Conditional Comparative Statics

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Conditional Comparative Statics Conditional Comparative Statics James A. Robinsony Ragnar Torvikz August 15, 2010 Abstract Why was the Black Death followed by the decline of serfdom in Western Europe but its’ intensi…cation in Eastern Europe? What explains why involvement in Atlantic trade in the Early Modern pe- riod was positively correlated with economic growth in Britain but negatively correlated in Spain? Why did frontier expansion in the 19th Century Americas go along with economic growth in the United States and economic decline in Latin America? Why do natural re- source booms seem to stimulate growth in some countries, but lead to a ‘curse’in others, and why does foreign aid sometimes seem to encour- age, other times impede economic growth? In this paper we argue that the response of economies to shocks or innovations in economic oppor- tunities depends on the nature of institutions. When institutions are strong, new opportunities or windfalls can have positive e¤ects. But when institutions are weak they can have negative e¤ects. We present a simple model to illustrate how comparative statics are conditional on the nature of institutions and show how this perspective helps to unify a large number of historical episodes and empirical studies. Keywords: JEL: Paper prepared for the 2010 World Congress of the Econometic Society. We are grateful to Marco Battaglini for his incisive comments. yHarvard University, Department of Government and Institute for Quanti- tative Social Science, 1737 Cambridge St., Cambridge MA02138. E-mail: [email protected]. zNorwegian University of Science and Technology, Department of Economics, Dragvoll, N-7491 Trondheim, Norway. E-mail: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction The most basic and fundamental exercise in economics is the comparative statics of a decision problem or an equilibrium. The equilibrium of a model determines the endogenous variables in terms of the parameters and exoge- nous variables. The empirical context of this is then often contained in the answers the equilibrium predicts to questions about what happens to the value of endogenous variables when we change an exogenous variable. In the tradition of the Arrow-Debreu model the basic set-up of a model in- cludes preferences, factor endowments, production possibilities and the struc- ture of markets. In such a speci…cation we might ask what happens to the equilibrium price of a particular produced good if the technology used to produce it improves? What happens to the price of a factor of production if its’supply increases? Perhaps the canonical comparative static results in this tradition are those of international trade theory, the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem (Stolper and Samuelson, 1941) and the Rybczynski Theorem. (Rybczynski, 1955). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem implies that (in a 2x2x2 world) if the relative price of a traded good increases the rate of return on the factor of production used intensively in the production of that good will increase. For instance, if labor and capital are the only factors of production and if the good whose price has increased intensively uses labor relative to the production tech- nology for the other good then real wages will rise and the rental rate on capital will fall. This theorem then can be used to make predictions about the implications of changes in the terms of trade and how free trade is for the functional distribution of income. The Rybczynski Theorem is equally simple and powerful. It says that (again in the 2x2x2 world) if the supply of a particular factor of production increases then the output of the good which uses this factor intensively must increase while the output of the other good must fall. These fundamental results have inspired a vast amount of research not only in economics, but also in political science. For example, the Stolper- Samuelson Theorem has dominated the way scholars of international political economy think since they have turned the implications of the theorem for income distribution into a politics of trade and globalization (Rogowski, 1990, 1 Frieden and Rogowski, 1996). Unfortunately, this parsimonious approach and others it inspires runs into many empirical problems. For instance, when faced with the issue of what is the impact of a discovery of valuable natural resources, for example oil, on national income a natural view would be that is positive and the Rybczynski Theorem might enable us to make more speci…c predictions about which sector would expand and which contract. It is of course natural to argue that additional endowments of natural resources are good since they create wealth apparently raising national income in a mechanical way and they are complementary inputs into production processes. Indeed, the conventional wisdom in US and British economic history is indeed that natural resources are good, even crucial (Wright, 1990, Wrigley, 2004, Allen, 2008). Indeed, the greater natural resources available to Britain and Western Europe has been argued to be the key reason for the divergence with China (Pomeranz, 2000). Though compelling, this view began to run aground on some empirical puzzles. The …rst set concerned the ‘Dutch Disease’and the impact of natural gas discoveries on the competitiveness of manufacturing in the Netherlands. The second set suggested a much more general negative correlation between economic growth and the importance of natural resources in the economy (Sachs and Warner, 1997). Since then such …ndings have expanded into a whole literature on the ‘resource curse’replete with detailed case studies as well as econometric results. Indeed, Sachs and Warner (2001, p. 828, 837) argue “What the studies based on the post-war experience have ar- gued is that the curse of natural resources is a demonstrable em- pirical fact, even after controlling for trends in commodity prices. Almost without exception, the resource-abundant countries have stagnated in economic growth since the early 1970s, inspir- ing the term ‘curse of natural resources.’ Empirical studies have shown that this curse is a reasonably solid fact.” This view is shared by many, for example (Auty, 2001, 840) “Since the 1960s, the resource-poor countries have outperformed the resource-rich coun- 2 tries compared by a considerable margin”. How can a resource boom reduce income? Consider another example in the spirit of the Stolper-Samuelson The- orem. After the discovery of diamonds in Kimberly in 1873 and gold in Johannesburg in 1886 the economy of South Africa boomed on the basis of its mineral sector. In the …rst half of the 20th century the terms of trade improved and the relative price of gold increased. The goldmines were very labor intensive and the government of South Africa created a whole set of labor market institutions which were speci…cally designed to mobilize labor for the mines (van der Horst, 1942, Feinstein, 2005). The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem applied to a booming relative price of gold in an economic sector which was clearly very labor intensive implies that the real wage rate ought to increase. That it did not is clearly indicated by the data in Wilson (1972) which shows that in fact the real wages of (black) gold miners fell over this period. Indeed, in 1970 they were 20% lower than they had been in 1911. How can booming terms of trade reduce real wages in labor intensive sectors? Of course it is well known that Theorems such as those of Stolper and Samuelson and Rybczynski are not general. As long ago as 1958 Bhag- wati proposed the notion of ‘immizerizing growth’ where a country could become worse o¤ when it got a positive endowment shock because of severe deterioration in the terms of trade. In addition, it is clear from the Debreu- Mantel-Sonnenschein Theorem (Debreu, 1974, Mantel, 1974, Sonnenschein, 1973, 1974) that such simple comparative static results are not robust and Opp, Sonnenschein and Tombaz (2007) show one can build a non-pathological model where there is a ‘Reverse Rybczynski Theorem’(see also Kemp and Shimomura, 2002). Nevertheless, there is a tendency to regard such demonstrations as theo- retically interesting but probably not right empirically (Hildenbrand, 1994). In addition, it seems unlikely that the forces that generate the Reverse Ry- bczynski Theorem are what also cause the types of empirical phenomenon we describe above even though if this theorem holds then factor growth is immizerizing (Opp, Sonnenschein and Tombaz, 2007, Proposition 5). For one thing many of the negative correlations between resource booms and economic growth take place in the context of increases in the prices of the re- 3 sources and improving terms of trade, which means they cannot be generated by immizerizing growth type e¤ects. So what might make resources a curse? Why might a relative price in- crease in a labor intensive economic sector drive down the real wage? Though these …ndings are provocative, the discussion of the impact of resources on US growth suggests that it is not plausible that resources are always a curse in every circumstance. In addition, terms of trade booms don’talways drive down real wages. In these and many other contexts we argue that one cannot hope for clean unconditional comparative statics. In this paper we develop the simple idea that the comparative statics of an equilibrium are often conditional on the institutional equilibrium of a society, a phenomenon we call conditional com- parative statics.1 The di¤erence between a country like Sierra Leone, which experienced a diamond boom alongside a contraction of GDP per-capita and Botswana which experienced the opposite is the initial institutional equilib- rium which fundamentally shaped the economic and political incentives that the diamonds created and thus their economic impact. We develop a simple model which illustrates these ideas. A large literature in political economy and development has of course em- phasized the importance of the institutional environment for thinking about di¤erences in income levels, development paths and public policy outcomes.
Recommended publications
  • Aggregate Comparative Statics
    This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and education use, including for instruction at the authors institution and sharing with colleagues. Other uses, including reproduction and distribution, or selling or licensing copies, or posting to personal, institutional or third party websites are prohibited. In most cases authors are permitted to post their version of the article (e.g. in Word or Tex form) to their personal website or institutional repository. Authors requiring further information regarding Elsevier’s archiving and manuscript policies are encouraged to visit: http://www.elsevier.com/authorsrights Author's personal copy Games and Economic Behavior 81 (2013) 27–49 Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect Games and Economic Behavior www.elsevier.com/locate/geb Aggregate comparative statics ✩ ∗ Daron Acemoglu a, , Martin Kaae Jensen b a Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, United States b Department of Economics, University of Birmingham, United Kingdom article info abstract Article history: In aggregative games, each player’s payoff depends on her own actions and an aggregate of Received 31 August 2011 the actions of all the players. Many common games in industrial organization, political Available online 23 April 2013 economy, public economics, and macroeconomics can be cast as aggregative games. This paper provides a general and tractable framework for comparative static results in JEL classification: aggregative games. We focus on two classes of games: (1) aggregative games with strategic C60 C72 substitutes and (2) nice aggregative games, where payoff functions are continuous and concave in own strategies.
    [Show full text]
  • Robust Comparative Statics  Susan Athey, Paul Milgrom, and John Roberts
    Robust Comparative Statics Susan Athey, Paul Milgrom, and John Roberts DRAFT ONLY - DO NOT CITE OR CIRCULATE Comments Welcome This Draft: October, 1998 OUTLINE Chapter 0: Introduction. Part I: Univariate Optimization Problems Chapter 1: An Introduction to the Theory. Chapter 2: Single Variable Problems with Separable Contexts. Chapter 3: Single Variable Problems with non-Separable Contexts. Part II: Multivariate Optimization Problems. Chapter 4: Multivariate Comparative Statics on Product Sets. Chapter 5: Elementary Lattice Theory and Comparative Statics on Lattices. Part III: Stochastic Optimization Problems. Chapter 6: Supermodularity and monotonicity. Chapter 7: Log-Supermodularity. Chapter 8: Single Crossing Properties. Part IV: Equilibrium Models. Chapter 9: One dimensional models. Chapter 10: Multidimensional models. Chapter 11: Conclusion. 2 0 Introduction This monograph describes a new approach to comparative statics analysis that has developed rapidly in the past several years. Comparative statics – the study of how the solutions of an economic model change as the model parameters and specification are changed – is important because (1) most of the testable predictions of economic theory are comparative statics predictions and (2) many economic equilibrium analyses are built from comparative statics analyses of the model’s components. The results of comparative statics analyses thus form the basis for much of our understanding of the behavior of the economy. Comparative statics predictions can be qualitative or quantitative, but the focus of the new methods is on the former. Typical examples of qualitative predictions include assertions that increasing employment taxes or a minimum wage will increase unemployment, or that relaxing trade restrictions will cause industrial pollution to fall in developed countries and rise in less developed ones.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalist Spirit and the Markets: Why Income Inequality Matters
    School of Business Economics Division Capitalist Spirit and the Markets: Why Income Inequality Matters Aristotelis Boukouras, University of Leicester Working Paper No. 16/16 Capitalist Spirit and the Markets: Why Income Inequality Matters Aristotelis Boukouras∗ October 30, 2016 Abstract I develop a simple static general equilibrium model with capitalist-spirit prefer- ences and prices set by firm owners (entrepreneurs). The model’s pure symmetric Nash equilibria differ markedly from the canonical model: (i) A positive output gap and unemployment may emerge in equilibrium, despite the absence of price rigidities or information asymmetries. (ii) Income and wealth inequality affect equilibrium prices and employment. (iii) The model generates ambiguous com- parative statics. Specifically, an increase in inequality of either type may reduce employment and increase the output gap of the economy, while productivity re- ductions may have the opposite effect. As a result, minimum wage policies may increase employment. These results provide some justification for a number of arguments used in public debates. Keywords: capitalist spirit, general equilibrium, income distribution, income inequal- ity, minimum wage, output gap, unemployment, wealth distribution, wealth inequality JEL Classification: D31, D63, E24, E25 ∗University of Leicester, AC206, Astely Clarke Building, University Road 1, LE1 7RH, Leicester, UK, email: [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Many western economies, including US, UK and the European Union, suffer from weak growth, low inflation and extremely low, or even negative, interest rates in the aftermath of the Great Recession. Summers (2014a, 2014b) calls this phenomenon “secular stagna- tion” and many economists agree that it is a result of weak aggregate demand (Summers, 2014a).
    [Show full text]
  • Global Comparative Statics in General Equilibrium: Model Building from Theoretical Foundations
    Global Comparative Statics in General Equilibrium: model building from theoretical foundations James R. Markusen Department of Economics University of Colorado, Boulder Abstract International trade economists made seminal contributions to general equilibrium theory, moving away from an emphasis on existence of equilibrium to algebraic formulations which enabled us to characterize key relationships between parameters and variables, such as that between tariffs and domestic factor prices and welfare. But the analysis remained limited in value for policy evaluation: the analysis was local, it provided only qualitative results, it was limited to very small models, and strictly interior solutions had to be assumed. The contribution of this paper is pedagogic and methodological, providing a primer for those wishing to do or teach general- equilibrium counterfactuals on computable general-equilibrium (CGE) or structural econometric models. I show how the tools from early local comparative statics analyses can be generalized via the use of Shepard’s lemma, duality, complementarity and the Karush-Kuhn-Tucker theorem into a global, quantitative analysis of large changes in high-dimension models which also allows for regime changes and corner solutions. I then show how the resulting non-linear complementarity problem directly translates into a numerical model using GAMS (general algebraic modeling system). The paper concludes with two examples: (a) comparison of a tax versus a real trade/transactions cost, (b) comparison of a tax versus a quantitative restriction such as a quota or license. Keywords: duality, complementarity, KKT conditions, global comparative statics, corner solutions, GAMS JEJ codes: F23, D50, D58 This paper is a re-orientated and much expanded version of a paper prepared for a special issue of the International Journal of Economic Theory in honor of Ronald W.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Statics and Heterogeneity
    Towson University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 2016-01 Comparative Statics and Heterogeneity by Finn Christensen October, 2016 © 2016 by Author. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Comparative Statics and Heterogeneity Finn Christensen Towson University October 7, 2016 Abstract This paper elucidates the role played by the heterogeneity of interactions between the endogenous variables of a model in determining the model’sbehav- ior. It is known that comparative statics are well-behaved if these interactions are relatively small, but the formal condition imposed on the Jacobian which typically captures this idea–diagonaldominance–ignores the distribution of the interaction terms. I provide a new condition on the Jacobian–mean positive dominance–which better captures a trade-o¤ between the size and heterogeneity of interaction terms. In accord with Samuelson’s(1947) correspondence princi- ple, I also show that mean positive dominance yields stability and uniqueness results. Applications are provided to optimization problems, di¤erentiable games, and competitive exchange economies. Keywords: comparative statics, heterogeneity, mean positive dominance, correspondence principle, B matrix, stability, uniqueness, optimization, dif- ferentiable games, Cournot oligopoly, general equilibrium JEL Classi…cation: D11 1 Introduction Comparative statics analysis is complicated by interactions between endogenous vari- ables. To see this, consider a game-theoretic context where the total equilibrium e¤ect of a positive shock on a player’s action can be decomposed into a partial e¤ect and an interactions e¤ect. The partial e¤ect is the increase in the player’saction holding constant all other players’actions.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics, Finance and Real Estate School of Business Montclair State University
    Department of Economics, Finance and Real Estate School of Business Montclair State University ECON 317 Course Outline Instructor: Ram Sewak Dubey Spring 2016 Office Hours: M W 1-2 pm, M 6-7pm Office: 553, School of Business Phone: 973-655-7778 Email: [email protected] Lecture Schedule: M W 10-11:15 am Location: School of Business 011 I COURSE NUMBER: ECON 317 II COURSE NAME: Elementary Mathematical Techniques for Economics III CREDIT HOURS: 3 Semester Hours IV PREREQUISITE: ECON 206 / ECON 207 and ECON 208; OR permission of the Depart- ment V CATALOG DESCRIPTION OF THE COURSE: Introduction to elementary concepts of mathematics used in economics. Formulation of economic theory in mathematical language. Application of optimization techniques in economic models. VI AIMS OF THE COURSE: The principal objective of this course is to gain facility in ap- plying the mathematical techniques to economic analysis. VII COURSE LEARNING GOALS: After completion of this course students will be able to A. learn the basic mathematical methods that have become indispensable for a proper under- standing of the current economic literature. B. describe economic / market outcomes commonly observed in mathematical model and solve for the observable variables in terms of the parameters / fundamentals of the model. C. analyze, both qualitatively and quantitatively, how the market outcomes will change when there is a change in the fundamentals of the economy. D. solve for the values of the decision variables in the optimization exercises faced by the individuals (consumers) and firms. 1 E. be better prepared for the required ECON 420 Applied Econometrics and ECON 438 Advanced Seminar in Economics courses.
    [Show full text]
  • Math Handout
    ECONOMICS 100A MATHEMATICAL HANDOUT Fall 2003 α abd β abc γ abc µ abc Mark Machina A. CALCULUS REVIEW1 Derivatives, Partial Derivatives and the Chain Rule You should already know what a derivative is. We’ll use the expressions ƒ6(x) or dƒ(x)/dx for the derivative of the function ƒ(x). To indicate the derivative of ƒ(x) evaluated at the point x = x*, we’ll use the expressions ƒ6(x*) or dƒ(x*)/dx. When we have a function of more than one variable, we can consider its derivatives with respect to each of the variables, that is, each of its partial derivatives. We use the expressions: ∂ƒ(x1,x2)/∂x1 and ƒ1(x1,x2) interchangeably to denote the partial derivative of ƒ(x1,x2) with respect to its first argument (that is, with respect to x1). To calculate this, just hold x2 fixed (treat it as a constant) so that ƒ(x1,x2) may be thought of as a function of x1 alone, and differentiate it with respect to x1. The notation for partial derivatives with respect to x2 (or in the general case, with respect to xi) is analogous. 2 For example, if ƒ(x1,x2) = x1 ⋅x2 + 3x1, we have: 2 ∂ƒ(x1,x2)/∂x1 = 2x1·x2 + 3 and ∂ƒ(x1,x2)/∂x2 = x1 The normal vector of a function ƒ(x1,...,xn) at the point (x1,...,xn) is just the vector (i.e., ordered list) of its n partial derivatives at that point, that is, the vector: ⎛⎞∂∂ƒ(xx11 ,...,nn ) ƒ( xx ,..., ) ∂ ƒ( xx 1 ,..., n ) ⎜⎟, ,...,= () ƒ11 (x ,...,xxxnnnn ), ƒ 21 ( ,..., ),..., ƒ ( xx 1 ,..., ) ⎝⎠∂∂xx12 ∂ xn Normal vectors play a key role in the conditions for unconstrained and constrained optimization.
    [Show full text]
  • ECON2285: Mathematical Economics
    ECON2285: Mathematical Economics Yulei Luo FBE, HKU September 2, 2018 Luo, Y. (FBE, HKU) ME September2,2018 1/44 Comparative Statics and The Concept of Derivative Comparative Statics is concerned with the comparison of different equilibrium states that are associated with different sets of values of parameters and exogenous variables. When the value of some parameter or exogenous variable that is associated with an initial equilibrium changes, we can get a new equilibrium. The question posted in the Comparative Statics analysis is: How would the new equilibrium compare with the old one? Note that in the CS analysis, we don’tconcern with the process of adjustment of the variables; we merely compare the initial equilibrium state with the final equilibrium. Luo, Y. (FBE, HKU) ME September2,2018 2/44 (Continued.) The problem under consideration is essentially one of finding a rate of change: the rate of change of the equilibrium value of an endogenous variable with respect to the change in a particular parameter or exogenous variable. Hence, the concept of derivative is the key factor in comparative statics analysis. We will study the rate of change of any variable y in response to a change in another variable x: y = f (x). (1) Note that in the CS analysis context, y represents the equilibrium value of an endogenous variable, and x represents some parameter or exogenous variable. The difference quotient. We use the symbol D to denote the change from one point, say x0, to another point, say x1. Thus Dx = x1 x0. When x changes from x0 to x0 + Dx, the value of the function y = f (x) changes from f (x0) to f (x0 + Dx).
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 1: Introduction to Comparative Statics
    Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences Ec 121a KC Border Theory of Value Fall 2020 Lecture 1: Introduction to Comparative Statics The models we study in this class are largely qualitative. Here is a simple example of what I mean by a qualitative model. 1.1 Supply and Demand in a Single Market You may recall from Ec 11 that a demand curve expresses a relation between quantities and prices for buyers. This being economics, there are at least two interpretations of the demand curve. The Walrasian demand curve [?] gives the quantity that buyers are willing to buy as a function of the price they pay. As a function it maps prices to quantities. The Marshallian demand curve [?] gives for each quantity the price at which buyers are willing to buy that quantity. This is not to be confused with the all-or-nothing demand curve. Since the time of Marshall it has been traditional to draw demand and supply curves with quantity as the abscissa, but I usually do not. Instead, I usually put price on the horizontal axis, since the theories we shall discuss treat price as the independent variable from the point of view of buyers and sellers. Fortunately, the sign of the slope is the same either way. See Figures ?? and ??. • The definition of a market and the Law of One Price. 1.2 Comparative Statics of Supply and Demand The model has these pieces: • The (Walrasian) demand curve gives the quantity that buyers are willing to buy as a function of the price they pay: D(p) is the quantity demanded at price p.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise and Fall of General Laws of Capitalism∗
    The Rise and Fall of General Laws of Capitalism Daron Acemogluy James A. Robinsonz August 2014. Abstract Thomas Piketty’s recent book, Capital in the Twenty First Century, follows in the tradition of the great classical economists, Malthus, Ricardo and Marx, in formulating “general laws” to diagnose and predict the dynamics of inequality. We argue that all of these general laws are unhelpful as a guide to understand the past or predict the future, because they ignore the central role of political and economic institutions in shaping the evolution of technology and the distribution of resources in a society. Using the economic and political histories of South Africa and Sweden, we illustrate not only that the focus on the share of top incomes gives a misleading characterization of the key determinants of societal inequality, but also that inequality dynamics are closely linked to institutional factors and there are endogenous evolution, much more than the forces emphasized in Piketty’s book, such as the gap between the interest rate and the growth rate. JEL Classification: P16, P48, O20. Keywords: Capitalism, Inequality, Institutions. We thank David Autor, Bengt Holmstrom, Amy Finkelstein, Chad Jones, Naomi Lamoureux, Kalle Moene, Joel Mokyr, Suresh Naidu, Jim Poterba, Matthew Rognlie, Ragnar Torvik, Laurence Wilse-Samson and Timo- thy Taylor for their comments and Pascual Restrepo for extensive discussions, comments and superb research assistance. yMassachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics, E52-380, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambridge MA 02142; E-mail: [email protected]. zHarvard University, Department of Government, IQSS, 1737 Cambridge St., N309, Cambridge MA 02138; E-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture Notes for Mathematical Economics
    Lecture Notes1 Mathematical Ecnomics Guoqiang TIAN Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, Texas 77843 ([email protected]) This version: August 2018 1The lecture notes are only for the purpose of my teaching and convenience of my students in class, please not put them online or pass to any others. Contents 1 The Nature of Mathematical Economics 1 1.1 Economics and Mathematical Economics . 1 1.2 Advantages of Mathematical Approach . 2 2 Economic Models 4 2.1 Ingredients of a Mathematical Model . 4 2.2 The Real-Number System . 4 2.3 The Concept of Sets . 5 2.4 Relations and Functions . 7 2.5 Types of Function . 8 2.6 Functions of Two or More Independent Variables . 10 2.7 Levels of Generality . 10 3 Equilibrium Analysis in Economics 12 3.1 The Meaning of Equilibrium . 12 3.2 Partial Market Equilibrium - A Linear Model . 12 3.3 Partial Market Equilibrium - A Nonlinear Model . 14 3.4 General Market Equilibrium . 16 3.5 Equilibrium in National-Income Analysis . 19 4 Linear Models and Matrix Algebra 20 4.1 Matrix and Vectors . 20 4.2 Matrix Operations . 23 4.3 Linear Dependance of Vectors . 25 4.4 Commutative, Associative, and Distributive Laws . 26 i 4.5 Identity Matrices and Null Matrices . 27 4.6 Transposes and Inverses . 29 5 Linear Models and Matrix Algebra (Continued) 32 5.1 Conditions for Nonsingularity of a Matrix . 32 5.2 Test of Nonsingularity by Use of Determinant . 34 5.3 Basic Properties of Determinants . 38 5.4 Finding the Inverse Matrix .
    [Show full text]
  • Monotone Comparative Statics: Geometric Approach
    J Optim Theory Appl (2008) 137: 641–673 DOI 10.1007/s10957-007-9339-1 Monotone Comparative Statics: Geometric Approach B.H. Strulovici · T.A. Weber Published online: 29 December 2007 © Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2007 Abstract We consider the comparative statics of solutions to parameterized opti- mization problems. A geometric method is developed for finding a vector field that, at each point in the parameter space, indicates a direction in which monotone com- parative statics obtains. Given such a vector field, we provide sufficient conditions under which the problem can be reparameterized on the parameter space (or a subset thereof) in a way that guarantees monotone comparative statics. A key feature of our method is that it does not require the feasible set to be a lattice and works in the ab- sence of the standard quasi-supermodularity and single-crossing assumptions on the objective function. We illustrate our approach with a variety of applications. Keywords Change of parameters · Parameterized optimization problems · Single-crossing · Supermodularity 1 Introduction In many model-based optimization problems, important insights can be derived by comparing solutions for different parameter values. The model’s parameters are ex- Communicated by D.G. Luenberger. We are grateful to Kenneth Arrow, Darrell Duffie, David Luenberger, Paul Milgrom, John Quah, and Pete Veinott for helpful comments. Research in part supported by a David Morgenthaler II Faculty Scholar Award. B.H. Strulovici Nuffield College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK e-mail: [email protected] T.A. Weber () Department of Management Science and Engineering, 442 Terman Engineering Center, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305-4026, USA e-mail: [email protected] 642 J Optim Theory Appl (2008) 137: 641–673 ogenously specified and often can be varied for analysis purposes, while its variables, which constitute the building blocks for its predictions, are endogenously determined by (i) imposed model relations and (ii) parameter values.
    [Show full text]