Robert M. Solow

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Robert M. Solow PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 22 ROBERT M. SOLOW ROBERT M. SOLOW doc. Ing. Vladimír Gonda, PhD. Faculty of National Economy, University of Economics in Bratislava Robert M. Solow is one of the major pro- butions to the theory and measurement of ponents of the neoclassical synthesis (the economic growth. synthesis of standard neoclassical micro- His pioneering work in the field of growth economics and Keynesian macroecono- theory had a profound effect on the further mics). In the vanguard of this theoretical development of economics and instigated orientation is a quintet of distinguished a discussion on the factors ensuring eco- economists: P. A. Samuelson, J. Hicks, J. nomic growth and, more importantly, a Tobin, F. Modigliani and Solow himself. It is completely new explanation of how tech- worth noting that each of them is a Nobel nological progress contributes to the laureate. Solow was awarded the Nobel growth of national income and social Prize for Economics in 1987 for his contri- wealth. Robert Merton Solow was born in Brooklyn, New York was offered publication in book form and $500 (in 1951 on 23 August 1924. His parents were the children of prices) once the thesis was ready to be printed. Nevert- immigrants. Educated in the neighbourhood public scho- heless, the thesis was not published and the cheque was ols of New York City, he was, as he himself has said, not cashed. Solow explained that after rereading the text, taught by a devoted teacher to read the great 19th cen- he realised he could do better. In the end, however, he tury French and Russian novelists and to take ideas seri- never returned to this work. ously. In 1940 he won a scholarship to Harvard Universi- In 1950 Solow was offered and accepted an Assistant ty where his first studies were in sociology, anthropology Professorship in the Economics Department at the Mas- and elementary economics. At the end of 1942 he left sachusetts Institute of Technology. After initially teaching university and joined the U.S. Army. He served briefly in courses in statistics and econometrics, he focused his North Africa and Sicily and then for the duration of the research on macroeconomics for what he himself has war in Italy, until his discharge in 1945. called a geographical reason – he was given an office Upon returning to Harvard in 1945 he decided to con- next to Paul Samuelson, who had already written a well- tinue with economics. This came about thanks to a mee- known textbook on economics. Daily contact with Samu- ting with Wassily Leontief, who became his teacher, elson and conversations on economics, politics and ordi- guide and friend and who taught him the spirit and sub- nary life, eventually drew Solow back to "straight" stance of modern economic theory. As his research assi- economics and he discovered in himself an instinctive stant, Solow produced a set of capital-coefficients for the macroeconomist. input-output model. Apart from his research and teaching, Solow has been Having become interested in statistics and probabilis- involved in practical activities in the government sector. tic models, Solow spent a year studying them at Colum- In 1960 – 1961 he served on President John F. Kenne- bia University in 1949-1950. He was at the same time dy's Council of Economic Advisors, and later he was part working on his Ph.D. thesis, which addressed the model- of a government commission examining the problems of ling of changes in the size distribution of wage income welfare recipients. For five years in the late 1970s Solow using interacting Markoff processes for employment- was a director of the Federal Reserve Bank in Boston. unemployment and wage rates. The thesis was awarded He has also been engaged in a range of topical contro- the Wells Prize at Harvard, along with which the author versies and discussions. Theory of economic growth Denison. They were nicknamed "economic archaeo- logists" since they were attempting to "dig up" the At the end of the 1950s a majority of economies source of economic growth. were experiencing fast economic growth generated Solow's main contribution is an elaboration of by demand deferred from the war period and by the neoclassical growth theory. His first pioneering work need to restore the war-torn economies. The econo- was the article "A Contribution to the Theory of Eco- mic sciences also responded to this situation. In the nomic Growth" (1956), in which he developed a neoc- United States the question of economic growth was lassical-type mathematical model of long-run growth being addressed mainly by Solow, J. Kendrick and E. based on criticisms of the Keynesian Harrod-Domar BIATEC, Volume XIII, 11/2005 PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS ROBERT M. SOLOW 23 model (regarding the fact it was a single factor model the traditional production factors of labour and capital. where the sole growth factor was capital accumula- He asserted that, in the mid-20th century, 87.5% of tion). Solow abandoned the standard Keynesian labour productivity was the result of "technological assumption of a fixed ratio between production fac- changes" and only 12.5% could be attributed to con- tors and introduced a ratio variable. The basis of ventional growth in the number of workers and capital growth in his model was, on the one hand, the sub- equipment. He construed technological progress in stitution of labour by capital and, on the other hand, quite broad terms – including, for example, the increa- technological progress, which he considered to be a sing educational qualifications of workers and the key determinant of growth in the long run. more effective organisation and management of pro- Solow drew on the Cobb-Douglas production func- duction – and, understandably, in the narrow sense tion, which expressed the functional dependence of too. Solow's conclusion represented an immediate national product growth on labour growth and on revolution in both economic science and economic capital growth. Developed by the mathematician policy.The importance of investments took a lower pro- Charles W. Cobb and the economist Paul Douglas at file, as economists and politicians gave priority to tech- the end of the 1920s for the U.S. economy, this pro- nical progress and how to go about accelerating it. duction function is represented as follows: Solow in his initial reasoning worked with disembo- died technological progress, which is not tied to the Y= A. La . Kb replacement of old equipment with new. Such tech- a + b = 1 nological progress has the character of an exoge- where: nous quantity, not related to the introduction of pro- A – a constant determined by the effect of other fac- duction factors into the production process. On this tors not directly expressed in the function, basis, the view spread that the main agent of growth L – labour input, is investment in people and science, rather than K – capital input, investment in capital, which led to a certain underes- a – an elasticity coefficient for labour's share of out- timation of capital accumulation. put; it indicates the percentage change in the pro- Solow later developed the hypothesis of embodied duct when, ceteris paribus, the volume of labour technological progress, in other words technical pro- changes by 1%, gress which is embodied in capital goods (in machi- b– an elasticity coefficient for capital's share of out- nes of various ages). In a work entitled "Investment put; it indicates the percentage change in the pro- and Technical Progress" (1960), he disaggregated duct when, ceteris paribus, the volume of capital capital according to its age structure and therefore changes by 1%. also according to its technical level. Embodied tech- Solow's contribution was to extend the Cobb-Doug- nological progress reckons on the fact that older pro- las production function with a third factor of growth – duction equipment is gradually replaced with new technological progress, which he understood as ope- and improved equipment. Each new generation of rating autonomously in time. For him, technological investments is more productive than the last. In this progress is an exponential function of time. As a case, technological progress is factored into the result he came to a modified version of the Cobb- growth indicator of capital itself. In such an under- Douglas production function: standing of technological progress, capital as a share of economic growth is substantially higher at the Y= A. La . Kb . ert , expense of disembodied technological progress. where ert represents the effect of technological The "Solow residual" – the rate of technological progress (r) in time (t) on economic growth. change that explains the difference between real inco- In contrast to the Harrod-Domar model, the Solow me growth and growth explicable by growth in labour growth model took into account labour-capital sub- and capital – is considered by many to be a key ele- stitution, in other words the change in production ment of the new economics since it reflects the overall technique as a response to changes in relative prices efficiency with which labour and capital are used. of labour and capital. There may be various origins of the efficiency growth Solow attempted to quantify the effect of individual – innovations, technological changes, management factors on the pace of growth. In an article entitled methods, organisational changes, more efficient met- "Technical Change and the Aggregate Production hods of organising production and services, and so on. Function" (1957), he carried out an empirical analysis Theoretical literature was dominated up to the mid- of the long-term growth of the U.S. economy. The key 1970s by the neoclassical theory of long-run econo- to economic growth in the period 1909-1949 was, mic growth that Solow and his followers had develo- according to him, technological progress rather than ped.
Recommended publications
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • Download The
    SPECIAL ANALYSIS NATIONAL HIGH SCHOOL DEBATE TOPIC 1964-65 WHAT POLICY FOR CONTROL Of \WEAPONS SYSTEMS WOULD BEST INSURE THE PROSPECTS FOR WORLD PEACE? PUBLISHED AND DISTRIBUTED BY THE AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE g_g;-J��,�� 1012 FOURTEENTH STREET, N.W., WASHINGTON, D. C., 20005 EXECUTIVE 3·8205 THE AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE FOR PUBLIC POLICY RESEARCH, established in 1943, is o nonpartisan research and educational organization which studies notional policy problems. Institute publications toke two major forms: 1. LEGISLATIVE AND SPECIAL ANALYSES - factual analyses of current legislative proposals and other public policy issues before the Congress prepared with the help of recognized experts in the academic world and in the fields of low and government. A typical analysis features: (1) pertinent background, (2) o digest of significant elements, and (3) o discussion, pro and con, of the issues. The reports reflect no policy position in favor of or against specific proposals. 2. LONG-RANGE STUDIES - basic studies of major notional problems of significance for public policy. The Institute, with the counsel of its Advisory Boord, utilizes the services of competent scholars, but the opinions expressed ore those of the authors and represent no policy position on the port of the Institute. ADVISORY BOARD Poul W. McCracken, Chairman Professor, School of Business Administration, University of Mi chi gon Kori Brandt Stanley Parry Director Professor, Deportment Food Research Institute of Politicol Science Stanford University University of Notre Dome Milton Friedman Roscoe Pound Poul S. Russell Distinguished Professor Emeritus Service Professor of Economics Harvard University University of Chicago E. Blythe Stoson Gottfried Hoberler Deon Emeritus, Low School Golen L.
    [Show full text]
  • Strength in Numbers: the Rising of Academic Statistics Departments In
    Agresti · Meng Agresti Eds. Alan Agresti · Xiao-Li Meng Editors Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics DepartmentsStatistics in the U.S. Rising of Academic The in Numbers: Strength Statistics Departments in the U.S. Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics Departments in the U.S. Alan Agresti • Xiao-Li Meng Editors Strength in Numbers: The Rising of Academic Statistics Departments in the U.S. 123 Editors Alan Agresti Xiao-Li Meng Department of Statistics Department of Statistics University of Florida Harvard University Gainesville, FL Cambridge, MA USA USA ISBN 978-1-4614-3648-5 ISBN 978-1-4614-3649-2 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-1-4614-3649-2 Springer New York Heidelberg Dordrecht London Library of Congress Control Number: 2012942702 Ó Springer Science+Business Media New York 2013 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. Exempted from this legal reservation are brief excerpts in connection with reviews or scholarly analysis or material supplied specifically for the purpose of being entered and executed on a computer system, for exclusive use by the purchaser of the work. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the Copyright Law of the Publisher’s location, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer.
    [Show full text]
  • Kenneth J. Arrow [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B
    Kenneth J. Arrow [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Daniel B. Klein Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 268-281 Abstract Kenneth J. Arrow is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/715/ArrowIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH Kenneth J. Arrow by Daniel B. Klein Ross Starr begins his article on Kenneth Arrow (1921–) in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics by saying that he “is a legendary figure, with an enormous range of contributions to 20th-century economics…. His impact is suggested by the number of major ideas that bear his name: Arrow’s Theorem, the Arrow- Debreu model, the Arrow-Pratt index of risk aversion, and Arrow securities” (Starr 2008). Besides the four areas alluded to in the quotation from Starr, Arrow has been a leader in the economics of information. In 1972, at the age of 51 (still the youngest ever), Arrow shared the Nobel Prize in economics with John Hicks for their contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory. But if the Nobel economics prize were given for specific accomplishments, and an individual could win repeatedly, Arrow would surely have several. It has been shown that Arrow is the economics laureate who has been most cited within the Nobel award lectures of the economics laureates (Skarbek 2009).
    [Show full text]
  • Date: To: September 22, 1 997 Mr Ian Johnston©
    22-SEP-1997 16:36 NOBELSTIFTELSEN 4& 8 6603847 SID 01 NOBELSTIFTELSEN The Nobel Foundation TELEFAX Date: September 22, 1 997 To: Mr Ian Johnston© Company: Executive Office of the Secretary-General Fax no: 0091-2129633511 From: The Nobel Foundation Total number of pages: olO MESSAGE DearMrJohnstone, With reference to your fax and to our telephone conversation, I am enclosing the address list of all Nobel Prize laureates. Yours sincerely, Ingr BergstrSm Mailing address: Bos StU S-102 45 Stockholm. Sweden Strat itddrtSMi Suircfatan 14 Teleptelrtts: (-MB S) 663 » 20 Fsuc (*-«>!) «W Jg 47 22-SEP-1997 16:36 NOBELSTIFTELSEN 46 B S603847 SID 02 22-SEP-1997 16:35 NOBELSTIFTELSEN 46 8 6603847 SID 03 Professor Willis E, Lamb Jr Prof. Aleksandre M. Prokhorov Dr. Leo EsaJki 848 North Norris Avenue Russian Academy of Sciences University of Tsukuba TUCSON, AZ 857 19 Leninskii Prospect 14 Tsukuba USA MSOCOWV71 Ibaraki Ru s s I a 305 Japan 59* c>io Dr. Tsung Dao Lee Professor Hans A. Bethe Professor Antony Hewlsh Department of Physics Cornell University Cavendish Laboratory Columbia University ITHACA, NY 14853 University of Cambridge 538 West I20th Street USA CAMBRIDGE CB3 OHE NEW YORK, NY 10027 England USA S96 014 S ' Dr. Chen Ning Yang Professor Murray Gell-Mann ^ Professor Aage Bohr The Institute for Department of Physics Niels Bohr Institutet Theoretical Physics California Institute of Technology Blegdamsvej 17 State University of New York PASADENA, CA91125 DK-2100 KOPENHAMN 0 STONY BROOK, NY 11794 USA D anni ark USA 595 600 613 Professor Owen Chamberlain Professor Louis Neel ' Professor Ben Mottelson 6068 Margarldo Drive Membre de rinstitute Nordita OAKLAND, CA 946 IS 15 Rue Marcel-Allegot Blegdamsvej 17 USA F-92190 MEUDON-BELLEVUE DK-2100 KOPENHAMN 0 Frankrike D an m ar k 599 615 Professor Donald A.
    [Show full text]
  • The Death of Welfare Economics: History of a Controversy
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Igersheim, Herrade Working Paper The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-03 Provided in Cooperation with: Center for the History of Political Economy at Duke University Suggested Citation: Igersheim, Herrade (2017) : The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy, CHOPE Working Paper, No. 2017-03, Duke University, Center for the History of Political Economy (CHOPE), Durham, NC This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/155466 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu The death of welfare economics: History of a controversy by Herrade Igersheim CHOPE Working Paper No. 2017-03 January 2017 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2901574 The death of welfare economics: history of a controversy Herrade Igersheim December 15, 2016 Abstract.
    [Show full text]
  • GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58Th Street, Chicago, Ill
    THE PROCESS AND PROGRESS OF ECONOMICS Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December, 1982 by GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, Ill. 60637, USA In the work on the economics of information which I began twenty some years ago, I started with an example: how does one find the seller of automobiles who is offering a given model at the lowest price? Does it pay to search more, the more frequently one purchases an automobile, and does it ever pay to search out a large number of potential sellers? The study of the search for trading partners and prices and qualities has now been deepened and widened by the work of scores of skilled economic theorists. I propose on this occasion to address the same kinds of questions to an entirely different market: the market for new ideas in economic science. Most economists enter this market in new ideas, let me emphasize, in order to obtain ideas and methods for the applications they are making of economics to the thousand problems with which they are occupied: these economists are not the suppliers of new ideas but only demanders. Their problem is comparable to that of the automobile buyer: to find a reliable vehicle. Indeed, they usually end up by buying a used, and therefore tested, idea. Those economists who seek to engage in research on the new ideas of the science - to refute or confirm or develop or displace them - are in a sense both buyers and sellers of new ideas. They seek to develop new ideas and persuade the science to accept them, but they also are following clues and promises and explorations in the current or preceding ideas of the science.
    [Show full text]
  • Dodging a Draft: Gary Becker's Lost Paper on Conscription
    DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 14284 Dodging a Draft: Gary Becker’s Lost Paper on Conscription Michael Gibbs Timothy Perri APRIL 2021 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES IZA DP No. 14284 Dodging a Draft: Gary Becker’s Lost Paper on Conscription Michael Gibbs University of Chicago Booth School of Business and IZA Timothy Perri Appalachian State University APRIL 2021 Any opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but IZA takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The IZA Institute of Labor Economics is an independent economic research institute that conducts research in labor economics and offers evidence-based policy advice on labor market issues. Supported by the Deutsche Post Foundation, IZA runs the world’s largest network of economists, whose research aims to provide answers to the global labor market challenges of our time. Our key objective is to build bridges between academic research, policymakers and society. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. ISSN: 2365-9793 IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Schaumburg-Lippe-Straße 5–9 Phone: +49-228-3894-0 53113 Bonn, Germany Email: [email protected] www.iza.org IZA DP No. 14284 APRIL 2021 ABSTRACT Dodging a Draft: Gary Becker’s Lost Paper on Conscription* Gary Becker wrote what may be the first economic analysis of conscription.
    [Show full text]
  • ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography
    Τεύχος 53, Οκτώβριος-Δεκέμβριος 2019 | Issue 53, October-December 2019 ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη Nobel Prize in Economics Τα τεύχη δημοσιεύονται στον ιστοχώρο της All issues are published online at the Bank’s website Τράπεζας: address: https://www.bankofgreece.gr/trapeza/kepoe https://www.bankofgreece.gr/en/the- t/h-vivliothhkh-ths-tte/e-ekdoseis-kai- bank/culture/library/e-publications-and- anakoinwseis announcements Τράπεζα της Ελλάδος. Κέντρο Πολιτισμού, Bank of Greece. Centre for Culture, Research and Έρευνας και Τεκμηρίωσης, Τμήμα Documentation, Library Section Βιβλιοθήκης Ελ. Βενιζέλου 21, 102 50 Αθήνα, 21 El. Venizelos Ave., 102 50 Athens, [email protected] Τηλ. 210-3202446, [email protected], Tel. +30-210-3202446, 3202396, 3203129 3202396, 3203129 Βιβλιογραφία, τεύχος 53, Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019, Bibliography, issue 53, Oct.-Dec. 2019, Nobel Prize Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη in Economics Συντελεστές: Α. Ναδάλη, Ε. Σεμερτζάκη, Γ. Contributors: A. Nadali, E. Semertzaki, G. Tsouri Τσούρη Βιβλιογραφία, αρ.53 (Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019), Βραβείο Nobel στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη 1 Bibliography, no. 53, (Oct.-Dec. 2019), Nobel Prize in Economics Πίνακας περιεχομένων Εισαγωγή / Introduction 6 2019: Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo and Michael Kremer 7 Μονογραφίες / Monographs ................................................................................................... 7 Δοκίμια Εργασίας / Working papers ......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Uncertainty and the Welfare Economics of Medical Care
    TH1E AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW VOLUME LIII DECEMBER 1963 NUMBER 5 UNCERTAINTY AND THE WELFARE ECONOMICS OF MEDICAL CARE By KENNETH J. ARROW* I. Introduction:Scope and Method This paper is an exploratoryand tentativestudy of the specific differentiaof medical care as the object of normativeeconomics. It is contendedhere, on the basis of comparisonof obviouscharacteris- tics of the medical-careindustry with the normsof welfareeconomics, that the special economicproblems of medicalcare can be explained as adaptationsto the existenceof uncertaintyin the incidenceof dis- ease and in theefficacy of treatment. It shouldbe notedthat the subjectis the medical-careindustry, not health.The causal factorsin health are many,and the provisionof medical care is only one. Particularlyat low levels of income,other commoditiessuch as nutrition,shelter, clothing, and sanitationmay be much more significant.It is the complexof servicesthat center about the physician,private and grouppractice, hospitals, and public health,which I proposeto discuss. The focus of discussionwill be on the way the operationof the medical-careindustry and the efficacywith which it satisfiesthe needs of societydiffer from a norm,if at all. The "norm"that the econo- mistusually uses forthe purposes of such comparisonsis theoperation of a competitivemodel, that is, the flowsof servicesthat would be * The author is professorof economicsat StanfordUniversity. He wishes to expresshis thanks for useful commentsto F. Bator, R. Dorfman,V. Fuchs, Dr. S. Gilson, R. Kessel, S. Mushkin,and C.
    [Show full text]
  • Chronicling 100 Years of the U.S. Economy Wassily Leontief
    Chronicling 100 Years of theChronicling 100 Years of the U.S. EconomyU.S. Economy December 2020 Volume 100, Number 12 Top Influencers The Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) and its journal, the Survey of Current Business, are respected sources of data on the health of our national economy due in large part to the individuals who influenced BEA and its predecessor agencies over the past century. From economic theory to the mechanics of producing reliable statistics, their contributions helped make BEA and its accounts the reliable, authoritative sources of economic data they are today. The Survey has chronicled the evolution of BEA's output for almost a century. As we celebrate the centennial of the Survey, some of these top influencers will be profiled on the centennial website. This month, we present Nobel laureate and economist Wassily Leontief. Wassily Leontief Nobel Award-Winning Input-Output Economist The contributions of Wassily Leontief (1906–1999) to economic theory were gamechangers in many different ways. His seminal work on input- output analysis became integral to understanding both the U.S. and global economies. Leontief's research on international trade flows led him to be credited with the “Leontief paradox,” which questions the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem on the flows of capital-intensive and labor-intensive goods. This paradox finds that a country with higher capital per worker has a lower capital/labor ratio in exports than in imports, contrary to the Heckscher- Olin theorem, which states that U.S. exports would require more capital Wassily Leontief than imports. Leontief is also credited, along with John Hicks, with the composite commodity theorem on the composite price measurement of a basket of goods, which states that if the prices of a group of goods change in the same proportion, the group of goods behaves as if it were a single commodity.
    [Show full text]
  • 2017 Leontief Announcement
    Global Development And Environment Institute Tufts Institute to Award Economics Prize to James Boyce and Joan Martinez-Alier Awardees to present Leontief Prize Lectures on Economics, Equity, and the Environment March 28, 2017 October 6, 2016: Tufts University’s Global Development And Environment Institute (GDAE) announced today that it will award its 2017 Leontief Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought to James Boyce and Joan Martinez-Alier. GDAE awards the Leontief Prize each year to leading theorists who have developed innovative work in economics that addresses contemporary realities and supports just and sustainable societies. The award recognizes Boyce and Martinez-Alier for their ground-breaking theoretical and applied work in which they have effectively integrated ecological, developmental, and justice- oriented approaches into the field of economics. “It is essential to address the ecological crisis generated by the old-paradigm economy,” said GDAE Co-Director Neva Goodwin. “James Boyce and Joan Martinez-Alier have highlighted the relationship between economic systems, resources (materials and energy) and social issues. Their particular focus on the intersections among economics, poverty, and inequality has strongly informed GDAE’s thinking on these issues.” The ceremony and lectures by the awardees on the theme “Economics, Equity, and the Environment” will take place on March 28, 2017 on Tufts University’s Medford campus. GDAE inaugurated the Leontief Prize in 2000 in memory of Nobel Prize-winning economist and GDAE advisory board member Wassily Leontief. The Leontief Prize recognizes economists whose work, like that of GDAE and Leontief himself, combines theoretical and empirical research to promote a more comprehensive understanding of social and environmental processes.
    [Show full text]