Money Creation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Money Creation Money creation • Who does make money and who is making money out of it? You remember these guys? 2 Monetary misconceptions • Money doesn’t make you happy. Or does it? • Money is the ‘mud of the earth’ and it is the root of all evil • Pecunia non olet……….. • A world without money would be a better world. Which is true.. • …….if you are fond of extreme poverty • …….if you dislike economic freedom • …….or both • Money is an essential precondition for economic freedom in an advanced society 3 Content: above all a lot of questions! • What is money? (wrap up) • Who creates money and why? • Is the production of money very profitable? • What kind of reform is possible, if necessary? Some questions to start with • All money is created by the central bank (Yes/No) • Some money is created by commercial banks (Yes/No) • Allmost all money is created by commercial banks (Yes/No) • The government can create money ‘for free’ (Yes/No) • Commercial banks can create money at will (Yes/No) • Commercial banks create unlimited amounts of money (Yes/No) • Commercial banks generate seigniorage income (Yes/No) • The ‘money creation privilege’ is highly profitable (Yes/No) • You can create and destroy money yourself (Yes/No) Today’s situation • Governments/central banks create money: • Coins • Banknotes • Bank reserves • Sometimes: bank deposits (in case of monetary financing) • Commercial banks create bank deposits • Today, this is the lion’s share of the money supply 6 The Dutch money supply (source: DNB, based on ECB-data, Oct. 2017) Commercials banks Central bank and governments 7 Position 1: governments should decide on the money supply • Do you agree? • Why? • Who created money in the past? • During the early coining of gold and silver, private parties decided on the amount of coins in circulation! • Question: why did governments monopolize money creation? 8 Sound money? 9 Sound money! 10 Is money creation still profitable today? Yes it is. Enter seigniorage! • Seigniorage (in Dutch: geldscheppingswinst) : the income earned by the entity that produces the money and that is the first to bring it into circulation. • Example: the production of a € 100 banknote costs € 0.01 per note. Which means that its production is very profitable (to be precise € 99,99 pro note) for the first issuer. In this example: the central bank/government • Printing banknotes (both by public and private entities) is potentially highly profitable and therefore a dangerous thing • The production of bank money is of a different order……. 11 “History is largely inflation engineered by government” “The source and root of all monetary evil …..[is] the government monopoly on the issue and control of money” Friedrich A. Hayek (Nobel prize economics, 1974, 1978) 12 Is money creation by the government a bad thing? • Not by definition. The creation of money by the government is a form of taxation and taxation is a legal form of fund raising of governments. • Especially in countries with weak institutions seigniorage may be an essential part of the funding of the government budget. Absolutely no problem with that. • The danger is that in countries with weak institutions and lack of effective parliamentary control it may be very dangerous. • Germany 1923, Zimbabwe 2008, Venezuela 2018, Turkey 2019? 13 The road to hyperinflation “A Government can live for a long time, even the German Government or the Russian Government, by printing paper money.” What is raised by printing notes is just as much taken from the public as is a beer-duty or an income-tax. What a government spend the public pay for. There is no such thing as an uncovered deficit.’ John Maynard Keynes, A Tract on Monetary reform (1924) When money dies…… Germany 1923 15 ……. Zimbabwe 2008 16 The ugly face of hyperinflation (national currency/USD, index) 1E+15 1E+14 1E+13 1E+12 1E+11 1E+10 1E+09 100000000 10000000 1000000 100000 10000 1000 100 10 1 t=1 t=2 t=3 t=4 t=5 t=6 Germany Turkey Venezuela Zimbabwe 17 German hyperinflation: the run the hyperinflation: German Reichsmark/US dollar (1914 - 1921) 160 140 120 100 80 - up 60 40 20 0 18 feb-15 feb-16 feb-17 feb-18 feb-19 feb-20 feb-21 aug-18 aug-19 aug-20 aug-21 aug-14 aug-15 aug-16 aug-17 nov-14 nov-15 nov-16 nov-17 nov-18 nov-19 nov-20 mei-21 mei-15 mei-16 mei-17 mei-18 mei-19 mei-20 When money died money When Reichsmark/US dollar (1914 - 1923, logaritmische schaal) 1E+13 1E+12 1E+11 1E+10 1E+09 100000000 10000000 1000000 100000 10000 1000 100 10 1 19 jul-19 jul-21 jul-20 jul-22 jul-23 jan-21 jan-23 jan-19 jan-20 jan-22 sep-19 sep-22 sep-20 sep-21 sep-23 mrt-21 mrt-23 mrt-19 mrt-20 mrt-22 nov-19 nov-22 nov-20 nov-21 nov-23 mei-19 mei-21 mei-20 mei-22 mei-23 Hyperinflation: when money dies Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam The highest hyperinflations Hungary (1946) > 900.000.000.000.000.000.000.000.000% Greece (1944) > 30.000.000.000% Germany (1923) > 20.000.000.000% Venezuela (2018) > 1.000.000.000% Zimbabwe (2008) > 66.000% Poland (1923) 51.699% Russia (1990) 13.535% Nicaragua (1987) 13.110% Peru (1990) 7.482% Brazil (1990) 2.948% Source: Reinhart & Rogoff, This time is different, 2010, 182 -187 Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam Is money creation profitable? How about banks? And their clients? • Banks don’t earn seigniorage: the money created by commercial banks is not owned by the bank but by their clients. And the clients are the first to bring it into circulation. • But clients don’t earn seigniorage either. This is because against the newly created bank deposits (owned by the clients) stand newly created debt (owned by the banks). • Money creation by the banks does not change net wealth or debt positions • What changes is the degree of liquidity! 22 23 “Banks coin illiquid assets into liquidity” Milton Friedman, Nobel prize economics, 1976 24 25 Money creation: governments and banks compared Money creation by: Governments Commercial banks Seigniorage income Yes No Free funding Yes Yes Automatic brakes No Yes ‘out of thin air’ Yes No Initiative of money With the government With the banks and/or creation their clients Note that seigniorage income is a form of taxation 26 In Europe monetary financing of public spending is explicitly forbidden by law. • It is part of Treaty, article 123.1 • This reflects the German trauma of 1923, when hyperinflation effectively eliminated the middle class and paved the way for fascism. • Germany would rather kill the euro than accept a government monopoly on money creation! • Keep this in the back of your mind, we will come back to this later…… 27 Monetary financing of government spending Monetary base Banks can lend increases, bank more money , reserves larger which will result in increase of M1 Increase in government Money lands in bank spending, financed by accounts of Money is spend the central bank companies and and/or saved employee, involved in public projects (M1 increases) Money comes directly in circulation and economic activity will increase Helicopter Money Monetary base Banks can lend increases, bank more money , reserves larger which will result in increase of M1 Government hands out Money lands in bank money to citizens as a accounts of the Money is spend present, financed by people that receive and/or saved the central bank this present Can money creation by commercial banks also run out of hand? • Yes, it can. Banks can extend too much credit, buy to many securities…… • But supervisors have all instruments available to regulate it! • Central banks regulate the size and costs of bank liquidity • Banking supervisors demand minimum levels of solvency and liquidity ratios • Competition authorities prevent dominant market positions 30 What seems to be the most stable situation? • Governments: no, or little seigniorage by money creation • Central banks: regulate market liquidity • Bank supervisors: close monitoring of banking ratios • Commercial banks: creating liquidity for their clients • Central banks: ex-post monitoring of monetary aggregates and, if necessary, adapting market conditions 31 Central bank Loans to banks and goverments Open market operations Government Base Money (M0) Foreign sector General public Banks (cr) Money multiplier (rr) Loans to consumers, business and governments Money in circulation (M1, M2, M3) What are the problems with this system? Banks are vulnerable for bank runs Banks have a privilege in the shape of ‘free funding’ Bank may make mistakes in their lending decisions People make take up too much debt Supervisors may be too lax and/or make mistakes The system may be procyclical 33 What are the problems with this system? Banks are vulnerable for bank runs This is a serious item, which only the central bank can solve Banks have a privilege in the shape of ‘free funding’ If this is the case, it can be easily solved by paying interest on payment accounts Bank may make mistakes in their lending decisions and/or people make take up too much debt. Yes, they usually do Supervisors may be too lax and/or make mistakes. Yes, but they’ve learned a lot The system may be procyclical. Yes, but supervisors have many way to prevent this to happen 34 Reform proposals • There are several proposals, viz. 1. The Chicago Plan (100% money) (Fisher, 1935) 1. Make payment systems a public function, executed by a public institution (basically the same proposal) 2. Digital cash 3. Denationalization of money (Hayek, 1975) • We will focus on ad 1) and give some brief thoughts on ad 2).
Recommended publications
  • Short-Term Currency in Circulation Forecasting for Monetary Policy Purposes: the Case of Poland
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Koziński, Witold; Świst, Tomasz Article Short-term currency in circulation forecasting for monetary policy purposes: The case of Poland e-Finanse: Financial Internet Quarterly Provided in Cooperation with: University of Information Technology and Management, Rzeszów Suggested Citation: Koziński, Witold; Świst, Tomasz (2015) : Short-term currency in circulation forecasting for monetary policy purposes: The case of Poland, e-Finanse: Financial Internet Quarterly, ISSN 1734-039X, University of Information Technology and Management, Rzeszów, Vol. 11, Iss. 1, pp. 65-75, http://dx.doi.org/10.14636/1734-039X_11_1_007 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/147121 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Money Creation in the Modern Economy
    14 Quarterly Bulletin 2014 Q1 Money creation in the modern economy By Michael McLeay, Amar Radia and Ryland Thomas of the Bank’s Monetary Analysis Directorate.(1) This article explains how the majority of money in the modern economy is created by commercial banks making loans. Money creation in practice differs from some popular misconceptions — banks do not act simply as intermediaries, lending out deposits that savers place with them, and nor do they ‘multiply up’ central bank money to create new loans and deposits. The amount of money created in the economy ultimately depends on the monetary policy of the central bank. In normal times, this is carried out by setting interest rates. The central bank can also affect the amount of money directly through purchasing assets or ‘quantitative easing’. Overview In the modern economy, most money takes the form of bank low and stable inflation. In normal times, the Bank of deposits. But how those bank deposits are created is often England implements monetary policy by setting the interest misunderstood: the principal way is through commercial rate on central bank reserves. This then influences a range of banks making loans. Whenever a bank makes a loan, it interest rates in the economy, including those on bank loans. simultaneously creates a matching deposit in the borrower’s bank account, thereby creating new money. In exceptional circumstances, when interest rates are at their effective lower bound, money creation and spending in the The reality of how money is created today differs from the economy may still be too low to be consistent with the description found in some economics textbooks: central bank’s monetary policy objectives.
    [Show full text]
  • Money Creation and the Shadow Banking System∗
    Money Creation and the Shadow Banking System Adi Sunderam Harvard Business School [email protected] June 2012 Abstract Many explanations for the rapid growth of the shadow banking system in the mid- 2000s focus on money demand. This paper asks whether the short-term liabilities of the shadow banking system behave like money. We first present a simple model where households demand money services, which are supplied by three types of claims: de- posits, Treasury bills, and asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP). The model provides predictions for the price and quantity dynamics of these claims, as well as the behavior of the banking system (in terms of issuance) and the monetary authority (in terms of open market operations). Consistent with the model, the empirical evidence suggests that the shadow banking system does respond to money demand. An extrapolation of our estimates would suggest that heightened money demand could explain up to approximately 1/2 of the growth of ABCP in the mid-2000s. I thank Sergey Chernenko, Darrell Duffi e, Robin Greenwood, Sam Hanson, Morgan Ricks, David Scharf- stein, Andrei Shleifer, Jeremy Stein, and participants at the Federal Reserve Board Shadow Banking work- shop for helpful comments and suggestions. 1 Introduction Many explanations for the rapid growth of the shadow banking system in the years before the financial crisis focus on money demand.1 These explanations argue that the shadow banking system grew in order to meet rising demand for “money like”claims —safe, liquid, short-term investments — from institutional investors and nonfinancial firms. In doing so, they build on the long literature, starting with Diamond and Dybvig (1983) and Gorton and Pennacchi (1990), arguing that providing liquidity services through demandable deposits is a key function of banks.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory
    2021 A Primer on Modern Monetary Theory Steven Globerman fraserinstitute.org Contents Executive Summary / i 1. Introducing Modern Monetary Theory / 1 2. Implementing MMT / 4 3. Has Canada Adopted MMT? / 10 4. Proposed Economic and Social Justifications for MMT / 17 5. MMT and Inflation / 23 Concluding Comments / 27 References / 29 About the author / 33 Acknowledgments / 33 Publishing information / 34 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 35 Purpose, funding, and independence / 35 About the Fraser Institute / 36 Editorial Advisory Board / 37 fraserinstitute.org fraserinstitute.org Executive Summary Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is a policy model for funding govern- ment spending. While MMT is not new, it has recently received wide- spread attention, particularly as government spending has increased dramatically in response to the ongoing COVID-19 crisis and concerns grow about how to pay for this increased spending. The essential message of MMT is that there is no financial constraint on government spending as long as a country is a sovereign issuer of cur- rency and does not tie the value of its currency to another currency. Both Canada and the US are examples of countries that are sovereign issuers of currency. In principle, being a sovereign issuer of currency endows the government with the ability to borrow money from the country’s cen- tral bank. The central bank can effectively credit the government’s bank account at the central bank for an unlimited amount of money without either charging the government interest or, indeed, demanding repayment of the government bonds the central bank has acquired. In 2020, the cen- tral banks in both Canada and the US bought a disproportionately large share of government bonds compared to previous years, which has led some observers to argue that the governments of Canada and the United States are practicing MMT.
    [Show full text]
  • 86-2 17-37.Pdf
    Opinions expressedil'lthe/ nomic Review do not necessarily reflect the vie management of the Federal Reserve BankofSan Francisco, or of the Board of Governors the Feder~1 Reserve System. The FedetaIReserve Bank ofSari Fraricisco's Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank's Research and Public Information Department under the supervision of John L. Scadding, SeniorVice Presidentand Director of Research. The publication is edited by Gregory 1. Tong, with the assistance of Karen Rusk (editorial) and William Rosenthal (graphics). For free <copies ofthis and otherFederal Reserve. publications, write or phone the Public InfofIllation Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 974-3234. 2 Ramon Moreno· The traditional critique of the "real bills" doctrine argues that the price level may be unstable in a monetary regime without a central bank and a market-determined money supply. Hong Kong's experience sug­ gests this problem may not arise in a small open economy. In our century, it is generally assumed that mone­ proposed that the money supply and inflation could tary control exerted by central banks is necessary to successfully be controlled by the market, without prevent excessive money creation and to achieve central bank control ofthe monetary base, as long as price stability. More recently, in the 1970s, this banks limited their credit to "satisfy the needs of assumption is evident in policymakers' concern that trade". financial innovations have eroded monetary con­ The real bills doctrine was severely criticized on trols. In particular, the proliferation of market­ the beliefthat it could lead to instability in the price created substitutes for money not directly under the level.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America
    Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America Sebastian Edwards* Economics Working Paper 19106 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 April 25, 2019 According to Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e. the Federal Reserve) – to finance large fiscal deficits that will ensure full employment and good jobs for everyone, through a “jobs guarantee” program. In this paper I analyze some of Latin America’s historical episodes with MMT-type policies (Chile, Peru. Argentina, and Venezuela). The analysis uses the framework developed by Dornbusch and Edwards (1990, 1991) for studying macroeconomic populism. The four experiments studied in this paper ended up badly, with runaway inflation, huge currency devaluations, and precipitous real wage declines. These experiences offer a cautionary tale for MMT enthusiasts.† JEL Nos: E12, E42, E61, F31 Keywords: Modern Monetary Theory, central bank, inflation, Latin America, hyperinflation The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. * Henry Ford II Distinguished Professor, Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA † I have benefited from discussions with Ed Leamer, José De Gregorio, Scott Sumner, and Alejandra Cox. I thank Doug Irwin and John Taylor for their support. 1 1. Introduction During the last few years an apparently new and revolutionary idea has emerged in economic policy circles in the United States: Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). The central tenet of this view is that it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • The Use of Central Bank Money for Settling Securities Transactions May 2004
    THE USE OF CENTRAL BANK MONEY FOR SETTLING SECURITIES TRANSACTIONS MAY 2004 CURRENT MODELS AND PRACTICES THE USE OF CENTRAL BANK MONEY FOR SETTLING SECURITIES TRANSACTIONS MAY 2004 CURRENT MODELS AND PRACTICES In 2004 all ECB publications will feature a motif taken from the €100 banknote. © European Central Bank, 2004 Address Kaiserstrasse 29 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Postal address Postfach 16 03 19 60066 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Telephone +49 69 1344 0 Website http://www.ecb.int Fax +49 69 1344 6000 Telex 411 144 ecb d This Bulletin was produced under the responsibility of the Executive Board of the ECB. All rights reserved. Reproduction for educational and non-commercial purposes is permitted provided that the source is acknowledged. ISBN 92-9181-507-1 (print) ISBN 92-9181-508-X (online) CONTENTS 1 INTRODUCTION: AN OVERVIEW OF CURRENT MODELS 3 2 WHERE? – LOCATION OF ACCOUNTS USED FOR CASH LEG SETTLEMENT 4 3 WHO? – GENERATING PAYMENT INSTRUCTIONS AND OPERATION ACCOUNTS ENTRIES 7 4 HOW? – FREQUENCY AND TYPE OF DVP INTERACTION: GROSS VERSUS NET DVP SETTLEMENT 8 5 WHEN? – TIMING OF INTERACTION: MODELS VARIANTS FOR PRE-OPENING/ NIGHT-TIME PROCESSING OF NEXT VALUE DATE 9 6 THE COMPOSITION OF THE BALANCE AVAILABLE FOR CASH SETTLEMENT 14 ANNEX 1: REPLIES PROVIDED BY THE NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKS OF THE ESCB 16 c ECB The use of Central bank money for settling securities transactions May 2004 3 1 INTRODUCTION: AN OVERVIEW OF CURRENT MODELS A securities trade typically results in an The models presented here summarise the main obligation for the seller to deliver securities characteristics of the various national solutions, (securities leg) and a corresponding obligation and do not claim to reproduce in detail all the for the buyer to deliver cash funds (cash leg).
    [Show full text]
  • How Money Is Created by the Central Bank and the Banking System Zürcher Volkswirtschaftliche Gesellschaft
    Speech Embargo 16 January 2018, 6.00 pm How money is created by the central bank and the banking system Zürcher Volkswirtschaftliche Gesellschaft Thomas J. Jordan Chairman of the Governing Board∗ Swiss National Bank Zurich, 16 January 2018 © Swiss National Bank, Zurich, 2018 (speech given in German) ∗ The speaker would like to thank Samuel Reynard and Mathias Zurlinden for their support in the preparation of this speech. He also thanks Simone Auer, Petra Gerlach, Carlos Lenz and Alexander Perruchoud, as well as SNB Language Services. Page 1/12 Ladies and Gentlemen It is a great pleasure for me to be your guest here tonight. The subject of my speech is the creation of money in our economy. Since money creation in our financial system is closely linked to the granting of loans by banks, I am also going to talk about lending. I shall, moreover, address the issues of sovereign money and access to digital central bank money, insofar as they relate to our main topic. We are all aware of how profoundly the economic and monetary developments of the last ten years have been shaped by the global financial and economic crisis. Central banks responded swiftly and resolutely to the crisis, reducing interest rates and pumping large amounts of liquidity into the banking system. Once interest rates were down to almost zero, central banks were forced to adopt unconventional measures. Against the backdrop of a dramatic appreciation of the Swiss franc, the Swiss National Bank resorted mainly to interventions in the foreign exchange market, supplemented for a while by a minimum exchange rate for the Swiss franc against the euro.
    [Show full text]
  • Seigniorage Is Profit from Money Creation, a Way for Governments To
    Copyrighted Material seigniorage money system, seigniorage revenue is given by the product of the inflation rate and the inflation tax base. This inflation tax base reflects the purchasing power of the public’s money holdings and is the level of real money balances (nominal money holdings divided by the price level). Undertaking more rapid monetary expansion causes the inflation rate to rise, but the revenue effects are partially offset as indi- viduals attempt to quickly spend the extra money before it depreciates further. If people spend money faster thanitis beingprinted, therateof price increase comes to exceed the rate of money issuance. Hyperinflation Agovernmentthatisunableto fund its expenditures through conventional taxes or bond sales may become dependent on seigniorage revenues to maintain its existence. Attempts to raise seigniorage revenues are, however, not only infla- tionary but eventually self-defeating. Under cir- cumstances where the decline in real money balances seigniorage becomes proportionately larger than the rise in the Seigniorage is profit from money creation, a way for inflation rate, the inflationary policy actually back- governments to generate revenue without levying fires and lowers seigniorage revenue. The economist conventional taxes. In the days of commodity Phillip Cagan’s classic analysis of hyperinflations, money, seigniorage revenue was the difference be- with inflation rates exceeding 50 percent per month, tween the face value of the minted coins and the suggested instances where the process had, in fact, actual market value of the precious metal they con- been pushed beyond the revenue-maximizing point. tained. When this markup was insufficient for the It is possible that lags in the adjustment of inflation government’s revenue needs, the authorities might expectations may actually have allowed continued substitute less valuable base metal for some of the seigniorage gains, however, and subsequent analysis precious metal that was supposed to be in the coins.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Money Theory 101: a Reply to Critics
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Tymoigne, Éric; Wray, L. Randall Working Paper Modern Money Theory 101: A reply to critics Working Paper, No. 778 Provided in Cooperation with: Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Suggested Citation: Tymoigne, Éric; Wray, L. Randall (2013) : Modern Money Theory 101: A reply to critics, Working Paper, No. 778, Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Annandale- on-Hudson, NY This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/110016 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Working Paper No. 778 Modern Money Theory 101: A Reply to Critics by Éric Tymoigne and L. Randall Wray Levy Economics Institute of Bard College November 2013 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants.
    [Show full text]
  • Nominality of Money: Theory of Credit Money and Chartalism Atsushi Naito
    Review of Keynesian Studies Vol.2 Atsushi Naito Nominality of Money: Theory of Credit Money and Chartalism Atsushi Naito Abstract This paper focuses on the unit of account function of money that is emphasized by Keynes in his book A Treatise on Money (1930) and recently in post-Keynesian endogenous money theory and modern Chartalism, or in other words Modern Monetary Theory. These theories consider the nominality of money as an important characteristic because the unit of account and the corresponding money as a substance could be anything, and this aspect highlights the nominal nature of money; however, although these theories are closely associated, they are different. The three objectives of this paper are to investigate the nominality of money common to both the theories, examine the relationship and differences between the two theories with a focus on Chartalism, and elucidate the significance and policy implications of Chartalism. Keywords: Chartalism; Credit Money; Nominality of Money; Keynes JEL Classification Number: B22; B52; E42; E52; E62 122 Review of Keynesian Studies Vol.2 Atsushi Naito I. Introduction Recent years have seen the development of Modern Monetary Theory or Chartalism and it now holds a certain prestige in the field. This theory primarily deals with state money or fiat money; however, in Post Keynesian economics, the endogenous money theory and theory of monetary circuit place the stress on bank money or credit money. Although Chartalism and the theory of credit money are clearly opposed to each other, there exists another axis of conflict in the field of monetary theory. According to the textbooks, this axis concerns the functions of money, such as means of exchange, means of account, and store of value.
    [Show full text]