2020 Outlook for Sovereign Debt Restructurings

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

2020 Outlook for Sovereign Debt Restructurings EMERGING MARKETS DEBT Investment Management active.williamblair.com 2020 Outlook for Sovereign Debt Restructurings Historically, a combination of high yield and minimal default risk July 2020 has led emerging markets debt (EMD) investors to enjoy strong returns— Head of Emerging Markets Debt but the impact of COVID-19 has called into question the potential Marcelo Assalin, CFA for such favorable returns in the future. Historically speaking, however, markets have overestimated the probability of default and underestimated Portfolio Managers Jared Lou, CFA eventual recovery rates. Daniel Wood Introduction Historically, sovereign defaults in EMD have been rare events, and the combination of high yield and minimal default risk has led EMD investors to enjoy strong returns. On the rare occasions that EMD issuers have felt it necessary to restructure their external debt obligations, investors have often been compensated with high recovery values, reducing their potential losses, as exhibit 1 shows. “We believe the market has already priced and identified default candidates, and recovery values are generally understated.” However, the impact of COVID-19 has called into question the potential for such favorable returns. Not only has the virus had tragic consequences for human life, but the lockdown response also has had a devastating economic impact, with sharp downward revisions to global growth. This has led to fiscal deficits and debt ratios deteriorating at a significant pace. And this, in turn, has raised concerns about the sustainability of historic sovereign EMD returns and fears of an increase in default levels. That said, we believe the market has already priced and identified default candidates, and recovery values are generally understated. In the pages that follow, Jared Lou, CFA, and Daniel Wood, portfolio managers on our team, provide insights that I hope offer a useful guide to the current environment. Marcelo Assalin, CFA HEAD OF WILLIAM BLAIR’S EMERGING MARKETS DEBT TEAM 2 | 2020 OUTLOOK FOR SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURINGS Introduction (continued) EXHIBIT 1 Recovery Rates on Defaulted Sovereign Bond Issuers Default Year Default Country Rating at Default Recovery Rates* 1998 Russia Caa1 18% 1999 Pakistan Caa1 52% 1999 Ecuador B3 44% 2000 Ukraine Caa3 69% 2000 Ivory Coast (NR)** n.a.** 18% 2001 Argentina Caa3 27% 2002 Moldova Caa1 60% 2003 Uruguay B3 66% 2004 Grenada (NR)** n.a.** 65% 2005 Dominican Republic B3 95% 2006 Belize Caa3 76% 2008 Seychelles (NR)** n.a.** 30% 2008 Nicaragua*** Caa1 49%*** 2008 Ecuador Caa1 28% 2010 Jamaica Caa2 90% 2012 Greece C 24% 2012 Greece C 37% 2012 Belize Ca 40% 2013 Cyprus*** Caa3 53%*** 2013 Jamaica*** B3 89%*** 2013 Grenada (NR)** n.a.** 36% 2014 Argentina*** Caa2 68%**** 2015 Ukraine Ca 80% 2016 Mozambique B3 88% 2017 Mozambique Caa3 61% 2017 Belize Caa2 65% 2017 Republic of Congo Caa2 81% 2017 Venezuela Caa3 23% Issuer-Weighted Recovery Rates 55% Value-Weighted Recovery Rates 40% Source: Moody’s Investors Services, “Sovereign Default and Recovery Rates, 1983-2017,” as of July 2018. *Recovery is measured as the average trading price in percentage of the par value of the bond at the time of the initial default event, 30-day post-default for missed payments or around the close. ** NR = not rated by Moody’s at the time of default. Pricing information is not available for three other recent unrated sovereign defaults on local-currency bonds: Turkey 1999, Dominica 2003, and Cameroon 2004. ***When the trading price is not available, we calculate an equivalent measure estimating the recovery as the ratio of the present value of the cash flows of the new debt instruments received as a result of the distressed exchange versus the outstanding face value of those initially promised, discounted by an approximated market yield at the time of default. ****For Argentina, the trading-price-based recovery rate at the time of default in 2014 was 68%. The ultimate recovery as of the time of default resolution in 2016 was about 97% as the missed interest payments were repaid in full. WILLIAM BLAIR INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT | 3 Defaults Priced In, Recovery Values Understated The bad news is that we believe that in 2020, we will As a recent example, African nations have asked likely see more sovereign defaults than we have ever multilateral creditors to provide $44 billion in debt seen before in a single calendar year. On a positive note, relief while maintaining market access, which remains however, we believe the asset class is already priced to a priority for most. For those countries that have reflect this dynamic. experienced liquidity issues rather than structural debt problems, the IMF has already disbursed billions of Argentina, Lebanon, and Zambia (and to a lesser extent dollars under Rapid Financing Instruments (RFIs) to help Ecuador) were all pricing in a relatively high probability countries combat the pandemic by alleviating pressure of default before COVID-19 affected financial markets. on potentially problematic financing gaps. Each of these countries already had debt sustainability problems. While exacerbated by the negative impact Defaults Remain Rare of the coronavirus, these problems would have likely led Sovereign defaults remain rare and recovery rates to sovereign restructuring anyway. relatively high, offering EMD hard currency investors attractive return potential. The main reasons are Since the COVID-19 outbreak, Suriname, Belize, strong interest in retaining market access and strong and Angola in particular have all begun to price in a high support from multilateral organizations. probability of default as well. Moody’s, for example, estimates that from 1983 to Despite an elevated number of restructuring candidates, 2019, the sovereign default rate on bonded debt was only there are reasons to be optimistic about the potential 0.73%, as exhibit 2 illustrates.1 Median recovery rates impact on future asset-class returns. First, Suriname, have been about 52 cents on the dollar, implying that Belize, and Angola collectively represent less than 1% of EMD sovereign credit spreads historically have offered the total value of the J.P. Morgan EMBIGD. Second, investors a very attractive risk premium relative to we believe few other emerging markets will be forced into historical credit losses. restructuring. Third, we believe potential recovery values will be higher than the market is currently pricing. Moreover, sovereigns want the ability to run fiscal deficits and need access to capital markets to fund them. They There are a few reasons for this optimism. A sovereign also want to act as a benchmark for companies within default with a low recovery value can adversely affect their borders to grow and access financing abroad. When a country’s ability to access international capital markets, a country is in default, these goals become problematic. expose the country to litigation, and impair its citizens’ standard of living. Therefore, it is generally in a sovereign A Good Opportunity issuer’s best interests to reach a benign settlement Despite economic hardship brought on by the pandemic, agreement with creditors. we believe sovereign credit offers a very attractive opportunity set with respect to risk and reward. We IMF and Multilateral Support believe that investors are being overcompensated for Investors can also be comforted by the multilateral the risks, despite a higher-than-normal default outlook support a sovereign issuer is likely to receive in order to in 2020. improve current and future debt sustainability. This support comes through financial aid, and arguably more importantly, technical expertise and policy improvement. An IMF program’s stamp of credibility generally reduces some of the uncertainty of economic policy, which can help motivate investors to invest. 1 Source: Moody’s Investors Services, “Sovereign Default and Recovery Rates, 1983-2019,” as of May 2020. 4 | 2020 OUTLOOK FOR SOVEREIGN DEBT RESTRUCTURINGS Defaults Priced In, Recovery Values Understated (continued) EXHIBIT 2 Historical Default Rates AVERAGE DEFAULT RATE 1983-2019 RECOVERY RATE 1983-2019 RECOVERY RATES HAVE BEEN RISING 0.73% 52% 63% Moody’s estimates that the The historical recovery rate The median recovery rate from average default rate over the period for emerging markets sovereigns over 2015 to 2019 was 63%. 1983 to 2019 was 0.73%. this period was 52% • The coronavirus crisis should result in a temporary increase in default rates. • Multilateral and bilateral support limits the scope for widespread technical defaults. • We believe default rates should converge toward the long-term average in the medium term. Source: Moody’s Investors Services, “Sovereign Default and Recovery Rates, 1983-2019,” as of May 2020. EXHIBIT 3 Median Recovery Rates on Defaulted Sovereign Bond Issuers 90% 80% 70% 63% 60% 52.0% 49.0% 50% 46.5% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0 1998 to 2005 2005 to 2010 2010 to 2015 2015 to 2019 Source: Moody’s Investors Services, “Sovereign Default and Recovery Rates, 1983-2019,” as of May 2020. WILLIAM BLAIR INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT | 5 Our Experience With Historical Sovereign Defaults Despite the favorable outlook we have for EMD returns, “Understanding the political and as mentioned above, we believe there will be a record level of restructurings across the asset class over the next economic motivations of a particular two or three years. regime regarding capital market access Moreover, the process of restructuring can be long and is very important in determining complex. There are many complexities investors
Recommended publications
  • Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 by David Beers and Jamshid Mavalwalla
    Technical Report No. 101 / Rapport technique no 101 Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 by David Beers and Jamshid Mavalwalla June 2017 (An earlier version of this technical report was published in June 2016.) Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 David Beers1 and Jamshid Mavalwalla2 1Special Advisor, International Directorate Bank of England London, United Kingdom EC2R 8AH [email protected] 2Funds Management and Banking Department Bank of Canada Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 [email protected] The views expressed in this report are solely those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada. ISSN 1919-689X © 2017 Bank of Canada Acknowledgements We are grateful to Allan Crawford, Grahame Johnson, Philippe Muller, Peter Youngman, Carolyn A. Wilkins, John Chambers, Stuart Culverhouse, Archil Imnaishvili, Marc Joffe, Mark Joy and James McCormack for their helpful comments and suggestions, to Christian Suter for sharing with us previously unpublished data he compiled with Volker Bornschier and Ulrich Pfister in 1986, and to Jean-Sébastien Nadeau for his many contributions to this and earlier versions of the technical report and the database. We thank Norman Yeung and Isabelle Brazeau for their able technical assistance, and Glen Keenleyside, Meredith Fraser-Ohman and Carole Hubbard for their excellent editorial assistance. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. i Abstract Until recently, there have been few efforts to systematically measure and aggregate the nominal value of the different types of sovereign government debt in default. To help fill this gap, the Bank of Canada’s Credit Rating Assessment Group (CRAG) has developed a comprehensive database of sovereign defaults posted on the Bank of Canada’s website.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need Bankruptcy?
    MICHELLE J. WHITE University of California, San Diego Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need Bankruptcy? SHOULD THERE BE a sovereign bankruptcy procedure for countries in financial distress? This paper explores the use of U.S. bankruptcy law as a model for a sovereign bankruptcy procedure and asks whether adoption of such a procedure would lead to a more orderly process of sovereign debt restructuring. It assumes that a quick and orderly debt restructuring process is more efficient than a prolonged and disorderly one, because a lengthy process of debt restructuring takes a high toll on debtor countries’ economies as well as harming creditors in general. I concentrate on three goals for a sovereign bankruptcy procedure: preventing individual credi- tors or groups of creditors from suing the debtor for repayment, prevent- ing groups of creditors from strategically delaying negotiations or acting as holdouts, and increasing the likelihood that private creditors will pro- vide new loans to sovereign debtors in financial distress, thus reducing the pressure on the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to fund bailouts. I conclude that nonbankruptcy alternatives are less likely to accomplish these goals than a sovereign bankruptcy procedure. U.S. Bankruptcy Law and Important Trade-offs in Bankruptcy Three sections of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code are of possible relevance for a future international bankruptcy procedure: Chapter 7 (bankruptcy I am grateful to Edwin Truman and Marcus Miller for helpful comments and discussion. 1 2 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:2002 liquidation), Chapter 11 (corporate reorganization), and Chapter 9 (munic- ipal bankruptcy). Chapter 7 Chapter 7 is the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Duration of Sovereign Debt Renegotiation☆
    Journal of International Economics 86 (2012) 252–268 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of International Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jie Duration of sovereign debt renegotiation☆ Yan Bai a,⁎, Jing Zhang b,⁎ a Arizona State University, United States b University of Michigan, United States article info abstract Article history: In the period since 1990, sovereign debt renegotiations take an average of five years for bank loans but only Received 7 January 2010 one year for bonds. We provide an explanation for this finding by highlighting one key difference between Received in revised form 13 August 2011 bank loans and bonds: bank loans are rarely traded, while bonds are heavily traded on the secondary market. Accepted 15 August 2011 In our theory, the secondary market plays a crucial information revelation role in shortening renegotiations. Available online 1 September 2011 Consider a dynamic bargaining game with incomplete information between a government and creditors. The creditors' reservation value is private information, and the government knows only its distribution. Delays in JEL classification: F02 reaching agreements arise in equilibrium because the government uses costly delays to screen the creditors' F34 reservation value. When the creditors trade on the secondary market, the market price conveys information F51 about their reservation value, which lessens the information friction and reduces the renegotiation duration. We find that the secondary market tends to increase the renegotiation payoff of the government but decrease Keywords: that of the creditors while increasing the total payoff. We then embed these renegotiation outcomes in a sim- Sovereign debt restructuring ple sovereign debt model to analyze the ex ante welfare implications.
    [Show full text]
  • Avoiding Sovereign Default Contagion: a Normative Analysis De Ferra, Sergio and Enrico Mallucci
    K.7 Avoiding Sovereign Default Contagion: A Normative Analysis de Ferra, Sergio and Enrico Mallucci Please cite paper as: de Ferra, Sergio and Enrico Mallucci (2020). Avoiding Sovereign Default Contagion: A Normative Analysis International Finance Discussion Papers 1275. https://doi.org/10.17016/IFDP.2020.1275 International Finance Discussion Papers Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Number 1275 February 2020 Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers Number 1275 February 2020 Avoiding Sovereign Default Contagion: A Normative Analysis Sergio de Ferra and Enrico Mallucci NOTE: International Finance Discussion Papers (IFDPs) are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. The analysis and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by other members of the research staff or the Board of Governors. References in publications to the International Finance Discussion Papers Series (other than acknowledgement) should be cleared with the author(s) to protect the tentative character of these papers. Recent IFDPs are available on the Web at www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/ifdp/. This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network electronic library at www.ssrn.com. Avoiding Sovereign Default Contagion: A Normative Analysis∗ Sergio de Ferray Enrico Mallucciz Abstract Should debtor countries support each other during sovereign debt crises? We answer this question through the lens of a two-country sovereign-default model that we calibrate to the euro-area periphery. First, we look at cross-country bailouts. We find that whenever agents anticipate their existence, bailouts induce moral hazard an reduce welfare.
    [Show full text]
  • Boc-Boe Sovereign Default Database: What's New in 2021
    BoC–BoE Sovereign Default Database: What’s new in 2021? by David Beers1, 1 Elliot Jones2, Zacharie Quiviger and John Fraser Walsh3 The views expressed this report are solely those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada or the Bank of England. 1 [email protected], Center for Financial Stability, New York, NY 10036, USA 2 [email protected], Financial Markets Department, Reserve Bank of New Zealand, Auckland 1010, New Zealand 3 [email protected], [email protected] Financial and Enterprise Risk Department Bank of Canada, Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 1 Acknowledgements We are grateful to Mark Joy, James McCormack, Carol Ann Northcott, Alexandre Ruest, Jean- François Tremblay and Tim Willems for their helpful comments and suggestions. We thank Banu Cartmell, Marie Cavanaugh, John Chambers, James Chapman, Stuart Culverhouse, Patrisha de Leon-Manlagnit, Archil Imnaishvili, Marc Joffe, Grahame Johnson, Jamshid Mavalwalla, Philippe Muller, Papa N’Diaye, Jean-Sébastien Nadeau, Carolyn A. Wilkins and Peter Youngman for their contributions to earlier research papers on the database, Christian Suter for sharing previously unpublished data he compiled with Volker Bornschier and Ulrich Pfister in 1986, Carole Hubbard for her excellent editorial assistance, and Michael Dalziel and Natalie Brule, and Sandra Newton, Sally Srinivasan and Rebecca Mari, respectively, for their help designing the Bank of Canada and Bank of England web pages and Miranda Wang for her efforts updating the database. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. 2 Introduction Since 2014, the Bank of Canada (BoC) has maintained a comprehensive database of sovereign defaults to systematically measure and aggregate the nominal value of the different types of sovereign government debt in default.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Default: Which Shocks Matter?
    Sovereign default: which shocks matter? Bernardo Guimaraes∗ April 2010 Abstract This paper analyses a small open economy that wants to borrow from abroad, cannot commit to repay debt but faces costs if it decides to default. The model generates analytical expressions for theimpactofshocksontheincentivecompatiblelevel of debt. Debt reduction generated by severe output shocks is no more than a couple of percentage points. In contrast, shocks to world interest rates can substantially affect the incentive compatible level of debt. Keywords: sovereign debt; default; world interest rates; output shocks. Jel Classification: F34. 1Introduction What generates sovereign default? Which shocks are behind the episodes of debt crises we observe? The answer to the question is crucial to policy design. If we want to write contingent contracts,1 build and operate a sovereign debt restructuring mechanism,2 or an international lender of last resort,3 we need to know which economic variables are subject to shocks that significantly increase incentives for default or could take a country to “bankruptcy”. I investigate this question by studying a small open economy that wants to borrow from abroad, cannot commit to repay debt but faces costs if it decides to default. There is an incentive compatible level of sovereign debt – beyond which greater debt triggers default –anditfluctuates with economic conditions. The renegotiation process is costless and restores debt to its incentive compatible level. The model yields analytical expressions ∗London School of Economics, Department of Economics, and Escola de Economia de Sao Paulo, FGV-SP; [email protected]. I thank Giancarlo Corsetti, Nicola Gennaioli, Alberto Martin, Silvana Tenreyro, Alwyn Young and, especially, Francesco Caselli for helpful comments, several seminar participants for their inputs and ZsofiaBaranyand Nathan Foley-Fisher for excellent research assistance financed by STICERD.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Default and Crisis Resolution
    Sovereign Default and Crisis Resolution Inaugural-Dissertation zur Erlangung des akademischen Grades eines Doktors der Wirtschaftswissenschaft (Dr. rer. pol.) Eingereicht am Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaft der Freien Universität Berlin von: Diplom-Volkswirt Christoph Trebesch Geburtsort: Uccle (Brüssel), Belgien Juni 2011 Datum der Disputation: 07.01.2011 Erstgutachter: Prof. Dr. Helge Berger Lehrstuhl Geldtheorie und Geldpolitik Freie Universität Berlin Zweitgutachter: Prof. Dr. Henrik Enderlein Professor of Political Economy Hertie School of Governance ii Für meine Eltern iii Table of Contents 1. Introduction ................................................................................................................ 1 2. Sovereign Debt Disputes .......................................................................................... 11 2.1. Introduction .............................................................................................. 12 2.2. Analyzing Debt Crises: Previous Approaches ......................................... 14 2.3. The Index of Government Coerciveness .................................................. 15 2.4. Coding and Resulting Datasets ................................................................ 22 2.5. Results and Stylised Facts ........................................................................ 26 2.6. Explaining Government Coerciveness ..................................................... 30 2.7. Conclusion ..............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • To Rank Pari Passu Or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds After the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga
    Law and Business Review of the Americas Volume 15 Number 4 Article 3 2009 To Rank Pari Passu or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds after the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra Recommended Citation Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal, To Rank Pari Passu or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds after the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga, 15 LAW & BUS. REV. AM. 745 (2009) https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra/vol15/iss4/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at SMU Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law and Business Review of the Americas by an authorized administrator of SMU Scholar. For more information, please visit http://digitalrepository.smu.edu. To RANK PARI PASSU OR NOT TO RANK PARI PASSU. THAT IS THE QUESTION IN SOVEREIGN BONDS AFTER THE LATEST EPISODE OF THE ARGENTINE SAGA Dr. Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal "Justice is the crowning glory of the virtues." CICERO (106-43 BC) "And maybe people who might consider lending money to the Repub- lic of Argentina in the future might realize what difficulties they're go- ing to run into if they are naive enough to rely on what the Republic offers." HON. THOMAS P. GRIESA 1 I. INTRODUCTION T can be said that the pari passu clause mistakenly migrated from secured private lending to unsecured sovereign lending.2 Once rooted in unsecured sovereign lending instruments, it faced certain provisions similar to those in Spain or the Philippines, which allowed a creditor to better position itself vis-d-vis other creditors, 3 and become a 1.Hon.
    [Show full text]
  • Interpreting the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Bond Contracts: It’S All Hebrew (And Aramaic) to Me
    Interpreting the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Bond Contracts: It’s All Hebrew (and Aramaic) to Me Mark L. J. Wright May 2014 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Reserve Federal WP 2014-06 May 4, 2014 Interpreting the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Bond Contracts: It’sAll Hebrew (and Aramaic) to Me Mark L. J. Wright Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and National Bureau of Economic Research ABSTRACT In this comment, we take a helicopter tour of the history of notions of “equality” and “justice” in sovereign debt restructuring in particular, and in the division of property more generally, and show that these concerns have existed for centuries, if not millennia. We argue that the issue at stake in the interpretation of the pari passu clause is not so much the treatment of holders of identical claims– it is now customary to treat them identically– but whether the holders of different claims should be treated differently. We show that exists a customary “principle of differentiation” that allows creditors with claims that differ in specific ways to be treated preferentially. One of these specific differences concerns debts that have been reduced in value during a previous debt restructuring or default, and based on this principle we conclude that the New York court has, if not completely misinterpreted the meaning of the pari passu clause, then at least misapplied it. Keywords: Sovereign debt restructuring, pari passu, Argentina, inter-creditor equity. JEL Codes: D63, F34, K12 To appear in the Capital Markets Law Journal. Senior Economist and Research Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and Faculty Research Fellow at the National Bureau of Economic Research.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Default and International Trade
    Sovereign Default and International Trade Charles Serfaty (MIT)∗ December 16, 2020 PLEASE CLICK HERE FOR THE LAST VERSION. Evidence suggests that sovereign defaults disrupt international trade. As a consequence, countries that are more open have more to lose from a sovereign default and are less inclined to renege on their debt. In turn, lenders should trust more open countries and charge them lower interest rate. In most cases, the country should also borrow more debt the more open it is. This paper formalizes this idea in a simple sovereign debt model à la Eaton and Gersovitz (1981). It also provides evidence using gravitational instrumental variables from Frankel and Romer (1999) and Feyrer (2019) as a source for exogenous variation for trade openness. ∗I am infinitely grateful to my PhD director, Arnaud Costinot, for his constant support and inventive suggestions, that went unabated by the 2020 crisis. I owe a great debt of gratitude to my PhD advisor Ivàn Werning for his incredibly helpful insights. I am also especially thankful to Ricardo Caballero and Daniel Cohen for insightful discussions about this paper. I want to thank Daron Acemoglu, Marios Angeletos, David Atkin, Martin Beraja, Dave Donaldson, Joel Flynn, Michele Fornino, Juliette Fournier, Masao Fukui, Clémence Idoux, Antoine Levy, Andrea Manera, Parinitha Sastry, Alp Simsek, Claudia Steinwender, John Sturm, Adrien Verdelhan as well as all MIT macro lunch and trade tea participants for their very useful comments. 1 1 Introduction The main peculiarity of sovereign debt contracts is that repayments are not easily enforce- able by the lender: a sovereign country with a strong enough army and divided enough lenders can default without expecting dire consequences.
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereign Defaults in Court Henrik Enderlein
    Working Paper Series Julian Schumacher, Christoph Trebesch, Sovereign defaults in court Henrik Enderlein No 2135 / February 2018 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Abstract For centuries, defaulting governments were immune from legal action by foreign creditors. This paper shows that this is no longer the case. Building a dataset covering four decades, we find that creditor lawsuits have become an increasingly common feature of sovereign debt markets. The legal developments have strengthened the hands of creditors and raised the cost of default for debtors. We show that legal disputes in the US and the UK disrupt government access to international capital markets, as foreign courts can impose a financial embargo on sovereigns. The findings are consistent with theoretical models with creditor sanctions and suggest that sovereign debt is becoming more enforceable. We discuss how the threat of litigation affects debt management, government willingness to pay, and the resolution of debt crises. Keywords: Sovereign default, enforcement, government financing, debt restructuring regime JEL codes: F34, G15, H63, K22 ECB Working Paper Series No 2135 / February 2018 1 Non-technical summary This paper provides novel empirical evidence that creditor lawsuits have become a significant cost of sovereign default. Based on a newly collected dataset, we show that creditor lawsuits against defaulting governments have proliferated, with far-reaching consequences for government willingness to pay and for government access to international capital markets. This finding stands in contrast to the common view that sovereigns are largely immune from legal action by foreign creditors.
    [Show full text]
  • The Politics of Sovereign Default Under Financial Integration∗
    The politics of sovereign default under financial integration∗ Marina Azzimonti Stony Brook University and NBER Vincenzo Quadrini University of Southern California and CEPR Abstract In this paper we study the role of portfolio diversification on op- timal default of sovereign debt in a two-country model with large economies that are financially integrated. Financial integration in- creases the incentives to default not only because part of the defaulted debt is owned by foreigners (the standard redistribution channel), but also because the endogenous macroeconomic cost for the defaulting country is smaller when financial markets are integrated. We show that the sovereign default of one country may be triggered by higher debt (liquidity) issued by other countries. Because the macroeconomic costs of default spill to other countries, creditor countries may find it beneficial ex-post to bail-out debtor countries. Although bailouts create moral hazard problems, they can be welfare improving also ex-ante. ∗We would like to thank seminar and conference participants for helpful comments at the Atlanta Fed, Bank of Canada, Claremont McKenna College, Minnesota Work- shop in Macroeconomic Theory, Penn State University, Philadelphia Fed, SED meeting in Toulouse, University of California San Diego, University of Georgia, University of Wis- consin, the Stockman Conference at the University of Rochester. 1 Introduction The last 30 years have been characterized by a dramatic increase in the international integration of financial markets. This allowed governments to `export' their public debt, that is, to borrow from foreign countries. Figure 1 plots the share of public debt for the US and the largest EU countries during the 1997-2010 period and shows that this share has increased substantially during this period.
    [Show full text]