To Rank Pari Passu Or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds After the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

To Rank Pari Passu Or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds After the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga Law and Business Review of the Americas Volume 15 Number 4 Article 3 2009 To Rank Pari Passu or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds after the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal Follow this and additional works at: https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra Recommended Citation Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal, To Rank Pari Passu or Not to Rank : That Is the Question in Sovereign Bonds after the Latest Episode of the Argentine Saga, 15 LAW & BUS. REV. AM. 745 (2009) https://scholar.smu.edu/lbra/vol15/iss4/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Law Journals at SMU Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Law and Business Review of the Americas by an authorized administrator of SMU Scholar. For more information, please visit http://digitalrepository.smu.edu. To RANK PARI PASSU OR NOT TO RANK PARI PASSU. THAT IS THE QUESTION IN SOVEREIGN BONDS AFTER THE LATEST EPISODE OF THE ARGENTINE SAGA Dr. Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal "Justice is the crowning glory of the virtues." CICERO (106-43 BC) "And maybe people who might consider lending money to the Repub- lic of Argentina in the future might realize what difficulties they're go- ing to run into if they are naive enough to rely on what the Republic offers." HON. THOMAS P. GRIESA 1 I. INTRODUCTION T can be said that the pari passu clause mistakenly migrated from secured private lending to unsecured sovereign lending.2 Once rooted in unsecured sovereign lending instruments, it faced certain provisions similar to those in Spain or the Philippines, which allowed a creditor to better position itself vis-d-vis other creditors, 3 and become a 1.Hon. Thomas P. Griesa, New York District Judge, on a hearing on January 12, 2006 in EM Ltd. v. Republic of Argentina, 03 CV 2S07 (TPG) (unreported hear- ing); NML Capital Ltd. v. Republic of Argentina, 03 CV 8845 (TPG) (unreported hearing) & 05 CV 2434 (TPG). 2. See Lee Buchheit & Jeremiah Pam, The Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Debt In- struments, 53 EMORY L.J. 913 (2004). 3. Articles 913(4) of the Spanish Commercial Code and 1924(3)(a) of the Spanish Civil Code refer to the preference of creditors whose credit is instrumented by means of a public deed (notarized by a Notary Public). As noted by Wood, these types of credits have a preference over those-although of the same type-not instrumented in a public deed. See Philip Wood, International Loans, Bonds and Securities Regulation: Law and Practice of International Finance, 41 (Sweet & Maxwell 1995). The Spanish Insolvency Law 22/2003 of July 9, 2003 amended section 1924 of the Spanish Civil Code. Although under section 91of the new insolvency law a whole new ranking of preferences, not including credits instrumented through public deeds, is included-subsection (3)(a) of section 1924 of the Spanish Civil Code has not been amended. Therefore, in the event of sovereign issuances-not subject to insolvency laws-the un-amended section 1924(3)(a) of the Civil Code still applies. The Philippines-strongly influenced by the Spanish Civil Code-have a norm similar to the ones of Spain. Article 2244(14) of the Philippines Civil Code grants priority to those credits that appear in a public instrument or a final judgment. These two cases are the main reason of the emergence of the pari passu clause in 746 LAW AND BUSINESS REVIEW OF THE AMERICAS [Vol. 15 'must have' provision in this type of debt instrument. Then, pari passu clauses stayed in unsecured debt instruments due to the fear of the earmarking revenues, or the risk of the sovereign, preferring a group of creditors over another.4 These two fears were tackled by an expanded negative pledge clause and the Libra Bank Limited v. Banco Nacional de Costa Rica S.A. 5 and Allied Bank Internationalv. Banco Credito Agricola de Cartago6 cases. Therefore, if a proper due diligence was conducted; there was no need to have a pari passu clause unless there was an excep- tional circumstance, like the ones of Spain or the Philippines. Unfortu- nately, a misguided interpretation of the pari passu clause in the Elliot Associates LP v. Banco de la Naci6n y Repatblica del Perli case 7 opened the door to litigation on incorrect grounds, which mainly focused on pay- ment interpretation or broad interpretation of the pari passu clause. 8 It was an 'aberration', but one that caused furor.9 In Elliot, there was no breach of the pari passu clause, but rather a wrong understanding of its meaning. In the case of Argentina, the whole story could be different since it can be correctly interpreted as a breach of the paripassu clause in its ranking or narrow form. This article will focus on the recent Argentine sovereign debt restructuring exercise that might re-ignite litigation based on the paripassu clause. It is important to stress the difference between the two scenarios, i.e. litigation pre and post Ar- gentina's sovereign debt exchange offer. Pre-Argentina's litigation was based on an incorrect interpretation of the pari passu clause made by a Belgium court. Post-Argentina's potential litigation could be based on an sovereign debt bond instruments. Buchheit and Pam also consider Argentina a country that forced the inclusion of the pari passu clause since 1972, when they re- enacted a practice dating back to 1862 where foreign creditors were subordinated to local creditors in the bankruptcy of an Argentine debtor. See Buchheit, supra, note 2 (quoting EMILIO J. CARDENAS, INTERNATIONAL LENDING: SUBORDINA- TION OF FOREIGN CLAIMS UNDER ARGENTINE BANKRUPTCY LAW, IN DEFAULT AND RESCHEDULING 63 (David Suratgar eds., 1984). 4. See WILLIAM TUDOR JOHN, SOVEREIGN RISK AND IMMUNITY UNDER ENGLISH LAW AND PRACTICE IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL LAW 95-96 (Robert S. Rendell ed., 2nd ed. 1983). 5. See Libra Bank Ltd. v. Banco Nacional de Costa Rica S.A., 570 F. Supp. 870 (S.D.N.Y. 1983). 6. Allied Bank Int'l v. Banco Credito Agricola de Cartago, 566 F. Supp. 1440 (S.D.N.Y. 1983), 757 F. 2d 516 (2d Cir.), 473 US 934 (1985). 7. Elliott Assoc. v. Republic of Peru, 948 F. Supp 1203 (S.D.N.Y 1996); Elliott Assoc. v. Republic of Peru, 961 F. Supp 83 (S.D.N.Y 1997); Elliott Assoc. v. Republic of Peru, 12 F. Supp 2d 328 (S.D.N.Y 1998); Elliott Assoc. v. Republic of Peru, 194 F.3d 363 (2d Cir. 1999); Elliott Assoc. v. Republic of Peru, 194 F.D.R. 116 (S.D.N.Y. 2000); see also Elliot Assocs, L.P., General Docket No. 2000/QR/92 (Court of Appeals of Brussels, 8th Chamber, Sept. 26, 2000), (not reported, on file with the author). 8. See Buchheit, supra note 2; Philip Wood, Pari Passu Clauses-What Do They Mean?, 18 Butterworths J. of Int'l Banking & Fin. L. 10 (2003); Pari Passu Clauses: Analysis of the Role, Use and Meaning of Pari Passu Clauses in Sovereign Debt Obligations as a Matter of English Law (Fin. Markets Law Comm't Issue 79, 2005), available at www.fmlc.org [hereinafter Fin. Market Law Comm't Issue 79]. 9. See Rodrigo Olivares-Caminal, Understanding the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Debt Instruments: A Complex Quest, INT'L LAW. (forthcoming Fall 2009). 2009] TO RANK PARI PASSU OR NOT actual breach of the pari passu clause. If this is the case, if there was an actual breach of the pari passu clause, a new wake of litigation can be triggered. This article is the second part of a study on the pari passu clause in sovereign debt instruments. Part I was published by The Inter- national Lawyer in the Fall Issue 2009, under the title Understanding the Pari Passu Clause in Sovereign Debt Instruments. A Complex Quest.10 II. ARGENTINA: A NEW CHAPTER IN THE PARI PASSU SAGA? On December 23, 2001, in an ill-famed assembly, the Argentine Con- gress gave the President of the nation a standing ovation when he an- nounced a moratorium on the Argentine sovereign debt. The message given to the international investors who had decided to invest in Argen- tine debt securities, however, was far from respectful to the rule of law. A 38.4 percent of the defaulted debt was held by individuals and corpora- tions domiciled in Argentina, while the rest was scattered throughout the world." To overcome the default status, Presidential Decree 1735/0412 ordered the restructuring of two Argentine securities, first, debt instrumented in the form of bonds, and second, payment of which had been deferred under the provisions of Article 59 of Argentine Law No. 25,827.13 The restructuring was carried out through a domestic and international ex- change of sovereign debt bonds for new securities. The domestic ex- change offer comprised three phases: 1) local debt,14 2) debt of political subdivisions, and 3) and the international exchange offer. On January 13, 2005,-after thirty-six months in default-Argentina released, by means of Resolution 20/05 (issued by the Ministry of Econ- omy), the final offering prospectus and supplement, including the terms 10. It is recommended that the two parts should be read as a whole, they each can be accessed through Westlaw and Lexis Nexis. 11. See Dr. Guillermo Nielsen, Speech of Secretary of Finance: Argentina's Restruc- turing Guidelines (Sept. 22 2003), available at http://www.argentinedebtinfo.gov.ar/ ingpresen.htm. 12. Presidential Decree 1725/04 (Dec. 9, 2004). A Spanish version is available at http:// www.infoleg.gov.ar/infoleglnternet/anexos/100000-104999/101861/norma.htm.
Recommended publications
  • COMP Operations
    EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 20.02.2013 C (2013) 775 final In the published version of this decision, PUBLIC VERSION some information has been omitted, pursuant to articles 24 and 25 of Council This document is made available for Regulation (EC) No 659/1999 of 22 information purposes only. March 1999 laying down detailed rules for the application of Article 93 of the EC Treaty, concerning non-disclosure of information covered by professional secrecy. The omissions are shown thus […]. COMP Operations Subject: State aid SA.35956 (2013/C) (ex 2013/NN) (ex 2012/N) – Estonia Rescue aid to Estonian Air Sir, The Commission wishes to inform Estonia that, having examined the information supplied by your authorities on the measures referred to above, it has decided to initiate the procedure laid down in Article 108(2) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union. 1. PROCEDURE (1) On 3 December 2012, in the context of pre-notification contacts, Estonia submitted to the Commission information on its plans to provide rescue aid in favour of AS Estonian Air (hereinafter "Estonian Air" or "the airline") as well as T.E. hr. Urmas PAET Välisminister Islandi väljak 1 15049 Tallinn ESTONIA Commission européenne, B-1049 Bruxelles – Belgique Europese Commissie, B-1049 Brussel – België Telefon: 00 32 (0) 2 299 11 11. on several capital injections carried out in the past. A meeting with representatives of the Estonian authorities took place on 4 December 2012. (2) Following these pre-notification contacts, by SANI notification number 7853 of 20 December 2012, Estonia notified to the Commission the planned provision of rescue aid to the airline in the form of a loan amounting to EUR 8.3 million.
    [Show full text]
  • Bankrupt Subsidiaries: the Challenges to the Parent of Legal Separation
    ERENSFRIEDMAN&MAYERFELD GALLEYSFINAL 1/27/2009 10:25:46 AM BANKRUPT SUBSIDIARIES: THE CHALLENGES TO THE PARENT OF LEGAL SEPARATION ∗ Brad B. Erens ∗∗ Scott J. Friedman ∗∗∗ Kelly M. Mayerfeld The financial distress of a subsidiary can be a difficult event for its parent company. When the subsidiary faces the prospect of a bankruptcy filing, the parent likely will need to address many more issues than simply its lost investment in the subsidiary. Unpaid creditors of the subsidiary instinctively may look to the parent as a target to recover on their claims under any number of legal theories, including piercing the corporate veil, breach of fiduciary duty, and deepening insolvency. The parent also may find that it has exposure to the subsidiary’s creditors under various state and federal statutes, or under contracts among the parties. In addition, untangling the affairs of the parent and subsidiary, if the latter is going to reorganize under chapter 11 and be owned by its creditors, can be difficult. All of these issues may, in fact, lead to financial challenges for the parent itself. Parent companies thus are well advised to consider their potential exposure to a subsidiary’s creditors not only once the subsidiary actually faces financial distress, but well in advance as a matter of prudent corporate planning. If a subsidiary ultimately is forced to file for chapter 11, however, the bankruptcy laws do provide unique procedures to resolve any existing or potential litigation between the parent and the subsidiary’s creditors and to permit the parent to obtain a clean break from the subsidiary’s financial problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Overview of the Fdic As Conservator Or Receiver
    September 26, 2008 OVERVIEW OF THE FDIC AS CONSERVATOR OR RECEIVER This memorandum is an overview of the receivership and conservatorship authority of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (the “FDIC”). In view of the many and complex specific issues that may arise in this context, this memorandum is necessarily an overview, but it does give particular reference to counterparty issues that might arise in the case of a relatively large complex bank such as a significant regional bank and outlines elements of the FDIC framework which differ from a corporate bankruptcy. This memorandum has three parts: (1) background on the legal framework governing FDIC resolutions, highlighting changes and developments since the 1990s; (2) an outline of six distinctive aspects of the FDIC approach with comparison to the bankruptcy law provisions; and (3) a final section illustrating issues and uncertainties in the FDIC resolutions process through a more detailed review of two examples – treatment of loan securitizations and participations, and standby letters of credit.1 Relevant additional materials include: the pertinent provisions of the Federal Deposit Insurance (the "FDI") Act2 and FDIC rules3, statements of policy4 and advisory opinions;5 the FDIC Resolution Handbook6 which reflects the FDIC's high level description of the receivership process, including a contrast with the bankruptcy framework; recent speeches of FDIC Chairman 1 While not exhaustive, these discussions are meant to be exemplary of the kind of analysis that is appropriate in analyzing any transaction with a bank counterparty. 2 Esp. Section 11 et seq., http://www.fdic.gov/regulations/laws/rules/1000- 1200.html#1000sec.11 3 Esp.
    [Show full text]
  • Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 by David Beers and Jamshid Mavalwalla
    Technical Report No. 101 / Rapport technique no 101 Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 by David Beers and Jamshid Mavalwalla June 2017 (An earlier version of this technical report was published in June 2016.) Database of Sovereign Defaults, 2017 David Beers1 and Jamshid Mavalwalla2 1Special Advisor, International Directorate Bank of England London, United Kingdom EC2R 8AH [email protected] 2Funds Management and Banking Department Bank of Canada Ottawa, Ontario, Canada K1A 0G9 [email protected] The views expressed in this report are solely those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Bank of Canada. ISSN 1919-689X © 2017 Bank of Canada Acknowledgements We are grateful to Allan Crawford, Grahame Johnson, Philippe Muller, Peter Youngman, Carolyn A. Wilkins, John Chambers, Stuart Culverhouse, Archil Imnaishvili, Marc Joffe, Mark Joy and James McCormack for their helpful comments and suggestions, to Christian Suter for sharing with us previously unpublished data he compiled with Volker Bornschier and Ulrich Pfister in 1986, and to Jean-Sébastien Nadeau for his many contributions to this and earlier versions of the technical report and the database. We thank Norman Yeung and Isabelle Brazeau for their able technical assistance, and Glen Keenleyside, Meredith Fraser-Ohman and Carole Hubbard for their excellent editorial assistance. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the authors. i Abstract Until recently, there have been few efforts to systematically measure and aggregate the nominal value of the different types of sovereign government debt in default. To help fill this gap, the Bank of Canada’s Credit Rating Assessment Group (CRAG) has developed a comprehensive database of sovereign defaults posted on the Bank of Canada’s website.
    [Show full text]
  • 10.11.3.D Equitable (In)Subordination − Considerations for Sponsors Lending to Portfolio Companies
    10.11.3.d Equitable (In)subordination − Considerations for Sponsors Lending to Portfolio Companies By Joe Basile, Ron Landen and Rose Constance of Weil, Gotshal & Manges LLP Private equity sponsors are increasingly providing additional capital to their portfolio companies either to address liquidity issues at those companies or as part of a negotiated debt restructuring. From a sponsor's point of view, it is often preferable to invest that additional capital in the form of debt rather than equity. However, in structuring that transaction sponsors should be aware that the priority of this debt in a portfolio company's capital structure could be attacked by other creditors if that portfolio company ends up in bankruptcy under the theories of equitable subordination or recharacterization. It is important that sponsors structure any such investments to reduce the risk of a successful attack on the priority status of their debt. Equitable Subordination Section 510(c) of the Bankruptcy Code provides that bankruptcy courts may exercise principles of equitable subordination to subordinate all or part of one claim to another claim. Conceptually, this gives the bankruptcy court power to demote a higher priority claim to a lower priority claim under certain circumstances. In some instances, this can convert an otherwise first priority secured claim into a general unsecured claim ranking pari passu with all other general unsecured claims. Although the statutory authority for equitable subordination is clear, the application is not. However, there are some general principles that can be applied as a guide in properly structuring a credit arrangement. Generally, the courts consider three factors in determining whether to equitably subordinate a claim.
    [Show full text]
  • FIN501-10-S3A-VC Term Sheet
    BLACK BOX TECHNOLOGY, INC. Term Sheet These terms do not constitute any form of binding contract but rather are solely for the purpose of outlining the principal terms pursuant to which a definitive agreement may ultimately be entered into. Security and Percentage 1,000,000 shares of Series A Convertible Preferred Stock (the of Equity: “Preferred”) at an issue price of $2.00 per share (“Original Purchase Price”). The Preferred is convertible into Common Stock representing [30%-70%] of the outstanding securities of the Company on a fully diluted basis. Valuation: $2,000,000 pre-financing; $4,000,000 post-financing TERMS OF THE PREFERRED STOCK: Rights, Preferences, (1) Dividend Provisions: Privileges and (A) Current Dividend: Dividends shall accrue on each share Restrictions of of the Preferred at the rate of [8%-15%] per annum Preferred Stock: payable quarterly. No dividends shall be paid on the Common Stock until all accrued but unpaid dividends have been paid on the Preferred. (B) Pari Passu Dividend: Preferred shall be entitled to dividends at the same rate as the Company’s Common Stock when and as declared on the Common Stock, based on the number of whole shares of Common Stock into which the Preferred is convertible on the date any dividend is declared. (C) Cumulative Dividend: ISSUES: Dividends shall accrue on each share of Preferred on a • Investor generally wants cumulative basis at the rate of [8%-15%] per annum. some guaranteed rate of Cumulative dividends shall be payable only in the event of return before Common a liquidation, dissolution or winding up of the Company or Stock receives anything - upon redemption.
    [Show full text]
  • The Anti-Deprivation Rule and the Pari Passu Rule in Insolvency
    The Anti-deprivation Rule and the Pari Passu Rule in Insolvency Peter Niven* In 2011 the UK Supreme Court delivered a judgment in Belmont Park Investments Pty v BNY Corporate Trustee Services Ltd that addressed the common law anti-deprivation rule. The anti-deprivation rule is a rule that is aimed at attempts to withdraw an asset on bankruptcy, with the effect that the bankrupt’s estate is reduced in value to the detriment of creditors. The underlying public policy is that parties should not be able to contract to defeat the insolvency laws. The Supreme Court in Belmont recognised, for the first time, that there are two distinct rules arising from that public policy, the anti-deprivation rule and the pari passu rule. The latter rule provides that parties cannot contract out of the statutory provisions for pari passu distribu- tion in bankruptcy. The Supreme Court’s judgment has been applied in a number of cases in the UK.This article examines Belmont and its application in two subsequent cases. 0There is a general principle of public policy that parties cannot contract out of the legislation governing insolvency. From this general principle two sub-rules have emerged: the anti-deprivation rule and the rule that it is contrary to public policy to contract out of pari passu distribution (the pari passu rule). The anti-deprivation rule is a rule of the common law that is aimed at attempts to withdraw an asset on bankruptcy, with the effect that the bankrupt’s estate is reduced in value to the detriment of creditors.
    [Show full text]
  • A Theory of the Regulation of Debtor-In-Possession Financing
    Vanderbilt Law Review Volume 46 Issue 4 Issue 4 - May 1993 Article 4 5-1993 A Theory of the Regulation of Debtor-in-Possession Financing George G. Triantis Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/vlr Part of the Banking and Finance Law Commons, and the Bankruptcy Law Commons Recommended Citation George G. Triantis, A Theory of the Regulation of Debtor-in-Possession Financing, 46 Vanderbilt Law Review 901 (1993) Available at: https://scholarship.law.vanderbilt.edu/vlr/vol46/iss4/4 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. It has been accepted for inclusion in Vanderbilt Law Review by an authorized editor of Scholarship@Vanderbilt Law. For more information, please contact [email protected]. A Theory of the Regulation of Debtor-in-Possession Financing George G. Triantis* I. INTRODUCTION .......................................... 901 II. THE REGULATION OF DIP FINANCING UNDER SECTION 364 ........................................ 904 III. FINANCIAL AGENCY PROBLEMS OF INSOLVENT FIRMS AND BANKRUPTCY LAW RESPONSES ............................. 910 IV. A MODEL OF JUDICIAL OVERSIGHT OF FINANCING DECISIONS UNDER SECTION 364 ................................. 918 V. CONCLUSION ............................................... 927 MATHEMATICAL APPENDIX ............................... 929 I. INTRODUCTION The profile of Chapter 11 of the Bankruptcy Code in public con- sciousness has surged recently. Other than the automatic stay on the enforcement of claims,1 the
    [Show full text]
  • Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need Bankruptcy?
    MICHELLE J. WHITE University of California, San Diego Sovereigns in Distress: Do They Need Bankruptcy? SHOULD THERE BE a sovereign bankruptcy procedure for countries in financial distress? This paper explores the use of U.S. bankruptcy law as a model for a sovereign bankruptcy procedure and asks whether adoption of such a procedure would lead to a more orderly process of sovereign debt restructuring. It assumes that a quick and orderly debt restructuring process is more efficient than a prolonged and disorderly one, because a lengthy process of debt restructuring takes a high toll on debtor countries’ economies as well as harming creditors in general. I concentrate on three goals for a sovereign bankruptcy procedure: preventing individual credi- tors or groups of creditors from suing the debtor for repayment, prevent- ing groups of creditors from strategically delaying negotiations or acting as holdouts, and increasing the likelihood that private creditors will pro- vide new loans to sovereign debtors in financial distress, thus reducing the pressure on the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to fund bailouts. I conclude that nonbankruptcy alternatives are less likely to accomplish these goals than a sovereign bankruptcy procedure. U.S. Bankruptcy Law and Important Trade-offs in Bankruptcy Three sections of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code are of possible relevance for a future international bankruptcy procedure: Chapter 7 (bankruptcy I am grateful to Edwin Truman and Marcus Miller for helpful comments and discussion. 1 2 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:2002 liquidation), Chapter 11 (corporate reorganization), and Chapter 9 (munic- ipal bankruptcy). Chapter 7 Chapter 7 is the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Duration of Sovereign Debt Renegotiation☆
    Journal of International Economics 86 (2012) 252–268 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Journal of International Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jie Duration of sovereign debt renegotiation☆ Yan Bai a,⁎, Jing Zhang b,⁎ a Arizona State University, United States b University of Michigan, United States article info abstract Article history: In the period since 1990, sovereign debt renegotiations take an average of five years for bank loans but only Received 7 January 2010 one year for bonds. We provide an explanation for this finding by highlighting one key difference between Received in revised form 13 August 2011 bank loans and bonds: bank loans are rarely traded, while bonds are heavily traded on the secondary market. Accepted 15 August 2011 In our theory, the secondary market plays a crucial information revelation role in shortening renegotiations. Available online 1 September 2011 Consider a dynamic bargaining game with incomplete information between a government and creditors. The creditors' reservation value is private information, and the government knows only its distribution. Delays in JEL classification: F02 reaching agreements arise in equilibrium because the government uses costly delays to screen the creditors' F34 reservation value. When the creditors trade on the secondary market, the market price conveys information F51 about their reservation value, which lessens the information friction and reduces the renegotiation duration. We find that the secondary market tends to increase the renegotiation payoff of the government but decrease Keywords: that of the creditors while increasing the total payoff. We then embed these renegotiation outcomes in a sim- Sovereign debt restructuring ple sovereign debt model to analyze the ex ante welfare implications.
    [Show full text]
  • Recent Trends in Second Lien Loans
    VEDDERPRICE ® Finance and Transactions Group Winter 2008–2009 Special Report “SECOND LIEN” LOANS Executive Summary. During the past few years, the financial markets have enabled borrowers to issue multiple layers of debt in sophisticated fi nancings, particularly in the case of highly leveraged companies. Thus, second lien fi nancing has not only become a recognized part of the capital structure of such fi nancings, but has experienced impressive expansion. The “market” terms that govern the second lien layer of debt evolved in light of increased involvement of nonbank investors (i.e., private equity sponsors, hedge funds, distressed debt funds, etc.). As the continued level of involvement of these nonbank investors remains uncertain and the credit markets tighten, the relationships between senior and junior secured lenders will change and certain provisions not typically found in recent intercreditor agreements may once again surface. This article discusses in detail the recent progression of second lien fi nancing structures and certain relevant intercreditor provisions (including payment subordination, enforcement actions, amendment rights and rights in bankruptcy) that may face increased scrutiny by fi rst lien and second lien lenders alike. WWW.VEDDERPRICE.COM VEDDERPRICE RECENT TRENDS IN SECOND LIEN LOANS Over the past several years, lenders have offered quarterly reviews, between 2003 and 2005, borrowers many alternative fi nancing vehicles as second lien loan volume spiked from $3.1 billion to options for fi nancing their acquisitions, corporate $16.3 billion. By 2006, LCD that reported the restructurings or operations. The creative and volume increased to $28.3 billion; in 2007, the complex fi nancing structures that resulted gave volume grew to nearly $30 billion, with more than rise to many different classes and types of lien 90% of the loans funded during the fi rst three priorities.
    [Show full text]
  • A Primer on Second Lien Term Loan Financings by Neil Cummings and Kirk A
    A Primer on Second Lien Term Loan Financings By Neil Cummings and Kirk A. Davenport ne of the more noticeable developments in can protect their interests in the collateral by requiring the debt markets in the last year has been second lien lenders to agree to a “silent second” lien. Othe exponential increase in the number of Second lien lenders can often be persuaded to second lien fi nancings in the senior bank loan mar- agree to this arrangement because a silent second ket. Standard & Poor’s/Leveraged Commentary & lien is better than no lien at all. In addition, under Data Team reports that second lien fi nancings raised the intercreditor agreement, in most deals, the more than $7.8 billion in the fi rst seven months of second lien lenders expressly reserve all of the 2004 alone, compared with about $3.2 billion for all rights of an unsecured creditor, subject to some of 2003. important exceptions. In this article, we discuss second lien term loans All of this sounds very simple, and fi rst and second marketed for sale in the institutional loan market, lien investors may be tempted to ask why it takes with a goal of providing both an overview of the pages of heavily negotiated intercreditor terms to product and an understanding of some of the key document a silent second lien. The answer is that business and legal issues that are often at issue. a “silent second” lien can span a range from com- In a second lien loan transaction, the second lien pletely silent to fairly quiet, and where the volume lenders hold a second priority security interest on the control is ultimately set varies from deal to deal, assets of the borrower.
    [Show full text]