Zbwleibniz-Informationszentrum
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Leijonhufvud, Axel Working Paper Hicks on time and money Diskussionsbeiträge - Serie A, No. 182 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Konstanz Suggested Citation: Leijonhufvud, Axel (1984) : Hicks on time and money, Diskussionsbeiträge - Serie A, No. 182, Universität Konstanz, Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften und Statistik, Konstanz This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/75126 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Universitat Konstanz A Fakultat fiir Wirtschaftswissenschaften und Statistik AxeljJ_eijonhufvud Hicks On Time And Money Diskussionsbeitrage Postfach 5560 SerieA— Nr. 182 D-7750 Konstanz Mai 1984 •i JUL1 19B'i HICKS ON TIME AND MONEY Axel jLeijonhufvud * Serie A - Nr. 182 Mai 1984 •Member (1983-1984), Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton. Professor of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles Standiger Gastprofessor, Universitat Konstanz. •'* Serie A: Volkswirtschaftliche Beitrage Serie B: Finanzwissenschaftliche Arbeitspapiere Serie C: Betriebswirtschaftliche Beitrage My assignment is Hicks and Keynes. It is too large for a paper: Modern macroeconomic theory has been shaped to an extraordinary degree by these two men. I .will con-fine my discussion of Hicks's role to two related themes: Time and Money. Even within these boundaries, the fallowing attempt at an 1 interpretation cannot be definitive. Among the several reasons •for this, one is germane: I know that I will learn more -from Sir John Hicks in the future. But I cannot know exactly what I will learn newt time I sit down to read or reread him. Hence today's assessment cannot be my "optimal" or final one. Rather than commit myself fully, I should retain a measure of "flexibility." In certain types of situations, it is rational to commit oneself fully or contingently. In others, where the future contingencies cannot be enumerated or their nature anticipated, one should retain flexibility. One difference between neoclassical and Keynesian theory is that the former tends to exclude, whereas the latter must include, situations of the 3 second sort. The younger Hicks is remembered for his contributions to neoclassical economics; over the years the elder Hicks has become more insistently Keynesian in this particular sense. "Every economist is familiar with the accomplishments of Hicks the Younger, whether he has read him or not. That brilliant young man was supremely successful — by reformulating utility theory, by simplifying monetary theory, by interpreting Keynes and the Glassies, and by reviving general equilibrium theory — in constructing the molds into which 40 years of subsequent 4 theoretical developments were to be cast." It is helpful to try to see the young Hicks in historical context. What went on at the London School in the early thirties appears in retrospect almost as important as what was going on in Cambridge. At LSE, the world of Anglo-American economics was being won over from the tradition of Ricardo and Marshall to modern neoclassical economics—or, in the terms of Hicks the Elder, from "plutology" to "catallactics." If Cambridge was sufficient unto its British self, Lionel Rob'bins's London School encouraged the study of the Austrian and the Lausanne schools, of the Americans and the Swedes. ("We were such 'good Europeans' in 5 London that it was Cambridge that seemed 'foreign'.") Robbins brought Hayek to London and assembled a stable of superbly talented junior people: R.6.D. Allen, Marian Bowley, John Hicks and Ursula Webb-Hicks, Nicholas Kaldor, Abba Lerner, ^'era. Smith- Lutz, Richard Sayers and G.L.S. Shackle. Most importantly, Robbins wrote the programmatic tract that, highly controversial in its time, has long since permeated the teaching of economics to the point where its main message has become a platitude (thus depriving its author o-f the Nobel Prize?) His Nature and of Economic Science argued the "scarcity" definition of economics, a definition that fundamentally changed both the scope and the content of Marshall's subject. Robbins made rational means-ends calculation the core of economics. v It was the younger Hicks that demonstrated how this Robbins program could be realized. The Hicks-Allen "Reconsideration* recast demand theory in terms of rational decision theory. Hicks's simplification of monetary theory drew Money into the orbit of marginalist calculation. "Taking step after step along a road which seemed pre-ordained as soon as one had taken the first step" in a few years time led to the 'static' parts (Chapters I- 6 VIII). of Va^ue and Capital.. These were the parts of Hicks's early work that, together with "Keynes and the Classics", were to have such a profound and pervasive influence on how economics was to be taught in the United States in the era when American economics was becoming strongly predominant. Perhaps it is more accurate to say that these parts of Hicks's work were selected by the generation of American economists led by .Paul Samuel son that were reerecting the structure of economic theory using constrained optimization building blocks. Pure decision theory, formalized as optimization subject to constraints, is essentially timeless. The choice among the 7 foreseen outcome's of alternative actions is a purely logical calculus that does not involve time in any essential way. Thus was created a durable tension between neo-Walrasian microtheory and Keynesian macrotheory that, decades later, was to culminate in crisis. This could hardly have been foreseen. As Robert Clower has 8 remarked, ... it was only natural for economists generally to proceed on the presumption that general equilibrium theory had no inherent limitations.... That any even moderately "general" economic model should Cbe incapable of representing Keynesian processes]...would hardly occur naturally to any but a very perverse mind. That the elaborate Neo-Walrasian model set out in Hicks' Val_ye and Capital, might fail tin this respect] would have seemed correspondingly incredible to any sensible person at the outset of the Neo-Walrasian Revolution. The younger Hicks knew that Time was a problem. We find him wrestling with it in almost all the parts of his early work that did not become part of the American neoclassical canon. It was to become even more of a preoccupation — an unfashionable preoccupation — for Hicks the Elder. From the first, it seems, Hicks saw it as a supreme theoretical challenge, deserving the most sustained effort, to find a mode of process analysis that would retain a role for equilibrium constructions without denying ', (or trivializing) change. In the early going, this amounted to finding a workable way between Walras and Pareto, on the one hand, and Knight and 9 Hayek on the other. Thirty or forty years later, the opposed alternatives — Arrow-Debreu vs. Shackle or Lachmann —_^ clearer and also further apart. Shackle poses the issue with uncompromising force: "... the theoretician is confronted with a 10 stark choice. He can reject rationality or time." The American Neo-Walrasians, from Paul Samuel son to Robert Lucas, have not seen this choice as at all difficult. In general, they have simply gone whole hog for Rationality, letting Time and Change be trampled underfoot in the philosophical muck as unfit food for economic thought. If forced (somehow) to choose, -it is possible that Hicks the Younger might also have opted for rational allocation theory; Hicks the Elder almost certainly would opt for economic history. In actuality, Hicks fought fifty years to maintain a conceptual middle ground. The issue may have come into focus at LSE precisely because all of the neoclassical schools were to some extent cultivated in the circle around Robbins and Hayek. Marshall had been aware of 11 the problem and had devised a method that at least partly evaded it. Hayek had worked on the construction of an equilibrium process "in time" and had found himself forced back onto 'perfect 12 foresight' assumptions. Robbins had drawn the conclusion that "(t)he main postulate of the theory of dynamics is the fact that 13 we are not certain regarding future scarcities." As matters stood around 1930, the static toolbox of economic theory was strictly applicable only to stationary, perfect foresight processes. It was not at all clear that economic theory provided any foundation for the disciplined analysis of monetary questions or business cycles. Hicks's earliest work dramatized the predicament. In particular, his remarkable 1933 paper on 14 "Equilibrium and the Cycle" drove home a point made by Knight: that in a perfect foresight equilibrium process, people would not demand cash-balances. This spelled trouble for the most sophisticated cycle theory available at the time. What became of Hayek's notion of "neutral money" as a criterion for maintaining macroeconomic equilibrium, if in equilibrium there could be no place for money, "neutral" or otherwise? The Swedish followers of Wicksell had run into similar quandaries and it was from Myrdal and Lindahl that Hicks got help 15 with the next step.