХ ГІР За науковою редакцією І.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critical Perspective on the Global Political Ecology of Aquaculture and Sustainability
    Master’s Thesis 2018 30 ECTS Faculty of Life Science Department of International Environment and Development Studies NORAGRIC William Derman, Main Supervisor at NMBU A Critical Perspective on the Global Political Ecology of Aquaculture and Sustainability Per Ditlef Faye International Environmental Studies Faculty of Life Science Norwegian University of Life Sciences Master's Thesis 2018 Department of International Environment and Development Studies – NORAGRIC A Critical Perspective on the Global Political Ecology of Aquaculture and Sustainability Sustainable farming of the Ocean: A perspective on Sustainability and Aquaculture Per Ditlef Faye International Environmental Studies The Department of International Environment and Development Studies, Noragric, is the international gateway for the Norwegian University of Life Sciences (NMBU). Eight departments, associated research institutions and the Norwegian College of Veterinary Medicine in Oslo. Established in 1986, Noragric’s contribution to international development lies in the interface between research, education (Bachelor, Master and PhD programmes) and assignments. The Noragric Master thesis are the final theses submitted by students in order to fulfil the requirements under the Noragric Master programme “International Environmental Studies”, “International Development Studies” and “International Relations”. The findings in this thesis do not necessarily reflect the views of Noragric. Extracts from this publication may only be reproduced after prior consultation with the author and on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation contact Noragric. Declaration I, Per Ditlef Faye, declare that this thesis is a result of my research investigations and findings. Sources of information other than my own have been acknowledged and a reference list has been appended. This work has not been previously submitted to any other university for award of any type of academic degree.
    [Show full text]
  • Stars – Papua New Guinea's National Strategy for Responsible Sustainable Development
    - StaRs – Papua New Guinea's National Strategy for Responsible Sustainable Development Misty E Baloiloi CMG PhD Email: [email protected] 1 Abstract for 2016 PNG Update Sustaining development (in PNG) beyond the resources boom Abstract 1 StaRs – Papua New Guinea's National Strategy for Responsible Sustainable Development Prof Misty Baloiloi, former adviser to Minister for National Planning and Monitoring on Sustainable Development From StaRS, “PNG is in an unique position to choose a future that is responsible and sustainable”. PNG can lead the way in a development revolution toward sustainability revolution towards an ecologically or responsible sustainable future. Papua New Guinea has its own Agenda 21. PNG has its own national strategy for responsible sustainable development (RSD). It is called StaRS. It is the process of transformation from a brown economy to a green economy. StaRS provide a totally new paradigm for development in PNG. It does not replace our development plans but elevates within them the principles of responsible sustainable development and strategic planning. It redefines the development road map by prescribing a growth strategy built on the principles of green growth, green economics, ecological economics and sustainable livelihoods and sustainable development. Em mi yah! In 2009 PNG adopted its Vision 2050 – an aspirational statement and set of beliefs and principles on the sort of PNG we want by 2050. In 2014 the PNG Government endorsed a new national strategy for responsible sustainable development called ”The Strategy”. One year later this was superseded by StaRS. “We believe that the people of PNG, both of today and tomorrow, should be continually aware that in striving to improve their lot they should not make the mistake of blindly destroying their rich natural environment.” “StaRS has been developed at a time when there is a recognizable growth in the economic fortunes of the nation, but also a growing global consciousness that environmental threats are being realized.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainability
    Alternatives for Saving Energy, Chemicals, and Materials If existing treatment processes are appropriate, efficient and functioning well; if the quality of water derived from its source and produced by the plant meet drinking water regulations and are of satisfactory quality, what steps can be taken to achieve economies in the use of energy, chemicals, and materials? Water Conservation Only if less water is produced will chemical use, sludge production, and the energy costs associated with water production decline. However, water conservation is an anathema to water utility management since the costs of operations must be paid for by the revenues produced by the sale of water. For example, water utility budget shortfalls often occur in those years in which adequate and timely rainfall reduce the peak summer demands for water. If a community adopts water conservation as a step toward reduced consumption of resources and long-term system sustainability, enlightened municipal management is obligated to ensure that revenues for properly operating and maintaining their water system are secured even in the face of declining water use. In other words, rates must be managed to both promote conservation and maintain economic viability of the utility enterprise. This has recently been defined as Full Cost Pricing. Full Cost Pricing In 2006, the United States Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA) convened an expert workshop of academics, water utility executives, public utility commissioners, utility rate setting practitioners, and other responsible parties to explore the issue of full cost pricing for water and wastewater service. Full cost pricing was defined as a pricing structure for drinking water and wastewater service that fully recovers the cost of providing that service in an economically efficient, environmentally sound, and socially acceptable manner.
    [Show full text]
  • Ocean Governance and Its Implementation, All of Which May Be Applicable in the Context of the Arctic Council’S Work
    O CEA N GOVERNANCE AN D ITS IM PLEM ENTATION: GU IDIN G PRINCIPLES FO R THE ARCTIC REGIO N 1 Dr. François N. Bailet2 TABLE OF CONTENT INTORDUCTION: MANIFESTATIONS OF OCEAN GOVERNANCE............................................... 2 THE GUIDEING PRINCIPLES OF OCEAN GOVERNANCE ........................................................... 3 LEVELS OF IMPLEMENTATION OF OCEAN GOVERNANCE ....................................................... 6 CONCLUSION............................................................................................................................. 19 This background paper is intended to serve as an information piece which outlines Ocean Governance Theory, as envisioned by the late Elisabeth Mann Borgese, and as it may be applicable to the Arctic Region in support of the Arctic Council’s (PAME) work in the elaboration of an Arctic Marine Strategic Plan. It is not the intent of this paper to review the current status of legal, political and institutional approaches to the management of Arctic resources and activities. These topics are extensively reviewed in the current literature and numerous relevant subject experts may contribute directly to the work of the Arctic Council.3 It is also not the intent of this paper to provide a prescriptive commentary on an approach to adopt in the Arctic Region. The contents of this paper are thus solely intended to contribute to the relevant discussions by providing an overview of Ocean Governance and its Implementation, all of which may be applicable in the context of the Arctic
    [Show full text]
  • Annual Report 2019-2020
    Table of Contents ABOUT KALPAVRIKSH 1 Beginnings 1 Philosophy 1 Governance 1 Functioning 1 Annual General Body Meeting 1 Committee for Prevention Of Sexual Harassment 2 ​ Kalpavriksh’s ​40 year Journey- A brief overview 3 PART A: PROJECTS/ACTIVITIES/CAMPAIGNS 5 A1 Environment Education 5 A1.1 Development, promotion, marketing of Children’s Books 5 A1.2 Ladakh Food Book 5 A1.3 Miscellaneous 6 A2 Conservation and Livelihoods 8 A2.1 Community Conserved Areas 8 A2.2 Continued Research and Advocacy on the Forest Rights Act 9 A2.3 Democratising Conservation Governance 10 A2.4 Documentation and Outreach Service in Community Based Biodiversity Conservation and Livelihood ​ Security ​ 11 ​ A2.5 Intervention, Documentation and Outreach towards Community Based Biodiversity Conservation and Livelihood Security in and around Bhimashankar Wildlife Sanctuary 12 A2.6 Biodiversity Assessment and Conservation Priority Plan of Sahyadri School Campus 13 A2.7 P.A. Update 14 A3 Environment and Development 16 ​ A3.1 Rivers, Dams and environmental governance in Northeast India 16 A3.2 Andaman & Nicobar Islands e-group 16 ​ A4 Alternatives 17 ​ A4.1 Activities in / relating to India 17 A4.1.1 Alternatives Confluences of Youth for Ecological Sustainability 17 A4.1.2 Documentation and Outreach Centre For Community Based Biodiversity Conservation and Livelihood Security 20 ​ A4.1.3 Agro-ecology case-study on millet revival 21 A4.1.4 Alternative Practices and Visions in India: Documentation, Networking, and Advocacy 22 A4.2 Global Activities 29 A4.2.1 Academic-Activist
    [Show full text]
  • Achieving a Sustainable Global Society Anno 2100?
    ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOBAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? Lars Josephsen [email protected] Presentation at The 3rd Nordic Post-Keynesian Conference Aalborg (Denmark) - 22. - 23. May 2014 ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOCAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? OVERVIEW 1. On Keynes’ Grandchildren Essay 2. Some necessary conditions for achieving ’A good society’ in 2100 * Shift from ’Society in the Economy’ to ’Economy-in-Society-in Nature’ * Economic models in a worldview perspective * Global sustainable development and the Post-2015 Agenda 3. Concluding remarks ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOCAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? The global perspective . Human activities on the planet are huge The global ecological footprint (2007) amounts to 1.4 x the planet’s biocapacity . Human activities are perhaps too large Are close to - or crossing - planetary boundaries WE LIVE ON A FRAGILE PLANET ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOCAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? On Keynes’ Grandchildren Essay Keynes’ perspective 1930 2014 2100 ? Actual perspective ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOCAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? On Keynes’ Grandchildren Essay Keynes identifies two key drivers of progress (only active in the last part of the considered epoch): ”Important technical inventions” ”Capital accumulation” Observers of today could note, that these two factors also today play decisive roles as drivers of ’progress’, but might add, that they both have their dark sides ON KEYNES’ GRANDCHILDREN ESSAY Keynes reflects on the needs of human beings - absolute needs (struggle for ’subsistence) - relative needs (”seem to be instiable”) ”The economic problem of the human race is not - if we look into the future - the permanent problem of the human race” The Brundtland report (1987) and documents from Rio 1992 are - at best - unclear about human needs ACHIEVING A SUSTAINABLE GLOCAL SOCIETY ANNO 2100 ? Many things could be said about the economic conditions in e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • Identifying Key Issues of Education for Sustainable Development
    sustainability Article Identifying Key Issues of Education for Sustainable Development Peter Glaviˇc Department of Chemistry and Chemical Engineering, University of Maribor, Smetanova 17, 2000 Maribor, Slovenia; [email protected]; Tel.: +386-4140-9611 Received: 16 June 2020; Accepted: 6 August 2020; Published: 12 August 2020 Abstract: This paper elaborates and presents key issues established for a course on Education for Sustainable Development (ESD). ESD is supported by the United Nations (UN) organization and its agency, the United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization (UNESCO). Quality education is also one of the seventeen UN Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). The evolution of sustainable development and ESD is overviewed first in order to define the most important content of ESD in future teaching. Because of the fast development of humankind in all the SD pillars (economic, social and environmental), the climate crises as well as the new technologies and knowledge emerging, education leaders and teachers are lacking modern and effective content for ESD. Therefore, twelve key issues of ESD are identified and elaborated in the present article. The issues are organized into four groups (approach, contents, teaching, and organization) with three items each. The approach is including ESD scope, policy, and cooperation, the contents part deals with the three ESD pillars — environmental, social and economic; the third group, teaching, regards ESD methodologies, transformative teaching and learning, and capacity building; the organization group presents ESD metrics, documents, and institutions. The twelve issues have been synthesized after reviewing the available literature, enhanced by the participation in several international projects on education. In addition, they were further elaborated from feedback obtained from three international conferences focused on education for sustainable development, social responsibility, and sustainable consumption and production.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 3 Scientific Understanding of Ecosystem Services
    Part III Assessment of Major Ecosystem Services from the Marine Environment (Other than Provisioning Services) Chapter 3. Scientific Understanding of Ecosystem Services Contributors: Marjan van den Belt (Lead author and Convenor), Elise Granek, Françoise Gaill, Benjamin Halpern, Michael Thorndyke, Patricio Bernal (Lead member) 1. Introduction to the concept of ecosystem services from oceans Humanity has always drawn sustenance from the ocean through fishing, harvesting and trade. Today 44 per cent of the world's population lives on or within 150 kilometres from the coast (United Nations Atlas of Oceans). However this fundamental connection between nature and people has only very recently been incorporated into trans-disciplinary thinking on how we manage and account for the human benefits we get from nature. Today, when a product taken from an ecosystem1, for example, fibres, timber or fish, enters the economic cycle (i.e., a part of the human system), it receives a monetary value that accounts at least for the costs associated with its extraction and mobilization. If that natural product is the result of cultivation, as in the case of agriculture, forestry and aquaculture, the monetary value also includes the production costs. However, the extraction of natural products and other human benefits from ecosystems has implicit costs of production and other ancillary costs associated with preserving the integrity of the natural production system itself. Traditionally these benefits and costs have been hidden within the “natural system,” and are not accounted for financially; such hidden costs and benefits are considered “externalities” by neoclassical economists. While the neoclassical economic toolbox includes non-market valuation approaches, an ecosystem services approach emphasizes that ‘price’ is not equal to “value” and highlights human well-being, as a normative goal.
    [Show full text]
  • Ecosystem Services in Theory and Practice
    2 ECOSYSTEM SERVICES IN THEORY AND PRACTICE Robert Costanza The world has changed dramatically. We no longer live in a world relatively empty of humans and their artifacts. We now live in what some are even calling a new geologic era – the “Anthro- pocene” (Crutzen, 2002) – a full world where humans are dramatically altering our ecological life support system (Daly, 2005). Our traditional concepts and models of the economy were developed in the empty world. The conventional view of the “economy” is based on a number of assumptions about the way the world works, what the economy is, and what the economy is for (Table 2.1). In this “empty world” context, built capital – the houses, cars, roads, and factories of the market economy – was the limiting factor. Natural capital – our ecological life support system – and social capital – our myriad relationships with each other – were abundant. It made sense, in that context, not to worry too much about environmental and social “externalities” – effects that occurred outside the market – since they could be assumed to be relatively small and ultimately solvable. It made sense to focus on the growth of the market economy, as measured by Gross Domestic Product (GDP), as a primary means to improve human welfare. It made sense, in that context, to think of the economy as only marketed goods and services and to think of the goal as increasing the amount of the goods and services produced and consumed. But in the new full world context, we have to think differently about what the economy is and what it is for if we are to create sustainable prosperity.
    [Show full text]
  • Ecological Footprint and Governing The
    ECOLOGICAL FOOTPRINT AND GOVERNING THE ANTHROPOCENE THROUGH BALANCING INDIVIDUALISM AND COLLECTIVISM McIntyre-Mills, J Flinders University [email protected] http://vocaroo.com/i/s03QQ2jfkxmh ABSTRACT The current way of life is unsustainable (Papadimitriou, 2014) and in a bid to maintain the status quo – profit is extracted from people and the environment. The challenge of scaling up efforts to engage people in an alternative forms of democracy and governance is that currently the response to social, economic and environmental challenges is that internationally politics is being shaped by so-called realist politics (Beardsworth, 2011) based on a) competition for resources, b) the notion that profit and loss, win and lose is contained /carried by ‘the other’ and c) Huntington’s ‘clash of cultures’ thesis rather than an understanding of our interlinked, co-created and co-determined fate. Keywords: consumption, accountability participation, governance, stewardship INTRODUCTION Growth = poverty according to Vandana Shiva. This paper argues that growth in the size of the population and cities, growth in the size of the gap between rich and poor as a result of the greed of a few at the expense of the majority in this generation and the next is unsustainable. The program of research on which this paper is based is that democracy and governance needs to be reframed through better accounting and accountability. This involves valuing human and natural resources and relationships appropriately and monitoring them fairly and equitably. This requires a transformation in our thinking, decision making and practice to ensure a livable future for this generation and the next.
    [Show full text]
  • ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS and SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Building a Sustainable and Desirable Economy-In-Society-In-Nature
    18 ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS AND SUSTAINABLE DEVELOPMENT Building a sustainable and desirable economy-in-society-in-nature Robert Costanza, Gar Alperovitz, Herman E. Daly, Joshua Farley, Carol Franco, Tim Jackson, Ida Kubiszewski, Juliet Schor and Peter Victor Introduction The current mainstream model of the global economy is based on a number of assumptions about the way the world works, what the economy is, and what the economy is for (Table 18.1). These assumptions arose in an earlier period, when the world was relatively empty of humans and their artifacts. In this context, built capital was the limiting factor, while natural capital was abundant. It made sense not to worry too much about environmental “externalities,” since they could be assumed to be relatively small and ultimately solvable. It also made sense to focus on the growth of the market economy, as measured by gross domestic product (GDP), as the primary means to improve human welfare. And it made sense to think of the economy as only marketed goods and services and to think of the goal as increasing the amount of these goods and services produced and consumed. Now, however, we live in a radically different world that is relatively full of humans and their built capital infrastructure. In this new context, we have to reconceptualize what the economy is and what it is for. We have to fi rst remember that the goal of the economy should be to sus- tainably improve human well-being and quality of life, and that material consumption and GDP are merely means to that end, not ends in themselves.
    [Show full text]