Conditional Comparative Statics
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Conditional Comparative Statics James A. Robinsony Ragnar Torvikz August 15, 2010 Abstract Why was the Black Death followed by the decline of serfdom in Western Europe but its’ intensi…cation in Eastern Europe? What explains why involvement in Atlantic trade in the Early Modern pe- riod was positively correlated with economic growth in Britain but negatively correlated in Spain? Why did frontier expansion in the 19th Century Americas go along with economic growth in the United States and economic decline in Latin America? Why do natural re- source booms seem to stimulate growth in some countries, but lead to a ‘curse’in others, and why does foreign aid sometimes seem to encour- age, other times impede economic growth? In this paper we argue that the response of economies to shocks or innovations in economic oppor- tunities depends on the nature of institutions. When institutions are strong, new opportunities or windfalls can have positive e¤ects. But when institutions are weak they can have negative e¤ects. We present a simple model to illustrate how comparative statics are conditional on the nature of institutions and show how this perspective helps to unify a large number of historical episodes and empirical studies. Keywords: JEL: Paper prepared for the 2010 World Congress of the Econometic Society. We are grateful to Marco Battaglini for his incisive comments. yHarvard University, Department of Government and Institute for Quanti- tative Social Science, 1737 Cambridge St., Cambridge MA02138. E-mail: [email protected]. zNorwegian University of Science and Technology, Department of Economics, Dragvoll, N-7491 Trondheim, Norway. E-mail: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction The most basic and fundamental exercise in economics is the comparative statics of a decision problem or an equilibrium. The equilibrium of a model determines the endogenous variables in terms of the parameters and exoge- nous variables. The empirical context of this is then often contained in the answers the equilibrium predicts to questions about what happens to the value of endogenous variables when we change an exogenous variable. In the tradition of the Arrow-Debreu model the basic set-up of a model in- cludes preferences, factor endowments, production possibilities and the struc- ture of markets. In such a speci…cation we might ask what happens to the equilibrium price of a particular produced good if the technology used to produce it improves? What happens to the price of a factor of production if its’supply increases? Perhaps the canonical comparative static results in this tradition are those of international trade theory, the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem (Stolper and Samuelson, 1941) and the Rybczynski Theorem. (Rybczynski, 1955). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem implies that (in a 2x2x2 world) if the relative price of a traded good increases the rate of return on the factor of production used intensively in the production of that good will increase. For instance, if labor and capital are the only factors of production and if the good whose price has increased intensively uses labor relative to the production tech- nology for the other good then real wages will rise and the rental rate on capital will fall. This theorem then can be used to make predictions about the implications of changes in the terms of trade and how free trade is for the functional distribution of income. The Rybczynski Theorem is equally simple and powerful. It says that (again in the 2x2x2 world) if the supply of a particular factor of production increases then the output of the good which uses this factor intensively must increase while the output of the other good must fall. These fundamental results have inspired a vast amount of research not only in economics, but also in political science. For example, the Stolper- Samuelson Theorem has dominated the way scholars of international political economy think since they have turned the implications of the theorem for income distribution into a politics of trade and globalization (Rogowski, 1990, 1 Frieden and Rogowski, 1996). Unfortunately, this parsimonious approach and others it inspires runs into many empirical problems. For instance, when faced with the issue of what is the impact of a discovery of valuable natural resources, for example oil, on national income a natural view would be that is positive and the Rybczynski Theorem might enable us to make more speci…c predictions about which sector would expand and which contract. It is of course natural to argue that additional endowments of natural resources are good since they create wealth apparently raising national income in a mechanical way and they are complementary inputs into production processes. Indeed, the conventional wisdom in US and British economic history is indeed that natural resources are good, even crucial (Wright, 1990, Wrigley, 2004, Allen, 2008). Indeed, the greater natural resources available to Britain and Western Europe has been argued to be the key reason for the divergence with China (Pomeranz, 2000). Though compelling, this view began to run aground on some empirical puzzles. The …rst set concerned the ‘Dutch Disease’and the impact of natural gas discoveries on the competitiveness of manufacturing in the Netherlands. The second set suggested a much more general negative correlation between economic growth and the importance of natural resources in the economy (Sachs and Warner, 1997). Since then such …ndings have expanded into a whole literature on the ‘resource curse’replete with detailed case studies as well as econometric results. Indeed, Sachs and Warner (2001, p. 828, 837) argue “What the studies based on the post-war experience have ar- gued is that the curse of natural resources is a demonstrable em- pirical fact, even after controlling for trends in commodity prices. Almost without exception, the resource-abundant countries have stagnated in economic growth since the early 1970s, inspir- ing the term ‘curse of natural resources.’ Empirical studies have shown that this curse is a reasonably solid fact.” This view is shared by many, for example (Auty, 2001, 840) “Since the 1960s, the resource-poor countries have outperformed the resource-rich coun- 2 tries compared by a considerable margin”. How can a resource boom reduce income? Consider another example in the spirit of the Stolper-Samuelson The- orem. After the discovery of diamonds in Kimberly in 1873 and gold in Johannesburg in 1886 the economy of South Africa boomed on the basis of its mineral sector. In the …rst half of the 20th century the terms of trade improved and the relative price of gold increased. The goldmines were very labor intensive and the government of South Africa created a whole set of labor market institutions which were speci…cally designed to mobilize labor for the mines (van der Horst, 1942, Feinstein, 2005). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem applied to a booming relative price of gold in an economic sector which was clearly very labor intensive implies that the real wage rate ought to increase. That it did not is clearly indicated by the data in Wilson (1972) which shows that in fact the real wages of (black) gold miners fell over this period. Indeed, in 1970 they were 20% lower than they had been in 1911. How can booming terms of trade reduce real wages in labor intensive sectors? Of course it is well known that Theorems such as those of Stolper and Samuelson and Rybczynski are not general. As long ago as 1958 Bhag- wati proposed the notion of ‘immizerizing growth’ where a country could become worse o¤ when it got a positive endowment shock because of severe deterioration in the terms of trade. In addition, it is clear from the Debreu- Mantel-Sonnenschein Theorem (Debreu, 1974, Mantel, 1974, Sonnenschein, 1973, 1974) that such simple comparative static results are not robust and Opp, Sonnenschein and Tombaz (2007) show one can build a non-pathological model where there is a ‘Reverse Rybczynski Theorem’(see also Kemp and Shimomura, 2002). Nevertheless, there is a tendency to regard such demonstrations as theo- retically interesting but probably not right empirically (Hildenbrand, 1994). In addition, it seems unlikely that the forces that generate the Reverse Ry- bczynski Theorem are what also cause the types of empirical phenomenon we describe above even though if this theorem holds then factor growth is immizerizing (Opp, Sonnenschein and Tombaz, 2007, Proposition 5). For one thing many of the negative correlations between resource booms and economic growth take place in the context of increases in the prices of the re- 3 sources and improving terms of trade, which means they cannot be generated by immizerizing growth type e¤ects. So what might make resources a curse? Why might a relative price in- crease in a labor intensive economic sector drive down the real wage? Though these …ndings are provocative, the discussion of the impact of resources on US growth suggests that it is not plausible that resources are always a curse in every circumstance. In addition, terms of trade booms don’talways drive down real wages. In these and many other contexts we argue that one cannot hope for clean unconditional comparative statics. In this paper we develop the simple idea that the comparative statics of an equilibrium are often conditional on the institutional equilibrium of a society, a phenomenon we call conditional com- parative statics.1 The di¤erence between a country like Sierra Leone, which experienced a diamond boom alongside a contraction of GDP per-capita and Botswana which experienced the opposite is the initial institutional equilib- rium which fundamentally shaped the economic and political incentives that the diamonds created and thus their economic impact. We develop a simple model which illustrates these ideas. A large literature in political economy and development has of course em- phasized the importance of the institutional environment for thinking about di¤erences in income levels, development paths and public policy outcomes.