Reading Economic Geography

Edited by

Trevor J. Barnes, Jamie Peck, Eric Sheppard, and Adam Tickell

Reading Economic Geography Blackwell Readers in Geography

Each volume in the Blackwell Readers in Geography series provides an authorita- tive and comprehensive collection of essential readings from geography’s main fields of study, edited by the discipline’s leading authorities. Designed to complement the Blackwell Companions to Geography series, each volume represents an unparal- leled resource in its own right and will provide the ideal platform for course use.

Published

The Blackwell City Reader Edited by Gary Bridge and Sophie Watson The Blackwell Cultural Economy Reader Edited by Ash Amin and Nigel Thrift Reading Economic Geography Edited by Trevor J. Barnes, Jamie Peck, Eric Sheppard, and Adam Tickell Reading Economic Geography

Edited by

Trevor J. Barnes, Jamie Peck, Eric Sheppard, and Adam Tickell Editorial material and organization © 2004 by Blackwell Publishing Ltd

350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148-5020, USA 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK 550 Swanston Street, Carlton, Victoria 3053, Australia

The right of Trevor J. Barnes, Jamie Peck, Eric Sheppard, and Adam Tickell to be identified as the Authors of the Editorial Material in this Work has been asserted in accordance with the UK Copyright, Designs, and Patents Act 1988.

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, except as permitted by the UK Copyright, Designs, and Patents Act 1988, without the prior permission of the publisher.

First published 2004 by Blackwell Publishing Ltd

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Reading economic geography / edited by Trevor J. Barnes . . . [et al.]. p. cm. – (Blackwell readers in geography) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-631-23553-1 – ISBN 0-631-23554-X 1. Economic geography. I. Barnes, Trevor J. II. Series.

HF1025.R275 2003 330.9–dc21 2002155058

A catalogue record for this title is available from the British Library.

Set in Sabon 10/12 by SNP Best-set Typesetter Ltd., Hong Kong Printed and bound in the United Kingdom by TJ International, Padstow, Cornwall

For further information on Blackwell Publishing, visit our website: http://www.blackwellpublishing.com Dedicated to the memory of Robert G. Peck 1936 –2002 The Editors

Trevor J. Barnes is Professor of Geography at the University of British Columbia. His previous publications include A Companion to Economic Geography (co-edited with Eric Sheppard, Blackwell, 2001).

Jamie Peck is Professor of Geography and Sociology at the University of Wisconsin–Madison. He is the author of Work-place (1996) and Workfare States (2001) and co-editor with Henry Yeung of Remaking the Global Economy: Economic–Geographical Perspectives (2003).

Eric Sheppard is Professor of Geography at the . He is the author of The Capitalist Space Economy and A World of Difference and the co-editor with Trevor Barnes of A Companion to Economic Geography (Blackwell, 2001) and with Robert McMaster of Scale and Geographic Inquiry (Blackwell, 2003).

Adam Tickwell is Professor of Human Geography at the University of Bristol. He is editor of Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers and review editor of the Journal of Economic Geography. Contents

Acknowledgments x Introduction: Reading Economic Geography 1

Part I: Worlds of Economic Geography 11 Introduction: Paradigms Lost 13 1 The Difference a Generation Makes 19 David Harvey 2 Industry and Space: A Sympathetic Critique of Radical Research 29 Andrew Sayer 3 An Institutionalist Perspective on Regional Economic Development 48 Ash Amin 4 Refiguring the Economic in Economic Geography 59 Nigel J. Thrift and Kris Olds 5 The Economy, Stupid! Industrial Policy Discourse and the Body Economic 72 J. K. Gibson-Graham

Part II: Realms of Production 89 Introduction: Problematizing Production 91 6 Is There a Service Economy? The Changing Capitalist Division of Labor 97 Richard A. Walker 7 Uneven Development: Social Change and Spatial Divisions of Labor 111 Doreen Massey 8 Flexible Production Systems and Regional Development: The Rise of New Industrial Spaces in North America and Western Europe 125 Allen J. Scott viii CONTENTS

9 Global–Local Tensions: Firms and States in the Global Space-Economy 137 Peter Dicken 10 The Politics of Relocation: Gender, Nationality, and Value in a Mexican Maquiladora 151 M. W. Wright

Part III: Resource Worlds 167 Introduction: Producing Nature 169 11 Nature, Economy, and the Cultural Politics of Theory: The “War Against the Seals” in the Bering Sea, 1870–1911 175 Noel Castree 12 Modernity and Hybridity: Nature, Regeneracionismo, and the Production of the Spanish Waterscape, 1890–1930 189 Erik Swyngedouw 13 Oil as Money: The Devil’s Excrement and the Spectacle of Black Gold 205 Michael J. Watts 14 Converting the Wetlands, Engendering the Environment: The Intersection of Gender with Agrarian Change in The Gambia 220 Judith Carney 15 Nourishing Networks: Alternative Geographies of Food 235 Sarah Whatmore and Lorraine Thorne

Part IV: Social Worlds 249 Introduction: Bringing in the Social 251 16 Bringing the Qualitative State back into Economic Geography 257 Phillip M. O’Neill 17 Territories, Flows, and Hierarchies in the Global Economy 271 Michael Storper 18 Contesting Works Closures in Western Europe’s Old Industrial Regions: Defending Place or Betraying Class? 290 Ray Hudson and David Sadler 19 Class and Gender Relations in the Local Labor Market and the Local State 304 Ruth Fincher 20 Thinking through Work: Gender, Power, and Space 315 Linda McDowell

Part V: Spaces of Circulation 329 Introduction: From Distance to Connectivity 331 21 The End of Geography or the Explosion of Place? Conceptualizing Space, Place, and Information Technology 336 Stephen Graham CONTENTS ix

22 Best Practice? Geography, Learning, and the Institutional Limits to Strong Convergence 350 Meric S. Gertler 23 Blood, Thicker than Water: Interpersonal Relations and Taiwanese Investment in Southern China 362 Y. Hsing 24 From Registered Nurse to Registered Nanny: Discursive Geographies of Filipina Domestic Workers in Vancouver, BC 375 Geraldine Pratt 25 Discourse and Practice in Human Geography 389 Erica Schoenberger

Consolidated bibliography 403 Index 439 Acknowledgments

The editors and publisher wish to thank the following for permission to use copyright material:

1. Harvey, D. 2000. “The difference a generation makes.” In Spaces of Hope, pp. 3–8, 11–18. Edinburgh University Press. Copyright © 2000 David Harvey. Reprinted with permission of Edinburgh University Press. Copyright © Edinburgh University Press. 2. Sayer, A. 1985. “Industry and space: A sympathetic critique.” Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 3 (1), 3–7, 9–23. Copyright © 1985 Pion Limited. Reprinted by permission of the publisher. 3. Amin, A. 1999. “An institutionalist perspective on regional economic devel- opment.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 23, 365–78. Copyright © 1999 Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishing Ltd. 4. Thrift, N. and K. Olds. 1996. “Refiguring the economic in economic geogra- phy.” Progress in Human Geography, 20, 311–22, 330–38. Copyright © 1996 Arnold. 5. Gibson-Graham, J. K. 1996. “The economy stupid! Industrial policy discourse and the body economic.” In The End of Capitalism (as we knew it), pp. 92–119. Oxford: Blackwell. Copyright © 1996 Julie Graham and Katherine Gibson. Reprinted by permission of the authors. 6. Walker, R. 1985. “Is there a service economy? The changing capitalist division of labor.” Science & Society, 49, 42–83. 7. Massey, D. 1994. “Uneven development: Social change and spatial divisions of labour.” In Space, Place and Gender, ed. D. Massey, pp 86–114. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press. Copyright © Doreen Massey. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS xi

8. Scott, A. J. 1988. “Flexible production systems and regional development: The rise of the new industrial spaces North America and Western Europe.” Inter- national Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 12 (2), 171–83. Copyright © Edward Arnold. Reprinted with permission of Blackwell Publishers. 9. Dicken, P. 1994. “Global–local tensions: Firms and states in the global space- economy.” Economic Geography, 70 (1), 101–28. Copyright © 1994 Clark University. 10. Wright, M. W. 1999. “The politics of relocation: Gender, nationality, and value in a Mexican maquiladora.” Environment and Planning A, 31, pp. 1601–17. Copyright © Pion Limited. Reprinted by permission of the publisher. 11. Castree, N. 1997. “Nature, economy and the cultural politics of theory: The ‘war against the seals’ in the Bering Sea, 1870–1911.” Geoforum, 28 (1), 1–15, 17–20. Copyright © 1997 Elsevier Science. Reprinted with permission of Elsevier Science. 12. Swyngedouw, E. 1999. “Modernity and hybridity: Nature, Regeneracionismo, and the production of the Spanish waterscape, 1890–1930.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 89 (3), 443–54, 456–65. Copyright © 1999 Association of American Geographers. Reprinted with permission of Blackwell Publishers. 13. Watts, M. 1994. “Oil as money: The Devil’s excrement and the spectacle of black gold.” In Money Power and Space, eds. S. Corbridge, R. Martin and N. Thrift, pp. 406–22, 430–35, 438–45. Oxford: Blackwell. Copyright © 1994 Blackwell Publishing. 14. Carney, J. 1993. “Converting the wetlands, engendering the environment: The intersection of gender with agrarian change in The Gambia.” Economic Geography, 69, 329–48. Copyright © 1993 Clark University. 15. Whatmore, S. and L. Thorne. 1997. “Nourishing Networks: Alternative geographies of food.” In Globalising Food: Agrarian Questions and Global Restructuring, eds. D. Goodman and M. J. Watts, pp. 287–304. London: Routledge. Copyright © 1997 David Goodman and Michael Watts. 16. O’Neill, P. 1997. “Bringing the qualitative state into economic geography.” In Geographies of Economies, eds. Roger Lee and Jane Wills, pp. 290–301. London: Arnold. Copyright © 1997 Arnold. Reprinted with permission. 17. Storper, M. 1997. “Territories, flows and hierarchies in the global economy.” Aussenwirtschaft 50(2), 265–293. Copyright © 1995 Aussenwirtschaft. This edited version is reprinted by permission of the publisher. 18. Hudson, R. and D. Sadler. 1986. “Contesting works closures in Western Europe’s old industrial regions: Defending place or betraying class?” In Production, Work Territory – The Geographical Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism, eds A. J. Scott and M. Storper, pp. 172–93. London: Allen & Unwin. Copyright © 1996 Allen J. Scott, Michael Storper and the Contributors. xii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

19. Fincher, R. 1989. “Class and gender relations in the local labor market and the local state.” In The Power of Geography: How Territory Shapes Social Life, eds. J. Wolch and M. Dear, pp. 93–117. London: Allen & Unwin. Copy- right © 1989 Jennifer Wolch, Michael Dear and Contributors. 20. McDowell, L. 1997. “Thinking through work: Gender, power and space.” In Capital Culture: Money, Sex and Power at Work, pp. 11–42. Oxford: Blackwell. Copyright © 1997 Linda McDowell. Reprinted with permission of Blackwell Publishers. 21. Graham, S. 1998. “The end of geography or the explosion of place? Concep- tualizing space, place and information technology.” Progress in Human Geography, 22 (2), 165–85. Copyright © 1998 Arnold. 22. Gertler, M. 2001. “Best practice? Geography, learning and institutional limits to strong convergence.” The Journal of Economic Geography 1 (1), 5–26, by permission of Oxford University Press. 23. Hsing, Y. 1996. “Blood thicker than water: interpersonal relations and Taiwanese investment in southern China.” Environment and Planning A, 28 (12), 2241–62. Copyright © 1996 Pion Ltd. Reprinted by permission of the publisher. 24. Pratt, G. 1999. “From registered nurse to registered nanny: discursive geo- graphies of Filipina domestic workers in Vancouver, B.C.” Economic Geography, 75 (3), 215–36. Copyright © 1999 Clark University. 25. Schoenberger, E. 1998. “Discourse and practice in human geography.” Progress in Human Geography, 22 (1), 1–14. Copyright © 1998 Arnold.

Every effort has been made to trace copyright holders and to obtain their permis- sion for the use of copyright material. The authors and publishers will gladly receive any information enabling them to rectify any error or omission in subsequent editions. Introduction: Reading Economic Geography

Eric Sheppard, Trevor J. Barnes, Jamie Peck, and Adam Tickell

The Stuff of Economic Geography Economic geographers study why, where, and when things are produced: food, shelter, commodities of all kinds, money, cultural meanings, and landscapes. But what do economic geographers produce? Economic geographers, like other natural and human scientists, produce inscriptions – written accounts of the nature of the world, and explanations of it. If writing is the output, reading is one input: The two are utterly interlinked, and co-produced. Economic geographers read the inscrip- tions of others, and themselves, rearranging and reinterpreting them to produce their own inscriptions, which are in turn read by others, who engage in yet further writing. So turns the world of economic geography. The student of economic geo- graphy, then, is first and foremost a reader and a writer – a consumer and producer of inscriptions. Some may question our claim that economic geography is primarily about reading and writing. While this does describe well how economic geographers (indeed, all scientists) spend much of their time, surely there is more to economic geography? What about data collection and analysis, observation and fieldwork, conversations and debates, interviews and surveys, political interventions and policy work? While at times scientists have sought to give a privileged status to data and facts, it is now widely recognized that they too are a kind of inscription – a descrip- tion of the world. Secondary databases, such as the census, are produced by par- ticular agencies for particular purposes and represent their accounts of what matters in the world. Even when we go out and collect our own information on our own terms, that information is generally largely a social construct. A landscape, for example, is an inscription of human activities on the earth’s surface – either directly, as in the case of an urban neighborhood or an agricultural landscape, or indirectly, as in how even the most remote and seemingly natural landscapes are now being transformed by human-induced global climate change. Biophysical processes are also important in shaping the world we seek to understand – constituting non- human inscriptions – but even these have to be read and interpreted by economic 2 ERIC SHEPPARD, TREVOR J. BARNES, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL geographers. A fieldtrip is a bit like a trip to the library; we start out with ideas about what we are looking for, sort through the materials deposited there by others, read and interpret them, and then write about them.1 Of course, economic geo- graphers engage in practices other than reading and writing: operating overhead projectors and Xerox machines, talking with corporate executives and domestic workers, visiting Italian industrial districts and Turkish villages. These would not get us far, however, without reading and writing. In terms of the inscriptions we produce, surely these are more than “just” writing? Again, practicing scientists often claim that scientific writing is fundamen- tally different from that of, say, novelists: It provides a definitive analysis of reality, as opposed to story-telling. Yet, again, it is now widely recognized that such claims to the objectivity of scientific accounts are problematic (Longino, 2002). While sci- entific writing is not the same as that of novelists, scientists also tell stories – about how the world works – that reflect their preexisting beliefs, understandings, and interpretations. By the same token, novelists often seek to provide an account of how the world works through their novels, which, like the scientists’ essays, can be more or less compelling, plausible, and insightful. (David Lodge’s recent novel Thinks . . . provides a humorous narrative of how scientists’ and novelists’ accounts overlap.) If reading and writing is the stuff of economic geography, then a Reader should be more than just a collection of economic geography’s “greatest hits.” Our aim in producing this collection is to help students of economic geography (including our- selves) become better readers and writers. Our strategy is to provide what we think are effective and provocative examples of writing by economic geographers, and some guidance about how to read them critically and place them in context. In doing this, we have faced a series of dilemmas that we have attempted to negotiate. First, there is no canon in economic geography, that is, there is not a common understanding of how to “do” economic geography nor of those articles that are the “classics.” Although, as we argue below, this is one of the strengths of economic geography, it made our editorial task difficult. This is compounded by the fact that any selection may well contribute to the canonization of those essays included – and the marginalization and disaffection of those authors excluded. The sheer quantity of writing by economic geographers poses a separate problem. There are, perhaps, a thousand practicing professional economic geographers worldwide. If each of us writes and publishes on average, say, 15,000 words a year, then over a fifteen-year period that would amount to 225,000,000 words. We only had room for less than one-thousandth of that output here. Rather than providing a definitive selection, then, we offer only a partial collec- tion reflecting our own readings, presuppositions, and opinions. Our choices can only be justified within the context in which it was produced, summarized below. Yet, we hope that even though others inevitably will disagree with our choices, students of economic geography will find our guidance to reading economic geo- graphy helpful. Our approach underlines the variegated character of contemporary economic geography in a way that says something about the restlessness and open- ness of the subdiscipline. Its very dynamism and differentiation is the reason that there is no universally accepted canon, and our selections here have consequently been made in such a way as to highlight some of the diverse ways in which eco- INTRODUCTION 3 nomic geographies have been conceived, practiced, and written. Part of our task has been to illustrate how the boundaries of economic geography have been breached, stretched, and remade, but at the same time it is important to hold on to what is distinctively economic-geographic. Today, “being an economic geographer” is not just a matter of institutional affiliation, nor is it simply a reflection of sub- stantive empirical concerns; it symbolizes a deeper set of commitments, inclinations, and sensibilities. From our particular historically and geographically situated perspective, the work of economic geographers involves mapping out the geographies of localization and globalization; exploring the geographical founda- tions of economic structures and restructuring processes; developing accounts for uneven spatial development in the economy; documenting and explaining the spa- tiality of economic processes; and uncovering the social and institutional bases of economic performance, and the ways in which these vary between places and across scales.

The Broader Context: A Brief History of Economic Geography The field of economic geography dates back to commercial geography in the nineteenth century – which attempted to compile and give meaning to the geo- graphy of economic production, often as a handmaiden to the colonial adventures of European powers (Barnes, 2000). Its current form, direction, and status are largely a result of a remarkable efflorescence of writing in the English-speaking world over the past fifty years (Scott, 2000). Beginning in the early 1960s, economic geography became the primary vehicle through which a new way of doing human geography became popular. The quantitative revolution refashioned geography as a theoretical discipline, whereby geographers sought to explain the spatial organi- zation of human activity rather than just to describe and map it; and as a positivist discipline, developing deductive theories about the world and determining their validity by seeing whether they accurately predict observed spatial patterns. Eco- nomic geography proved well suited to this agenda; it could be easily quantified, and there were well-developed deductive theories in economics that some German economists and geographers (notably Johan Heinrich von Thünen, Alfred Weber, August Lösch, and Walter Christaller) had already been adapting to predict the loca- tion of economic activities on the basis of rational economic decision-making. It was in the English-speaking world, and to a lesser extent Sweden, that this approach developed particularly rapidly. Initial research adapted statistical methods to test the location theories of von Thünen et al., leading subsequently to new statistical methods and elaborations of these location theories into a rich research program that also gained the attention of urban and regional economists, and even a new interdisciplinary field of study – regional science.2 This approach to economic geography has remained an important field of endeavor, but to a significant degree it has been taken up by trained economists rather than trained geographers. The work of Paul Krugman has been particularly influential in recent years, stamping his own personality and engaged writing on this research program (Fujita, Krugman, and Venables, 1999), thereby catalyzing renewed interest from some influential economists under the moniker of the “new” economic geography. Some geographers have protested, with justification, that their 4 ERIC SHEPPARD, TREVOR J. BARNES, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL contributions within this research program in the 1970s–1990s have been largely ignored, and many have found the program irrelevant to their current preoccupa- tions. But there has been a high-profile attempt to catalyze a conversation between economists and geographers around these issues (Clark, Gertler, and Feldman, 2000), culminating in the establishment of a new journal in 2001, The Journal of Economic Geography. Among trained geographers, the quantitative revolution bequeathed to economic geography an interest in, and commitment to, theory, but neoclassical economic- influenced location theories and positivism have largely been replaced with a suc- cession of different approaches. Beginning in the mid-1970s, political economy became influential. Inspired by the classical economics of Marx, this approach has focused on how the political and economic forces of capitalism shape the space- economy (Harvey, 1982; Swyngedouw, 2000). Economic landscapes are explained as an evolutionary and conflict-laden consequence of contestation among social classes mediated by the state, in contrast to the harmonious equilibrium outcome of rational economic choice favored by location theory. At the same time, with quan- titative geography tarred by the brush of positivism, there was a methodological shift away from mathematical models and statistical testing towards a more quali- tative, case-study-oriented approach, often grounded in critical realism (Sayer, 1984; Plummer, 2000). During the 1990s, political economy in turn came under fire, as geographers began to criticize it for over-emphasizing the importance of economic forces relative to culture, for under-playing the importance of human agency in shaping socio-spatial structures, and for its inattention to gender. As a consequence, there is now an unprecedented diversity of approaches to economic geography among geographers, with the creative surge in poststructuralist, feminist, and cultural theoretic approaches (Gibson-Graham, 2000; Oberhauser, 2000; Thrift, 2000), and a related turn to ethnographies and discourse analysis. These approaches emphasize that adequate forms of explanation in economic geography must involve critical reassessments of what we mean by terms like production and consumption, seeking redefinitions that highlight previously neglected aspects of these processes. The boundaries of economic processes do not conveniently coin- cide with those of firms or labor markets, or those established by censuses or national accounting systems. So, a focus on wage work, for example, can obscure the role of households as places of production, while neglecting the role of women (and other carers) in the process of social reproduction. It is characteristic of much recent work in economic geography to unveil these previously margin- alized phenomena, partly in service of the more general argument that economic processes, and the places where production and consumption occur, are shaped by the cultural contexts within which they are embedded. Yet in many senses the research program remains grounded within the broad questions motivating the original forays into political economy: Understanding how the geographical organization of economic activities (now much more broadly defined) is both shaped by, and shapes, the evolution of economic, political, social, and cultural processes; processes that themselves are constituted by the deliberate actions of individuals, and by the social structures and processes of identity formation shaping those actions. INTRODUCTION 5

The Immediate Context: The Blackwell Companion This Reader was conceived in parallel with the Blackwell Companion to Economic Geography (Sheppard and Barnes, 2000). The Companion sought to highlight the predominant focus of geographers working in economic geography, and was organ- ized to reflect the range of theoretical approaches and substantive topics that con- stitute this diverse research program. It is the richness, breadth, and ambition of this research program that makes economic geography a particularly vibrant area of study at present. Moving beyond the traditional questions of economics, contemporary economic geographers examine what is meant by “economic,” and how the economic co-evolves in space with other societal, cultural, political, and environmental processes. One consequence is that what once were considered the “boundaries” of economic geography – say, the interface with environmental issues, gender relations, or the state – are now especially intensive zones of activity. There is no longer a single core or “center” even of Anglo-American economic geography, but a differentiated terrain of debates, emergent questions, fashionable topics, and enduring concerns. Economic geography may defy most attempts at codification and classification: It is not easily bounded, nor can it be easily located within a domi- nant methodological or theoretical schema; it is fidgety and somewhat unruly, and hardly ever unified or cohesive. But this also means that it is rarely dull. The original Companion was organized into five sections, a basic structure that has been duplicated in this volume. Part I, Worlds of Economic Geography, illus- trates the variety of theoretical approaches favored by economic geographers, emphasizing political economy, post-structuralism, feminism, and cultural and insti- tutional approaches. Essays illustrating each of these traditions have been selected here. Part II, Realms of Production, focuses on traditional themes of economics, to examine how they are addressed within geography: Production, labor, firms, competition, growth, and technical change. The essays selected include political economic, post-structural, and feminist approaches to production, firms, regional growth, and work. Part III, Resource Worlds, seeks to bring attention to, and cat- alyze research on, the relationship between the economy and the biophysical envi- ronment – a long-standing area of interest in economic geography that has received less attention within the current research program. Themes emphasized here, as in the Companion, include agriculture, resources, and the production of nature, from political economic, cultural theoretic, and feminist perspectives. Part IV, Social Worlds, was designed to emphasize one of economic geography’s principal achieve- ments in recent years – recognizing that economic processes cannot be analyzed in isolation from society. Gender relations, class, governance, and the state, and their relationship to space, are the foci of the essays selected here. Finally, Part V, Spaces of Circulation, was developed (like Part III) to refocus attention on some long-standing issues in economic geography that have not had such a high priority in recent research. Beginning with the spatial implications of Sayer’s critical realism, and reinforced by more recent interest in territories, local embeddedness, and scale, the nature and implications of the ways in which places are systematically connected together across space have received less attention recently. Connectivity, as expressed through transportation and communications technologies, and the movements of commodities, people, capital, and ideas, is the subject-matter of this section. The 6 ERIC SHEPPARD, TREVOR J. BARNES, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL essays selected here examine the spatiality of telecommunications, and the connec- tivity of places through flows of capital and migration.

Selection Strategies We did not set out to select the best articles ever written in economic geography. Indeed, we do not believe that any such list can be drawn up; its creation would imply the existence of an economic geographical canon that is neither extant nor desirable. It would be possible to compile a list of the most influential papers, based on their measurable influence (say, by the frequency that they are cited), or the ways in which they can be argued to have indirectly influenced subsequent research tra- jectories, but such approaches are also problematic. For example, the frequency that an article is cited is not a reliable indicator of influence, notwithstanding the popu- larity of this crude measure among university administrators seeking to quantify research performance. The culture of citation differs across disciplines and research communities within disciplines, and motivations for citation extend beyond formally acknowledging influential ideas to include: marking the intellectual program to which you would like to belong; citing your friends, influential people whose friend- ship you seek, or what you think potential referees will have expected you to read; citing those whose work you think is poor; and showing off how much you know (Curry, 1991). Selection is made more difficult by the sheer volume of publication over the past fifteen years, by our own inability to read it all or even recall what we’ve read, and by language barriers. Despite passing familiarity with a couple of European lan- guages, we are not in a position to survey the relevant non-English literature in any knowledgeable way. To the extent that English has become the lingua franca for international scholarship in economic geography, this language barrier might be per- ceived as less limiting than, say, Japanese. Yet, as noted above, this self-limitation of course also serves to reinforce this English canon, and any broader Eurocentrism that it entails. There is substantial scholarship in economic geography that is not translated into English. The writings by scholars in other languages that are trans- lated are naturally written in such a way as to fit within the English-speaking debates, thus often seeming derivative of the English language literature. It is there- fore commonly asserted that the English-speaking realm dominates the research frontiers of economic geography. At the same time, however, we do not wish to underestimate the possibility that very different approaches to the field already exist in the non-English scholarship, or that exposure to these ideas would substantially enrich the English language scholarship. We look forward, therefore, to the devel- opment of forums for economic geographers to engage in a multilingual exchange of expertise, from which a very different kind of Reader, relevant for a much broader audience, might emerge. Our goals are modest: To select articles that reflect our own collective and situ- ated understanding of what is worth reading in the English language. We sought, first, articles that illustrate at least one of the five themes shaping contemporary eco- nomic geography as summarized above. In addition, we wanted to include as authors a number of the more influential scholars in the field, people with whose writing we believe any student of economic geography should have some familiar- INTRODUCTION 7 ity. Since this volume is conceived of as a complement to the Companion, authors whose essays already appear in the Companion were not our first choice. Yet, we also selected articles that we find particularly interesting or especially relevant to the thematic structure of the two books, and tried to stay away from conflicts of interest (such as selecting articles by our own students, or ourselves). We sought to provide some balance across the different theoretical perspectives currently shaping geographic work in this field, by gender and location (both of the authors and of the empirical research). Needless to say, this kind of winnowing down and balanc- ing is a very difficult and subjective exercise. In another context, even the same four editors might well have made different choices. Inclusion also entails exclusion, and we can only hope that colleagues who feel left out appreciate the complexity, and understand the contingent nature, of our choices. Even our choice of just 25 articles from this productive and diverse field transcended limits imposed by the economics of publishing. Constrained to some 200,000 words, we were unable to realize our original aim of publishing the arti- cles in their entirety. While our original goal was to let the readers decide what is important to them, this also abrogates some of our responsibility as editors to provide a representative sample of articles that also is accessible to a student audi- ence, as one referee of the book proposal pointed out. Thus, we decided to include more articles, selectively edited, rather than just three per section in their entirety. In editing the articles, we have again imposed our own particular reading on the writings of others – seeking to make the essays more accessible when necessary, and highlighting those aspects of them that make them relevant to their inclusion in the volume. Some were sufficiently cogent to be included almost in the original length; others had to be cut in half. We cut out all abstracts, acknowledgments, and foot- notes from the original papers, and extensive sections that were of limited relevance to their role within this volume. We also engaged in more detailed editing to increase their accessibility, in our view, and to reduce their length. We have not indicated all the places where this more detailed editing occurred, as that would have substan- tially reduced the legibility of our selections.3 Our editorial selections, of which parts to include, do not reflect some general and definitive judgment as to which are the “best parts” of an article, but only which parts are most relevant to our context and goals. As always, we urge students of economic geography (or any discipline) to take these readings as only a starting point: Always read the original writings, rather than second-hand accounts or others’ abbreviations of the originals; and make your own judgments about which articles are of most use for you, by going beyond edited books and course bibliographies to undertake your own survey of the literature.

Critical Reading Each section of the Reader is prefaced by a brief introduction, placing the readings in the context of the development of thinking around this theme, and providing some specific questions to ponder with respect to the readings in that section. Here, we offer some tips about reading in a constructively critical manner. This may sound time consuming, but think for a minute about how much effort it took to write the article! 8 ERIC SHEPPARD, TREVOR J. BARNES, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL

• Gain an overall sense of the argument. Before reading an article in detail, peruse the introduction and conclusion to get a sense of the research questions driving the scholarship, and the overall argument. A detailed reading will be more mean- ingful if you can situate it within this overall understanding. • Engage in a detailed initial reading. Take detailed notes, jotting down major arguments advanced, and figuring out how the various parts of the article con- tribute to constructing the overall argument. • Learn the terminology. Terms mean different things in different contexts, so it is important to know how they are used within economic geography. Make notes of terms you do not understand, and look them up on the Internet or in an ency- clopedia or dictionary of human geography (Hanson, 2001; Johnston et al., 2001). • Pay attention to writing. Think about the writing style of the author. What makes it effective, or ineffective? Is the style appropriate for the task at hand? Is the author trying to overwhelm you with fancy words, jargon, and obscure refer- ences, thereby undermining your ability to criticize the article, or is he or she adept at making complex ideas accessible and highlighting the most important points? • Contextualize the essay. Determine how authors situate themselves. Which the- oretical or philosophical perspective is being adopted? Which kinds of research do the authors engage with, or ignore? How does the article fit within their trajectory of work (visiting authors’ web sites often helps)? • Take little on faith. Do not be satisfied with authors’ renditions of others’ argu- ments, or their interpretations of empirical material. Wherever possible, go back to the sources, and read critically the various inscriptions that the authors mobi- lize in support of their argument. • Engage in an internalist critique. An internalist critique pays attention to how well authors achieve the goals they set for themselves. This is essential to any constructive critical reading. Since economic geography is such a diverse field, it is too easy to dismiss an article for taking what you believe to be the wrong general approach, or for asking questions in which you are not interested. This kind of externalist critique (below) is important, but is insufficient. An inter- nalist critique gives due respect to the author and the effort he or she invested. Based on your understanding of the article, how convincing is the overall argu- ment? Is the theoretical argument rigorous, and the use of empirical evidence appropriate and convincing, with respect to the norms of the scholarship within which the article is situated? If not, how could it be improved? • Engage in an externalist critique. What important questions/issues regarding the topic have been omitted in the article? What other approaches to the topic could the author have taken? How would choosing a different approach affect the overall research questions and methodologies? What might be the relative value, in your view, of a different approach? • Be reflexive. Reflect on the critiques you have developed, and how they are shaped by your own personal and intellectual biography (What has interested you? What have you been taught to value? What constitutes your identity and interests?). Use this as an opportunity to reflect on the context from which your critique stems, and to challenge your own preconceptions. To learn from others’ INTRODUCTION 9

scholarship you have to engage with the research and even change your mind. Finally, ask the ethical question of whether your critical assessment is the kind that you would like to receive from someone reading your essays.

Critical reading is central to the reproduction of economic geography as a vital field of scholarly inquiry. Constructive criticism can contribute to advancing knowledge within a particular research program. It can also lay the foundation for a produc- tive engagement among the different approaches of economic geography (Longino, 2002). At present, different approaches too often seem to be like ships passing in the night; the latest fashions are put on display while last month’s styles are scup- pered. Effective writing also requires the reflexive application of critical reading skills to our own inscriptions. Everyone who reads economic geography can, through critical reading, partici- pate in the production of economic geographic knowledge. We thus invite readers to contribute to the vitality of the field by developing and articulating their own critical readings.

NOTES

1. In making this analogy, we do not wish to suggest that fieldtrips can be substituted by trips to the library. To the contrary: arguably economic geography is becoming impov- erished because we spend too much time in the library and on the Internet and too little in the field. 2. By “research program” we mean a school of thought that emerges in a discipline, sharing a worldview and a common understanding about what are the most important research questions and how to go about answering them (Lakatos, 1970). Intellectual progress within economic geography, as in any discipline, does not proceed in a steady direction from poor to excellent understandings of the subject matter, but rather proceeds in fits and starts, as older research programs run out of steam, and new ones attempt to replace them. 3. The academic convention when quoting is to indicate every word left out with an “ellipse”: ...We have dispensed with this convention here because space constraints meant that our editing was sometimes extensive and we did not want our editorial pres- ence to be unnecessarily intrusive.

Part I Worlds of Economic Geography

Editors’ Introduction: Paradigms Lost

Trevor J. Barnes, Adam Tickell, Jamie Peck, and Eric Sheppard

David Harvey’s essay, which begins this section, is called “The difference a genera- tion makes.” It would make an apt title for this editorial introduction. The age span that separates us four editors is less than a generation, but the kind of economic geography into which each of us was first socialized as undergraduates was radi- cally different. Sheppard attended one of the iconic centers of quantitative, model- based geographical training of the late 1960s and early 1970s, Bristol University, and imbibed the purity of those methods. Barnes went to University College London during the mid-1970s, by which time political economic change was in the air, result- ing in an incongruous educational mix of Markov chain and Marxian value analy- sis, sometimes within the same lecture. When Peck finished his BA at Manchester during the early 1980s, there was only one approach to economic geography – political economy, solidified by the publication of Doreen Massey’s (1984) water- shed book, Spatial Divisions of Labour, which for Peck made everything written before seem irrelevant. Finally, when Tickell completed his degree in 1987, again at Manchester, political economy was still central, but there was also the first whiff of a social and cultural sensibility, linked to discussions of gender and local culture (later culminating in the locality project; Cooke, 1989). The difference a generation makes in economic geography, then, is at least three different paradigms.1 That term paradigm comes from the work of the historian and philosopher of science, Thomas Kuhn (1962), and is found in his classic, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. There is some debate over what exactly he meant – critics say that there are over twenty separate definitions of paradigm within his slim book – but the gist is clear enough. A paradigm is a way of looking at the world, like Galileo’s helio- centric view of the solar system, or David Harvey’s class-based (Marxist) view of industrial capitalism. Kuhn was also keen to stress that a paradigm includes an affil- iated set of practices that bind practitioners to a common culture and social group. That is, paradigms are not just ethereal abstractions, but are embodied in people, in their relationships and interactions, in institutions, in artifacts, and in a culture’s very form of life. This is what made Kuhn’s book itself revolutionary: he recognized that academic enquiry, even of the most rarefied form, is never just academic. 14 TREVOR J. BARNES, ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, AND ERIC SHEPPARD

For this reason, changing paradigms can be fraught, the stakes and consequence sometimes enormous. Galileo was locked up by the Inquisition for suggesting a change in paradigms from geocentrism to heliocentrism, while Darwin was (and still is) denounced in pulpits, legislatures, and court rooms for favoring an evolu- tionary paradigm over a creationist one. In economic geography, the consequences of paradigm change have not been quite so dramatic, although it is still likely that some assistant professors and lecturers have been denied tenure or promotion, and certain that some students have done less well in their exams and projects, because of the paradigms that they held. In economic geography there have been some famous paradigm quarrels, such as the mid-1950s Hartshorne–Schaefer debate signaling a move from regional geography to spatial science, or the mid-1970s Berry–Harvey exchange in which the spatial scientist Berry took on Harvey’s Marxism on its home turf of Antipode, or yet again the early 1990s Harvey–Massey dispute in which Massey castigated Harvey’s brand of Marxism for omitting the culture of gender. In line with Kuhn’s broader thesis, these various disputes were won or lost partly on rational, intellectual criteria, but also on social and cultural ones. For example, Hartshorne fell to Schaefer not because he lacked good, plausi- ble arguments – Hartshorne wears you down with his inexorable, grinding logic – but because he was fighting against the rising tide of a postwar American culture and society, and the economic geography that emerged from it that valued science and technology, instrumental reasoning, and the young and the new (for more details see Barnes, 2000). As these examples indicate, and as is clear from our opening story, paradigm change has come thick and fast in economic geography over the past fifty years. It’s not quite “if it’s Tuesday it must be Marxism,” but intellectual change has been the disciplinary name of the game for the past half-century. While this might be viewed as a sign of immaturity, of a juvenile flavor-of-the-month mentality, we believe the opposite. We think it indicates intellectual maturity, and that it is characterized by vibrancy, dynamism, and openness. The contemporary American pragmatist philosopher Richard Rorty argues that there is always hope as long as the conver- sation continues. From the pieces we have assembled, it is clear that the conversa- tion in economic geography sparkles, and that hope remains vitally alive. And to prove the point, the first essay by David Harvey (2000) comes from his book, Spaces of Hope. Harvey is the foremost Marxist in Anglo-American geo- graphy. In his earlier volume The Limits to Capital, Harvey (1982) provided a geographical exegesis of Marx’s three volumes of Capital, and the Grundisse, giving economic geographers a body of theory, concepts, and a vocabulary to understand the capitalist space economy. But as Harvey now reflects, the Marxism found in that volume, and in the sometimes-covert seminars and lecture courses he has run on Marx since 1971, is out of fashion, or perhaps even worse, normalized. Marx has become just another dead, white European male we need to know a smattering about in order to pass the exam. For Harvey this is both tragic and comic. Marx’s theories, he argues, have never been more relevant to the present generation than they are right now. They are the spitting image of our times. The present genera- tion, including economic geographers, often shuns Marx, however, or provides only ritualistic acknowledgment. They are concerned with carrying out a different par- adigm, cultural analysis, rather than political economy, which for them is “much INTRODUCTION TO PART I 15 more fun than being absorbed in the dour world and crushing realities of capital- ist exploitation.” But for Harvey it is on those crushing realities that we must con- centrate: it is our political and moral obligation. Andrew Sayer argues that our obligation as economic geographers is to employ a set of methodological precepts drawn from critical realism. Only by drawing on this paradigm can we ensure that radical (Marxist) theorizing and empirical research of the kind sparked by people like Harvey remains consistent, coherent, and com- pelling. Originating with the writings of two British philosophers, Roy Bhasker and Rom Harré, during the 1970s, critical realism was introduced into geography by Sayer (1984) in the early 1980s, quickly becoming the unofficial paradigm of eco- nomic geography for a decade, especially in the UK. At its most basic, critical realism is an alternative to positivist science (of the kind that dominated economic geography during the 1960s and 1970s) that sought simple empirical relations of association, taken as equivalent to causes. In contrast, Sayer conceives causation as more complicated. He argues that objects, including social objects, contain within them necessary causal powers and liabilities to make things happen, but which are realized only under specific contingent conditions. To use Sayer’s favorite example, a barrel of gunpowder by virtue of its constituent com- ponents contains the necessary causal powers to produce an explosion, but whether it does depends upon the contingent fact of someone throwing in a lighted match. Under critical realism, then, we are led to two different but related forms of enquiry. On the one hand, to an abstract examination of the necessary relations that con- stitute the causative power of an entity (what is it about the abstract chemistry of the various compounds found in gunpowder that makes the combination so volatile?), and, on the other, to a concrete investigation into the multifarious con- tingent circumstances under which that power is released (Does gunpowder explode when someone accidentally drops a match? Or when a soldier primes the pan of their musket? Or when a miner lights a fuse?). What does any of this have to do with the project of radical economic geogra- phy? Sayer’s argument is that it has been methodologically slipshod, undermining the politically important analysis it carries out on such important topics as indus- trial location and uneven development. The problem is that radical economic geographers foist abstract, necessary relations on to the concrete world without recognizing the effects that contingent, mediating relations produce. For example, a necessary relation within Marx’s abstract conception of capitalism is the movement of capital to low-cost, profit-maximizing locations; it is as much a defining feature of an abstract capitalism as is the chemical formula for gunpow- der. Some radical geographers have then used this necessary relation to make concrete claims about the world. For example, as in the new international division of labor thesis, the idea that manufacturers in developed countries switch their industrial investment to much cheaper developing countries. The problem, though, as Sayer argues, is that a bevy of contingent, concrete relations interrupt the abstract relation, changing its form and consequence, if not negating it alto- gether. Note, Sayer is not denying the importance of Harvey’s Marxist agenda focusing on a “dour world” and “crushing realities,” but he is saying that to achieve the best purchase on them requires use of at least an ancillary paradigm: critical realism. 16 TREVOR J. BARNES, ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, AND ERIC SHEPPARD

The paradigm favored by Ash Amin, institutionalism, is quite different. Originally formulated by the maverick American economist Thorstein Veblen, at the turn of the twentieth century, institutionalism is a third way lying between, on the one hand, a more politically driven and often deterministic Marxism, and, on the other, a more abstract and formal orthodox economics with its uncritical belief in the beneficence of the market. In contrast, institutionalism insists on the centrality of contingent and concrete social, cultural, and political institutions, and their interaction, in the con- stitution and maintenance of the economy. The economy is always embedded in a set of complex institutional relations that shape and animate it. Failure to recognize their importance results in a failure to comprehend both the economy (and its geography), and the means to effect propitious change. It is around this last issue that Amin works out the meaning of an institutionalist paradigm in economic geography by focusing on policies designed to benefit less-favored regions within industrialized countries. During the 1990s, those policies were often predicated on neo-liberalism, the belief that a market-based solution is best. Following institutionalism, Amin convincingly shows the inadequacy of such a policy, and of the wider approach of orthodox eco- nomics justifying it. The problem is that market-based solutions appear best only because of the theoretical assumption of an asocial, acultural, maximizing individ- ual, homo economicus. The effect of such an assumption is to make institutions dis- appear; they are reduced to the sum of the rational maximizing individuals that compose them. For Amin this is nonsense. Institutions are the very stuff of a real economy, and integral to any solution to economic failure such as found in less- favored regions. The answer is not to ignore institutions, but to nurture tighter, broader, and thicker linkages among them, and by doing so unequivocally rejecting fictions such as homo economicus (satirized by Veblen as a “homogenous globule of desire”). Moreover, this is an inherently geographical project. Institutions are not free-floating, waiflike entities, but substantially grounded in particular places. To practice institutionalism is to practice economic geography. Amin’s article begins to push economic geography away from strict political economy as imagined by Harvey and Sayer, allowing through the role of institu- tions an expanded role for the social and cultural. Such a shift is even more clearly defined in Thrift and Olds’ essay that follows. Published in 1996, it has become a manifesto within economic geography for Harvey’s dreaded paradigm of “cultural analysis.” Thrift and Olds’ argument is that there have been sea changes both in the way economies operate, and in the way social sciences represent them, and eco- nomic geographers must respond to the new agenda. On the one hand, economy and culture have become “incorrigibly intertwined,” which they illustrate using the example of Christmas. Marking the birth of one of the world’s greatest cultural reli- gious figures, Christmas in high-income Western countries is now also fundamen- tally about money: of shopping until you drop, of crowded retail malls and shopping centers, of sales and bargains, of gifting, re-gifting, and de-gifting. Is Christmas a cultural celebration? Or is Christmas a once-a-year economic bonanza for capital- ism? It is both. And such hybridity, as Thrift and Olds illustrate, is now pervasive: culture and economy are so blurred that it is difficult to know where one begins and the other ends. On the other hand, if blurring is the new reality, how should economic geography as a social science deal with it? They argue, first, by becom- ing more polycentric, that is, by “celebrating a qualitative multiplicity of ‘economic’ INTRODUCTION TO PART I 17 times and spaces.” And second, by drawing on the panoply of social scientific the- orizing available, and not just the one thin slice found in orthodox economics. In doing so, economic geography become “more inclusive and more able to mix in company.” More generally, Thrift and Olds recommend a loosening up in how eco- nomic geographers theorize; that they move away from the straight and narrow paradigms of orthodox economics and Marxism to more inventive, creative, and experimental theoretical forms. This is what Thrift and Old do at the end of their paper when they offer up a series of topological metaphors to conceive economy and culture. This is not Economics 101, but precisely because it’s not, it is so important. Related arguments about economy and culture, but presented in even starker terms, and expressing perhaps an even more dreaded version of cultural analysis, are continued in Gibson-Graham’s essay which appeared in their now classic book, The End of Capitalism (as we knew it) (1996). They – Gibson-Graham are two sep- arate authors, Kathy Gibson and Julie Graham – are concerned with metaphor, in this case, metaphors that underpin the very notion of the economy. Metaphors for them are not mere figures of speech, interchangeable, frivolous, and of no conse- quence. Rather, they produce profound material consequences, determining within the economy, for example, which person does what job, how much they are paid, and whether industries and associated communities are saved or let slip. In partic- ular, they argue that the metaphorical origins of the economy are with the body. But it is not any old body, it is the body of a heterosexual man. In turn, the mas- culinity of that body shapes the now familiar characteristics of the economy on to which it is transposed: its purity, its sovereignty, its heroicness, and its mastery. These metaphors create, to use Gibson-Graham’s vocabulary, a particular discourse about the economy. Discourse is a difficult term, but the general idea is that rather than language reflecting the world, the world comes to reflect language. Furthermore, language is never neutral, and transparent, but reflects all number of social inter- ests, and relations of power. So, in this case, once people begin to use (male) bodily metaphors to represent the economy, and structure their actions and beliefs accord- ingly, the economy discursively takes on those characteristics, shaping its material form. Gibson-Graham, however, want to challenge that discourse, which means chal- lenging the dominant cultural metaphor of the male, heterosexual body that under- lies it. Only in this way, they suggest, is progressive political change possible. They do so by trying out new metaphors taken from feminist interpretations of the female body, and contra the male body, conceived as porous, non-hierarchical, and partial. Through these alternative metaphors, they argue, it is possible to imagine other dis- cursive possibilities for the economy, and other material prospects than the one promised by capitalism. This too is a space of hope, but the paradigm from which it is envisioned is quite different from Harvey’s classical Marxist one. In reading these essays, we would like you to bear in mind the following ques- tions. As economic geography has moved from Marxism to critical regionalism and now to some form of cultural analysis, has there been any progress? Is economic geography a better discipline now than it was, say, twenty or even thirty years ago? If so, how is it better? What are the criteria? But if we can’t claim progress, then how do we interpret the methodological changes represented by the five chapters? 18 TREVOR J. BARNES, ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, AND ERIC SHEPPARD

Are we left only with a relativist view that says each approach is as relatively good as any other? But if so, how do we choose among them? Or do we have to choose among them at all? Can we combine different paradigms? Or, again, is it possible to undertake economic geography without using any paradigm at all? What does a paradigm give you that you might need in carrying out economic geography, and what are the grounds for picking one over another?

NOTE

1. Of course, there have been more than just these three. For a fuller discussion see the Introductory essay to this book, and Barnes’s (2000) essay which appeared in the Companion. Chapter 1 The Difference a Generation Makes

David Harvey

1 Marx Redux Every year since 1971 (with the exception of one) I have run either a reading group or a course on Marx’s Capital (Volume 1). While this may reasonably be taken as the mark of a peculiarly stodgy academic mind, it has allowed me to accumulate a rare time-series of reactions to this particular text. In the early 1970s there was great political enthusiasm for it on the part of at least a radical minority. Participation was understood as a political act. Indeed, the course was set up (in parallel with many others of its sort across American campuses at the time) to try to find a theoretical basis, a way of understanding all of the chaos and political disruption evident in the world (the civil rights movement of the 1960s and the urban upris- ings that followed the assassination of Martin Luther King in the United States, the growing opposition to the imperialist war in Vietnam, the massive student move- ments of 1968 that shook the world from Paris to Mexico City, from Berkeley and Berlin to Bangkok, the Czech “Spring” and its subsequent repression by the Soviets, the “Seven Days’ War” in the Middle East, the dramatic events that occurred at the Democratic National Convention in Chicago, just to name a few of the signal events that made it seem as if the world as we knew it was falling apart). In the midst of all this turmoil there was a crying need for some sort of political and intellectual guidance. Given the way in which Marx’s works had effectively been proscribed through the long history of McCarthyite repression in the United States, it seemed only right and proper to turn to Marx. He must have had something important to say, we reasoned, otherwise his works would not have been suppressed for so long. This presumption was given credibility by the icy reception to our efforts on many a campus. I disguised the name of the course, often ran it of an evening, and gave “independent study” credit for those who did not want any mention of it on their transcript (I later learned from someone high up in the administration that since the course was taught in the geography program and was called “Reading Capital” it took them nearly a decade to figure out it was Marx’s Capital that was being taught). 20 DAVID HARVEY

Capital was not an easy text to decipher, at least for the uninitiated (and there were many of us in that condition and only a few old hands could help us on our way, most of them of European extraction where communist parties had long remained active). But for those of us in universities the intellectual difficulty was, at least, a normal challenge. In these early years many young faculty members participated, as did many gra- duate students. Some of them have gone on to be famous (and though some have changed their stripes most will generously acknowledge the formative nature of the whole experience). They came from all manner of disciplines (Philosophy, Math Sciences, Political Theory, History of Science, English, Geography, History, Sociology, Economics . . .). In retrospect I realize what an incredible privilege it was to work through this text with people armed with so many different intellectual skills and political perspectives. This was how I learned my Marx, through a process of mutual self-education that obeyed little or no particular disciplinary logic let alone party political line. I soon found myself teaching the text well beyond the con- fines of the university, in the community (with activists, teachers, unionists). I even got to teach some of it (not very successfully) in the Maryland penitentiary. Teaching undergraduates was somewhat more fraught. The dominant tone of undergraduate radicalism in those days was anti-intellectual. For them, the academy seemed the center of ideological repressions; book learning of any sort was inher- ently suspect as a tool of indoctrination and domination. Many undergraduate student activists (and these were, of course, the only ones who would ever think of taking the course) thought it rather unradical to demand that they read let alone understand and write about such a long and tortuous book. Not many of them lasted the course. They paid no mind to Marx’s injunction that “there is no royal road to science” nor did they listen to the warning that many readers “always anxious to come to a conclusion, eager to know the connexion between general principles and the immediate questions that have aroused their passions, may be disheartened because they will be unable to move on at once.” No amount of “fore- warning and forearming those readers who zealously seek the truth” (Marx, 1967 edition, p. 104) seemed to work with this audience. They were carried forward largely on a cresting wave of intuitions and bruised emotions (not, I hasten to add, necessarily a bad thing). The situation is radically different now. I teach Capital as a respectable regular course. I rarely if ever see any faculty members and the graduate student audience has disappeared (except for those who plan to work with me and who take the course as some kind of “rite of passage” before they go on to more important things). Most of the graduate survey courses in other departments now allot Marx a week or two, sandwiched in between, say, Darwin and Weber. Marx gets attention. But in academia, this is devoted either to putting him in his place as, say, a “minor post-Ricardian” or passing him by as an outmoded “structuralist” or “modernist.” Marx is, in short, largely written off as the weaver of an impossibly huge master-narrative of history and an advocate of some totally impossible historical transformation that has in any case been proven by events to be just as fallacious politically and practically as it always was theoretically. Even before the collapse of the Berlin Wall, in the early 1980s, Marx was definitely moving out of academic and political fashion. In the halcyon years of THE DIFFERENCE A GENERATION MAKES 21 identity politics and the famous “cultural turn” the Marxian tradition assumed an important negative role. It was ritualistically held up (incorrectly) as a dominant ideology that had to be fought against. Marx and “traditional” Marxism were sys- tematically criticized and denigrated as insufficiently concerned with more impor- tant questions of gender, race, sexuality, human desires, religion, ethnicity, colonial dominations, environment, or whatever. Cultural powers and movements were just as important if not more so than those of class, and what was class anyway if not one out of many different and cross-cutting cultural configurations. All of that might have been fair enough (there were plenty of grounds for such criticisms) if it had not also been concluded that Marxism as a mode of thought was inherently antag- onistic towards any such alternative formulations and therefore a totally lost cause. In particular, cultural analysis supplanted political economy (the former, in any case, being much more fun than being absorbed in the dour world and crushing realities of capitalist exploitation). And then came the collapse of the Wall, the last nail in the coffin of any sort of Marxist credibility even if many of a Marxian persuasion had long distanced themselves (some as long ago as the Hungarian uprising of 1956 and still more with the crushing of the Czech Spring in 1968) from actually existing socialism of the Soviet–Chinese sort. To pretend there was anything interesting about Marx after 1989 was to sound more and more like an all-but-extinct dinosaur whimpering its own last rites. Free-market capitalism rode triumphantly across the globe, slaying all such old dinosaurs in its path. “Marx talk” was increasingly confined to what might best be described as an increasingly geriatric “New Left” (I myself passed none too gently into that night known as “senior citizen”). By the early 1990s the intellectual heft of Marxian theory seemed to be terminally in decline. But some undergraduates still continue to take the Capital course. For most of them this is no longer a political act. The fear of communism has largely dissipated. The course has a good reputation. A few students are curious to see what all the fuss with Marxism was about. And a few still have some radical instincts left to which they feel Marx might add an extra insight or two. So, depending on their timetable and their requirements, some undergraduates end up in Marx’s Capital rather than in Aristotle’s Ethics or Plato’s Republic. This contrast I have drawn between then and now in terms of political and intel- lectual interest and response to Marx is hardly surprising. Most will recognize the broad outlines of what I have described even if the specific lens I am using exag- gerates and distorts here and there. But there is another tale to be told that makes matters rather more confusing. In the early 1970s it was hard to find the direct relevance of Volume I of Capital to the political issues that dominated the day. We needed Lenin to get us from Marx to an understanding of the imperialist war that so unnerved us in Vietnam. We needed a theory of civil society (Gramsci at least) to get us from Marx to civil rights, and a theory of the state (such as Miliband or Poulantzas) to get us to a critique of state repressions and welfare state expenditures manipulated to requirements of capital accumulation. We needed the Frankfurt School to understand questions of legiti- macy, technological rationality, the state and bureaucracy, and the environment. But then consider the historical-geographical conditions. In much of the advanced capitalist world, the trade union movement (often far too reformist for our radical 22 DAVID HARVEY tastes) was still strong, unemployment was broadly contained, everywhere (except in the United States) nationalization and public ownership was still on the agenda and the welfare state had been built up to a point where it seemed unassailable if flawed. Elsewhere in the world movements were afoot that seemed to threaten the existence of capitalism. Mao was a preeminent revolutionary leader in China while many other charismatic revolutionaries from Che Guevara and Castro in the Latin American context to Cabral and Nyerere in Africa actively held out the possibility of a socialist or communist alternative. Revolution seemed imminent and we have subsequently learned that it was actively feared among many of the rulers of the time (even going beyond what might be expected from the evident paranoia of someone like Richard Nixon). How that revolution might occur and the kind of society to which it might lead were not topics even remotely touched upon in Marx’s Capital (though there were plenty of other texts of Marx and the Marxists to which we could turn for enlightenment). In short, we needed a whole host of mediations to get from Marx’s Capital to the political issues that concerned us. And it frequently entailed an act of faith in the whole history of the Marxist movement (or in some charismatic figure like Mao or Castro) to believe in the inner connection between Marx’s Capital and all that we were interested in. This is not to say there was nothing in the text to fascinate and delight – the extraordinary insights that came from consideration of the com- modity fetish, the wonderful sense of how class struggle had altered the world from the pristine forms of capital accumulation that Marx described. And once one got used to it, the text provided its own peculiar and beguiling pleasures. But the plain fact was that Capital did not have that much direct relevance to daily life. It described capitalism in its raw, unmodified, and most barbaric nineteenth-century state. The situation today is radically different. The text teems with ideas as to how to explain our current state. There is the fetish of the market that caught out that lover of children Kathy Lee Gifford when she was told that the line of clothing she was selling through Wal-Mart was made either by thirteen-year-olds in Honduras paid a mere pittance or by sweated women workers in New York who had not been paid for weeks. There is also the whole savage history of downsizing (prominently reported on in the New York Times), the scandals over child labor in Pakistan in the manufacture of carpets and soccer balls (a scandal that was forced upon FIFA’s attention), and Michael Jordan’s $30 million retainer for Nike, set against press accounts of the appalling conditions of Nike workers in Indonesia and Vietnam. The press is full of complaints as to how technological change is destroying employ- ment opportunities, weakening the institutions of organized labor and increasing rather than lightening the intensity and hours of labor (all central themes of Marx’s chapter on “Machinery and Modem Industry”). And then there is the whole ques- tion of how an “industrial reserve army” of labor has been produced, sustained, and manipulated in the interests of capital accumulation these last decades, includ- ing the public admission by Alan Budd, an erstwhile advisor to Margaret Thatcher, that the fight against inflation in the early 1980s was a cover for raising unem- ployment and reducing the strength of the working class. “What was engineered,” he said, “in Marxist terms was a crisis in capitalism which re-created a reserve army THE DIFFERENCE A GENERATION MAKES 23 of labour, and has allowed the capitalists to make high profits ever since” (Brooks, 1992). All of this now makes it all too easy to connect Marx’s text to daily life. Stu- dents who stray into the course soon feel the heat of what amounts to a devastat- ing critique of a world of free-market neo-liberalism run riot. For their final paper I give them bundles of cuttings from the New York Times (a respectable source, after all) and suggest they use them to answer an imaginary letter from a parent/ relative/friend from home that says:

I hear you are taking a course on Marx’s Das Kapital. I have never read it myself though I hear it is both interesting and difficult. But thank heavens we have put that nineteenth-century nonsense behind us now. Life was hard and terrible in those days, but we have come to our collective senses and made a world that Marx would surely never recognize . . .

They write illuminating and often devastatingly critical letters in reply. Though they dare not send them, few finish the course without having their views disrupted by the sheer power of a text that connects so trenchantly with conditions around us. Herein, then, lies a paradox. This text of Marx’s was much sought after and studied in radical circles at a time when it had little direct relationship to daily life. But now, when the text is so pertinent, scarcely anyone cares to consider it.

2 The Work of Postmodernity The paradox I have described relates to a massive discursive shift that has occurred over the past three decades. There are all kinds of aspects to this shift and it is easy to get lost in a mass of intricacies and complexities. But what is now striking is the dominance of an almost fairy-tale-like belief, held on all sides alike, that once upon a time there was structuralism, modernism, industrialism, Marxism, or what have you and now there is post-structuralism, postmodernism, postindustrialism, post- Marxism, post-colonialism, and so forth. Like all such tales, this one is rarely spoken of in such a crude or simplistic way. To do so would be particularly embarrassing to those who deny in principle the significance of broad-based “metanarratives.” Yet the prevalence of “the post” (and the associated inability to say what it is that we might be “pre”) is a dominant characteristic of contemporary debate. It has also become a serious game in academia to hunt the covert modernists (if you are a dedicated postmodernist) or to hunt the decadent postmodernists (if you happen to be in favor of some sort of modernist revival). One of the consequences of this prevalent fairy tale (and I call it that to capture its beguiling power) is that it is impossible to discuss Marx or Marxism outside of these dominant terms of debate. For example, one quite common reaction to my recent work, particularly Justice, Nature and the Geography of Difference, is to express surprise and disbelief at how I seem to merge modernist and postmodernist, structuralist and poststructuralist arguments (see, e.g., Eagleton, 1997). But Marx had not read Saussure or Lévi Strauss and while there are some powerful struc- turalist readings of Marx (principally by Althusser) the evidence that Marx was a 24 DAVID HARVEY structuralist or even a modernist avant la lettre, as these terms came to be under- stood in the 1970s, is neither overwhelming nor conclusive. Analyses based on Marx’s work collide with the beguiling power of this fairy-tale reading of our recent discursive history. Put bluntly, we do not read Marx these days (no matter whether he is relevant or not) because he is someone whose work lies in a category that we are supposed to be “post.” Or if we do read him, it is solely through the lenses pro- vided by what it is we believe we are “post.” Now it is indeed interesting to look at Marx’s oeuvre through such lenses. He was, of course, an avid critic of classical bourgeois political economy and devoted much of his life to “deconstructing” its dominant principles. He was deeply con- cerned with language (discourse) and was acutely aware of how discursive shifts (of the sort he examined in depth in The Eighteenth Brumaire) carried their own dis- tinctive political freight. He understood in a deep sense the relationship between knowledge and “situatedness” (“positionality”) though it was, of course, the “standpoint” of the worker that was the focus of his attention. I could go on and on in this vein, but my point here is not to try to prove that much of what passes for innovative in our recent discursive history is already pre-figured in Marx, but to point to the damage that the fairy-tale reading of the differences between the “then” and the “now” is doing to our abilities to confront the changes occurring around us. Cutting ourselves off from Marx is to cut off our investigative noses to satisfy the superficial face of contemporary intellectual fashion. Bearing this in mind, let me now focus on two facets of this discursive shift that have occurred since around 1970: those captured through the terms “globalization” and “the body.” Both terms were little if at all in evidence as analytical tools in the early 1970s. Both are now powerfully present; they can even be regarded as con- ceptual dominants. “Globalization,” for example, was entirely unknown before the mid-1970s. Innumerable conferences now study the idea. There is a vast literature on the subject, coming at it from all angles. It is a frequent topic of commentary in the media. It is now one of the most hegemonic concepts for understanding the political economy of international capitalism. And its uses extend far beyond the business world to embrace questions of politics, culture, national identity, and the like. So where did this concept come from? Does it describe something essen- tially new? “Globalization” seems first to have acquired its prominence as American Express advertised the global reach of its credit card in the mid-1970s. The term then spread like wildfire in the financial and business press, mainly as legitimation for the deregu- lation of financial markets. It then helped make the diminution in state powers to regulate capital flows seem inevitable and became an extraordinarily powerful polit- ical tool in the disempowerment of national and local working-class movements and trade union power (labor discipline and fiscal austerity – often imposed by the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank – became essential to achieving internal stability and international competitiveness). And by the mid-1980s it helped create a heady atmosphere of entrepreneurial optimism around the theme of the liberation of markets from state control. It became a central concept, in short, associated with the brave new world of globalizing neo-liberalism. It helped make it seem as if we were entering upon a new era (with a touch of teleological inevitability thrown in) and thereby became part of that package of concepts THE DIFFERENCE A GENERATION MAKES 25 that distinguished between then and now in terms of political possibilities. The more the left adopted this discourse as a description of the state of the world (even if it was a state to be criticized and rebelled against), the more it circumscribed its own political possibilities. That so many of us took the concept on board so uncritically in the 1980s and 1990s, allowing it to displace the far more politically charged con- cepts of imperialism and neocolonialism, should give us pause. It made us weak opponents of the politics of globalization particularly as these became more and more central to everything that US foreign policy was trying to achieve. The only politics left was a politics of conserving and in some instances downright conser- vative resistance. There is, however, one other angle on much of this that may have equally deep significance. The NASA satellite image entitled “Earth Rise” depicted the earth as a free-floating globe in space. It quickly assumed the status of an icon of a new kind of consciousness. But the geometrical properties of a globe are different from those of a two-dimensional map. It has no natural boundaries save those given by lands and oceans, cloud covers and vegetation patterns, deserts and well-watered regions. Nor does it have any particular center. It is perhaps no accident that the awareness of the artificiality of all those boundaries and centers that had hitherto dominated thinking about the world became much more acute. It became much easier, with this icon of the globe hanging in the background, to write of a “borderless world” (as Miyoshi, 1997, has so persuasively done) and to take a radically decentered approach to culture (with the massive cultural traditions of China, India, South America, and Africa suddenly looking as salient and as geographically dominant across segments of the globe as those of the West). Travel around the world, already much easier, suddenly had no natural stopping point and the continuity of spatial relations suddenly becomes both practically and rhetorically a fundamental fact of life. And it may well be that the focus on the body as the center of all things is itself a response to this decentering of everything else, promoted by the image of the globe (rather than the two-dimensional map) as the locus of human activity and thought. So what of the body? Here the tale, though analogous, is substantially different. The extraordinary efflorescence of interest in “the body” as a grounding for all sorts of theoretical enquiries over the last two decades has a dual origin. In the first place, the questions raised particularly through what is known as “second-wave feminism” could not be answered without close attention being paid to the “nature–nurture” problem and it was inevitable that the status and understanding of “the body” became central to theoretical debate. Questions of gender, sexuality, the power of symbolic orders, and the significance of psychoanalysis also repositioned the body as both subject and object of discussion and debate. And to the degree that all of this opened up a terrain of enquiry that was well beyond traditional conceptual apparatuses (such as that contained in Marx), so an extensive and original theoriz- ing of the body became essential to progressive and emancipatory politics (this was particularly the case with respect to feminist and queer theory). And there is indeed much that has been both innovative and profoundly progressive within this movement. The second impulse to return to the body arose out of the movements of post-structuralism in general and deconstruction in particular. The effect of these 26 DAVID HARVEY movements was to generate a loss of confidence in all previous established cate- gories (such as those proposed by Marx) for understanding the world. And it is in this context that the connexion between decentering and the figure of the globe may have done its undermining work. The effect, however, was to provoke a return to the body as the irreducible basis for understanding. Lowe (1995, p. 14) argues that:

[T]here still remains one referent apart from all the other destabilized referents, whose presence cannot be denied, and that is the body referent, our very own lived body. This body referent is in fact the referent of all referents, in the sense that ultimately all sig- nifieds, values, or meanings refer to the delineation and satisfaction of the needs of the body. Precisely because all other referents are now destabilized, the body referent, our own body, has emerged as a problem.

The convergence of these two broad movements has refocused attention upon the body as the basis for understanding and, in certain circles at least (particularly those animated by writers such as Foucault and Judith Butler), as the privileged site of political resistance and emancipatory politics. [Let me] comment on the positioning of these two discursive regimes [– “glo- balization” and “the body” –] in our contemporary constructions. “Globalization” is the most macro of all discourses that we have available to us while that of “the body” is surely the most micro from the standpoint of understanding the workings of society (unless, that is, we succumb to the reductionism of seeing society as merely an expression of DNA codings and genetic evolutions). These two discursive regimes, globalization and the body, operate at opposite ends of the spectrum in the scalar we might use to understand social and political life. But little or no system- atic attempt has been made to integrate “body talk” with “globalization talk.” The only strong connections to have emerged in recent years concern individual and human rights (e.g., the work of Amnesty International), and, more specifically, the right of women to control their own bodies and reproductive strategies as a means to approach global population problems (dominant themes in the Cairo Conference on Population in 1994 and the Beijing Women’s Conference of 1996). Environ- mentalists often try to forge similar connections, linking personal health and con- sumption practices with global problems of toxic waste generation, ozone depletion, global warming, and the like. These instances illustrate the potency and the power of linking two seemingly disparate discursive regimes. The line of argument I shall use is broadly based in a relational conception of dialectics embodied in the approach that I have come to call “historical- geographical materialism.” I want, at the outset, to lay out just one fundamental tenet of this approach in order to lay another of the key shibboleths of our time as firmly to rest as I can. And this concerns the tricky question of the relation between “particularity” and “universality” in the construction of knowledge. I deny that we have a choice between particularity or universality in our mode of thinking and argumentation. Within a relational dialectics one is always inter- nalized and implicated in the other. There is a link between, for example, the par- ticularities of concrete labors occurring in particular places and times (the seamstress in Bangladesh who made my shirt), and the measured value of that labor arrived at through processes of exchange, commodification, monetization, and, of course, THE DIFFERENCE A GENERATION MAKES 27 the circulation and accumulation of capital. One conception of labor is concrete and particular and the other is abstract and “universal” (in the sense that it is achieved through specific processes of generalization). Obviously, there could be no abstract labor at all without a million and one con- crete labors occurring throughout the world. But what is then interesting is the way in which the qualities of concrete labor respond and internalize the force of abstract labor as achieved through global trade and interaction. Workers engaging in pro- ductive concrete labors suddenly find themselves laid off, downsized, rendered tech- nologically obsolete, forced to adapt to new labor processes and conditions of work, simply because of the force of competition (or, put in the terms proposed here, the concrete labor adjusts to abstract conditions at the same time as the qualities of abstract labor depend upon movements and transitions in concrete labor processes in different places and times). I have used this example to illustrate a general point. The particularity of the body cannot be understood independently of its embeddedness in socio-ecological processes. If, as many now argue, the body is a social construct, then it cannot be understood outside of the forces that swirl around it and construct it. One of those key determinants is the labor process, and globalization describes how that process is being shaped by political-economic and associated cultural forces in distinctive ways. It then follows that the body cannot be understood, theoretically or empiri- cally, outside of an understanding of globalization. But conversely, boiled down to its simplest determinations, globalization is about the sociospatial relations between billions of individuals. Herein lies the foundational connexion that must be made between two discourses that typically remain segregated, to the detriment of both. Part of the work of postmodernity as a set of discursive practices over the last two decades has been to fragment and sever connexions. In some instances this proved a wise, important, and useful strategy to try to unpack matters (such as those of sexuality or the relation to nature) that would otherwise have remained hidden. But it is now time to reconnect. There is a final point that I need to make. One important root of the so-called “cultural turn” in recent thinking lies in the work of Raymond Williams and the study of Gramsci’s writings (both particularly important to the cultural studies movement that began in Birmingham with Stuart Hall as one of its most articulate members). One of the several strange and unanticipated results of this movement has been the transformation of Gramsci’s remark on “pessimism of the intellect and optimism of the will” into a virtual law of human nature. I wish in no way to detract from the extraordinary feats of many on the left who have fought a rearguard action against the wave of neo-liberalism that swept across the advanced capitalist world after 1980. This showed optimism of the will at its noble best. But a powerful inhibitor to action was the inability to come up with an alternative to the Thatcherite doctrine that “there is no alternative” (a phrase that will echo as a recurring refrain throughout this book). The inability to find an “optimism of the intellect” with which to work through alternatives has now become one of the most serious bar- riers to progressive politics. Gramsci penned those famous words while sick and close to death in an Italian prison cell under conditions that were appalling. I think we owe it to him to rec- ognize the contingent nature of the comment. We are not in prison cells. Why, then, 28 DAVID HARVEY might we willingly choose a metaphor drawn from incarceration as a guiding light for our own thinking? Did not Gramsci (1978, p. 213) also bitterly complain, before his incarceration, at the pessimism which produced then the same political passiv- ity, intellectual torpor, and skepticism towards the future as it does now in ours? Do we not also owe it to him, out of respect for the kind of fortitude and political passion he exhibited, to transform that phrase in such a way as to seek an optimism of the intellect that, properly coupled with an optimism of the will, might produce a better future? And if I turn towards the end of this book towards the figure of utopia and if I parallel Raymond Williams’s title Resources of Hope with the title Spaces of Hope, then it is because I believe that in this moment in our history we have something of great import to accomplish by exercising an optimism of the intellect in order to open up ways of thinking that have for too long remained foreclosed. 1998 is, it turns out, a fortuitous year to be writing about such matters. It is the thirtieth anniversary (the usual span given to a generation) of that remarkable movement that shook the world from Mexico City to Chicago, Berlin, and Paris. More locally (for me), it is thirty years now since much of central Baltimore burned in the wake of the riots that followed the assassination of Martin Luther King (I moved from Bristol to Baltimore the year after that). If only for these reasons this is, therefore, a good moment to take stock of that generational shift that I began by reflecting upon. But 1998 is also the 150th anniversary of the publication of that most extraor- dinary of all documents known as The Communist Manifesto. And it happens to be the 50th anniversary of the signing of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights at the United Nations. Connecting these events and reflecting on their general meaning appears a worthwhile way to reflect on our contemporary condition. While Marx was deeply suspicious of all talk about rights (sensing it to be a bourgeois trap), what on earth are workers of the world supposed to unite about unless it is some sense of their fundamental rights as human beings? Connecting the sentiments of the Manifesto with those expressed in the Declaration of Human Rights provides one way to link discourses about globalization with those of the body. The overall effect, I hope, is to redefine in a more subtle way the terms and spaces of political struggle open to us in these extraordinary times. Chapter 2 Industry and Space: A Sympathetic Critique of Radical Research

Andrew Sayer

1 Introduction In the last decade there have been major advances in the theory of industrial loca- tion and uneven spatial development, both at the international and the subnational or regional levels. In terms of theory, this research has drawn upon and extended primarily Marxist concepts, though often in alliance with concepts from institu- tionalist economics and empirical studies of industry. At both spatial scales many researchers have recently shifted from theoretical exegesis to empirical application, with the result that we can now begin to see more clearly how the theories work in practice. The misgivings voiced here about their adequacy have been developed in the course of ongoing research on the electronics industry and regional develop- ment which I have undertaken with Kevin Morgan. In this paper, I shall outline a critique and illustrate the points with empirical examples from this concrete research. The dissatisfactions cover a variety of particular issues. But beneath almost all of these lie a few pervasive problems of theory and method whose identification justifies the use of the term critique rather than criticism. Moreover, it will be argued that the problems identified in the realm of theory and empirical research repeatedly carry over into misguided prescriptions about what should be done about industry and regional development in the realm of practice. In the second part of the paper these underlying problems are identified in stark abstract terms. In the third and main section, the particular issues mentioned above are discussed as instances of these problems and their consequences illustrated in terms of understanding concrete phenomena by means of examples drawn largely from our research.

2 Underlying Problems of Theory, Method, and Orientation These cover the content of theory, method or the way theory is used in concrete research, and the general orientations or patterns of selection of material in con- 30 ANDREW SAYER ducting research. Although highly related, I shall separate them into three classes for the purpose of expositional clarity.

Problem A: “Pseudoconcrete analysis” This concerns the relationship of abstract and concrete research: the problem takes the form either of a reduction of the con- crete to the abstract or of a fetishization of certain transient and contingent social forms as the only possible results of capitalist development, with a consequent underestimation of the variety of forms that the latter can take. My case rests upon a realist interpretation of method (see Sayer, 1982a, 1982b, 1984). On this view, abstract theory isolates one-sided aspects of the objects of inter- est, particularly those elements of the process or system which are necessarily related; for example, in an abstract analysis of capital accumulation, the necessary conditions for the realization of surplus value. In so doing, it abstracts from the many contingent concrete forms that capital accumulation may take. Concrete forms of development represent combinations of processes and elements, some nec- essarily related, others contingently related, and each of which may be isolated by abstract theory. These combinations of contingent and necessary relationships can easily mislead. It often happens that, although a particular combination of objects is contingent, when it does happen to occur, certain tendencies follow necessarily; for example, it is contingent whether capital ever uses electric power, but, where it does, its actions are constrained and enabled by the range of inherent (necessary) powers and liabilities of electricity. Moreover, a complicating factor is that the powers and liabilities of people can change as they learn new skills, as they come to understand their situation differently, and as they adopt new forms of organiza- tions with their own powers and liabilities; for example, unions possess powers not wholly reducible to those of the individuals who constitute them. Despite its extraordinary breadth, Marxism does not monopolize the abstract theory relevant for understanding concrete phenomena. For example, as we shall see, concrete forms of capital accumulation are influenced by technological devel- opments whose explanation lies partly outside Marxism. Whether the combination of abstractions from different sources is successful, or merely eclectic and inconsis- tent, depends on how it is done. What is certain is that concrete forms of develop- ment cannot simply be “read off” from Marxist or neo-Marxist abstract theory, or for that matter, from any other abstract theory. Concrete systems include contin- gent relations whose form cannot be theorized and hence known in advance, but which must be discovered empirically. Conversely, theories cannot be derived suc- cessfully by reading them off from concrete forms: for example, summaries of par- ticular concrete forms of uneven development cannot be turned into theoretical models or ideal types without making a radical underestimation of the range of other possible contingent forms and of their historical specificity. Yet this is pre- cisely what has happened in the study of uneven development. Particular attempts to produce descriptive generalizations about the concrete forms of development have been interpreted – often against the intentions of their authors – as a model or stereo- type or way of seeing, such that types of development which do not conform to these local, historically specific generalizations are rendered almost invisible. In some cases, as we shall see, the original descriptive generalizations were not even accu- rate for their intended objects, let alone others. INDUSTRY AND SPACE 31

Problem B The second problem concerns space and its identification with process, or more specifically the identification of particular sets of processes with particular spaces, such as a certain kind of economic activity with, say, metropolitan regions. Space and process have to be identified together somehow, because neither can exist independently of the other – but the problem is how? Because the spatial forms in which objects occur are contingent, we abstract from space in abstract theory according to a principal of “spatial indifference.” So, for example, Marx’s abstract discussion of capital abstracts from the particular spatial contexts in which concrete instances of capital find themselves. However, in a concrete study, we have to take account of how capital (or whatever) is affected by these contingent conditions, and this cannot be understood apart from their spatial and temporal form. So, as Sack (1980) puts it, having been abstracted, space and form must be “recombined.” Yet, it is one thing to note that any material process, such as industrial capital, must have spatial extension and hence is not “aspatial,” but quite another to recombine space and process by identifying something as heterogeneous as a certain kind of industry (for example, basic production and assembly) with an even more hetero- geneous type of region (for example, peripheral regions), so that it appears one can “read off” one from the other. As we shall see, the theoretical grounds for making such identifications are flimsy indeed.

Problem C The third problem is of a rather different kind, but as will be shown it interacts with problems A and B in a strikingly recurrent manner. It relates to the theoretical and political priorities of Marxist and other radical research which govern the relative attention given to different kinds of economic activity and person. Perhaps the most general of these priorities is now being challenged by fem- inist research: the priority of paid over unpaid work. Another is the neglect of services, again possibly reinforced by sexist biases with regard to what are con- sidered to be “real” jobs. But even within manufacturing studies, certain biases are clear:

(a) towards basic standardized mass production and assembly, and away from custom and small batch production, and project production (for example, civil engineering production); (b) a slight bias towards consumer industries and away from producer industries, or a tendency to assume that the second are no different from the first; (c) towards manual work, away from clerical and administrative work, away from management, research and development, and marketing (consequently, labor- process studies tend to reduce the diverse kinds of labor process going on in a plant to one central stage of manufacture, ignoring prior and subsequent manual work and ignoring administrative labor processes); (d) towards the bottom of the status hierarchy; (e) towards declining regions and localities and away from relatively prosperous ones; (f) towards the more radical kinds of worker and region, and towards combative industrial relations. 32 ANDREW SAYER

Together these biases explain why there is plenty to read on car-workers and the like, and more recently on the female assembly worker, but little on the wages clerk, telephone operator, or technician; also why we know so little about southern non- metropolitan England compared with the assisted areas and inner cities. Even where researchers break out of this system of preferences, it is usually in a very limited way, and within the terms of the remaining priorities; so, for example, recent studies of female workers tend to concentrate on those engaged in manual work such as assembly rather than, say, on canteen staff or office workers (for example, Pollert, 1981; Cavendish, 1982). In part, such biases are perfectly understandable for Left researchers insofar as they prioritize the worse-off (though probably not the worst-off), but they are also influenced by what are little more than prejudices – in particular, leftist intellectu- als images of the “ideal” or “real” (either adjective will do) worker. The Left is nat- urally more interested in workers than in supervisors, managers, and professionals and in radical rather than conservative regions, but ignoring the latter does not help our understanding either of economic change or of the political forces supported by the neglected fractions. Insofar as classes (in the Marxist sense) are internally related, one simply cannot expect to understand one class independently of the other. However, some of the biases are also induced by practical considerations of doing research; for example, the greater ease of understanding producers of mass goods relative to producers of highly-differentiated goods and services and the restriction of participant observation to groups with status lower than that of the researcher. I do not pretend that I have been immune to these biases but I believe that they have supported a distorted and outdated view of existing society and hence one which is unhelpful in guiding our thinking about what an alternative society could be like.

3 Specific Criticisms in Industrial and Regional Studies Having outlined these three basic problems of theory, method, and orientation, we can now proceed to see how they generate more substantive problems in the study of industry and space. My criticisms of radical research in this area concern both distortions and omissions in the use of theory in interpreting empirical cases, and, as I hope will become clear, many of them overlap and reinforce one another.

3.1 The neglect of use-values, technology, and product innovation As many authors have pointed out (for example, Rosdolsky, 1977; Grossman, 1978; Harvey, 1982), it is wrong to accuse Marx of ignoring use-values. However, as abstract theory, Capital inevitably has to treat use-values generically rather than in terms of their concrete forms and the differences they make. The same could be said of neoclassical economics, even though it conflates value with use-value. As soon as one engages in concrete studies of particular capitalist industries, it becomes apparent that the specific nature of particular use-values and technologies has some crucial effects on capital accumulation and uneven development. Although one cannot (for reasons stated earlier) expect abstract theory to anticipate the actual effects, one might at least expect it to alert us to the problem, so that empirical INDUSTRY AND SPACE 33 research does not inadvertently filter these effects out. There are three specific kinds of problems that I will now detail.

3.1.1 Changes in labor processes and deskilling Many explanations of these changes assume that the range of commodities being produced is fixed or else simply ignore such changes. As a result, excessive explana- tory weight is thrown upon capital’s attempts to wrest control from labor (Tomlinson, 1982, pp. 23–6; Kelly, 1983). This is not to deny the place of class struggle in the labor process as an ever present condition, but some authors (for example, Aglietta, 1979) erect it into the dominant or sole cause of change, perhaps because such an explanation seems more “radical” than others. Labor processes are often changed because the available process technology and/or nature of the product have changed, rather than as a strategy purely aimed at winning greater control over labor for its own sake. In fact, capital may sometimes replace a labor process over which it has great control by one over which it has less control, if the new process is the only existing way of producing a new commodity for which market prospects are better than for its predecessor. Technology is rarely “plastic” in the hands of management; it can create, rather than solve problems of control. There- fore, an increase in labor’s control over the labor process may be a “windfall” gain rather than a hard-won victory, and similarly for capital, if its power over labor is increased. In other words, the power of either side can be affected by changes orig- inating outside the workplace in terms of changes of markets for products (Kelly, 1983). Intensification of labor and deskilling are not the only means towards the end of profit maximization, nor the only possible result: product diversification and cheap- ening of constant capital are alternatives. So new technology may or may not have the effect of weakening labor’s control over production, and when that effect does occur it may or may not be the main reason for its introduction. Certainly an expla- nation of changing work organization which puts all the weight on the historic struggle between capital and labor sounds more radical – until that is, you notice how this gives the impression that labor must lose in the long run as the forces of production develop and capital inexorably deskills labor – but in any case having a radical ring does not make a theory right. The exaggeration of deskilling owes its influence to Braverman’s eloquent but flawed Labor and Monopoly Capital (1974); it seems to have become a conven- tional wisdom that on balance, changes in capitalist labor processes (necessarily) induce a net deskilling effect. If one theorizes or empirically investigates the history of the labor processes used to make a particular product, a long-term deskilling effect seems probable. The problem lies not here but in the assumption that if this is true then it must also be so for the whole economy. As we saw earlier, this is partly an illusion, produced by an abstraction from product innovation and hence from qualitative change in the mix of industries. But it is partly also influenced by a view of early capitalism which ignores its unskilled masses and sees only craft labor, and perhaps by a modern tendency to ignore newer skills whose possessors do not fit stereotypes of real or ideal workers. New technologies, products, and industries may involve reskilling, and, although these are likely to decline too for any product in the long term, there will in turn be successive new products at later 34 ANDREW SAYER dates. Even new process (as opposed to product) technologies need not necessarily involve net deskilling if the new machinery outweighs the higher cost of the more skilled labor needed to run it In any case, the concept of “deskilling,” not to mention “skill” itself, also seems ill defined, insofar as it is sometimes used to refer to individuals and at other times to refer to the content of jobs, often in the same analysis. If large numbers of low skilled are made redundant, as has happened in recent years, the remaining opera- tor jobs may either be deskilled or be reskilled, but overall the proportion of the low skilled jobs will decrease; it seems odd to call this a case of “deskilling.” In electronics the proportion of skilled jobs, even allowing for definitional problems, has risen, and at several levels there has been a shift towards “multiskilling” which eludes a simple deskilling–reskilling categorization. As it is contingent whether deskilling or reskilling is dominant in the economy, it must be treated as an empirical question. Interestingly, I find that those who have done extensive empirical research on skills are far more circumspect about the overall direction of change than those who have merely read Braverman and fol- lowers (see EITB, 1981; Kelly, 1983). There is also often some reluctance on the Left to believe that there can ever be serious shortages of technical skills and that such shortages can inhibit development.

3.1.2 Economies of scale Problems of abstraction from product differentiation also contribute to misinter- pretations of the effect of scale on the economies of production. It is easy to get the impression from some theoretical literature that economies of scale are a simple phe- nomenon or an independent variable, and that optimal scales of production will rise inexorably. Frequently, business or economics literature cites optimal scales which are far beyond that achieved by any firms, for example, in the car industry, the figure of 1 million units per annum for engine plants, even though this has probably never been approached (D. T. Jones, personal communication). Belief in such figures pro- duces puzzlement over how so many firms survive with lower volumes – and not just marginal firms but leading ones too. There are several reasons for this gap between theoretical expectations and empir- ical evidence. One is that abstraction from product differentiation conceals the extent to which the market is segmented, thereby limiting scale of output and induc- ing firms to sacrifice length of production runs for the sake of gaining entry into more sectors of the market. Again, it is not necessarily in the interests of firms to try to homogenize their products excessively because they can also compete more effectively by making themselves different. (Competition is invariably contradictory: sometimes the most effective competitors are those who manage to reduce com- petition, and product standardization as a means to becoming more competitive may reduce a firm’s competitiveness by intensifying competition.) In practice, the stagnation of demand associated with the ending of the postwar long boom has enhanced the attractiveness of product-diversification strategies over maximum- scale strategies. Further problems arise from the tendency to treat economies of scale as an inde- pendent variable when in fact they depend upon a number of conditions internal INDUSTRY AND SPACE 35 to the plant, which can be changed: for example, the setup time for machines, the costs of maintaining large inventories and coordinating long production runs of parts needed in different amounts, and more generally particular ways of organizing the production process. Change these conditions, and optimal scale changes, and not necessarily upwards. In fact, the most significant innovations in recent years in process technology and management techniques point to greatly reduced lot sizes in production. On the technical side, computerized numerical control (CNC) and computer-aided design and manufacture (CAD/CAM) have given some respite to smaller producers such as Jaguar in the car industry. More dramatically, on the management side, familiar Western ideas that the secret of profitable production lies in the single-minded pursuit of maximum volumes and line speeds have been turned upside down by the revolutionary Japanese “just-in-time” system of production which unearths and eliminates formerly hidden sources of diseconomies (Ohno, 1982; Schonberger, 1982; Abernathy et al., 1983). This is not to say that firms do not still gain from volume but that volume on its own does not guarantee maximized productivity. Last, a further influence tending to strengthen smaller units of production is the growing consensus in management circles that small plants make for less-adversarial indus- trial relations. The spatial consequences of these developments are dealt with later.

3.1.3 The technical and social divisions of labor Another possibly related problem concerns a common underestimation of nonmar- ket interactions in exchanges between firms. Frequently, radical distinction is drawn between the technical division of labor within a firm involved in making a particu- lar product and the social division of labor between firms and between different kinds of production. The first is planned a priori and carefully controlled by man- agement, whereas the second relies upon the anarchy of the market and is regulated a posteriori in response to market signals. However, an important qualification to this contrast, particularly the description of markets as “anarchic,” is required to deal with market transactions which are set within a context of buyer–seller inter- actions which to a certain extent lock the activities of both parties together. These are most obvious in inter-industry transactions where firms do not merely send an order to another firm in return for goods but actually intervene in the management of the subcontracting form in order to guarantee supply and quality. Also, techno- logical interdependencies between the products and components of the firms lock them into a more rigid and controlled relationship than would a simple market exchange. By such means, major firms (for example, oil companies) are able, to a certain degree, to manage labor processes in other firms “at a distance,” without the impediment of formal ownership responsibilities. In some cases it might there- fore be legitimately argued that the technical division of labor can be extended to embrace a network of firms under separate ownership. Indeed, if as I suspect, this form of industrial organization is becoming more common, a rethinking is required of the concept of industrial concentration, for some of the “largest” companies in revenue terms may do little more than manage production undertaken by other firms. 36 ANDREW SAYER

3.2 Misleading stereotypes of the spatial division of labor One of the most important sources of progress in understanding the space economy has come from the recognition of the interdependence of activities in different areas as parts of a “spatial division of labor.” This may take the form of a corporate spatial hierarchy of activities or, at a more aggregate level, a spatially segregated division of labor between different kinds or stages of production undertaken within either a national economy or the international economy. As a result it is now real- ized that the performance of individual establishments cannot be understood in abstraction from this context and that the nature of national economies, regions, or other localities may be illuminated by examining them in terms of their place within the international division of labor. But problems start to arise as soon as anyone assumes that these spatial divisions of labor must necessarily take particular forms which are inherent in capital accu- mulation; indeed such an assumption amounts to what I termed in section 2 a misidentification of space and process. The misleading stereotypes I have in mind can be traced back to the work of individual authors, although what I am attack- ing is not so much those authors’ original positions as the popular views of what they said – views which now seem to constitute part of the “common sense” of the Left. As often happens, there are significant differences between the original argu- ments and their popularized versions: the latter tend to be shorn of the many and reasonable qualifications made by the original authors. Three overlapping and similar stereotypes might be distinguished: what I term “Hymer’s stereotype”; the product-cycle stereotype; and the new international divi- sion of labor (NIDL) thesis.

3.2.1 Hymer’s stereotype The first of these can be traced back to Hymer’s ideas about the developing corre- spondence between global patterns of uneven spatial development and the hierar- chical internal structure of multinational firms. Similar ideas – though for different spatial scales – can be found in work by Westaway (1974), Massey (1979), and Lipietz (1980), among others. Hymer’s work on multinationals was innovative and extensive, but its limitations are clear in some of his short and more rhetorical arti- cles, and it is probably ideas such as those contained in the following passages which have seeped into radical consciousness:

a regime of North Atlantic Multinational Corporations would tend to centralize high level decision-making occupations in a few key cities in the advanced countries, sur- rounded by a number of regional subcapitals, and confine the rest of the world to the lower levels of activity and income, i.e. to the status of towns and village: in a new imperial system, income, status, authority and consumption patterns would radiate out from these centres along a declining curve, and the existing pattern of inequality and dependency would be perpetuated. The pattern would be complex, just as the structure of the corporation is complex, but the basic relation between different countries would be one of the superior–subordinate, head office and branch plant. (1975, p. 38)

The association of space and function is still more clearly stated in the same paper. INDUSTRY AND SPACE 37

Table 2.1: “Hymer’s stereotype” (see text), in which the space–process relationship takes the form A–B–C

Level of corporate Type of area hierarchy Major metropolis regional capitals periphery (for (for example, (for example, example, South New York) Brussels) Korea, Ireland)

1 Long-term strategic planning A 2 Management of divisions D B 3 Production, routine work F E C

Since business is usually the core of the city, geographical specialization will come to reflect the hierarchy of corporate decision making, and the occupational distribution of labor in a city or region will depend for its function in the international economic system. (p. 50)

Again it should be stressed that the positive contribution of this work, like that of Murray (1972), was to unite two bodies of theory – on industrial location and regional development – which had formerly been largely separate. But it was the particular way in which capital and region, process and form were related that was problematic, particularly if the following relationship between levels of the corpo- rate hierarchy and region were assumed – see Table 2.1. With certain modifications and adjustments of geographical scale, similar stereo- types could be devised; for example, Lipietz adds a fourth type of region but the principle of his scheme is very similar to that of Table 2.1. According to Hymer’s stereotype, the space–process relationship takes the form A-B-C. But of course, D, E, and F are also present. The interpenetration of corporate hierarchies with multi- national firms with headquarters in different countries and the influence of preex- isting patterns of uneven development make it a poor “model” of the accumulation. At both international and subnational scales and for most sectors, advanced regions dominate levels 2 and 3 in absolute terms, that is, F > E > C.

3.2.2 Product-cycle theory and the new international division of labor thesis In practice, at least with regard to their spatial implications, these two theories tend to be similar. Although the NIDL thesis has received explicit attention on the Left, for example, through the work of Fröbel et al. (1980), the product-cycle theory is rarely endorsed explicitly by such researchers. However, I believe it to have had a significant unacknowledged influence. In this case too, the errors of the resulting stereotype are compounded by those discussed earlier concerning product differen- tiation. As with the Hymer stereotype, the target of my criticisms is more the styl- ized popular version of the spatial implications of the theory than the original work of Vernon (1966). According to the theory, each product passes through a cycle from innovation to standardization, during which the economics, skill, and gender composition of the workforce and location of production change markedly. After innovation, firms 38 ANDREW SAYER move down the “learning curve,” rapidly at first as initial market responses are obtained, then more slowly as the product drops in price and changes from a luxury into a mature product. Innovation and launching the product require close man- agement, research, and technical involvement and also an affluent market which can afford an expensive new product. This suggests a location in a metropolitan region of the home (rich) country. As costs fall, production is moved offshore in search of new markets and cheaper labor so that, by the final stage, the firm imports the product back to the home market. This theory (or model) certainly has a logic to it, but it is easy therefore to over- look how circumscribed that logic is by (largely hidden) restrictive assumptions about the nature of the firm and industry involved and about its external economic environment. Not surprisingly, very few products resemble the model to any degree or for any length of time. According to Cable and Clarke (1981), hand-held elec- tronic calculators are one of the “better” examples, though even here there are some important divergences, such as the recent tendency to shift straight from innovation to production in a Third World country without the intermediate stage of produc- tion in the home country. Second, as with Hymer’s “model,” the product-cycle model and the NIDL thesis give one the expectation that the general nature of regional or national economies can be “read off” from their place within the cor- porate divisions of labor. This is an attractive idea, but at the moment it rarely works in practice, as we shall see; although the spatial stereotypes associated with these models and with the “spatial division of labor thesis” are interesting preparations for research, I have not found them very useful for interpreting concrete instances. The first problem – of an unacknowledged restriction to particular kinds of product – comes out in several ways. One of these is the overestimation of the pres- ence of unskilled labor-intensive production in the later stages of the product cycle, and in this respect the model reinforces the biases of the Hymer stereotype towards cheap labor locations. There is no reason why standardization of process technol- ogy during the life of a product should not make the production process highly capital-intensive rather than labor-intensive so that the advantages of cheap-labor locations are irrelevant. In fact, given the persistence of advanced countries as the most favored locations for direct overseas investment, one suspects that this is usually the case. As has frequently been noted, the “runaway industries” are strictly limited to (certain parts of) a few industries like clothing and electronics. Even within these, changes in the cost structure of production can quickly change the locational strategies of multinationals. For example, many US semiconductor firms have moved assembly stages of production to Third World locations, particularly in Southeast Asia. This appears to support the NIDL thesis that production is being decentralized out of advanced countries. However, more recently, some assembly has been moved back into the advanced countries because increased integration and power of circuitry reduces the relative number of chips to be assembled, and because assembly has become more automated (Rada, 1982). The shift back to the home countries is likely to be slow and uneven as cost balances vary considerably from firm to firm, but some major chip producers, like IBM, have never used offshore manual assembly. A further limitation concerns the paucity of clear-cut instances of products actu- ally completing the cycle. In particular, it is difficult to identify mature and stan- INDUSTRY AND SPACE 39 dardized products: just when they appear to have matured they tend to be modi- fied and/or go through another stage of changing process technology. And in prac- tice it is always difficult to know how big a change in the product must be before it should be treated as a new product. For example, at first sight, cars might appear to be a classic mature product, but significant changes both in process (for example, robots) and in product technology (for example, new wheel designs, ignition, and fuel-efficiency systems) are occurring. They are certainly not cosmetic changes, for success or failure in them can make major differences to sales. In the case of tele- vision production, British firms in the early nineteen seventies did treat televisions as a mature product (though they failed to decentralize production to the newly industrialized countries), but this was an effect rather than a cause of their lack of expenditure on research and development (R&D); their complacent assumptions were rudely shattered by Japanese producers who proceeded to make major inno- vations both in process and in product technology which completely changed the nature of the industry (Arnold, 1984). So paradoxically, although in one sense product-cycle theory deals expressly with product innovation, in another it under- estimates it by abstracting out changes within the development of a single product, thereby drawing attention away from the connections between the development of one product and the next.

3.2.3 The “branch-plant economy” stereotype This resulting exaggeration of the importance of standardized production leads to an underestimation of R&D done in production work, especially process engineer- ing, and encourages the belief that all or nearly all “branch plants” are “mere” “overspill” plants – simply adding to the production capacity of an already stan- dardized product. We might call this a defining feature of the “branch-plant economy” stereotype. However, it hardly makes sense for capital to rest content with existing production methods and products, and to duplicate existing facilities at new locations. Our research on electrical engineering in South Wales and else- where shows the stereotype to be inaccurate. Most branch plants we saw make products which are in some ways novel (for example, to meet the characteristics of a national market in which the firm has not previously sold) and they use produc- tion methods which are in some ways novel. For example, some new branch plants have been set up in Britain by foreign telecommunications firms, but in most cases they will produce new products. However, it may be that the branch-plant economy stereotype had more validity in the nineteen fifties and nineteen sixties, when mass production of standardized products was more prevalent, but, as we saw earlier, product differentiation, new technologies and management systems require us to rethink our assumption. Another factor which militates against the duplication of identical overspill plants is the shift in patterns of internationalization of capital towards “complementation.” By this is meant the specialization of functions within plants of a multinational and their integration into an international production system, where previously each country might have had its own fairly self-contained plants. This has been widely noted in the car industry with its complex cross-border flows of components between different countries (CIS, undated), but it exists on a possibly larger scale in industries such as electronics and computers. This does not necessarily mean that 40 ANDREW SAYER the same model will be sold in all countries. In the car industry it was indeed the intention of the biggest firms to produce a “world car,” but diseconomies of scale and resistance to further homogenization of the product has caused a rethink (Jones, 1983). Coupled with the erroneous view that most branch plants are located in periph- eral areas and that most do routine standardized production is the belief that they employ largely “deskilled” “cheap female labor.” Many of course do and it is true that feminization serves as a rough index of low skill, given discrimination against women, but the problem is again the treatment of historically specific developments as universal. Some decentralization of industry has been largely governed by the search for cheap female labor, and this was particularly important in labor- intensive industries prior to the recession, when many firms met rising demand simply by hiring more operators, who would mostly be women. Once again the exaggeration of the relative importance of mass assembly production contributes to the overestimation of the phenomenon.

3.2.4 The stereotypes in practice At a general methodological level, the basic failing of all these stereotypes is that they freeze, and then present as universal, relationships which are contingent and historically specific. They therefore combine problems A and B in section 2 (pseudo- concrete analysis and misidentification of space and process), but problem C in the shape of the exaggeration of the relative importance of mass standardized produc- tion and its workforces is also influential. When applied in practice, these stereotypes fail to come to terms with the fact that most foreign direct investment is located within the most advanced regions and countries, by exaggerating the significance of labor-intensive production and cheap labor locations and underestimating capital-intensive and high-skill-intensive activ- ity and the consequent need for market locations. This is surely why it seems easier to find literature on electronics in Southeast Asia than it does on electronics in Europe and America, and why the South East is so neglected by researchers in com- parison with other British regions! The stereotypes are also based on a very limited subset of firms, that is, certain kinds of US multinational. In presenting themselves as universally applicable, they encourage a “fallacy of composition” (Elster, 1979) in which it is not realized that what is possible for some individuals (in this case, firms) cannot be possible for all individuals simultaneously. Now we have seen that the attraction of theories of the internationalization of capital lies in the fact that they suggest the possibility of being able to “read off” the characteristics of regional and national economies from their place in the inter- national order. This would seem to make sense insofar as economies are dominated by international capital. But, as with the Hymer stereotype, whether it is successful depends again on the way the corporate structures are portrayed and hence on how process and space are identified. Obviously there are problems of extrapolating from a few sectors to multisector economies. In our research, we have tried to make more modest inferences about the characteristics of national and regional electronics industries on the basis of their supposed place in the corporate hierarchies. INDUSTRY AND SPACE 41

Attempting to minimize these problems does not mean retreating into a position where any attempt to discover the logic behind behavior is abandoned. Although behavior is more complex than the models suggest, it is not random and it has a rationale. In realist terms, it can be understood by a method which uses abstraction of causal mechanisms and necessary relations coupled with understanding (verste- hen) of the reasons which cause actors to act as they do, and not by the traditional method of attempting universal generalizations of contingent patterns. In all the examples we have discussed, the logic of capital accumulation is still present, but it constantly adapts to changes in labor, technology, and markets, each of which have their own causal powers and liabilities. Small wonder then that the outcomes continually elude models which freeze and attempt to extrapolate contingent patterns. Let us consider an illustrative example: we might, on the basis of a rigid and restrictive interpretation of models of corporate structure, conjecture that R&D and marketing functions would be at opposite ends of the corporate hierarchy and so be spatially independent of each other. If (contingent fact) the product is a mass one and highly standardized then they probably will be separate. If on the other hand (contingent fact) the product is not standardized but has to be adapted to buyers’ needs (for example, business software and custom electronic components) then R&D may be integrated both functionally and spatially with marketing and after- sales service functions. (Actually, a more careful and flexible reading of product- cycle literature would alert one to such a possibility.) Both cases are driven by the dictates of capital accumulation and competition, but the effects are crucially medi- ated by contingent facts. When one knows what these contingent facts are in a par- ticular situation, the interpretation of the conditional logic of the situation (that is, conditional on whatever contingencies are present) is not difficult. In fact the struc- ture of such explanations is quite ordinary: for example, we know that a bomb has a certain power to explode, but that whether it ever will do so is dependent on the contingent condition of its being detonated; we also know that the effects of its det- onation cannot be known if we do not know what the contingent conditions are in which it has been detonated – concrete, glass, or whatever – but when (through empirical investigation), those conditions are discovered, the explanation of the effects is not necessarily difficult. In both cases – capital accumulation or physical events – satisfactory explanation requires care in moving from abstract knowledge about mechanisms through an observation of contingent conditions to the concrete level of events which they codetermine (Sayer, 1984). And such a procedure is our best safeguard against the three basic problems identified in section 2. As the phenomena we are discussing are social, some of the causes of changes will be reasons held by actors for doing things. Their actions in turn will pre- suppose certain structures of social relations and other material conditions (for example, buying presupposes relations of exchange, commodity production). But one of the special properties of reasons which is not possessed by physical causes is that they are meaningful and based on some understanding of a situation held by the actor. As such the understanding may be in some way false and yet causally effective nevertheless. It is this relationship of understanding between actors and their situations which makes the realm of contingency seem large in social science relative to natural science. Ironically, understanding and learning – the very things 42 ANDREW SAYER that make knowledge possible – are also the very things that make explanation of social phenomena difficult, because they mean that people’s ways of acting are not restricted to a fixed repertoire of responses. Nevertheless, the meaningful character of reasons provides solutions as well as problems: precisely because they can be understood, the explanation of human action, however changeable, need not be par- ticularly difficult, indeed many actions are adequately explained in quite everyday terms. (Students of other cultures in different language communities experience more difficulty in explaining action simply because they lack the advantage of prior acquaintance with the sense of actors’ reasons; until they acquire this understand- ing, actions are indeed a mystery. So, far from being a problem, verstehen is a solution.) Although actors’ reasons are never based on perfect understanding of situations (no one’s are) their understanding is unlikely to be utterly inadequate if it informs practice. To some degree it is likely to grasp some of the patterns of necessity and contingency in the world, both natural and social, and learning consists largely in refining and extending this grasp. So, for example, the process engineer learns how to improve the manipulations of the inherent (that is, necessary) causal powers and liabilities of machines and materials, and managers learn those of particular orga- nizational forms; indeed, the material process of production is hardly intelligible without an implicit realist ontology (Sayer, 1984).

3.3 Space and proximity Associated with these stereotypes of spatial divisions of labor are some popular mis- conceptions about the significance of space, distance, and proximity. The crudest – and fortunately least widely held – of these is the idea that the reduction of transport costs and times has rendered location unimportant and made more firms “footloose.” Yet spatial “effects” are invariably double-edged; the removal of the protection of distance and the annihilation of space by time exposes capital to a greater variety of possible operating environments than hitherto and competition forces them to be more selective in their location decisions. In terms of space and distance, the runaway industry phenomenon exemplifies the conquering of space; in terms of spatial differentiation, it represents a heightened response. The “anni- hilation of space” for one process allows the significance of proximity for another to increase. Proximity to markets in order to ensure good access is still important, especially for the sale of specialized production goods. One of the reasons why large foreign computer firms operating in Britain do better than their British equivalents is that they can afford to set up larger and denser networks of service centers, thereby giving them closer access to customers (Sciberras et al., 1978). Superficially, such instances of the internationalization of production and marketing might be read one-sidedly as evidence of some inexorable annihilation of space, ignoring the complementary localization process. We have already discussed the possible spatial relationship between R&D and marketing, and the difference between mass marketing standardized products as against highly customized products can be seen as an illustration of the dependence of spatial effects on the processes involved. In the case of R&D and top manage- ment, proximity still confers considerable advantages for product innovation. INDUSTRY AND SPACE 43

Boston’s Route 128, and Silicon Valley demonstrate the strength of the localization of top scientific and managerial skills and the direct investments by European firms in such areas demonstrate their immobility relative to the mobility of money-capital. Although there may be “cultural” advantages in separating routine production work and R&D, on account of the different kinds of worker involved, there are also advantages in colocating them, insofar as this allows compatibility between process and product development to be maximized; Japanese consumer electronics firms have exploited such advantages of colocation for some time now and recently IBM have followed suit in combining product development and production of their personal computer at Boca Raton, FL (Business Week, 1983). Developments in CAD/CAM also shift the economies of development and production in favor of agglomeration of different spheres of production (Kaplinsky, 1984). Another development which points to increasing agglomeration is the “just-in- time” method of production, with its need for frequent interplant movements of small lots of goods and close buyer–seller coordination. As these methods begin to diffuse outside Japan we find examples of firms known for their high degree of inter- nationalization, like General Motors, Apple, Motorola, Hewlett Packard, Kawasaki, Sony, and Nissan, setting up localized networks of plants and suppliers (Business Week, 1984). This is not to suggest that such firms will “deinternationalize” or that the growth of interest in internationalized production systems has been misplaced – on the con- trary. It is merely to point out the double-edged effects of space and the depend- ence of such effects on the nature of the processes involved. Equally, at the same time there are undoubtedly other developments which encourage greater decentral- ization of production, for example computerization of production administration, “modularization” of production processes, not to mention the fear of the power that workers derive from large agglomerations (Murray, 1983). Again the general thrust behind these points about space takes us back to the three problems identified in section 2: in order of obviousness, first the care needed in identifying space with process (problem B); second the related danger of freezing contingent patterns or reductionist explanations (problem A); and third the neglect of activities such as R&D, marketing and servicing, and customized production relative to less spatially restricted activities such as mass production (problem C).

3.4 The neglect of the nation-state Capital and labor are not the only economic agents affecting capital accumulation and uneven development – the nation-state also plays a part. Although the capital- ist state always has certain relationships to capital (for example, guarantor of currency, protector of property rights) other aspects of the relationship vary considerably and make a difference to patterns of internationalization of capital. Its variable roles in this respect include: (1) responding to the net effects of the myriad of capitals operating within (and outside) its boundaries (for example, responses to balance of payments problems); (2) defensive protectionism, for example, tariffs, regulations on inward investment; (3) aggressive nationalism and corporatism, for example, coordinating and funding R&D, giving investment grants, encouraging restructuring. 44 ANDREW SAYER

In addition to active roles such as these, the particular characteristics of each nation-state form a differentiated context for international capital. There is a con- tinuum of responses to inward investment ranging from “open-door” policies (for example, in the United Kingdom) to aggressively nationalist policies such as those of Japan or France. Defensive protectionist measures such as tariffs may not seem interesting theoretically, but their impact on actual patterns of internationalization of capital – both of foreign and home multinationals – can be significant. Differ- ences in national technical standards can also be important. Defensive protection- ism in Europe has been the main reason for Japanese direct investment in Europe, and in the semiconductor industry, as already noted, differences between tariffs governing imports into the USA and Europe partly explain the different locational strategies of their respective multinationals. Patterns of competition (and collaboration) between states are invariably complex because they work through individual capitals whose interests and spheres of activity bear little correspondence to those of the nation-state. So, for example, the governments of most advanced countries have support programs for micro- electronics and, in ESPRIT, the European Economic Community (EEC) has a community-wide program aimed at catching up with the US and Japan in micro- electronics and computers. These programs invariably give support to capital in the home country. But this usually includes resident foreign capital; also home multi- nationals may be technologically dependent on overseas ones. And, although several capitals in one country or the EEC may collaborate to fight off external competi- tion (for example, from Japan), each firm’s priority is to defend itself against others whatever their nationality and so they often simultaneously act against such coali- tions by entering into deals with foreign competitors. Anarchic though the results of such attempts to regulate competition may be, national differences are still impor- tant. For example, the liberalization of British Telecom has been responsible for a major influx of telecommunications firms into Britain in recent years. Too often such influences have been seen as untheorizable external factors inter- fering with an otherwise laissez-faire (and more theorizable) international economy. Economic nationalism has also to be explained – and in its concrete forms. Ten years ago there was a lively debate on the relationship of multinational firms to nation-states, but, despite its continuing relevance, interest has fallen off, although Radice has recently reopened the debate (1984). It is also increasingly necessary, both for academic and for political reasons to decide what we mean by the concept of a “national economy” or “the British electronics industry,” when most capital is multinationally organized. And in dealing with the relationship between multina- tionals and host and home governments it is increasingly necessary to take into account intercapitalist competition and interstate rivalries, and these within a context of uneven development and international patterns of technological superi- ority and dependence.

3.5 The neglect of the social or institutional forms of capital In any concrete empirical study of capital, contrasts in the social and institutional (or perhaps cultural) forms of capital are striking. Given the internal relation between capital and labor, the same applies to labor. New social forms do not arise INDUSTRY AND SPACE 45 automatically out of the particular characteristics of the forces of production, but are born and then succeed or fail in specific cultural contexts, both in the spheres of production and reproduction. Some of these forms fit successfully with emerging technical forces, others do not. At the level of abstract theory the particular nature of these forms can and must be ignored, although as with the effects of use-values, the fact that they can be expected to vary concretely must at least be appreciated at the abstract level. The concrete variations make important differences to workers’ experience and political consciousness and therefore need to be understood. Although it is true, at the abstract level, as Harvey says, that “Capitalists behave like capitalists wherever they are” (Harvey, 1982, p. 424), at the concrete level this will not do and will only generate false expectations with regard to political con- sciousness. The concrete variations cannot be dismissed as distractions from the task of developing some essentialist universal theory of capital and labor in general. In a particular region, the institutional and social forms of capital and labor inter- act and adapt to one another, and when either side changes it sets up stresses. For example, there is an interdependence between the traditional style of British man- agement and the shop stewards movement. British managers are notoriously status conscious and anxious to distance themselves socially from manual labor. They are generally conservative as regards both technical and social innovations and, although less interventionist on the shop-floor than managers in other countries, they are more prone to aggravate grievances precisely because of their low shop- floor involvement. This is of course a caricature, but nevertheless widely observed on the whole in large plants. The other side of the coin is a ceding of shop-floor control to shop stewards (at least prior to 1979) through whom management’s communications with the workforce are channeled. Conversely the growth of the shop stewards movement helped to force management back off the shop-floor – it was not a one-way process. So, although British workers are less radical politically than many of their European counterparts, they are – or perhaps, were – econom- ically stronger within the workplace. Such lines of interdependence can come under attack in a variety of circumstances: through a strengthening of the economic and political leverage of labor; through the effects of a recession in weakening labor and (by intensifying competition) forcing capital to increase its power over labor; through in situ development or inward movement of new industries and new insti- tutional and social forms of capital; or through the use of new sources of labor such as women or migrants. It may be tempting to try to reduce such forms of interdependence to labor process categories such as “Taylorism,” “Fordism,” and “neo-Fordism,” but, although elements of these are common and although they constitute a vaguely discernible periodization of social forms of capital indicative of a learning process, they by no means exhaust the significant differences in social-institutional forms of capital. There are also contrasts between small and big capital, family-owned and non- family owned capital, and particularly between nationalities of capital. For example, the peculiar nature of Japanese capital has been the subject of much loose specula- tion in the media, but the inadequacy of the popular accounts does not mean that its peculiarities are of no material significance. The more visible cultural differences (paternalism, workaholism, and obsession with quality) do make a difference to 46 ANDREW SAYER

Japanese capital, although few commentators realize how far these “cultural” characteristics are reproduced by very material practices and relationships built into distinctively Japanese forms of management and labor-process organization (Schonberger, 1982). But then significant cultural characteristics always do have a material grounding: exceptionally high productivity is not achieved simply by exhortation or by the influence of a pro-work ethic. And, as Schonberger argues, if Japanese success were attributable purely to a realm of mysterious ethereal cultural characteristics having no material basis, it would hardly be possible for Japanese management methods to be exported and imitated as much as they are. This implies that, particularly where firms invest overseas, they can act not only as “bearers of market forces” (Murray, 1972) and technologies, and not only as bearers of the social relations of production “writ large,” but also as bearers of par- ticular forms of management, work practices, and social organization. Accordingly, capital not only assesses locations as regards labor simply in terms of wage differ- entials, narrowly defined, but takes into account indicators of existing work “culture” and tradition (for example, rates of absenteeism) in order to evaluate spatial variations in productivity levels. Labor has correspondingly to organize itself to face the challenge of the new social forms of capital, and at the present time it has to do so against the restraining forces of mass unemployment when its resources are at their lowest. In Britain this is evident not only in the increasing number of non-unionized or anti-union plants (at least in some regions – for example, Central Scotland) but in the shift towards single-union plants in place of traditional multiunion representa- tion and towards corporatist “top-down” forms of unionization. These changes show how labor’s own organizations have to restructure too, in this case in a way which destroys the traditional inter-union division of labor and increases inter-union competition. In these ways then, concrete analyses of industry must go beyond seeing uneven development as a simple scarcely mediated expression of the logic of capital-in-general, and grasp the specificities of actual social forms of capital and labor; they are not trivial nuances but an important component of uneven devel- opment and political consciousness.

4 Conclusion I want to conclude by making a few comments about the concern (obsession?) of this paper with differentiation and complexity. First, I have criticized certain stereo- types not for the sake of scoring pedantic points (which is never difficult where stereotypes are concerned) but because they seemed to be systematically misleading both as a way of understanding the world and as a means towards changing it. For the sake of constructing an overview of the state of some system we have to make approximations: the point is not to suggest that all researchers should forsake large scale historical surveys and the like for microstudies – although it would be useful to have a more balanced division of labor on this. Rather, such approximations must be reviewed constantly in the light of more intensive studies, and conversely the latter should always keep in mind the general context. Nor have I been attack- ing abstract theory: rather I have warned against the dangers of applying it at the concrete level without due regard for contingent mediations. INDUSTRY AND SPACE 47

However, from the point of view of concrete practice, we cannot simply abstract from diversity, distanciation, scale, and complexity, for social and economic organ- ization is itself in part a response to it. Practice always takes place in a highly dif- ferentiated context and to engage with it we must understand the local specificities if we are to understand local political responses. If we abstract from these differ- ences and specificities, arriving at generic categories, and then project these back unmediated, onto views of concrete practice, then obviously we will generate a utopian illusion of generic man and woman, living in harmony. Chapter 3 An Institutionalist Perspective on Regional Economic Development

Ash Amin

Introduction Until recently, regional policy has been firm-centered, standardized, incentive-based and state-driven. This is certainly true in the case of the Keynesian legacy that dom- inated regional policy in the majority of advanced economies after the 1960s. It relied on income redistribution and welfare policies to stimulate demand in the less favored regions (LFRs) and the offer of state incentives (from state aid to infra- structural improvements) to individual firms to locate in such regions. Paradoxi- cally, the same principles apply also to pro-market neo-liberal experiments which have come to the fore over the last fifteen years. The neo-liberal approach, placing its faith in the market mechanism, has sought to deregulate markets, notably the cost of labor and capital, and to underpin entrepreneurship in the LFRs through incentives and investment in training, transport and communication infrastructure, and technology. The common assumption in both approaches, despite their funda- mental differences over the necessity for state intervention and over the equilibrat- ing powers of the market, has been that top-down policies can be applied universally to all types of region. This agreement seems to draw on the belief that at the heart of economic success lies a set of common factors (e.g., the rational individual, the maximizing entrepreneur, the firm as the basic economic unit, and so on). The achievements of both strands of such an “imperative” approach (Hausner, 1995) have been modest in terms of stimulating sustained improvements in the eco- nomic competitiveness and developmental potential of the LFRs. Keynesian regional policies, without doubt, helped to increase employment and income in the LFRs, but they failed to secure increases in productivity comparable to those in the more prosperous regions and, more importantly, they did not succeed in encouraging self-sustaining growth based on the mobilization of local resources and interde- pendencies (by privileging non-indigenous sectors and externally-owned firms). The “market therapy” has threatened a far worse outcome, by reducing financial trans- fers which have proven to be a vital source of income and welfare in the LFRs, by exposing the weak economic base of the LFRs to the chill wind of ever enlarging AN INSTITUTIONALIST PERSPECTIVE 49 free market zones or corporate competition, and by failing singularly to reverse the flow of all factor inputs away from the LFRs. In short, the choice has been that between dependent development or no development. Partly in response to these failings, more innovative policy communities have begun to explore a third alternative, informed by the experience of prosperous regions characterized by strong local economic interdependencies (e.g., Italian indus- trial districts, certain technopoles, Baden Württemberg). It is an alternative centered on mobilizing the endogenous potential of the LFRs, through efforts to upgrade a broadly defined local supply-base. It seeks to unlock the “wealth of regions” as the prime source of development and renewal. This is not an approach with a coher- ent economic theory behind it, nor is there a consensus on the necessary policy actions. However, its axioms contrast sharply with those of the policy orthodoxy, in tending to favor bottom-up, region-specific, longer-term, and plural-actor based policy actions. Conceptually, against the individualism of the orthodoxy (e.g., the centrality of homo economicus), it recognizes the collective or social foundations of economic behavior, for which reason it can be described loosely as an institution- alist perspective on regional development. This chapter seeks to develop the institutionalist perspective by bringing together strands of policy action scattered across the literature, as well as suggesting new strands. It claims that the new perspective opens up novel but challenging oppor- tunities for policy action at the local level. It also claims, however, that the “new regionalism” will amount to very little in the absence of sustained macroeconomic support for the regions, notably a secure financial and income transfer base and expansionary programs to boost overall growth at the national and international level. The first section of the chapter summarizes the axioms of economic action and governance which emerge from a theorization of the economy rooted in insti- tutional economics and socioeconomics. The second section discusses applications of institutionalist thought within regional development studies that seek to explain the importance of territorial proximity for economic competitiveness. Part of the purpose of these two sections is to demonstrate that the new policy orientations, outlined in the third section, are not just ex-post generalizations based on the expe- rience of a small number of regions, but also ex-ante suggestions based on a par- ticular conceptualization/abstraction of the economy and its territoriality.

The Economy and Economic Governance in Institutional Economics The rise of institutional and evolutionary economics is now well documented (Hodgson, 1988, 1998; Samuels, 1995; Metcalfe, 1998), as is thought in economic sociology which stresses the influence of wider social relations in economic life (Smelser and Swedberg, 1994; Ingham, 1996). Against orthodox assumptions that the economy is equilibrium-oriented and centered on the rational individual or machine-like rules, the stress in these two bodies of thought falls on processes of institutionalization as a means of stabilizing and interpreting an economy that is essentially non-equilibrating, imperfect, and irrational. Three sets of ideas seem to be especially important in this regard. First, from economic sociology comes the well-known idea that markets are socially constructed (Bagnasco, 1988) and that economic behavior is embedded in 50 ASH AMIN networks of interpersonal relations. Crucially, therefore, economic outcomes are influenced by network properties such as mutuality, trust, and cooperation, or their opposite (Dore, 1983; Granovetter, 1985; Grabher, 1993; Fukuyama, 1995; Misztal, 1996). Granovetter, for example, has suggested that networks of weak ties might be more dynamic than those dominated by strong ties (e.g., enforced loyalty) or easy escape (e.g., contract-based ties). While weak ties offer economic agents the benefits of both cooperation and access to a varied selection environment for new learning, strong ties, as in many crime networks, pose the threat of both lock-in and restricted selection, and contractual self-reliance poses very high search costs. In addition, the rising influence of actor-network theory has furthered analysis of the powers of networks by stressing the inseparability of people and things within them, producing distinctive properties that weave together actors, organizational cultures, knowledge environments, machines, texts and scripts (Latour, 1986; Callon, 1991). Second, and against the rational actor model in standard economics, comes the idea from evolutionary and cognitive psychology (Cosmides and Tooby, 1994; Plotkin, 1994) and the behavioral tradition in economics (Simon, 1959) that dif- ferent actor-network rationalities produce different forms of economic behavior and decision-making. For example, an instrumentalist or substantive rationality is likely to favor reactive responses to problems, based on a largely rule-following behavior. Reactive responses may prove to be adequate in relatively unchanging and pre- dictable environments but their underlying rationality is not equipped for a varying environment. In contrast, a procedural actor rationality is one which seeks to adapt to the environment, drawing upon perceptive powers and generally more complex cognitive arrangements for solving problems. Finally, while the latter two rational- ities tend to assume an invariant environment (therefore largely problem-solving), a recursive rationality is problem-seeking and assumes that the environment can be anticipated and to a degree manipulated through such procedures as strategic monitoring, experimental games, group learning, and so on (Delorme, 1997). It tends to generate creative actor-networks with the ability to shape the environment, owing to the capacity to think and act strategically and multidimensionally (Orillard, 1997). Third, from the recent rediscovery of “old” institutional econom- ics (Hodgson, 1988, 1998; Hodgson et al., 1993) comes the idea that the economy is shaped by enduring collective forces, which make it an instituted process as claimed by Polanyi, not a mechanical system or set of individual preferences. These forces include formal institutions such as rules, laws, and organizations, as well as informal or tacit institutions such as individual habits, group routines, and social norms and values. All of these institutions provide stability in the real economic context of information asymmetry, market uncertainty, and knowledge bounded- ness, by restricting the field of possibilities available, garnering consensus and common understandings, and guiding individual action. They are also, however, templates for, or constraints upon, future development. It is their endurability and framing influence on action by individuals and actor-networks that forces recogni- tion of the path- and context-dependent nature of economic life, or, from a gover- nance perspective, the wide field of institutions beyond markets, firms, and states which need to be addressed by policies seeking to alter the economic trajectory. From these strands of institutionalist thought derives an understanding of the economy as something more than a collection of atomized firms and markets driven AN INSTITUTIONALIST PERSPECTIVE 51 by rational preferences and a standard set of rules. Instead the economy emerges as a composition of collective influences which shape individual action and as a diver- sified and path-dependent entity molded by inherited cultural and socio-institutional influences. In turn, the influences on economic behavior are quite different from those privileged by economic orthodoxy (e.g., perfect rationality, hedonism, formal rules, etc.). Explanatory weight is given to the effects of formal and informal insti- tutions, considered to be socially constructed and subject to slow evolutionary change; to values and rationalities of action ensconced in networks and institutions; to the composition of networks of economic association, especially their role in dis- seminating information, knowledge, and learning for economic adaptability; and to intermediate institutions between market and state which are relatively purposeful and participatory forms of arrangement. On the basis of these principles, we can begin to derive a number of general axioms of economic governance associated with an institutionalist approach. First, there is a preference for policy actions designed to strengthen networks of associa- tion, instead of actions which focus on individual actors alone. Second, part of the purpose of policy action might be to encourage voice, negotiation, and the emer- gence of procedural and recursive rationalities of behavior, in order to secure strate- gic vision, learning, and adaptation (Amin and Hausner, 1997). Third, emphasis is given to policy actions which aim to mobilize a plurality of autonomous organiza- tions, since effective economic governance extends beyond the reach of both the state and market institutions (Hirst, 1994). Fourth, the stress on intermediate forms of governance extends to a preference for building up a broad-based local “institutional thickness” that might include enterprise support systems, political institutions, and social citizenship (Amin and Thrift, 1995). Finally, a key institu- tionalist axiom is that solutions have to be context-specific and sensitive to local path-dependencies.

The Institutional Turn in Regional Development Studies In recent years, the region has been rediscovered as an important source of competitive advantage in a globalizing political economy (Scott, 1995; Cooke, 1997). In part, this rediscovery is based on studies of the success of highly dynamic regional economies and industrial districts which draw extensively upon local assets for their competitiveness. However, the rediscovery is also based on the insights of institutional economic theory, particularly its explanation of why terri- torial proximity matters for economic organization. Two conceptual strands stand out. One strand – perhaps the closest to the economics mainstream – derives from renewed interest in endogenous growth theory, which acknowledges the economic externalities and increasing returns to scale associated with spatial clustering and specialization (Porter, 1994; Krugman, 1995). The contention of Krugman and Porter is that the spatial clustering of interrelated industries, skilled labor, and tech- nological innovations offers some of the key elements of growth and competitive- ness. These include increasing returns, reduced transaction costs and economies associated with proximity and interfirm exchange, as well as specialized know-how, skills, and technological advancement. 52 ASH AMIN

This “new economic geography” has gained considerable influence and is undoubtedly appealing, as it provides solid economic reasons for local agglomera- tion in a globalizing economy (reduced transaction costs, economies of specializa- tion, externalities, etc.). It fails, however, to properly investigate the sources of these local advantages, which, according to a second conceptual strand developed largely by economic geographers, lie in the character of local social, cultural, and institu- tional arrangements. More specifically, insight is drawn from institutional and evo- lutionary economics concerning ties of proximity and association as a source of knowledge and learning (Amin and Thrift, 1995; Sunley, 1996; Storper, 1997). A leading exponent is Michael Storper (1997), who has suggested that a dis- tinctive feature of places in which globalization is consistent with the localization of economic activity is the strength of their “relational assets” or “untraded inter- dependencies.” They include tacit knowledge based on face-to-face exchange, embedded routines, habits and norms, local conventions of communication and interaction, reciprocity and trust based on familiarity, and so on. These relational assets are claimed to have a direct impact on a region’s com- petitive potential insofar as they constitute part of the learning environment for firms. Many of the insights of the literature on the so-called learning regions (Cooke and Morgan, 1998), such as Silicon Valley, Baden Württemberg, and Italian indus- trial districts, derive from analysis of the learning properties of local, industry- specialist, business networks. These networks of reciprocity, shared know-how, spillover expertise, and strong enterprise support systems, according to Malmberg (1996), are sources of learning, facilitated through such advantages as reduced opportunism and enhanced mutuality within the relationships of interdependence. Other observers (e.g., Becattini and Rullani, 1993; Asheim, 1997; Maskell et al., 1998; Blanc and Sierra, 1999; Nooteboom, 1999) suggest that geographical pro- ximity plays a unique role in supplying informally-constituted assets. For instance, Maskell et al. argue that tacit forms of information and knowledge are better con- solidated through face-to-face contact, not only due to the transactional advantages of proximity, but also because of their dependence upon a high degree of mutual trust and understanding, often constructed around shared values and cultures. Similarly, scholars (Becattini and Rullani, 1993; Asheim, 1997; Nooteboom, 1999) have distinguished between codified knowledge as a feature of trans-local networks (e.g., R&D laboratories or training courses of large corporations) and formally con- stituted institutions (e.g., business journals and courses, education and training insti- tutions, printed scientific knowledge) and non-codified knowledge (e.g., workplace skills and practical conventions) as aspects locked into the “industrial atmosphere” of individual places. The consensus among these commentators seems to be that in a world in which codified knowledge is becoming increasingly ubiquitously avail- able, uncodified knowledge, rooted in relations of proximity, attains a higher premium in deriving competitive advantage owing to its uniqueness.

Regional Policy Orientations Both strands of the new regionalism – the “new economic geography” and institu- tional economic geography – imply practical action which transcends the limits of traditional local economic development initiatives. The focus falls on building the AN INSTITUTIONALIST PERSPECTIVE 53 wealth of regions (not the individual firm), with upgrading of the economic, insti- tutional, and social base considered as the prerequisite for entrepreneurial success. In my view there are four novel areas of action which emerge from the “wealth of regions” perspective.

Building clusters and local economies of association The experience of some of the most dynamic economies in Europe shows that supply-side upgrading of a generic nature (e.g., advanced transport and communi- cations systems or provision of specialized training and skills), though desirable, is not sufficient to secure regional economic competitiveness. Instead, in small nations such as Denmark and successful regional economies such as Emilia-Romagna, Baden Württemberg, and Catalonia, policy action is increasingly centered on supporting clusters of interrelated industries which have long roots in the region’s skill- or capabilities-base. This helps not only to secure meaningful international competi- tive advantage, but also to reap the benefits of local specialization along the supply chain. In addition, considerable policy attention is paid to building economies of asso- ciation within clusters. This might include efforts to improve cultures of innovation within firms by encouraging social dialog and learning based on shared knowledge and information exchange. It might include initiatives to encourage interfirm exchange and reciprocity through buyer–supplier linkage programs, incentives for pooling of resources, joint ventures, task specialization, and so on. Finally, in order to maximize the efficiency of collective resources, it might include conscious effort to establish contact between sector-specific organizations (e.g., trade associations, sectorally-based service centers) and other support organizations (e.g., large and small-firm lobbies, function-specific producer services agencies, trade unions, chambers of commerce, local authorities, regional development agencies). Cluster programs are no longer new to the regional policy community. Indeed, following the spectacular translation of Michael Porter’s ideas into policy action through his world-famous consultancy group, Monitor, most regions seem to have a cluster program of some sort. And, ironically, in contradiction to the institution- alist stress on context-specificity and path-dependency, the most common tendency beyond the selection of locally-sensitive industrial clusters has been to copy from the experience of successful regions or from some “expert” manual. Cluster pro- grams are becoming as standardized a mantra as were the incentive packages of pre- ceding regional policy. Very few regions have attempted to develop unique industrial strategies based on deep assessment of local institutional and cultural specificities. To a degree, this failing stems from the inability of the policy community to recog- nize the centrality of “softer” influences, such as the three considered in turn below.

Learning to learn and adapt The geographical strand of the new regionalism stresses learning as a key factor in dynamic competitiveness. Indeed, it is claimed that economically successful regions are “learning” or “intelligent” regions (Cooke and Morgan, 1998). It is their capacity to adapt around particular sectors and to anticipate at an early stage new 54 ASH AMIN industrial and commercial opportunities that enables them to develop and retain competitive advantage around a range of existing and future possibilities. Their strength lies in “learning to learn” (Hudson, 1999). By contrast, a very large number of less favored regions suffer from the problem of industrial and institutional lock- in and that of reactive adaptation to their economic environment, thus preventing the formation of a learning culture. Vexing from a policy perspective is that there is no received wisdom on the factors which contribute to regional learning and adaptability. However, some of the con- tributing factors can be discerned from an observation of the relevant regions. One obvious factor is quite simply the scale and density of “intelligent” people and insti- tutions, as reflected in the skill and professional profile of the labor market, the volume and quality of training and education across different levels, the depth of linkage between schools, universities, and industry, the quality and diversity of the research, science, and technology base, and the availability of intermediate centers of information and intelligence between economic agents and their wider environ- ment (e.g., commercial media, trade fairs, business service agencies). These are vital sources of codified knowledge, grounded in the regional milieu. Many LFRs display a discernible lack of most of these attributes, with policy actions often geared towards the production of low-grade skills and training or towards disembodied ventures such as university expansion, science parks, and training schemes which fail to build the necessary connections. Less obviously, the quality of ties associated with economies of association is another important source of learning and adaptation, through its impact on the cir- culation of informal information, innovation, and knowledge. Networks of associ- ation in the economy facilitate the spread of information and capabilities and the prospect of economic innovation through social interaction. Of course, there is always the danger that ties which are too strong and long-standing might actually prevent renewal and innovation by encouraging network closure and self- referential behavior (Grabher and Stark, 1997). On the other hand, in contexts where economic agents have the option of participating in many competing net- works on the basis of loose ties and reciprocal relations, often through independ- ent intermediaries, the prospect for learning through interaction is enhanced. The policy challenge in this regard for LFRs is to find a way of substituting their tradi- tional ties of hierarchy and dependency (e.g., big firms, state provision, family con- nections) with links of mutuality between economic agents and institutions. Third, as mentioned earlier, research has begun to appreciate the connection between rationalities of action and adaptive potential. It would appear that rule- based, substantive rationality, which encourages reactive responses to the external environment, is ill-equipped for learning and adaptation. Procedural rationality, on the other hand, based on cognitive and behavioral interpretation by economic agents of the external environment, favors incremental adjustment and adaptation. In con- trast, a reflexive rationality, involving strategic and goal-monitoring behavior (Sabel, 1994), encourages experimental anticipation and actions seeking to shape the exter- nal environment. The cognitive frame of regional actors and institutions, in short, is the central source of learning. The culture of command and hierarchy that char- acterizes so many LFRs has stifled the formation of a reflexive culture among the majority of its economic institutions and, consequently, prevented the encourage- AN INSTITUTIONALIST PERSPECTIVE 55 ment of rationalities geared towards learning and adaptation. Considerable policy attention needs to be paid to the nature of organizational and management cultures and actor rationalities which circulate within a region’s dominant institutions. Importantly, but rarely addressed by the policy community, the capacity to change lies centrally in the ability of actor-networks to develop an external gaze and sustain a culture of strategic management and coordination in order to foresee opportu- nities and secure rapid response. The key factor is the ability to evolve in order to adapt (Amin and Hausner, 1997). The encouragement of this ability requires effort to identify the potential sources of behavioral alternatives – for example the preser- vation of diverse competencies (e.g., redundant skills and industrial slack – see Grabher and Stark, 1997); the scope for subaltern groups to break the grip of hege- monic interests which gain from preserving the past; the openness of organizations to external and internal influences; the scope for strategic decision-making through agent–environment interaction; and the encouragement of diversity of knowledge, expertise, and capability, so that new tricks are not missed.

Broadening the local institutional base The last point illustrates the need for wider institutional changes to tackle impedi- ments to economic renewal rooted in institutional dominance and closure. Partly in recognition of this problem, it has become increasingly common to assume that region-building has to be about mobilizing independent political power and capac- ity. In the European Union this assumption lies at the center of the discourse on “Europe of the regions” and has led to strong endorsement for local fiscal and finan- cial autonomy, together with enlargement of the powers of local government and the establishment of vigorous regional assemblies or parliaments. The linkage made with economic development is that local political power and voice facilitates the formation of a decision-making and decision-implementing community able to develop and sustain an economic agenda of its own. The institutionalist perspective, however, suggests that region-building cannot stop at simply securing regional political autonomy. Equally – perhaps more impor- tant – are matters of who makes decisions and how. Let us recall two institution- alist governance axioms, namely, the desirability of decision-making through independent representative associations and the superiority of participatory decision-making. The added challenge for the regions, therefore, is to find ways of developing a pluralist and interactive public sphere that draws in both the state and a considerably enlarged sphere of non-state institutions. Governance, especially in the institutionally thin regions, has always been in the hands of elite coalitions, and the resulting institutional sclerosis has been a source of economic failure by acting as a block on innovation and the wider distribution of resources and opportunity. In an increasingly global economy, these elites and their charismatic leaders may undoubtedly help regions to jostle for influence with national and international organizations (e.g., the European Commission or transnational corporations), but they will achieve little in terms of mobilizing a regional development path based on unlocking hidden local potential. This is why it is vital that regional actors ask whether their decision-making processes constitute an obstacle to institutional renewal, away from a culture of hierarchy and rule-following, towards one that 56 ASH AMIN focuses on informational transparency, consultative and inclusive decision-making, and strategy-building on the basis of reflexive monitoring of goals. Ultimately, the process of institutional reform has to go beyond the decentral- ization and democratization of a region’s official organizations. Many of the pros- perous regions of Europe are also regions of participatory politics, active citizenship, civic pride, and intense institutionalization of collective interests – of society brought back into the art of governance. Within them, associational life is active, politics is contested, public authorities and leaders are scrutinized, public space is considered to be shared and commonly owned, and a strong culture of autonomy and self- governance seeps through local society. They are regions of developed “social capital” (Putnam, 1993), serving to secure many economic benefits, including public-sector efficiency in the provision of services; civic autonomy and initiative in all areas of social and economic life; a culture of reciprocity and trust which facil- itates the economics of association; containment of the high costs of social break- down and conflict; and potential for economic innovation and creativity based on social confidence and capability.

Mobilizing the social economy The preceding discussion implies that a regional culture of social inclusion and social empowerment is likely to encourage economic creativity by allowing diverse social groups and individuals to realize their potential. This reinforces the view that poli- cies to stimulate regional entrepreneurship should recognize, oblique though it may appear, the centrality of policies to combat social exclusion in this process. This is especially relevant in the context of regions marked by problems of persistent structural unemployment and rudimentary entrepreneurship, both of which act as a severe constraint on economic renewal. In such regions, the depth and scale of unemployment and the trend towards jobless growth in the economy at large, makes a return to full employment highly unlikely through improvements in regional eco- nomic competitiveness (via, say, industrial upgrading, clusters and economies of association). An interesting contemporary policy innovation in the European Union is experi- mentation with the social economy as a source of local renewal. In countries such as Germany, France, Belgium, the Netherlands, Italy, and Ireland, there is growing public policy support (e.g., subsidies and indirect aids such as training, facilitating legislation, specialized services) for community projects that are run by the third sector and involve excluded groups either as providers or users of socially useful services. This might involve support for a community group that employs school leavers to offer affordable housing to low-income groups or for a cooperative through which the long-term unemployed provide domestic care or transport access to the elderly. In other words, the battle against social exclusion is being combined with reforms to the welfare state, towards building an intermediate economic sphere that serves to meet real local welfare needs. In turn, this intermediate sphere, sus- tained by both monetary and innovative non-monetary metrics of exchange (e.g., service vouchers or services in kind), is seen as a source of employment and entre- preneurship in “markets” which are of limited interest to state organizations and AN INSTITUTIONALIST PERSPECTIVE 57 private-sector firms. In the longer run, it is seen as a vital source for unlocking social confidence and creativity among the excluded. The policy implication is that regions need to incorporate a social economy program into their efforts to improve regional economic competitiveness. It is important, however, for the reasons given in the preceding section, that support is provided with a light governmental touch, leaving a great deal to local actors. For example, regional, or city-based, “social inclusion commissions” could be estab- lished, with an elected chair from a widely-drawn membership of relevant local organizations. The commissions would audit local service needs, propose rules for action, invite and consider applications for funding, work with the local authorities and other economic interest groups, and so on. The local authorities and the central government would play a facilitating role, providing, for example, resources and legislation, but they would not provide a direct steer on local priorities and projects.

Conclusion: Back to the Macro-Economy The new regionalism offers a solution based on the mobilization of local resources. But it does so on the basis of a very broad definition of what constitutes the economy and economic action. It is an approach that builds outwards from a new industrial policy and effort to strengthen local economies of association to actions to improve institutional reflexivity, learning potential, and social creativity. To a degree, the focus on endogenous regional solutions has been forced by an uncomfortably pervasive agreement across the policy community around the neo- liberal rejection of macroeconomic actions in favor of LFRs which might hinder market forces. Across the political spectrum, the consensus has grown that national and regional competitiveness is the only pathway to prosperity and that redistribu- tive measures alone will not suffice. This is a perilous supposition, not least because of the institutionalist axiom that action has to be contextually relevant and medium- to long-term. The policy ori- entations outlined above are not equally applicable to all types of region, and where they are, they require time to be built up. The orientations are especially appropri- ate for regions characterized by certain impediments to economic renewal: fragile small-firm entrepreneurship; domination by externally owned or controlled firms with poor levels of local economic integration; restricted diversification, innovation, and learning capacity; and state dependency and institutional closure. These are problems which are rather typical of old industrial regions and their particular insti- tutional legacies. Lagging rural regions face a different set of impediments, and their institutional base might also be less equipped for experimenting with learning-based industrial clusters and reflexive goal-monitoring institutional behavior. Region- building, in short, may not be an option for all regions, owing to the restrictions of context and time. To a degree, the responsibility for the management of wider connectivity lies in the hands of non-regional actors, notably government. No amount of imaginative region-building will be able to sustain a spiral of endogenous economic growth in the absence of a conducive macroeconomic framework. Interregional competition 58 ASH AMIN in a Europe in recession and dominated by restrictive macroeconomic policies will continue to work in favor of the core regions. Therefore, something has to be done to secure the less-favored regions sufficient time and resources to implement boot- strapping reforms. The reforms suggested here are controversial and need further debate. However, the point of raising them here is that in the absence of a conducive macroeconomic framework, it seems irresponsible to ask the regions to embark upon a long-term and comprehensive overhaul in pursuit of an endogenous pathway to prosperity. Chapter 4 Refiguring the Economic in Economic Geography

Nigel J. Thrift and Kris Olds

Introduction If I had the cash to buy all of my family something to wear I would, but I don’t. Last year I did all my shopping on Christmas Eve and spent far too much money on not very nice presents. (Martha in Williams, 1995, p. 5)

Mum always claims she’d be happy with a kiss, so she’s very easy to buy presents for at Christmas. (Milly in Williams, 1995, p. 5)

The full complexity of modern economies only becomes apparent when we move outside of what are often still considered to be the “normal” territories of economic enquiry. Then a whole new world hoves into view. Take Christmas. Now, at last, the subject of sustained academic enquiry (e.g., Bennett, 1981; Pimlott, 1978; Thrift, 1993; Miller, 1993; Restad, 1995), Christmas is a cultural event of immense economic significance – or an economic event of immense cultural significance. That this is the case can be seen from the case of Great Britain. In 1993, for example, seasonal factors contributed an extra £5 billion to fourth quarter consumption, compared to the third quarter, and this amount has been increasing steadily since 1960 (A. Scott, 1994). Sectors of the economy that bene- fited especially included drink, tobacco, and “other goods” like sports equipment, toiletries, jewelry, and greetings cards. To be more specific, in the period leading up to Christmas 1995 various newspapers reported that 1.95 billion Christmas cards were mailed in Great Britain, 14 million turkeys were slaughtered, 5.25 million Christmas trees were harvested (including new varieties like Nordman blue), 5 million poinsettias were sold, and 200,000 children visited Santa Claus’ grotto in Selfridges in London. Nearly all of this seasonal increase in consumption is the result of changing social customs associated with Christmas, and most especially an upward trend in gift- giving (Cheal, 1988; Belk, 1995). Of course, this phenomenon of mass reciprocity 60 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS is hardly restricted to Great Britain. Since the mid-nineteenth century, Christmas has been a syncretic tradition, which has depended upon symbols drawn from a whole range of different national sources; “the Christmas tree from the German tra- dition, the filling of stockings from the Dutch tradition, the development of Santa Claus mainly from the United States, the British Christmas card, and many other such elements” (Miller, 1993, p. 4). And this tradition has spread out from Europe and North America to all corners of the world. Thus, as Miller (1993, p. 5) puts it, “by the 1990s we are faced with the extraordinary phenomenon of a global festival which seems to grow in its accumulated rituals and the extravagance of the homage paid to it, even as all other festivals and comparable events have declined.” We could as easily have chosen other examples of practices which until quite recently would have been counted as outside the normal orbit of economic geo- graphy, yet which illustrate the extraordinary difficulty of separating out something called “the economic” from “the social” or “the cultural” or “the political” or “the sexual” or what have you – the scent industry, the gambling industry, the “com- panion animal” industry (all the way from petfood to kennels and catteries), the gardening industry, the music industry, the drugs industry. The list goes on and on. But hopefully the point is made; until quite recently economic geographers would probably have been quite uneasy considering these kinds of industries and, more particularly, the kinds of issues that they raise. This is because economic geography had become stale, when compared with, say, the vibrancy of cultural geography. But now a determined effort is being made to make a space for new kinds of eco- nomic geography that can supplement or even replace the older forms of economic geography. That space is meant to be inclusive, critical, and committed. It is a space that cannot help but have roots in the economic geographies of the past – which, after all, produced many good things – but which also represents a determined effort to avoid the bad habits that sometimes (and only sometimes) impoverished them. The new economic geography will be different, and in three ways. First, it will be polycentric. It will not consist of one narrative (or one narrative and its oppo- site) but of a set of narrative communities in relation. In turn, this means that it will celebrate a qualitative multiplicity of “economic” times and spaces seen, cer- tainly, as in unequal relation with one another but not thereby giving credence to the composition of an overarching centered, theoretical order, or the fictive telos of a “new world order.” Second, it follows that the new economic geography will be much more open to outside influences. It will want to trawl the social sciences and humanities in search of the traces of the economic. But this new emphasis on multiplicity and openness does not mean that the new economic geography needs to be politically quiescent. It will want to generate counter-narratives, it will hunger after critical readings, it will want to disseminate new, alternative economic prac- tices. Third, the new economic geography will necessarily obtain a good part of its impetus from refiguring what is conventionally regarded as “the economic.” To use a phrase much favored by Richard Rorty (1989), the assumption of polycentrism, the injection of new perspectives, and the commitment to political action, must produce a shift in the “final vocabulary” that economic geographers fall back on – words like “economy,” “market,” “industry,” and “work” – key words beyond which lies only silence, tautology, or physical force. What seems clear is that REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 61 attempting to build a unified culture around these key words will become increas- ingly difficult because the articulations and readings of the economic are pro- liferating. Indeed, one of the tasks of the new economic geography will be precisely to aid this proliferation by “stretching” its own definition so as to make itself more inclusive and more able to mix in company. In this paper, we want to address some of these changes in economic geography’s final vocabulary through a three-part study. In the first part we want to briefly point to some of the ways in which the practices of the economy have been changing, ways which problematize what we mean by the economic in “economic geogra- phy.” In turn, in the second part of the paper we want to suggest that these prob- lematizations have produced changing perspectives on how to approach modern space economies which can be encapsulated in four “topological presuppositions.” Finally, the last part of the paper presents some brief conclusions about future directions.

1 The Main Changes There are clearly many important changes taking place in what is conventionally called “economic life.” We want to interpret these changes as processes of prob- lematization, that is as new practices which set off new accounts which set off new practices . . . on and on in an endless discursive and recursive loop. These new prob- lematizations are only rarely singular and unbending. More often, they are multi- ple and contested, “dilemmatic” arguments over what the world is like which are, at the same time, constitutive of that world (Billig et al., 1988). Here, we present just our “top ten” of these problematizations. Other writers will no doubt choose other problematizations but most writers would, we are sure, be able to agree on both on a core list and the need to establish the case for change.

1.1 The rise of the social The first problematization is the rise to prominence of economic concomitants which in previous times might well have been regarded as extra-economic. Recent research has demonstrated perfectly the extraordinary social nature of modern economies and it has done so in four main ways. First, the social basis of economic success has become more and more apparent. Thus, at the national scale, a whole series of writers have pointed to the way in which certain forms of business have proved par- ticularly successful because of the strength of ethnic ties ranging from friendly asso- ciations to rotating credit associations. At the international scale, commentators now routinely point to the social differences in national economies as crucial deter- minants of economic success. For example, Kay (1993) notes how the United States economy is based on a regime of expressive individualism and therefore tends to contractual law and public forms of quality certification like brands. In contrast, Japan’s economy is based on a collectivist regime and therefore relies more on build- ing relationships of trust, consensus, and shared knowledge (Hamilton and Biggart, 1992; Orrú, Biggart, and Hamilton, 1991; Whitley, 1991, 1992a). Second, more and more work stresses the importance of the construction of trust in economic interaction, realized through networks of personal contact (e.g., Platteau, 1994a, 62 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS

1994b; Wong, 1991; Zucker, 1986). This kind of work no longer sees the economic as simply “embedded” in the social – a favorite metaphor of an earlier phase of economic sociology – but instead sees the economic and social as incorrigibly inter- twined, unable to be separated off from one another. Third, the rediscovery of the work of Michael Polanyi (1958, 1966) has led to more and more emphasis being placed on the importance of “tacit knowledge,” human behavior which habitually escapes verbal formulation or coding but which is seen, in the shape of particular skills, as being at the heart of the economic success of numerous firms, regions, and nations. Fourth and finally, the honing of social skills, understood as a language of bodily presentation and stance, and conversational skills, is increasingly presented as being determinant of the construction of successful client and customer encounters and, indeed, as being a key component of many modern jobs. That this is the case can be seen in work spanning all manner of economic sectors, from retailing (Crang, 1994) to merchant banking (McDowell and Court, 1994a, 1994b).

1.2 The market Perhaps the rise of the social is best illustrated by the increasingly explicit prob- lematization of markets (e.g., Swedberg, 1994; White, 1993). Because of events in Eastern Europe, the attempts to form a European Single Market, the increasing use of market regulators, and the rediscovery of the work of Karl Polanyi (1994) on the instituted nature of markets, the inherently social nature of markets has now become much clearer. In turn, this realization of the social nature of markets has changed the idea of the market as a neutral arena in which pure exchange takes place to an arena in which there are complex moral and institutional orders regu- lating not only the conduct of exchange but also what is defined as exchange in the first place. The mediated nature of the mediations of markets has been reworked through three main approaches (Swedberg, 1994): the social-structural, the cultural, and the legal-political. In the first approach, the chief focus of attention is social structure, usually identified through networks of affinity. The second approach pays more attention to how actors construct markets through shared meanings. Finally, the third approach emphasizes markets as political arenas within which property rights, governance structures, and transactional rules are primary.

1.3 The rise of the representational Since the writings of McLuhan and Baudrillard, it has become something of a cliché to point to the image consciousness associated with modern economic formations. Through the action of the media, and technological change, the image becomes a currency in and of itself, one which can be shuttled back and forth between pro- ducers and consumers in multiple ways (Wark, 1994). Most particularly, the fore- grounding of the image has had important effects in deterritorializing and reterritorializing signs, meanings, and identities around the world (Lash and Urry, 1994). But the process is no longer seen as simply a vehicle of cultural hegemony (driven by, for example, the mass media or Americanism). Rather it now tends to REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 63 be seen as the fusion of different master narratives (for example, consumerism, enlightenment concepts such as universal rights and citizenship) with local verna- culars (for example, separatism, folklorism, sacred beliefs) (e.g., Appadurai, 1990; Smith, 1994).

1.4 The rise of consumption The rise of the representational is often associated with consumption. Consumption has, of course, become a major area of problematization in geography and else- where (although much of this research has been carried out by cultural rather than economic geographers (Jackson and Thrift, 1995)). Consumption can be seen now as offering four main forms of innovation. First, it has involved major innovations in retailing, from superstores to shopping malls, and more recently, from warehouse clubs to factory outlet villages (Wrigley and Lowe, 1995). Second, it has involved new selling practices (for example, new forms of direct mail and the use of GIS in marketing). Third, it has involved new consumption practices (for example, in Britain, the “consuming Sunday,” new forms of gift-giving, and new imported con- sumption festivals like Father’s Day and Halloween). Then, finally, it has involved new forms of material culture based around a process of social and cultural refiguring of both new and old objects (as, for example, in the rise of various forms of heritage culture).

1.5 The rise of new intelligent technologies Another problematization arises from the new, “intelligent” telecommunicating technologies. No longer seen as a paranoid vision of machines supplanting their builders, these new technologies still problematize the world in several ways. First, they highlight the subject–object relation. The rise of machines that, in a certain fashion, “talk back” has produced reconceptualizations of bodies and selves (new metaphors and figurations now populate the language of self and other which recon- stitute the relation between subject and object). Second, the crucial role of infor- mation is made much clearer by the machines. It is no surprise that information has become central to the practice of modern economic theory and practice, either as cybernetically inclined systems models or as models of information asymmetry (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1991; Boisot, 1995). Third, intelligent machines suggest many new economic practices by “informating” organizations (Zuboff, 1988).

1.6 Mix ‘n’ match A further problematization is the increasing degree of mixing of the functions of the economy which calls all manner of taken-for-granted boundaries into question. What is production and what is consumption? What is supply and what is demand? What is one industrial sector and what is another? What is use and what is exchange? All these and many other categories become increasingly difficult to iden- tify with any clarity. The signs of this recombinant economy are everywhere. Flex- ible production systems bring production and consumption much closer together and mix and match market and hierarchy in new ways. Ideas of production filières 64 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS and commodity claims now circulate, including buyer-driven commodity chains. Some authors argue that services now drive production (Lash and Urry, 1994). Soft- ware has become more important than hardware. And so on. The ultimate example of this recombinant tendency is probably the biological engineering industry where the “liveware” produced by genetic engineering operates at levels which question the independence of the human subject as a category.

1.7 The gendering of economies A seventh problematization has been that produced by gender and sexuality. The increasing visibility of women in the waged workforce has been mirrored by their increased visibility as unpaid workers, thus problematizing even further the bound- ary between the formal economy of work and the informal economy of unwaged and unpaid work for women and this has happened at exactly the same time as many men have become unemployed and had their traditional male roles challenged (Crompton and Sanderson, 1990). In addition, sexuality in the workplace has become a major issue, both because of the issue of sexual harassment and because particular constructions of sexuality have so clearly been a part of the (masculinist) definition of certain kinds of job (McDowell and Court, 1994a, 1994b). Finally, the rise of the gay and lesbian communities has produced a new and relatively distinct source of demand which is now being consciously played to (Edge, 1995; Mort, 1995).

1.8 Informalization These changes are paralleled by the increasing informalization of work as the world of the mass collective worker is left behind. The informal or shadow economy based on what Smith (1994) calls “idiosyncratic forms of livelihood” spreads. Much of this economy is still, in fact, locked into the institutions of the formal economy, and in some cases, because of the rise of flexible production systems, it is more tightly locked in than ever before. Other parts of it simply represent the survival strategies of the poor and impoverished. Yet other parts represent conscious attempts to buck the prevailing system by building alternative institutions, as in the case of LETS, rotating credit associations, credit unions, community development banks, and the like (Boothroyd and Davis, 1993; Leyshon and Thrift, 1997). It is also worth noting that in this sector of the economy, what we mean by labor becomes increasingly difficult to separate out, because of the highly intersubjective nature of work. What Smith (1994) calls “livelihood practices” often, in one way or another, span the whole day, with no clearly-defined moments of work as opposed to non-work.

1.9 Time and space It is a sine qua non of the current literature that we are witness to sweeping changes in the nature of our practice and understanding of time and space. Epic stories of “time–space compression,” “time–space distanciation,” “disembedding,” “globali- zation,” and new and uncharted “hyperspaces,” zones of informational performa- tivity which cannot be tied to one place, circulate (e.g., Castells, 1989; Giddens, REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 65

1990; Harvey, 1989). These stories are important constitutive elements of how we problematize the current world, but they are one-sided. They spin a history of detachment without considering the parallel changes in the history of involvement which is only now being written. For, at the same time, it is clear that face-to-face interaction has not died out. Indeed in some senses it has become more important as reflexivity (including an enhanced ability to see ourselves as others see us) has become built into economic conduct (Lash and Urry, 1994). Most particularly, the “core sets” (Collins, 1981) of people in any economic sector still need to build trust: “here it is far from obvious that the world of familiarity, face-to-face interaction, and virtue is indeed lost” (Shapin, 1994, p. 414). These stories also tend to miss, as they make obeisance to new technological developments, how these developments often act as a supplement to face-to-face interaction, rather than as a substitute (Thrift, 1994).

1.10 The rise of new economic discourses The last problematization has simply been the rise to prominence of new economic discourses in response to all these changes. These discourses have been of three types. First of all, within conventional economics new forms of economic theoriz- ing have been constantly appearing, such as information economics, behavioral eco- nomics, and agency theory, which make it much less easy to simply dismiss classical economics out of hand. Second, new discourses have arisen on the borders of con- ventional economics. For example, the last fifteen years have seen the rise of evo- lutionary economics (Hodgson, 1988, 1993), ecological economics of various kinds, and so-called rational choice or analytical Marxism (Carling, 1992). Finally, there is a whole area of economics which has appeared quite independently of mainstream economics, arising chiefly out of new economic practices, which is very much the domain of non-economists. This is the area of “new economics,” based on “real- world” attempts to institute sustainability, new monetary practices (like revolving credit associations, women’s banks, and local economic trading schemes), commu- nity economic policies, and ethical investment strategies.

2 Changing Perspectives There are many other changes that could, no doubt, be pointed to. But already the cumulative effect of the changes we have mentioned is sufficient to suggest that underlying these singular problematizations is a more comprehensive change of per- spective on how to approach modern economies; this change of perspective has four main components: the fall of the singular, the disorganization of organization, the multiplication of time, and the erosion of orientalist and occidentalist beliefs.

2.1 The fall of the singular Of course, economic life has only rarely been characterized by stable accounts of what an economy is or how it proceeds. In retrospect, we can now see that the period from the 1870s to the fall of Bretton Woods was one of these rare periods when relatively stable accounts held sway. It was a period in which grand machines 66 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS of truth were able to operate with relative impunity, whether in the shape of a number of variants of Marxism or a number of variants of marginalist–neoclassi- cal economics. But now, for all the talk of the triumph of the market, these monu- mental machines have broken up. They have broken up in theory, partly because of the sheer diversity of approaches that now characterize even mainstream econom- ics, partly because of the challenge from “new” forms of “economics,” especially those with their roots in ecology, and partly because of the general acceptance of the importance of instability and change, implicit in the importation of concepts of nonlinearity and chaos (Appadurai, 1990). They have also broken up in practice. The proliferation of the media and telecommunications has produced a war of unde- cideable narratives which shows no signs of resolution. There is now, therefore, a vast industry making accounts of economies which we, as academics, have difficulty acknowledging, for three reasons. First, academics do not occupy a privileged place in this industry. There are numerous extra-academic generators of knowledge who now aim to provide guidance, from management gurus to pundits to research analysts to tip sheet editors. In Bauman’s (1992) terms, academics are no longer legislators of knowledge, but just one out of many com- peting groups of interpreters. Second, the economic system is intensely practical. That is, aided by developments like electronic telecommunications, it is based on the needs of the moment and what works. It is therefore ordered, but not in ways which conventional representational theories find easy to come to terms with (Thrift, 1996b). Third, many of the mechanisms through which modern economies cohere are not what have conventionally been regarded as “economic” by academics. They are therefore able to be blanked out. What seems clear, then, is that the very idea of a singular story of an object denoted “economic” is now lost. It follows that the idea of trying to focus a new economic geography around one concept or theoretical tradition, however broadly defined, cannot hold.

2.2 The disorganization of organization The second component of the change in perspective on modern economies is in how economic organizations are depicted. Previously, these organizations tended to be enclosed, seen as shells through which transactions with the outside world took place to a greater or lesser degree. Such organizations were also characterized by pre-set goals which they worked towards. But this contained and directed model is now seen to be at odds with what we know of the intensely practical and ad hoc character of most organizations. Four points follow. First, organizations require continual improvisation to maintain, often make mistakes, and can spiral down to collapse at short notice. They will therefore have partial views of the world at best. In other words, organizations are always and everywhere tentative and temporary. Second and consequently, organizations are seen as in action, “on the move, if only stumbling or blundering along” (Boden, 1994, p. 192). They are therefore intensely focused on the purposes at hand, on generally local focal points, which will be responded to in part through improvisation and in part through conforming to the organizational field of formal, codified instructions and previous practice. In other words, organizations are talked into being at each moment, by actors who often REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 67 have to fashion informal solutions to formal goals. Third, organizations are seen as always open to the outside, operating in various kinds of transactional regime. The thrust of modern theory has been to characterize this inevitable process as a problem: there are transaction costs. Or, alternatively, attention has focused on a very limited set of successful transactional arrangements, like industrial districts. The result is that we still have only the most limited knowledge of the range of transaction network structures that may exist. Fourth, more attention is now being devoted to new work processes, like teams, and new interactional structures in an acknowledgment that the organizational environment is too complex for an organization to have a fixed strategy, especially as, under the impulse of informa- tion technology, response times have had to become faster.

2.3 The multiplication of time The third component of the change in perspective on modern economies concerns time. In the past, time was seen as a Cartesian bracket around practices, a metric that located them and fixed them in an all-pervasive order. Now time is seen as multidimensional, differential, and produced by participants: “there is no single time, only a multitude of times which interpenetrate and permeate our daily lives” (Adam, 1995, p. 12; Parkes and Thrift, 1980). Thus, the economy is refigured as not one but a series of timelines in which meanings and relevancies are being constantly rekeyed to the moment.

As social actors look over their shoulders at past actions and decisions, they also look sideways, fitting their current activities with parallel points and agents on their orga- nizational landscape. Simultaneity is a critical contingency of action. Nor are these local relevancies of various aspects and stages of a decision-in-progress simply con- structed by temporal contingencies; they are also constitutive of them, creating time- lines, controlling, to a high degree, the practical enactment of organizational actions and even goals. (Boden, 1994, p. 191)

2.4 The erosion of orientalist and occidentalist beliefs The fourth component of the change in perspective on modern economies is the erosion of orientalist and occidentalist beliefs. Most particularly, the rise of Japan and the East and Southeast Asia newly industrializing countries has pointed out the limits of the occidental project and not just in theory but also in practice. At the same time, it has undermined the West’s sense of itself as necessarily different. Nowhere is this clearer than in the economic register. The distinction between the West and the rest was at first drawn in terms of a classical orientalist/occidentalist opposition: the economic success of the countries of East and Southeast Asia was based on a “gift model” which arose from the construction of durable personal rela- tionships which were cemented in place by signs of reciprocity like the gift. These were social procedures that were supposedly in opposition to the West’s reliance on a “commodity model” of impersonal transactions, contracts, and the market. But this opposition is now breaking down. For example, Carrier (1995, p. 94) is able to review an impressive amount of evidence which allows him to conclude that: 68 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS

in different areas of life in industrial capitalist society, identities, relations, and trans- actions depart from the commodity model and instead resemble what exists in gift systems in important ways (through this assertion of resemblance is not an assertion of identity). Impersonal commodity relations and transactions clearly are important in the modern West. But equally important is the distinction between saying that com- modity relations are important in the West on the one hand, and on the other con- structing the West as a society in which commodity relations are so essential that we can ignore the existence of other sorts of relations.

Interestingly, the way in which the new ways of talking about economic practices is most often summarized is through a spatial description of one kind or another. We think it is possible to argue that four of these “topological presuppositions” cur- rently coexist, each of them successively more recent, more polymorphous, and less enveloping (Figure 4.1). We think of each presupposition, following Mol and Law (1995), as a different cluster of rules for localizing through which the social per- forms itself, involving different modes of proceeding and different sets of coordi- nates. The first and most familiar of these presuppositions represents the economy as a set of bounded regions within which different “economic” objects can be iden- tified, constituted, disciplined, by being linked together in various modes of terri- torial government (e.g., Miller and Rose, 1990). The second topology represents the economy as a set of interlocking or overlapping networks; economic objects are the result of the interaction between these networks (Grabher, 1993; Hamilton, 1991). The third topology represents the economy as flows; economic objects are contin- ual movements of capital, people, information, commodity, and the like (e.g., Castells, 1989; Lash and Urry, 1994). The fourth and final topology represents the economy as in two places at once: economic objects are bifocal, being both point and wave form (Bohm, 1980, 1994; Virilio, 1993). The economy is always virtual, never present. Note that there is no need to take topological sides, since each of these presuppositions coexists in intricate relation with the others. But clearly these four presuppositions produce radically different means of framing the world.

3 Conclusions Dr Ferrari examined 240 mall shoppers, measuring “procrastination scores (on arousal and avoidance measures), the closeness of the measurement to Christmas, and shop- pers’ rationales for why they were shopping at that particular time.” He reckoned pro- crastination was “motivated by arousal from working against a deadline and attributed their lack of diligence to job-related attributes (e.g., work, business commitments) that compelled them to begin shopping at the last possible opportunity.” Or they were moti- vated by a need to “avoid situations involving threats to self-esteem, attributing their postponed shopping to personal attributes (e.g., lack of energy, indecisiveness, per- ceived task aversiveness) reflecting their belief in their own inabilities” (White, 1995, p. 6).

The outlines of the new economic geography are only just beginning to become clear. But, already, we think it is possible to see some of the key areas of work that REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 69

Topological Current major Inspirations presupposition theorist

Bounded regions Biological Physical

Parts of Euclidean Foucault body spaces

Networks

Nervous Electrical Latour system networks

Flows

Circulation Deleuze Energy of blood

Two places at once Quantum Bohm DNA physics

Figure 4.1 Four topological propositions

will occupy its future. For convenience, we have grouped these around the four topological presuppositions set down above. The first area of work will be based around the topological presupposition of the bounded region. Most especially, it will consist of work that adopts a heterodox but broadly structural approach, which deals in the currency of the nation-state, and multinational corporations, international competitiveness, international regimes, third wave regulation theory, governmentality, and the like, and which increasingly goes under the name of “international political economy.” The kinds of concepts gathered under this umbrella title are being leavened by other concerns, for example to do with gender and ethnicity, but they seem likely to remain the most recognizably “economic.” The second area of work will be based around the topological presupposition of the network. It will chiefly be concerned with the social determinants of the eco- nomic and will range from the literature on self-organizing networked firms and learning regions, through monetary networks, to ethnic business networks. This area of work will also address the intertwining of different types of networks. In con- trast to the chiefly structural approach of the bounded region area of work, this area of work will be founded on pragmatist, constructionist, and ethnographic approaches. 70 NIGEL J. THRIFT AND KRIS OLDS

The third area of work will be based on the topological presupposition of flow. It will chiefly be concerned with cultural determinants of the economic and will be most concerned with issues like the body, self, and desire, and with different modes of representation and sensation (moving on from simply the visual) as they relate to different economic processes like money. The kinds of methods deployed will include semiotics, discourse analysis, iconography, and ethnography. The fourth area of work will be based on the topological presupposition of two places at once. This will be the preserve of a cybergeography. It will consist of work on economies as instantaneous media events (e.g., Wark, 1994) as well as more Nietzschean-inspired work on cyberspace, in the tradition of Plant (1994), Land (1994, 1995), and others, which conjures up a cybernetic world populated by artificial demons and dragons. The kinds of methods employed will include a powered-up poststructuralism and the kinds of approaches to the materiality of communication made popular by Kittler (1990) and Gumbrecht and Pfeiffer (1994). Yet what will be most interesting, we think, is the kind of work that will be done at the boundaries of these presuppositions, on the borderlines. For example, at the boundaries between international political economy and cultural work is a whole area of work on the transmission of various forms of economic discourse, where discourse is understood in the Foucauldian sense as a transindi- vidual and multi-institutional archive of images and statements providing a common language for representing knowledge about a given theme (e.g., Leyshon and Tickell, 1994). What all this also shows is the increasing difficulty of stabilizing “the economic” as an entity, in part, because the number of approaches to what we call the eco- nomic is multiplying and, in part, because our final vocabulary, to use the Rortyan phrase again, is changing. This last point is worth underlining. What is most strik- ing currently is the degree to which the very borderlines of what we have called “the economic” are now changing. We are moving away from the first round of cri- tiques of economics, such as those offered by McCloskey (1985) or Barnes (1994) or Mirowski (1995a) which pointed to the effects of the different metaphors that can be deployed as descriptions of the economic, towards a second round of recon- struction. This second round, which involves authors like Brennan (1994), Goux (1989, 1990) and Derrida (1992, 1995), questions the whole basis of the occiden- tal model of exchange by drawing on three main sources. The first of these is psy- choanalytic models of the ego, most especially drawing on the work of Freud and Lacan. Thus Brennan (1994), for example, argues that proliferation of commodi- ties blocks the mobility of psychical energy and therefore blocks the generation of life and ideas. The second source is the growing body of work on time which chal- lenges prevailing Western “chronotypes” (see, for example, Thrift, 1977; Bender and Wellbery, 1991; Lloyd, 1993). Derrida’s (1982) remorseless war on the pres- ence of the present is a case in point. The third and final source is the inspiration provided by Bataille’s (1988; Bennington, 1995) theories of expenditure as excess, and equally his appropriation of Mauss’s theory of the potlatch as an illustration of the general economy of loss, disequilibrium, and expenditure without return, in which exchange does not imply reciprocity. These three sources all challenge the notion of a “restricted” economy of production, equilibrium, and balanced books REFIGURING THE ECONOMIC IN ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 71

– the determined and determinate economy of classical utility – and focus, instead, on loss, excess, chance; an energetics of laughter, excitement, poetry, and all the other activities that are apparently outside “the economic.” This challenge, which becomes more concerted day by day, suggests that our final vocabulary is not so final after all. There is no last word. Chapter 5 The Economy, Stupid! Industrial Policy Discourse and the Body Economic

J. K. Gibson-Graham

Once upon a time, people used to talk about ISSUES and HAVE FUN. But then someone invented the economy . . . The economy grew and grew! It took over EVERY- THING and NO-ONE COULD ESCAPE. (Morris, 1992, p. 53, quoting from memory a recent cartoon)

I saw men on television (trade-union stars, Cabinet Ministers, left-wing think-tank advisers) visibly hystericized by talking economics: eyes would glaze, shoulders hunch, lips tremble in a sensual paroxysm of “letting the market decide,” “making the hard decisions,” “leveling the playing field,” “reforming management practices,” “improv- ing productivity” . . . those who queried the wisdom of floating the exchange rate, deregulating the banks, or phasing out industry protection were less ignored than washed away in the intoxicating rush of “living in a competitive world” and “joining the global economy.” (Morris, 1992, pp. 51–2)

In Ecstasy and Economics, Meaghan Morris chronicles the ecstatic submission of white Australian men to “the economy.” Humbled before its godlike figure, grown men grovel and shout in fundamentalist rapture, transported in “an ecstasy of Reason” (1992, p. 77). By giving themselves over to a higher power, they have paradoxically gained mastery and authority. They “talk economics” and find themselves speaking the language of pure necessity, unhampered by base specifici- ties of politics and intention. In the face of necessity, and in its despite, they project a willful certainty that their economic “interventions” will yield the outcomes they desire. During the 1980s and 1990s Australia was one of the few OECD countries gov- erned by a social democratic (albeit right-wing) Labor Party in which intervention- ist economic and industrial policies were on the national agenda. Recently, though abortively, the Clinton administration promised to concern itself with many of the things that concerned the Hawke and Keating governments from the beginning: deindustrialization, lack of technological innovation, a labor force unsuited to the needs of industry, a weak competitive position in a rapidly changing world. In seeking models of successful intervention that have presumably fostered rather than blocked economic adaptation, American economic strategists looked to Australia THE ECONOMY, STUPID!73 for innovative ways of meeting Clinton’s mandate to “grow the economy.” These American analysts included not merely center and right-wing Democrats but Marxists and other leftists whose pronouncements were suddenly contiguous to debates in the mainstream press. After 12 years (or maybe a lifetime) in exile, leftists in the US were “talking eco- nomics” in a room where just possibly they could be overheard. And the econom- ics they were talking was in some ways very different from what was permissible just a few years before, when “industrial policy” or “managed trade,” for example, could not be broached at the national level. Yet despite its release from old stric- tures and prohibitions, the discussion of economic policy seemed entirely familiar. It moved laboriously in a confined space, as though hobbled by an invisible tether or circumscribed by a jealous and restrictive force – something more potent even than the political realities that also operate to keep debate within narrow and famil- iar limits. Despite their divergent positions on every issue, the right and left share a “dis- course of economy” that participates in defining what can and cannot be proposed. What from a right-wing perspective may seem like a truly misguided left-wing pro- posal is nonetheless intelligible and recognizable as a member of the extended family of potential economic initiatives, and vice versa. This is not to say that right- and left-wing policy analysts profess the same economic theories and harbor the same social conceptions. In their positive proposals, their understandings of economy and society are often revealed to be quite different, and indeed they may have been trained in very different schools of thought. Nevertheless, there seems to be a sub- strate of commonality, detectable in the ubiquitous affective paradoxes of submis- sion and control, arrogance and caution, that structure the range of economic emotions. If the economy of the left is so different in its operations and possibili- ties from that of the right, why does it produce such similar affective disjunctions? Why is “the economy” at once the scene of abject submission, the social site that constrains activities at all other sites, the supreme being whose dictates must unques- tioningly be obeyed and, at the same time, an entity that is subject to our full under- standing and consequent manipulation? And how is it, furthermore, that something we can fully understand and thus by implication fully control is susceptible only to the most minimal adjustments, interventions of the most prosaic and subservient sort? What accounts for the twin dispositions of utter submission and confident mastery, and for boldness and arrogance devolving to lackluster economic interventions? Of course, these questions could be turned upon the questioner, and one might wish to understand how it is that I am positioned to see the left and the right as operating within the same “discourse of economy” despite the cacoph- ony produced by their different starting places, their divergent ends and means, their backgrounds in Marxism or neoclassicism, their heterogeneous present attachments to Keynesianism, post-Keynesianism, and various forms of develop- ment economics. In what discursive space am I situated, that left proposals appear strangled and truncated rather than as reasonable or even as exhausting the realm of the possible? If I turned to cultivating that space, to “growing an alternative discourse of the economy,” what monstrous novelties might emerge? 74 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM

The task of cultivation is so daunting that I scarcely know where to begin. But fortunately I do not have to make a beginning, since I too am part of a lineage. Indeed, I can only locate myself outside the “discourse of the economy” by virtue of my association with an alternative economic knowledge, even though the prod- ucts of that knowledge are few and far between. What follows, then, can be read as the delineation of an existing formation whose magnificent contours can sud- denly be seen from the vantage of a new and separate space, itself uncultivated and unformed.

The Body Economic Ailments in search of a cure Anorexia, meaning without appetite, is a starvation syndrome that has reached epi- demic proportions in wealthy Western social formations. Deindustrialization, defined as the decline of traditional manufacturing, is an economic condition widely perceived as a threat to the industrial capitalist nations. What might be the con- nection between these two representations of disorder? A solution to this riddle can be found in the ways in which medical interventions into anorexia, and industrial policy interventions into deindustrialization, are con- strued as potential “cures” for the ailments of a suffering body. Food is adminis- tered intravenously to the anorectic, and investment is lured to declining industrial regions, in order to revitalize an ailing corporeal being. Convincing the anorectic to participate in family therapy and negotiating with the downsized workforce to stem wage growth and introduce a new work culture are both attempts to foster the con- ditions under which the essential life forces, calories and capital, might restore the body to its natural state of health. Twenty years of investment policies directed at declining industries and regions have resulted in only marginal success in redressing the deindustrialization disorder. Yet there are few attempts to rethink the economic discourse upon which this “cure” is predicated. By contrast, the human body is currently the focus of a radical rethink- ing (see, for example, Bordo, 1989; Gatens, 1991; Grosz, 1994; Kirby, 1992). Feminists exploring the social construction of the female body have questioned the centrality of the phallus, or its lack, in governing the actions of the embodied subject. The body is reappearing as a fluid, permeable, and decentered totality in which physiological, erotic, mental, psychological, social, and other processes mutually constitute each other, with no one process or zone being more invested with meaning or effectivity than another. In part what has motivated this rethinking are the social effects of representing the (female) body as a bounded and structured totality governed by the psyche (or some other locus of dominance) instead of as a “material-semiotic generative node” with boundaries that “materialize in social interaction” (Haraway, 1991, pp. 200–1). The physical and psychological tortures associated with the treatment of anorexia, for example, have prompted a reconceptualization of the body as a com- plexly overdetermined social site rather than a discrete entity subject to internal gov- ernance and medically restorable to self-regulation. Thus psychotherapist Harriet THE ECONOMY, STUPID!75

Fraad sees anorexia as an agonized crystallization of the contradictions “crowding in on [women’s] lives” (1994, p. 131) as men, bosses, the media, and women them- selves exercise new and demanding expectations of women. Whereas feminist theorists have scrutinized, and often dispensed with, the under- standing of the body as a bounded and hierarchically structured totality, most speak- ers of “economics” do not problematize the nature of the discursive entity with which they are engaged. Instead, they tend to appropriate unproblematically an object of knowledge and to be constructed thereby as its discursive subjects. In famil- iar but paradoxical ways, their subjectivity is constituted by the economy which is their object: they must obey it, yet it is subject to their control; they can fully under- stand it and, indeed, capture its dynamics in theories and models, yet they may adjust it only in minimal ways. These experiential constants of “the economy” delin- eate our subjective relation to its familiar and unproblematic being. Constituted in relation to the economy as both submissive and manipulative beings, capable of full knowledge but of limited action, our political effectivity is both undermined and overstated. With the consummate and ultimately crippling arrogance of modernist humanism, we construct ourselves as both the masters and the captives of a world whose truth we fully apprehend. In the face of that world or, more specifically, of the discourse of its economic form, and in the trains of the subjectivity which that discourse posits and promotes, we struggle to mark the existence and possibility of alternate worlds and to liberate the alternative sub- jectivities they might permit. But in order to re-create or reinform the political subject – a project which is arguably a rallying point for left social theory in the late twentieth century – it is necessary to rethink the economic object. Given the centrality of the economy to modernist social representations, and given its role in defining the capacities and possibilities of the left, it is necessary to defa- miliarize the economy as feminists have denaturalized the body, as one step toward generating alternative social conceptions and allowing new political subjectivities to be born.

The birth of the organism: metaphors of totality and economy Like the anorectic woman constructed as a target of medical intervention, the economy of the economic strategists and planners is depicted as a body, and not just any body. It is a bounded totality made up of hierarchically ordered parts and energized by an immanent life force. In a word, the body economic is an organism, a modern paradigm of totality that is quite ubiquitous and familiar. The organismic totality emerged, by some accounts, with the birth of “the economy” as a discrete social location. When Adam Smith theorized the social divi- sion of labor as the most productive route to social reproduction, he laid the ground- work for a conception of “the economy” as a coherent and self-regulating whole (Callari, 1983, p. 15). By analogy with the individual who labored to produce his own means of subsistence, thereby constituting a unity of production and con- sumption, Smith saw society as structured by a division of labor among quintes- sentially “economic” human beings laboring for their own good and achieving the common good in a process of harmonious reproduction. 76 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM

In the absence of specialization producers are atomized, producing on their own or in small communities the wealth that satisfies their wants and needs; the “economy” is a plurality of practices scattered over a landscape. Increased special- ization, however, requires greater social integration, in order for reproduction to take place. The division of labor, and the specialization it entails, thus necessitates the integration of labor. Over the course of history, then, what was once plural becomes singular. Fragmentation becomes an aspect of unification rather than a state of atomism and dispersal. Scattered economic practices come together as “the economy” – something we all recognize, though may differently define, in economic discourse today. It is relatively easy to read certain forms of Marxian theory as tracing the linea- ments of an economic body. In many versions of Marxism, the capitalist economy or society is represented as a totality governed and propelled by the life force of capital accumulation. The requirements of this life force structure the relationship of parts within the whole, ordaining the extraction of surplus value from labor by capital, for example, which is facilitated by the division of functions among finan- cial, commercial, and industrial capitalist fractions. Social labor is pumped from the industrial heart of the economy and circulates through the veinous circuitry in its commodity, money, and productive forms. As it flows, it nourishes the body and ensures its growth. As the invisible life force of the capitalist economy, capital accumulation establishes the economy’s overarching logic or rationale, its telos of self-maintenance and expanded reproduction. In addition, a regulatory mechanism such as the rate of profit, or competition, or the business cycle, may operate like a ther- mostat to maintain the economy in a steady state. Ultimately, however, the life “nar- rative” of the economic organism incorporates not only health and stability but illness and death. Thus a capitalist economy experiences growth punctuated by crises, and may even be susceptible to breakdowns of an ultimate sort. When it eventually fails and dies, it will be succeeded by another organic totality, a social- ism that is presumably better adapted to the conditions that brought about capitalism’s dissolution. Some Marxian theories have attempted to dispel or attenuate the economic deter- minism and functionalism of this story by externalizing the regulatory function and by theorizing reproduction as a contingent rather than a necessary outcome of capitalist existence. French regulation theory and social structures of accumula- tion (SSA) theory, for example, have invoked the role of political and ideological as well as economic norms, habits, and institutions in the process of economic regu- lation and have attributed to historical “accident” the maintenance of stability in the relation of production to consumption. Despite these attempts to suppress both the teleological and functionalist aspects of “classical” Marxian theory, these frameworks represent the economy and society as an organic structure that oper- ates as a unity among harmoniously functioning parts. Capitalist history is por- trayed as a succession of such structures, each one experiencing maturation and healthy functioning followed by sickness and death. Growth and reproduction are the narrative constants of capitalism’s story, revealing the hidden role of accumula- tion as its life force. THE ECONOMY, STUPID!77

Metaphor and mastery, organism and intervention Foucault places in a transitional moment at the end of the eighteenth century the first use of organic structure as a “method of characterization” that

subordinates characters one to another; . . . links them to functions; . . . arranges them in accordance with an architecture that is internal as well as external, and no less invisible than visible. (1973, p. 231)

Man’s body, constituted as an organism structured by a life force that produces order from within, became at this time the modern episteme, setting unspoken rules of discursive practice that invisibly unified and constrained the multifarious and divergent discourses of the physical, life, and social sciences. Modern economics is grounded in Man’s body, finding the essence of economic development in man’s essential nature – his labor (the struggle against nature and death), for example, or his needs and desires (Amariglio, 1988, pp. 596–7; Amariglio and Ruccio, 1999). These bodily essences structure a field which is itself the very map of Man, an economy that is organically interconnected, hierarchically organized, and engaged in a process of self-regulated reproduction. Feminist theorists have argued that it is a gendered body “that was the founda- tion for representing all things, and thus giving things their hidden meaning” (Amariglio, 1988, p. 586) in the modern age. In the modernist regime of gender, human characteristics and other categories are disaggregated upon a binary discursive template in which one term is dominant and the other subordinate and devalued. Though the two terms exist in and through relation to each other, the regime of gender conveys a license to forget the mutuality of dependence. The dominant term thus becomes independent – in other words, its dependence upon its other for its very existence is forgotten – while the subordinate term is unable to exist without its opposite; it is defined negatively, as all that the dominant term is not. It is not difficult to see in the story of Man and his body the interplay of an infinite set of gendered oppositions – a brief list might include mind/body, reason/passion, man/nature, subject/object, transcendence/immanence. What is interesting, however, is the way in which the regime of gender is a colonizing regime, one that is able to capture other dualities and to partially subsume them. Thus as soon as we produce a dualism incorporating two related terms, gender may operate to sustain meanings of wholeness, positivity, definition, dominance, reason, order, and subjectivity (among others) for the first term and incompleteness, negativity, unboundedness, subordination, irrationality, disorder, and objectification for the second. In this way it becomes possible to understand the bizarre dance of dominance and submission through which Man addresses the economy. When Man is posi- tioned as the first term in their binary relation, he is the master of the economy and of its processes; but when Man (perhaps in the guise of “society”) is positioned as the second term, he bows to the economy as to his god. Each positioning is informed and constituted by an infinity of binary hierarchalizations. 78 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM

In Man’s discursive constitution, dominant (male) human characteristics are rep- resented as universal while subordinate (female) characteristics are externalized or suppressed. They subsist as the Other – woman or nature – to Man, by whose absence or suppression he is defined. Through the operation of the regime of gender, Man becomes a creature who is fundamentally rational and whose fate is mastery and control of nature, of woman, of all non-Man (Sproul, 1993). He is the arro- gant knower, whose thoughts replicate and subjugate “reality.” Given its qualities of wholeness, transcendence, and rationality (for which one might read “perfection”) the organic economy is sometimes seen as functioning appropriately without intervention. From certain perspectives, the economy is the word to which the flesh is always and necessarily subsumed. From others, however, the existence of reason in the economy signals the possibility of successful inter- vention but also and simultaneously the limited need and scope for intervention. Thus the economy may need its “pump primed” or its life force “re-ignited”; it may need to be “whipped into shape” or “kick-started” to get it “rolling” again. Someone may need to take the helm, pulling on the “levers” that govern the speed and direction of the machine:

(“Mr Keating emerges from his bunker”): headlines shouted that he was picking up the reins, handling gears and pulling levers again. (Morris, 1992, p. 24)

Once Labor was elected, the labour movement made a number of assumptions about taking control of the economic levers of power. (Comment by Chris Lloyd, a left-wing union researcher, from an interview by Curran, 1991, p. 27)

Ultimately, however, these interventions are subservient to the logic and function- ing of the economy itself.

Bypass surgery: tinkering with the ticker The organismic economy calls forth a particular discourse of intervention that estab- lishes the masculinist subject position of intervener/controller. Thus the affective dis- course of economy is always to some extent a discourse of mastery: the terrain of the economy is laid out by economic theory, with its entryways and pathways clearly marked and its systems interconnected. Spreading the economy before him as his dominion, economic theory constructs Man as a sovereign/ruler. And the familiar terrain of the body is his domain. It is not hard to see lurking in the vicinity of economic and industrial policy a body engaged in a battle for survival. Couched in the language of the living body or machine, the economy is portrayed as an organism (machine) whose endemic growth dynamic (or mechanical functioning) is in jeopardy. Diagnoses usually focus upon two key areas of economic physiology, obstructions in the cir- culation system and/or malfunctioning of the heart. The faltering national economy is often compared to healthier bodies elsewhere, all poised to invade and deprive the ailing, or less fit, organism of its life force. Economic and industry policy is for- mulated to remove the internal, and create immunity to the external, threats to reproduction. THE ECONOMY, STUPID!79

The analogy of the blood’s circulation system and the role of the heart in keeping the volume and rate of flow sufficient to ensure reproduction enables a specific set of interventions and manipulations. In recent years, for example, in most industri- alized nations the call for wage restraint has been justified in terms of the presumed negative effect of wage increases upon profitability and economic growth. Wages, it is argued, have been the problem, the obstruction in the system of capital circu- lation that has prevented growth. In the United States wage cuts have been imple- mented through such tactics as union decertification, two-tier wage structures, and concession bargaining. In Australia, federally legislated policies of wage restraint have been supported by the unions through the Accord. Visions of an organized and interconnected economic system in which interven- tions have predictable (and even necessary) effects have facilitated the acceptance of cuts in real wages in Australia. Wage increases have been portrayed as blocking (via their influence on the rate of profit) the generation of a pool of funds available for investment in the expansion and modernization of Australian industry. The backwardness of national industry has been seen as the major constraint upon the international competitiveness of Australian products. By the straightforward logic of organic reproduction, in which specific and focused interventions have a non- contradictory and presumably restorative effect on the whole, wage cuts have been proposed not only to free up investment capital and increase competitiveness, but to “overcome the problem of a deficit in the current account of the balance of pay- ments” by “curtailing the demand for imports” and “cutting the costs of exporting and import-substituting industries” (Stilwell, 1991, p. 32). When a totality is centered, internally connected, hierarchically ordered, and gov- erned by laws of motion that can be replicated by reason in the mind of man, the strategist has only to identify the right place to start the treatment (tinkering) and soon the whole will be healthy (working) again. Curtail wages, it is argued, and the flow of investment into the crucial parts of the body economic will take place. At the base of this curative vision is the metaphoric heart of the economy – manufac- turing production. It is here that the life blood of the system, capital, is most effi- ciently created and it is from this site that it is pumped to peripheral sectors and the unproductive extremities. Given its presumably critical role in economic development and social well-being, it is not surprising that manufacturing investment has long been a concern on the left. In the US in the 1980s, Bluestone and Harrison’s influential book The Deindustrialization of America (1982) focused attention on disinvestment in the domestic manufacturing sector, identifying foreign investment by multinational corporations and unproductive expenditures on mergers and acquisitions as its prin- cipal causes. In Australia, lack of generative investment in manufacturing has var- iously been attributed to the unwarranted expansionism of the mining sector or the alluring rewards of speculation. In the context of the prevalent discourse of manufacturing-centrism, it becomes clear that the organicist notion of a hierarchy of functions within the economy – and specifically the essentialist conception that one or several parts are critical while others are peripheral or supportive – has constrained and directed the possibilities of economic intervention. In this, as in other centered formulations, the growth dynamic is perceived as emanating from a single economic location. Manufacturing 80 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM is viewed as the driver of the economy, and all other parts of the economy (including agriculture, services, government, and households) are seen as ultimately deriving their growth from growth in manufacturing. These other sectors may contribute to the reproduction of capitalist society but they are not the key to its survival – perhaps because they are seen as not generating surplus value, or because they are viewed as low productivity sectors that do not contribute sufficiently to growth, or for some other reason. Growth in these sectors is portrayed as flab, not the hard muscle required for a taut and terrific body economic:

in order for the shift of employment to services to be developmental and not become a shift to poverty, we (the United States) must maintain mastery and control of manufacturing production. (Cohen and Zysman 1987, p. 16)

Many types of economic activity are thus relegated to secondary status as targets for resources and attention. Indeed the organicist conception contributes to a very familiar hierarchy of policy priorities. While some types of economic activity are seen as essential to social sur- vival, and as therefore necessitous of intervention, others are viewed as frosting on the social cake. Though it may be widely recognized and lamented that child-care and its low wage providers are in difficult economic straits, policymakers will remind us that unless we take care of manufacturing we are all up the creek. Buttressed by the conception of the organism as a self-maintaining, self- rectifying body, strategists may argue that restoring growth in key or lead sectors will set the entire economy upon a path of growth or recovery. In this view, the principle of efficiency dictates that interventions be targeted at the critical locations. When economic conditions are dire, intervening to improve child-care centers is like offering a bandaid to a patient with a heart attack. The interconnectedness of the parts, and the accessible logic of their intercon- nection, enables intervention at some distance from the problem (symptom). It thus becomes perfectly reasonable to argue that if we want decent child-care centers we must start with productivity increases or wage cuts in manufacturing. It is also acceptable to ignore or to postpone dealing with problems in most parts of the economy since these will be rectified by the healthy functioning of the heart. The truth of all these representations is guaranteed by a rationalist conviction that the reductive logic of economists reflects the orderly and parsimonious logic of the economy itself. These logics dictate that economic interventions will have pre- dictable and noncontradictory outcomes and they define the relation of policymak- ers to the economy as that of Man to the machine. Thus you may quite easily arrive at the bizarre conclusion that general economic well-being will be enhanced by wage cuts; and by associating this vision with an invincible and deific figure, you may sell this program to an entire nation of wage earners and economic believers.

Matters of life or death The lawful self-regulation of the economic organism dictates that interventions must ultimately serve or operate within the organism’s telos of organized growth. Policy then is affected not only by the essentialism of the organic metaphor, which ascribes THE ECONOMY, STUPID!81 generative power and causality to certain aspects of the totality and withholds it from others, but also by the functionalism of this conception. The economy is reduced to a set of functional relations that are coordinated by the rules and require- ments of capitalist reproduction. Thus no matter whether an intervention is well or ill conceived and managed, its effects are necessarily to perpetuate “capitalism” and capitalist class relations. This invisible prescription circumscribes and constrains even the most left-wing economic proposals and analyses. Organic functionalism subsumes the future to the contours of the present. But it also precludes envisioning diversity and multiplicity in the consequences of eco- nomic intervention. Society as organism is a set of conformable interests in which all benefit from the healthy functioning of the whole:

Functionalism has been developed on a foundation of organismic metaphors, in which diverse physiological parts or subsystems are coordinated into a harmonious, hierar- chical whole. Conflict is subordinated to a teleology of common interests. (Haraway, 1991, p. 24)

Certainly, in Australia, the interests of business and the organized labor movement have been represented by political and union leaders as effectively harmonious:

Australia needs a sustainable high growth strategy that avoids or minimizes the effects of the boom-bust cycles of the past. Metal workers and all Australians simply cannot afford a vision of nation building which leads to low growth and another one or two boom-bust cycles during the 1990s decade. (MEWU, 1992, p. 24, emphasis mine)

In the face of this kind of assertion, which is buttressed by a notion of common “national” interests, it is difficult to maintain a sense that any “growth strategy” – indeed, any intervention in a complex totality – will have uneven and contradictory effects. That the strategic unionism advocated by leftists has so easily been led into strate- gic functionalism, that is, into advocating policies that help materialize the repro- duction of capitalist practices, has long been a matter of concern to those whose economics focuses less upon reproduction and more upon the potential for eco- nomic dysfunction (MacWilliam, 1989). Bryan (1992) argues, for example, that the Australian left had no business supporting any form of wage restraint, as this only served to shore up the accumulation process and avert, once again, the threat of imminent crisis. The life/death opposition that lies at the nub of the organic metaphor presents the opportunities for political intervention in the form of a simple duality. If I don’t wish to pursue industrial strategies for patching up or resuscitating capitalism, I can upend the analysis and concentrate upon exacerbating the preconditions of death. Though most leftists now abjure the millennial goal of promoting “the revolution” by promoting organic dysfunction, organic functionalism has locked them into the alternative goal of promoting capitalist health. In order to create employment and rebuild communities, they must participate in strategies and programs to foster capitalist development, capitalist reindustrialization, and capitalist growth. Many on the left would like to see an alternative to capitalism, but they face a unitary 82 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM economy that allows for no such proximate possibility. Their options are to promote the healthy functioning of capitalist economies or to see working people and others marginalized and impoverished. This is not a particularly inspiriting choice, yet its grounding in humanism and organicism is seldom questioned or even brought to light.

Beyond life and death Donna Haraway argues that if the future is given by the possibility of a past, then an “open future” must rest upon a “new past” (1991, pp. 41–2). This could involve, I would argue, a new conception of totality, one that abandons the organ- ism as we know it. Haraway gives some encouragement that such a discontinuity is possible:

One is not born a woman, Simone de Beauvoir correctly insisted. It took the political- epistemological terrain of postmodernism to be able to insist on a co-text to de Beauvoir’s: one is not born an organism. Organisms are made; they are constructs of a world-changing kind. (1991, p. 208)

In a similar vein, Foucault prepares the way for a rethinking of totality in non-organic and non-anthropomorphic terms. Having shown how the vitalism of organic structure could not have been thought within the discourse of the sixteenth century and thus how Man’s body could not have existed as the “ground for dis- course” before the nineteenth century (Amariglio, 1988, p. 589), he speculates in the conclusion of The Order of Things upon the end of the modern episteme and the fundamental arrangements of knowledge that made it possible for the figure of Man to appear:

As the archaeology of our thought easily shows, man is an invention of recent date. And one perhaps nearing its end. If those arrangements were to disappear as they appeared, if some event of which we can at the moment do no more than sense the possibility without knowing either what its form will be or what it promises were to cause them to crumble, as the ground of Classical thought did, at the end of the eigh- teenth century, then one can certainly wager that man would be erased, like a face drawn in sand at the edge of the sea. (1973, p. 387)

In a search for a new social and economic totality, born of the old but perhaps not its semblance, I sometimes turn to discourses of economic change. Certainly, I tell myself at these moments, it is in the discourse of economic restructuring, produced over the last twenty years by Marxist political economists in a variety of social science fields, that I have had the most experience of [re]constructing the organic economy. Perhaps it is also in this context that I might have the greatest chance of perceiving an emergent totality, one that is no longer constrained by essentialism and reproductionism, or inflected with the arrogance of interventionist humanism. Perhaps I might find the ground from which to move beyond the outmoded but still unreplaced “progressive” options of socialist “revolution” or capitalism with a human face. THE ECONOMY, STUPID!83

The Ladder of Evolution Genealogies of capitalism, metaphors of organic development The discontinuity which, in Foucault’s archaeological terms, marked the beginning of the modern age brought the rise of History as the organizing principle of knowl- edge. Along with History came an interest in the internal organic relations between elements of a totality, the life and death of organic structures, and the linear sequenc- ing, or succession, of analogous structures (1973, pp. 218–19). Certainly in the discourse of economic change there has been no shortage of coherent structures succeeding each other in orderly progression. In recent years, for example, one of the distinctive features of Australian left-wing industrial policy has been the promotion of a new “model of industrial development.” This model is none other than post-Fordism, an industrial “paradigm” that focuses upon the developmental role of small and medium-sized firms and the reorientation of busi- ness and work cultures around flexibility, computerized technology, networking, and strategic alliances both within sectors and between producers and consumers (Mathews, 1990). The aim of industry interventions is to create the conditions under which a fully-fledged post-Fordist economy might be born, unimpeded by obstruc- tionist union regulations or demarcations, business attitudes, or statutory barriers. Underlying the vision of the new industrial model are the familiar metaphor of the economic organism and an associated conception of capitalist development as a suc- cession of organic structures, or “models of development” (this term is taken from Lipietz, 1992), each structurally similar to but qualitatively different from the last. In his collection of “popular scientific” essays on origins and evolution, Stephen Jay Gould (1991) tells the wonderful story (entitled “Life’s Little Joke”) of com- peting depictions of the evolutionary development of the modern-day horse. Until recently, the case of the horse has served as the common illustration of species evo- lution up a ladder of continuous development from primitive to modern. Each lock step of the ladder is marked by increasing size and height, decreasing number of toes, and an increase in the complexity of the grinding teeth. This standard icon- ography of evolution has, according to Gould, “initiated an error that captures pic- torially the most common of all misconceptions about the shape and pattern of evolutionary change” (p. 171). The metaphor (and illustrative device) of a ladder portrays evolutionary development as an unbroken continuity. It encapsulates the view that horses developed through a series of sequential stages of development, each adapted to the changing environment at hand. In similar fashion, the current penchant for representing the history of twentieth-century capitalist development in terms of a series of progressive steps from pre-Fordism to Fordism to post-Fordism places economic organisms on a ladder of sequential adaptation (see Figure 5.1). Gould’s reading of the fossil evidence, and that now commonly accepted, has caused a radical rethinking of the ladder metaphor and the adaptive functionalism it embodies. He argues that the metaphor of a bush might better suit the evolu- tionary drama that is partially revealed by the fossil record:

Evolutionary genealogies are copiously branching bushes and the history of horses is more lush and labyrinthine than most. To be sure, Hyracotherium is the base of the trunk (as now known), and Equus is the surviving twig. We can, therefore, draw a 84 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM

Post-Fordist

1975

Fordist monopoly 1920

Competitive

1860 Primitive accumulation

CAPITALIST NON-CAPITALIST CAPITALIST BUSH BUSH LADDER

Figure 5.1 Metaphors of economic evolution

pathway of connection from a common beginning to a lone result. But the lineage of modern horses is a twisted and tortuous excursion from one branch to another,... Most important, the path proceeds not by continuous transformations but by lateral stepping. (Gould, 1991, p. 175)

Within economic restructuring discourse some empirical studies likewise question the hegemony of the ladder of economic development. Salais and Storper (1992), for example, have produced an interesting discussion of four different models of technically dynamic industrial development that have coexisted during the twen- tieth century within different cultural contexts. Only one of these models (found, not surprisingly, in the United States) is consistent with what we have come to call Fordism. Piore and Sabel (1984) have highlighted the viability of forms of flexible specialization within capitalist industry in northern Italy throughout the so-called Fordist era. The work of economic sociologists and anthropologists suggests a vision of a diversity of industrial structures, firm types, and models of development inter- acting in different combinations. The selection of particular models as “universal” or “dominant” in the accepted narratives of capitalist development reflects, I would argue, the power of metaphors of organicism and ladders of evolutionary change. In economic development theory as in biology there has been a tendency to run “a steamroller over a labyrinthine pathway that hops from branch to branch through a phylogenetic bush” (Gould, 1991, p. 180) of economic forms (see Figure 5.1). In the process the many capitalist and noncapitalist forms that have coexisted with the “dominant” form have been obliterated from view. This discursive mar- ginalization functions powerfully to constrain the visions and politics of the future, prompting, for example, industry interventions designed to facilitate the step into post-Fordism (seen as currently the most adaptive, advanced, and efficient form of capitalism) and thereby making it less likely that non-post-Fordist and noncapital- ist forms will continue to exist. THE ECONOMY, STUPID!85

As Gould’s story shows, the representation of history as a sequential ladder has the effect of reducing economic diversity. By denying the existence of other branches and pathways, the image of development as a ladder of evolution promotes the monolithic capitalism it purports to represent. In its most egregious and easily rec- ognizable manifestation, the development ladder ranges the countries of the world along a unilinear hierarchy of progress, calling forth attempts to eradicate “tradi- tional” economic forms and replace them with capitalist industrialization. Modern Darwinian evolutionary theory constructs a vision of the “naturalness” of domination. During the early nineteenth century, the representation of the body or population (animal, vegetable, or human) as an organism which is somehow internally motivated by a fight for survival became inextricably linked to concepts of natural dominance (Haraway, 1991, p. 42). In economic terms, dominance came to be understood as the dominance of capitalism and capitalist class processes over all other forms of economy and exploitation. Economic evolution has become a story of the progressive emergence of ever more efficient, more competitive, and therefore dominant forms of capitalist enterprise, technology, and economic organization. In rethinking the economic totality, perhaps we might begin by abandoning the hegemony of dominance, as some feminist theorists have begun to do. Perhaps we might also abandon the narrative of History as a succession of hegemonic struc- tures, each of which has won a war of survival and adaptation. Finally and most importantly, we might abandon the organic body economic and seek a “new con- ception of the organism as an intereffective totality of determinations,” as Richard Lewontin puts it (quoted in Amariglio, Resnick, and Wolff, 1988, p. 499), or some- thing analogous on the social level. In an “intereffective social totality” each economic process might be understood as overdetermined by all non-economic processes, and as participating in their overdetermination (Resnick and Wolff, 1987). Privileged economic sites and processes would thereby lose their status as causes that are not simultaneously effects. Lacking its unifying rationale or essential life force, the economy would be deprived of its integrity and its commitment to reproduction. As the desiccated shell of the organism fell away, we might glimpse a region of infinite plurality and cease- less change, in which economic processes scatter and proliferate, unhampered by a ladder of development or a telos of organized growth. Here again Gould’s story may contribute to a reconceptualization:

Who ever heard of the evolutionary trend of rodents or of bats or of antelopes? Yet these are the greatest success stories in the history of mammals. Our proudest cases do not become our classic illustrations because we can draw no ladder of progress through a vigorous bush with hundreds of surviving twigs. (1991, p. 180)

My analogous question is “Who ever heard of the development in the contem- porary western world of noncapitalist class processes like feudalism or slavery as prevalent forms of exploitation, or of independent commodity production as a locus of self-appropriation?” Yet these are the greatest survival stories in the history of class. Our focus on the development of the different forms of capitalist enterprise (and by implication of capitalist exploitation) has made it difficult to conceptualize 86 J. K. GIBSON-GRAHAM the persistence and establishment of many noncapitalist forms of exploitation in households, shops, small factories, farms, and communes (represented in Figure 5.1 as a shadowy bush). Our metaphor of the organism, in its functionalism and holism, has contributed to the portrayal of all noncapitalist class processes as subordinate to and reproductive of “capitalism.” It has fostered an understanding of capitalism as a unitary figure coextensive with the geographical space of the nation-state (if not the world) rather than as a disaggregated and diverse set of practices unevenly distributed across a varied economic landscape. On the metaphorical ladder of evo- lutionary development, noncapitalist forms of exploitation have been denigrated as primitive remnants of a dominance long past, perhaps still existing in Third World countries but not consequential in the social formations of the so-called developed world. Ignored by socialists focused and fixated on capitalist dominance, these noncapitalist forms have been neglected as sites of political activity and class transformation or dismissed as the revolutionary ground of populists and romantics.

No organism, no guarantees By centering the organic economy on capitalist class processes and on ostensibly dominant economic forms, economic policy discourse curtails and truncates the pos- sible avenues of economic intervention, to the cost of all those interested in the polit- ical goal of class transformation (Ruccio, 1992). The ladder of development that places post-Fordism (or some other successful form of capitalism) at the pinnacle of contemporary economic adaptation precludes the possibility that noncapitalist adaptation may be simultaneously taking place and, at the same time, precludes the possibility of successful socialist projects and interventions. In the face of this restrictive vision and the set of possibilities it allows, some feminist theorists have abandoned the conception of the economy as a unified and singular capitalist entity, emphasizing the role of the household as a major site of noncapitalist production in so-called advanced capitalist social formations (see, for example, Folbre, 1993; Waring, 1988). Eschewing the formulations of what is some- times known as dual systems theory, in which patriarchy and capitalism are viewed as two forms of exploitation situated respectively in the household and industrial workplace, certain feminist theorists have identified a variety of forms of household class relations (Fraad et al., 1994; Cameron, 1995). They represent the household as a site of difference and change in terms of both the types of production that take place there (including use-values for domestic consumption, like clean rooms and cooked meals) and the ways in which surplus labor is produced and appropriated by household members. This feminist attempt to retheorize and displace “the economy” has powerful and potentially far-reaching implications. It effectively decenters the discourse of economy from the capitalist sector without at the same time establishing an alter- native center for economic theory. At the same time, its emphasis on the diversity of household forms of economy and exploitation opens the possibility of theoriz- ing class diversity in the non-household sector. Once that possibility exists, we may begin to produce a knowledge of diverse exploitations in “advanced capitalist” social formations. Such a knowledge is one of the conditions of a politics of class THE ECONOMY, STUPID!87 diversity, and the absence of such a knowledge is one of the conditions that renders such a politics unthinkable and obscure. The hegemony of the organism and the ladder within certain types of Marxian (and much non-Marxian) economic theory has prevented a complex, decentered knowledge of an overdetermined economic and social totality from emerging. These metaphors have generated a simple and restrictive vision of “the economy,” one that – in ironic counterpoint to the assessed failure of most economic policies and pro- grams – is associated with a discourse of masterful intervention and mechanical eventuation. To the extent that this vision has currency, economic discourse and the economic policy it gives rise to is a drama in which Man aspires to the state of transcendent Reason and mastery. Unfortunately, arrogance and failure are the shadows that play upon the stage. Though it is not malleable to our manipulations, our totality is what we discur- sively make it. Perhaps we can make it a site for the envisioning and enactment of a new class future.

Part II Realms of Production

Editors’ Introduction: Problematizing Production

Adam Tickell, Jamie Peck, Trevor J. Barnes, and Eric Sheppard

For much of its history, economic geography has been preoccupied with various attempts to grasp the geography of production. This was evident in the early descrip- tive geographies of agricultural and industrial activities. It took on a different form during the quantitative revolution (when economic geographers adopted and devel- oped the classical location models of von Thünen, Weber, Lösch, Christaller, and Palander) by integrating an analysis of raw materials, final manufactured products and distance in the search for systematic explanations of where things were made. An emphasis on production continued with the emergence of Marxist theorizing during the 1970s. In this work, profit and the profit motive were identified as the engines of economic change. It stresses that production was not organized simply for the satisfaction of human needs, nor did it simply respond to consumer demand, but instead, in Marx’s words, it represents “accumulation for accumulation’s sake.” Although Marxist theorizing is no longer de rigueur in economic geography (Harvey, Part I), its legacy remains central to the ways in which economic geogra- phers understand the geography of production. To differing degrees, the chapters in Part I explicitly or implicitly embrace, reject, or transform Marxist theorizations. For Marxists, profit-driven production lies at the core of social life in capitalist systems. It is characterized by a fundamental division between capitalists, who own the means of production, and workers, who have to sell their labor in order to survive. (There is also a third group of landlords and resource owners.) There is, thus, an unequal power relationship at the heart of society which produces “sys- tematic conditions of repression, social and ecological exploitation, uneven devel- opment, disempowerment, and social exclusion for many, as well as immense wealth, power, and freedom for a few” (Swyngedouw, 2000, p. 44). Among the following chapters, Richard Walker’s paper is the most obviously Marxist. During the 1970s it became clear from a simple reading of the economic statistics of most Western capitalist societies that employment in, and output from, services dwarfed their equivalents in physical production. To some observers such as Daniel Bell (1973), this was indicative of a transformation in the very organiza- tion of capitalism itself, with services becoming the motor of growth. Walker’s paper 92 ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, AND ERIC SHEPPARD is a sustained critique of this argument. In a simple, but erroneous, reading of Marxist thinking, physical production lies at the base of capitalism, on which rests the social and legal superstructure that holds society together. A shift to a service- oriented society, therefore, was consequently seen by some to pose a challenge to a political economy apparently rooted in the social relations of material production. Walker shows that this represents a misunderstanding both of the nature of Marxist analysis and of the actual role of services in the organization of the economy. He insists that services should properly be seen as a continuing and integral part of the production process. For Walker, the key feature of capitalism is that it is dynamic and revolutionary, leading to fundamental changes in both its internal organization and its form of production, but it is also conservative, in that the fundamental class cleavages in society – between those with access to capital and those forced to sell their labor – are enduring. The growth of services, Walker shows, arises precisely because capitalism is sufficiently dynamic to reinvent the way that human needs and desires are satisfied, while remaining sufficiently conservative to leave the funda- mental divisions in society unchanged. Consequently, Walker concludes that the prevalent optimism – about living standards and life chances – among theorists of the service society is misplaced and that only a socialist transformation of society can really improve people’s lives. Geographers brought to Marxian analysis the key insight that capitalism neces- sarily leads to “uneven development” because antagonistic relationships between capitalists and workers are organized in real places and over geographical space. In contrast to some of the prevailing liberal explanations, Marxists argued that capi- talism produces a necessarily “restless landscape”: economic decline in one area does not simply result from bad luck, “suboptimal” decisions, or an “unsuitable” local business climate. Consequently, an adequate analysis requires a focus on the totality of economic relationships and their complex connections with uneven spatial development. In order to maximize their profit rates, firms are constantly adapting (if they don’t, they are unable to compete effectively with other firms), making capitalism as a system highly dynamic, characterized by rapid industrial change and considerable locational mobility. Yet capitalism is also unstable, subject to periodic economic cycles of over-production and over-accumulation, where com- modities, equipment, money, workers, and the built environment may become under-utilized, leading to “devalorizations” of capital. Inflation, unemployment, stock market crashes, and the destruction of buildings and industrial capacity are among the typical consequences. Marxist geographers emphasize that these deval- orizations always take place in specific places, while both capitalists and the state attempt to contain or mitigate crisis through the reorganization of production and geographical relocation, or the transformation of existing built environments (such as the development of dockside housing or retail developments where once indus- try stood). In the 1980s in Britain, however, there was growing uneasiness with Marxist analysis. As John Lovering argues, Marxist theorizing in geography

was pitched at a very general level, throwing little light on specific empirical cases . . . This work was also generally silent on remedies, apart from an implicit or vaguely specified and ultimately millennial revolution. (1989, p. 206) INTRODUCTION TO PART II 93

It is within this context that the reading from Doreen Massey needs to be situated. Massey takes as her starting point the conflictual relationship between capitalists and workers and the centrality of the profit motive, but she goes on to insist that these relationships are manifest in variable forms in geographic space. While the resulting spatial structures may vary considerably, and new ones will develop all the time, axiomatic for Massey is the fact that these geographically constituted relations reflect and reproduce relations of power and control. A common feature of capi- talist societies is the emergence of regional economic specialization (for example, into industrial assembly, research and development, or financial services). For Massey, it is not just a matter of productive efficiency or local factor endowments, but, at a deeper level, reflects relations of power. Core regions accumulate power and control by virtue of significant concentrations of financial, managerial, and gov- ernmental decision-making functions, whereas others remain in subordinated eco- nomic, political, and social positions, often being subject to “external control.” Massey’s paper explores the changing economic geography of the United Kingdom between the 1960s and the middle of the 1980s, drawing on empirical evidence to support her argument that the decline of the industrial base of the UK reinscribed existing geographical relations of dominance. Although the southeast of England had always been the favored region, the growing importance of the City of London meant that the southeast was, to an extent, able to dictate its position in the international division of labor, while other parts of the UK were far more dependent on decisions taken elsewhere. Massey’s work on the restructuring of the British economy was produced during a period when the UK appeared to have given up on making things. Within British economic geography, the overwhelming emphasis was on grappling with the “geo- graphy of deindustrialization” (for example, Martin and Rowthorn, 1986; Mar- shall, 1987; Massey and Allen, 1988). Claims that capitalism was entering a new period of economic growth, involving new and dynamic forms of production, were consequently met with skepticism. No such reticence is found in Allen Scott’s essay. Scott draws upon the theoretical work of the French “regulation school,” which is associated with the claims that (a) capitalism is marked by episodes of relatively sustained growth, interspersed with periods of economic instability; and (b) these episodes of growth are in turn sustained by a supportive complex of institutional, cultural, and political conditions (such as patterns of consumption, the behavior of the state, labor relations, business norms, and so on) known as the “mode of social regulation.” (This insight, again, owes much to Marxist thinking about the eco- nomic “base” and the social and political “superstructure” of capitalist societies.) The paradigmatic case for the regulation school was that of “Fordism,” a phase of sustained economic growth between the late 1940s and the early 1970s. During the Fordist period, regulation theorists posit that a virtuous relationship was established between mass production and mass consumption on the one hand and a Keynesian- welfarist mode of regulation on the other. A highly productive factory system, based on assembly-line principles, was variously complemented and underwritten by (a) governments committed to the improvement of standards of living and social welfare (which helped secure incomes) and the sustenance of high employment levels, (b) rising real incomes and a growing financial infrastructure, which provided a material and institutional basis for the extension of mass consumer markets, and 94 ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, AND ERIC SHEPPARD

(c) the broad acceptance of various forms of “Keynesian” economic policy, which sought to flatten the economic cycle, making for more stable and predictable market conditions. By the 1980s, however, it had become clear that this virtuous relationship between production, consumption, and social regulation was no longer working to secure economic growth in Western countries (see Tickell and Peck, 1992). Com- petition from newly industrializing countries was intensifying, profit rates and labor productivity were falling, and both inflation and unemployment were rising, thereby further undermining the Keynesian-welfarist social settlement. While many eco- nomic geographers in northern and western Europe, and in the “rustbelt” regions of North America, were focusing on the readily observable downsides of this process (like deindustrialization and job loss) in their domestic economies, Scott’s principal interest is with the upside – the new, flexible economy rising from the ashes of the old. He is particularly concerned with the dynamics of nascent growth sectors and their accompanying forms of social regulation, which he captures in the rubric of “flexible accumulation.” Under this emergent regime, a would-be successor to Fordism, companies organize their production flexibly in at least three ways: within the firm, in their relationships with other firms, and in relation to their workers. Furthermore, for Scott, flexible accumulation thrives when it is complemented by supportive social and political structures. For example, firms can only treat labor flexibly if both the local labor laws and the local labor culture allow them to do so. Thus, the economic geography of flexible accumulation is different from its Fordist predecessor: an increased reliance on interfirm transactions is leading to renewed tendencies for spatial agglomeration, the most vivid expressions of which are to be found in the new growth areas, the “new industrial spaces.” While Massey, there- fore, tends to highlight historical continuities in regional power relationships, Scott emphasizes the potential for fluidity and path-altering change. It is important to note, however, that just as theories of deindustrialization were wrought within a context of economic decline, so were theorizations of flexible accumulation devel- oped within the somewhat atypical context of California’s booming industrial economy (Gertler, 1992). A concern with the changing nature of the capitalist economy is also evident in Peter Dicken’s exploration of the relationships between firms and states under con- ditions of deepening globalization. Dicken was probably the first economic geogra- pher to take seriously the rise of a globally interdependent economy, focusing particularly on the rise of transnational corporations (TNCs). In this reading he attempts to move beyond the dominant rhetorics of globalization, which are sharply polarized between a group of advocates, claiming that globalization is a form of incipient economic homogenization or “market rule,” and an opposing group who tend to downplay both the novelty and significance of globalizing processes. Reject- ing these polarized views, Dicken argues for a much closer theoretical and empiri- cal examination of the relationship between firms and states. This involves three principal components. First, it is necessary to understand both the nature of TNCs and the relationships between them. TNCs, Dicken argues, do not all behave in the same way. Each has a different structure and strategy, which might be seen as dis- tinctive responses to the same basic dilemma: how to be both globally effective and locally responsive. Second, there is a need carefully to reexamine the role of the INTRODUCTION TO PART II 95 nation-state in the international arena (see also Part IV, Social Worlds). Again, Dicken points to a diverse set of behaviors and strategies on the part of states, which must all, to a degree, act as national economic champions. Third, Dicken argues that the relationship between states and TNCs is a multifaceted and dynamic one, subject to significant change over time. Overall, then, Dicken seeks to draw atten- tion to the nuances of the power relationships between TNCs and states. He insists that the consequent economic geography of the world economy is not predeter- mined. Cautioning against exaggerated accounts of corporations “ruling the world,” Dicken nevertheless points out that it is becoming increasingly difficult for nation- states to extract concessions from TNCs. Resurgent local economies, of the kind identified by Scott, are certainly part of the variegated global economy described by Dicken, but his analysis casts some doubt on the claim that networks of “flexible regions” will constitute a new economic paradigm. Although economic geography has moved a long way from its early productionist ethos, a continuing emphasis on relatively abstract economic categories, such as regions, states, and TNCs, means that, in some respects, many of its accounts remain curiously disembodied. For example, while both Walker and Scott place emphasis on different forms of labor, they have little to say about people. Authors like Melissa Wright, however, tend to be more in agreement with the position of Gibson-Graham (in Part I), asking who fills the “empty spaces” created by these abstract economic categories. In her work on the Mexican maquiladora, the belt of intense industri- alization on the border with the United States, Wright focuses on the multiplicity of power relationships that are embodied in these apparently simple, if not crude, economic relationships. She draws attention to the complex social constitution of workplace relations, revealing how they are necessarily embodied and socially struc- tured, rather than being mere side-effects of efficient organization. Here, she reports on an empirical exploration of workplace politics in a US factory based in Mexico, demonstrating how gender and nationality complicate class analysis. Like Walker and Massey, Wright is strongly influenced by Marxism, yet she argues that this per- spective must be augmented in order to make sense of this empirical case. Conse- quently, she draws upon feminist theory to convey the multifaceted relations of dominance that are present in the maquila workplace (see also McDowell, Part IV; Gibson-Graham, Part I). First, as women workers, their labor is regarded as inher- ently less valuable than that of men. Second, as Mexican workers, their labor is like- wise seen as inferior to that of US workers (even to the extent that promotion into management positions requires that Mexican workers become US taxpayers). A par- ticular strength of Wright’s paper is that it rests upon a critical dialog between empir- ical and theoretical analysis. The research is based on a combination of in-depth interviews and participant observation over an extended period of time. This allowed Wright both to develop trust relationships with the principal actors and to reflect on the US management’s understanding of class, ethnicity, and gender. While reading the following papers, consider the following questions and issues. All of these readings are influenced by the political economy approach. In what sense do politics and “positionality” – the imprint of the researcher’s own class, eth- nicity, gender positions, and perspective – shape the research process and the accounts that are presented? Do the accounts simply “report on” the changing eco- nomic geographies of production or do they seek to remake our theoretical and 96 ADAM TICKELL, JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, AND ERIC SHEPPARD political understandings of these economic geographies? Has the production process become “de-centered” in contemporary economic geography, or is it that prevail- ing analytical treatments of this process have themselves changed? What is the evi- dence base for the papers? In particular, how do the authors draw upon empirical and theoretical evidence to construct their arguments? Would someone with a dif- ferent theoretical or political starting point arrive at different conclusions with similar evidence? Finally, and perhaps most challenging, can we distinguish between “real” changes in the economy and shifts in the ways we rationalize, visualize, and understand the economy, and if so how? Chapter 6 Is There a Service Economy? The Changing Capitalist Division of Labor

Richard A. Walker

Introduction The concepts “services” and “the service economy” have entered the language with little critical examination. The notion is widespread that the advanced economies have entered an era of “post-industrialism” and that the “services sector” has replaced manufacturing as the engine of economic growth (Bell, 1973). These views have begun to come under closer scrutiny (Stanback, 1979; Stanback et al., 1981; Stanback and Noyelle, 1982; Gershuny, 1976; Browning and Singelmann, 1975; Singelmann, 1978; Ginzberg and Vojta, 1981). Nonetheless, the lack of a system- atic framework of analysis continues to dog the field. Many disparate phenomena are haphazardly loaded onto a single overburdened concept, “services.” Stanback and his colleagues refer to this as “the misconception of homogeneity” (Stanback et al., 1981, p. 2; Singelmann, 1978, p. 24). Marx would have called it a “chaotic conception” (Sayer, 1982a). Our task is to sort out the various aspects of the “service economy” with the help of the Marxian theory of capital. The service thesis is, first of all, a theory of output. Our analysis must therefore begin with the distinction between services and “goods” as products of labor. The crudest version of the conventional wisdom takes personal consumption, or “con- sumer services,” as its starting point, and argues that consumer tastes now favor services over goods (Fuchs, 1968). More recent approaches focus on “producer ser- vices” (Stanback et al., 1981; Stanback and Noyelle, 1982). This still rests on a con- ception of services as a product – consumed by businesses instead of individuals. Stanback et al. realize, however, that one must not only talk about “what we produce” but “how we produce.” We must, therefore, address the problem of production. To speak of production is to take up the question of labor. The distinction between goods and services turns on the form of labor involved in their production. But this is not enough. One must deal with complex production systems, or what Marx called “the collective laborer.” What is needed is a way of handling the division of labor in the modern capitalist economy. Part of this paper is an attempt to dissect the division of labor, focusing 98 RICHARD A. WALKER on the concrete labor involved in the production and circulation of use-values. It requires a far more complex vocabulary than the impoverished categories of neo- classical economics. The service thesis is also a theory of economic development. In conventional ter- minology, there has been a shift over time from primary (extractive) to secondary (manufacturing) to tertiary (service) activities (Clark, 1940; Fisher, 1952) or a transformation from an industrial to a post-industrial economy (Bell, 1973). This thesis has two aspects: services have replaced goods as the principal output of the economy and service jobs have replaced industrial jobs as the principal occupation of workers. Gershuny (1976) has done yeoman work in distinguishing the two inter- pretations, salvaging the first, and directing attention to the changing occupational structure. Nonetheless, he proves unable to break decisively with conventional discourse. The stalemate arises because the debate never leaves the realm of concrete labor and forms of labor. The issue is not one of outputs versus occupations, but of two kinds of “output” from the actions of labor, use-value and (surplus) value. Gershuny points to the contribution of some occupations to the productivity of others. We must therefore consider the kinds of productive labor, in terms of value and surplus value. This is essential to the Marxist case for continuity in the capi- talist character of production and the logic of capital behind economic development and the changing division of labor. But it forces us to reconsider the question of productive and unproductive labor, for which purpose I develop the notion of indi- rectly productive labor. The notion of post-industrialism also carries a sociological and political message: capitalism has been replaced by post-industrial society. Social revolution is unnec- essary because it has already happened. This proposition is not logically distinct from the theory of the post-industrial economy in conventional thinking, which does not distinguish between forces of production (industrialism) and relations of pro- duction (capitalism), nor between class relations and the division of labor (Walker, 1984). The argument that runs throughout this paper is that recent changes in the division of labor can be comprehended within a theory of capitalist development. The products, activities, and types of labor may change over time, but the purpose of labor under capitalism remains the same: the generation and accumulation of surplus value.

What Is a Service? Use-Values and Useful Labor in a Complex Division of Labor The conventional view sees services everywhere. Apparently, the old-fashioned “good,” along with its world of factories, is passing from the scene. In its place has come the “service,” a term that implies personalized labor, immateriality, informa- tion, and greater human satisfaction, and fundamentally different modes of pro- duction, movement, and organization than in the industrial age. These presumptions do not hold up to a careful dissection of the forms of useful labor in the modern capitalist economy. The term “services” begs all significant questions about what is done in banks, repair shops, or hotels. Few of these putative “services” are either new or indecipherable in the language of industrialism. This part of the paper is IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY?99 therefore an exercise in disaggregation and analysis of concrete activities, or tasks of labor, in an economy still based on the production, exchange, and consumption of useful products, mostly in the form of commodities and chiefly in the shape of goods.

The product and simple labor The category “services” is conventionally defined in contrast to goods. Since all goods render a service of some kind, the crux of the distinction must rest with pro- duction, not consumption. We therefore begin with the simplest terms regarding concrete labor and its products, or use-values. The distinction between goods and services lies in the form of labor and its product. A good is a material object produced by human labor for human use. In its simplest form, it is tangible, discrete, and mobile. A labor service, on the other hand, is labor that does not take the intervening form of a material product, such as a play or a lecture. It is thus normally irreproducible by other workers and involves a unique transaction between producer and consumer. This is not an altogether simple distinction. The crux of the matter is the socio- technical nature of how to produce a desired result, and the consequent ease with which a discrete line can be drawn around the production process and its product. A halfway case is the haircut, which is a tangible product of labor – if it were a toupee it would unquestionably be a good – but adheres to the wearer, making it personal, unique, and irreproducible. Much confusion is caused by production that joins goods and labor services. Restaurants and other food outlets, for example, are ordinarily considered part of the service sector. Yet the meal is a good produced in the kitchen (notwithstanding some uniqueness in each dish). Waiting table is, however, a separate act of labor, which is often part of the pleasure of dining out. It is a labor service. The restau- rant produces a joint product. This is not the case at McDonald’s, where the service has been eliminated in the interest of mass production. It is absurd to include fast food outlets in the service economy when they mark the triumph of industrial food preparation. A good deal of confusion has arisen over the changing physical nature of goods, leading some observers to see services where none exist. This derives in part from increasingly sophisticated manipulations of nature involved in modern production, particularly via electronics. Many people have an antiquated notion of goods derived from the mechanical age. They fail to see that a computer program, which takes the form of electrons on a tape or disk, is every bit as much a material good as a chair. It was produced by labor, it has a continuing existence, and it performs a useful function. It has a discrete and tangible form, unlike a true labor service. The real distinction here is between tactile and non-tactile goods, or things that are easily seen and grasped, and those that are not. It may be argued that the informational aspect of goods is rising over time, and that it is wrong to emphasize the paper content over the informational content of a written document. My argument is that one should not confuse the use-value (information content) and the materiality of physical objects and, in the process, leap over the tangible acts of labor involved in their production. 100 RICHARD A. WALKER

Production and the division of labor Division of labor refers to the differentiation and specialization of labor within complex production processes and diversified production systems. Service theorists have carved the economy into boxes labeled “goods sectors” and “service sectors” in isolation, rather than as parts of an integrated economy. Too much can be made of the explosion in “producer services.” It has long been understood that some commodities serve as means of production for others within complex production processes (Marx, 1967). These are called “intermediate inputs,” and may be either goods or labor services. The growth of producer ser- vices says nothing about the nature of final output. The term “producer services” implies that all such inputs are labor services when in fact many are goods. But even if there are labor services, they are likely to be intermediate inputs in the produc- tion of goods, e.g., engineering consultants hired to help design a factory. The expan- sion of producer services does not indicate a growth in service outputs; only that the social division of labor in the production of all products is steadily expanding. It replicates the stage in 19th century industrialization when capital goods produc- tion spun off from consumer goods in separate firms and industries (Marx, 1967). This expansion cuts both ways. All goods production requires some labor service inputs and all labor services are produced with the use of goods (Gershuny, 1976). Thus an expansion of “health services,” for example, requires more pills and x-ray machines, and is, therefore, by no means a triumph of services over manufacturing. The question whether goods or services production predominates leads to a lengthy regress through the input–output matrix of the economy. This task is further clouded by the shifting lines of the social and detail divisions of labor, to which we now turn. The division of labor is a badly muddled category (Walker, 1984). The social division of labor traditionally means work in different product sectors, e.g., the tin- smith versus the shoemaker. The detail division of labor, on the other hand, refers to the specialization of tasks within the workshop, e.g., between the pattern cutter and sewer in shoe production. The detail division of labor has particularly been associated with the process of breaking production down to discrete steps, either sequential or simultaneous (followed by assembly of parts) (Marx, 1967). The classic distinction between the two divisions of labor runs into difficulties with intermediate inputs. When is steel-making an industry and when is it a part of automobile manufacture, as it was at Ford’s River Rouge plant? The distinction breaks down altogether where single production systems are divided into several smaller factories, as has become more common. We need to redefine the social divi- sion of labor in terms of the separation of work groups, normally having a spatial component as work places, and confine the term detail division of labor to the task specialization within work groups (Walker and Storper, 1983).

Circulation The focus has thus far been on the production of use-values. We have said nothing about circulation: the transfer and movement of goods, labor services, money and information between producers and consumers and among units of the social divi- IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY? 101 sion of labor. Along the way we introduce the notion of value, or abstract labor, because certain kinds of concrete labor are applied to the circulation of value. A commodity is any product of labor sold on the market in exchange for money. Commodities can be either goods or labor services. Commodities are both useful products and embodiments of value, a measure of the abstract (socially necessary) labor time involved in their production. Circulation therefore encompasses flows of value as well as of use-values. Not all goods and labor services circulate as commodities. Markets are not the only mode, or institution, of exchange. This has caused no end of confusion for service theorists, who often confuse the distinction between goods and labor ser- vices with that between commodities and non-commodities. There are both market and non-market forms of organizing and integrating the division of labor. Because we take “the market” as a fact of life, we are led to the false conclusion that any other mode of economic integration is an aberration or a complete break with the past. Markets are socially constructed institutions, built up over centuries (Braudel, 1982). In this century market exchange has been increasingly augmented by the cor- porate form of business organization. Massive amounts of goods and labor services are transferred within firms, without any price formation, change in property rights, or exchange of money. Whether a company supplies itself via the market or non- market route is strategic for cost and risk, but is often rather arbitrary. The growth of corporate organization is quite separate from the question of the type of output, good or labor service. The mode of exchange does not affect the form of the product. Corporate organization of the division of labor does not, in my view, annul the law of value, given that the dominant mode of exchange remains the market and large corporations actually replicate the market internally, seeking not to overthrow but to perfect the rules of equalization of (socially necessary) labor time and profit rates among productive activities (Harvey, 1982). Value production and circulation remain the order of the day under internal (non-commodity) as well as external (commodity) exchange. Corporations have as their principal goal organizing indus- trial production and circulation, not overthrowing it. Retail and wholesale trade are ordinarily counted among the service sectors. Yet most trade involves goods. Trade activities have grown large wherever commodity exchange has developed, and long before the industrial revolution (Braudel, 1982). Wholesaling dominated the early US economy (Porter and Livesay, 1971; Vance, 1970). Retailing had its greatest growth in the early 20th century, with the spread of mass consumption (Stanback et al., 1981). Today their size is chiefly a measure of industrial productivity, plus the mass of goods in circulation and the competitive sales effort among firms. The confusion of trade with “services” arises because retail sales often do involve additional labor services, beyond merely handing over the product. The salesperson may provide the buyer with information, instruction, or a package of goods and labor services – as in the case of the holiday tour prepared by a travel agent (Stanback et al., 1981). But in so far as the sales labor merely transfers the product from one owner to another, facilitating exchange, or promotes the product, as in advertising, nothing has been added to the product or its useful- ness – no production has taken place. Such labor is wholly that of circulation, a 102 RICHARD A. WALKER category apart. Production and the form of the product, good or labor service, is not the issue. Financial “services,” or the circulation of money, are always included among the litany of the service economy. Yet finance is an integral part of the goods- producing, or industrial, system. The development of a money system is part of the construction of the institutions of market exchange. Money serves as the medium of commodity exchange and the measure of exchange value. It everywhere ante- dates capitalism in this role. It also serves as the store of (labor) value accrued through commodity production, which gives the bearer command over a portion of the social product. Finally, it functions as capital to be invested in profit-making activities (Marx, 1967; Harvey, 1982; Braudel, 1982). In short, the bulk of economic information in circulation parallels the stocks and flows of materials, commodities, money, and capital, and is a basic fiber of market and organizational networks. Of course, information is not just raw data, “mere” reflection of “real” movements; it is also analytic knowledge about the functioning of the economy. In that sense, information production and circulation may grow faster than national product. Nonetheless, in the first instance, the vast bulk of information pertains to the industrial economy itself, and does not form a self- generative “informational economy.” The circulation of information, like that of money, was vital to the merchant of long ago (Braudel, 1982). Improved systems of communications were at the heart of the industrial revolution and the development of the US (Pred, 1973, 1980). AT&T was the largest industrial corporation for much of this century. In short, the information economy is nothing new.

Consumption Consumption has been a silent partner to the discussion of production and exchange. It merits further comment as to its purposes and modes. Some service theorists believe that as people grow more affluent they tend to satisfy their needs through personal labor services, rather than goods (Bell, 1973). There is no evidence for a trend in this direction. On the contrary, consumer services appear to have declined since a peak earlier in this century (Gershuny, 1976; Stanback et al., 1981). Indeed, the 19th century was a golden age of domestic and personal service, while the 20th century has been characterized by the mass consumption of goods (Gershuny, 1976). The principal objects of mass consumption have been houses, cars and appliances, and their accessories. The chief occupational effect of this con- sumption pattern has been an increase in sales labor, repair labor, and consumer finance. As Gershuny has pointed out, goods and labor services may be substitutes in the satisfaction of a given need (Gershuny, 1976). One may take concerts or records, a vacuum cleaner or a maid, a French laundry or a home washer and drier, a trip to the doctor or a pill; the results are largely the same, though never precisely so. There are strong reasons of cost for mass-produced goods to replace labor services over time. Yet new needs which can only be satisfied by labor services appear to take their place. The long-run tendency, if any, is difficult to discern. IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY? 103

The growth of “consumer services” is infused with great significance by service theorists, as indicative of the development of human potential. They draw their inspiration from the notion of “a hierarchy of needs,” up which people move as they grow more affluent (Ley, 1980; Bell, 1973; Stanback et al., 1981). This theory has no historical or anthropological foundations, other than the trivial notion that as people gain more income they cut back on potatoes and eat more steak. Human needs and the capacity to fulfill them develop in dialectical fashion. There is not a preexisting list of wants to which one turns as one’s income goes up. The materi- ally impoverished do not simply fulfill basic needs while the rich attend to all the finer aspirations of humanity. This trivializes human culture and elevates the activ- ities of the wealthy, who are by no means necessarily in the vanguard of civiliza- tion (Lebowitz, 1977–8; Walker and Greenberg, 1982). The growth of consumer products, both goods and labor services, is in part due to the replacement of household labor by commodities purchased in the market. Historically, this transfer from non-capitalist to capitalist production has been a fun- damental source of expansion of the home market (Tryon, 1917). The process still goes on with a vengeance, as demonstrated by the growth of fast food outlets. To some extent, no new needs are satisfied; they are just met from a new quarter. Of course, capitalist penetration also ordinarily means the creation of new needs and new products to meet them (Lebowitz, 1977–8). In either case, the expansion of consumer industries in this century is a sign of the triumph of capitalist industrialism.

Organization and management Conventional service theory commonly includes management among “services,” in the form of managerial occupations, headquarters activities, or independent “busi- ness services.” Because the result of managerial labor is not a “good,” it is assumed, by default, to be a “service” to production. But management stands as a category apart in the social division of labor, reducible to the labor of production and cir- culation it organizes and commands. As such it cuts across all the types of labor considered up to now. Every workplace requires some coordination, oversight and trouble-shooting, whether the product is a symphony or an organic solvent. As the scale and com- plexity of the labor process increases, an element of technical competence enters into these tasks as well. The labor of “management” may be considered a univer- sal feature of all large-scale and complex production of use-values (Marx, 1967). Its existence bears no relation to the kind of product, good or labor service. In the modern capitalist economy, work units of diverse kinds are linked to one another by means of corporations as well as by the market. This, too, requires labor of coordination. Corporate management has as its purpose, among other things, reducing the cost and time of circulation, coordinating far-flung production processes, and linking pre- and post-production labor inputs for more effective product development and sale (Chandler, 1977). Corporate administration has grown rapidly with the concentration of capital. Nonetheless, this type of labor is not new (see Chandler, 1977; Porter and Livesay, 1971; Pred, 1980; Braudel, 1982). 104 RICHARD A. WALKER

Most “business services” are an extension of the division of labor within management. As management has grown, it has commonly become lodged in sepa- rate workplaces, known as headquarters. Within these headquarters there are various divisions of management labor, such as the legal unit or accounting unit. Specialized management inputs may also be provided through the market, from outside firms. The growth in “business services” is chiefly due to the emergence as separate industries of work formerly carried on within large corporations (Fuchs, 1968). This phenomenon seems to raise a contradiction: while management is not itself production, it may utilize inputs that take a simple product/commodity form. There is nothing wonderful in this, however; it parallels the situation in which a consumer service, e.g., medical care, is produced using goods as inputs. Many business services take the form of labor services, but some are provided in the form of goods, such as computer software. In either case, the information content is likely to be high, but this does not alter the form of the product, the mode of circulation, or the managerial purpose of the labor input. As the scale of man- agement operations increases, the provision of managerial inputs can itself become a kind of industrial production, carried out in “back offices” by armies of clerical workers. So far we have viewed management purely from the point of view of organizing the production and circulation of use-values. Capitalist management encompasses another dimension however: the generation and accumulation of surplus value. The foundation of surplus value production is class power, exploitation and labor control; this function of management permeates all the others previously con- sidered (Braverman, 1974; Edwards, 1979; Marx, 1967; Walker and Storper, 1983). Similarly, the economic calculus of profit is everywhere on the mind of managers. Labor is, indeed, in the service of capital. But this does not make for a service economy.

Development and Productive Labor: The Dynamics of a Changing Division of Labor The discussion so far has been a static classification of the parts of a modern cap- italist economy. It will not do, however, to rest on the ahistorical conclusion that industrialism still reigns (and therefore always will), without addressing the legiti- mate issues of change raised by the service theorists. What is now needed is an assessment of capitalist development that recognizes the growth of new types and products of labor. This requires a shift in emphasis from the activities of concrete labor (the production and circulation of use-values) to the efforts of abstract labor (the production of surplus value). We have considered only the usefulness of various types of labor, not their productiveness in terms of value and surplus value. To ask why the division of labor has changed, we must focus on the capitalist logic of surplus value extraction and accumulation. Marxian value theory must be supple enough to allow for the reallocation of productive labor. It must defend the posi- tion that the relations of production, epitomized in the production and accumula- tion of surplus value, promote the development of the productive forces, rather than vice versa, and remain the heart of the industrial system. IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY? 105

The mass of surplus value: the edifice raised on productive labor At the outset we may say that capitalist industrialism has not been transcended, but simply extended, deepened and perfected. As has been shown, the great majority of “services” are the classic activities of a goods-producing, industrial economy. To a large degree, therefore, the “service economy” thesis is a fraud. While it is impor- tant to study innovation and change, one must not lose sight of an elemental con- stancy: the growth of so-called “service” activities rests on the productive power of the industrial system. Consumption levels have risen and products proliferated. With the mass production and consumption of goods has come the mass of labor engaged in distribution centers, retail outlets, elaborate sales efforts, and transportation. The value produced along with the goods circulates through a massive financial struc- ture, speeding exchanges, bridging time and space, leveraging capital accumulation. Specialized appendages have sprouted on this financial edifice, from leasing com- panies to secondary mortgage markets. Information about the economy swirls through communications channels created by that industry. Armies of managers rule over the system, paid out of the surplus of those they supervise; alongside them come the specialists in management inputs. In short, an enormous superstructure has been erected on the value and wealth generated by modern industry. The superstructure is often called the “service economy” and invoked as a self-generating force, but it would collapse without its industrial foundation. The image of base and superstructure raises the old question of productive and unproductive labor. This simple distinction has been badly mauled by years of mis- guided debate. Marx was merely taking a first cut at the distinction between pro- duction and circulation labor, in which he wished to maintain consistency with the basic premise of his theory of surplus value: that value must be produced by someone before it can be appropriated by someone else, i.e., it involves class exploitation. In other words, contrary to appearances and bourgeois ideology, money does not breed more money without production and “mere” exchange of commodities does not create value (this is nicely put by Bradby, 1982). Nor, as is commonly held in our own time, does management create its own profits, infor- mation give birth to new value, or science create anything without people and prac- tical knowledge being put to work to create new use-values. But the orthodox Marxist view can be equally unsatisfactory when it restricts all productive labor to basic acts of hacking, bending, bolting and hewing, and the like. The problem, then, is how to mesh the distinction between productive and unproductive labor in the value sense with the many varieties of useful labor previously discussed. The answer lies, I believe, in a structural approach. That is, value relations operate beneath the level of relations of useful labor. They capture certain essential features of the capitalist system, especially the necessity of employing wage-labor to produce value and surplus value somewhere in the economy. But we would not expect to read off tidy distinctions between productive and unproductive labor from everyday occupational categories, any more than we may read off values from everyday prices (Dominic, 1983–4). Therefore, any attempt to carve up a complex, dialectical, and structured division of labor into neat boxes of productive and unpro- ductive labor is bound to be futile. 106 RICHARD A. WALKER

Thus the simple view of base and superstructure, while a proper antidote to the inverted pyramids of the service thesis, only goes part way toward a correct view of the situation. We need to take a second look at the productive–unproductive labor relation, one which teases out the sources of productivity of the industrial base, many of which lie in the “superstructure” itself. This will not be a fully struc- tural analysis, but a first approach to it which at least recognizes the broad spec- trum of productive activities and the shadings across this spectrum from the most directly productive to the most indirectly productive labor.

The rate of surplus value and capital accumulation: the contribution of indirect labor to overall productivity Capitalist industrialization has been synonymous with raising the productivity of labor, or increasing relative surplus value and lowering the cost and time of circu- lation. Together these increase the rate of capital accumulation (Marx, 1967; Harvey, 1982). In the press to increase labor productivity and to speed capital accu- mulation, the emphasis has shifted from direct to indirect labor. As a result, the “hands-on” work of goods production has diminished as a percent of total social labor. This may well indicate a revolution in the organization of production as pro- found as the 19th century shift from workshop manufacture to factory “machino- facture,” or at least as great as that from mechanical to electro-mechanical techniques within the factory in the early 20th century. It is, in any event, the crux of the “service economy” phenomenon. Primary labor is work expended directly on a product, whether good or labor service. It is “hands-on” labor. The range of direct labor is wider than is often sup- posed, however, once the complexities of production in space and time are intro- duced. Secondary labor embraces those jobs that are a step away from direct labor, the shop floor or the immediate site of primary labor. Two general types may be dis- cerned. The first consists of certain tasks within the immediate workplace; these may be labeled auxiliary labor. Such workers do not themselves process, transfer or assemble materials, but their efforts cut down on labor time expended by direct laborers, improve general coordination and intensity, and monitor production data. Another group of secondary workers, preparatory labor, opens the way for primary labor. In short, secondary labor releases primary labor from extra tasks, makes pro- duction go more smoothly and makes it competitive (conforming to the dictates of socially necessary labor time). The category of secondary labor begins to capture the way in which the division of labor contributes to the productivity of primary workers. Under the heading of tertiary labor are included many types of labor not ordi- narily considered productive (of value): trade, management, advertising, banking, leasing, some transport and communication, insurance, etc. These all stand at some distance from direct production, but contribute to the overall integration and coor- dination of a complex production system, the rate of capital accumulation, and the long-term productivity of the economy. Most of these activities are circulation labor. The common position that this is “unproductive labor” takes a narrow view of circulation as completion of simple IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY? 107 exchanges, a mere property transfer. No new use-value is created, no value added; all that is involved is “realization” of existing value in the form of money. This misses the role of circulation in an ongoing process of production and development of the forces of production. The labor of circulation is an important lever of capi- talist growth (Harvey, 1975b). First, better commodity flows contribute to labor productivity by linking together workplaces, expanding markets, and lowering costs, thereby augmenting the field in which primary, secondary, and complementary labor operate. The same may be said of the flows of money and information that parallel the movement of products. But here we refer only to the simple rate of surplus value. Second, better circula- tion of capital, in terms of fuller realization of value (sales), more rapid turnover, and lower costs of circulation, accelerates the accumulation process. That, in turn, contributes to the successive development of the forces of production by generating larger masses of investible funds, a more rapid rate of investment in new technolo- gies, more funds for R&D, marketing and organizational growth, etc. That is, one must treat the growth of labor productivity and of the rate of surplus value over time. Knowledge production and worker reproduction are the hardest categories to handle: their functional links to capitalist production and circulation were empha- sized above. From that perspective, they contribute, from a considerable distance, to the productivity of direct labor. Science and other forms of inquiry contribute to the store of useful knowledge adopted by firms and learned by workers. Education prepares the worker for learning tasks and solving problems. Medical care keeps the worker working. They are all, therefore, preconditions for ordinary labor of all kinds, and add in obvious ways to the growth of labor productivity over time. Each of the above types of indirect labor is subject to further division in order to raise its productivity. The phenomenon of indirect labor should be clear without spinning out the web any further, however. Finally, not every contribution to productivity can be captured within the tidy confines of the preceding categories. The whole is greater than the sum of the parts. The development of social labor stimulates the productivity of all the collective human enterprise in unpredictable ways. Some of this rubs off on economic pro- duction in the narrow sense and benefits capital.

Use-values and surplus value: shifts in the objects of labor We have thus far drawn a static picture of the material products of labor, and their use-values. We must now consider the relation between indirect labor, or the shift- ing base of labor productivity, and product innovation, or the shifting base of com- modity production. The production of surplus value requires only that labor be applied to useful products, regardless of their nature. Since product innovation is a fundamental means of gaining competitive advantage and making profit, one should expect capitalists continually to introduce new and unfamiliar goods and labor services. The industrial revolution transformed the kinds of material inputs handed down from agrarian/handicraft production. That process has continued in this century as wood has given way to fiberglass in boat hulls, steel to concrete in bridges, and 108 RICHARD A. WALKER copper to plastic in piping. Industrialization has also transformed the kinds of use- values being produced. What I wish to emphasize here is how industrialism creates new needs out of its own development, i.e., serves as its own stimulus to product innovation. Consider again the shift from agriculture to industry – the historical parallel always drawn upon by the service theorists. The agrarian economy was at one time the principal market for manufactured goods, but the industrial economy soon stood on its own feet, becoming its own biggest market (Lindstrom, 1978; Pred, 1966). Today the realm of indirect labor may be the principal locus of indus- trialism, to which most product development (including means of production) is directed. For example, as US Steel Corporation grows it demands computers for the management of its accounts; computers, in turn, generate demand for microchips, plastic, cathode tubes, etc. – not steel. Similarly, banks generate an enormous demand for money handling, telecommunications and data processing equipment to carry out their financial functions (Hamelink, 1983). Doesn’t this mean a shift from manufacturing to some sort of “service” or “ter- tiary” economy? The content of output is certainly changing, in three ways. The users of products are increasingly those engaged in indirect labor. The use-value of products increasingly emphasizes “information.” And the materials involved in the products have shifted toward such “insubstantial” things as paper and printing, electrical impulses and disk drives. None of these changes is incommensurate with an industrial (manufacturing-based) economy, however. Furthermore – and this is the point usually missed – the labor involved increas- ingly takes a commodity form, and goods are substituted for labor services as fast as the latter can appear in new realms of production (Gershuny, 1976). In other words, segments of the “superstructure” continually enter directly into, or generate demands for commodities that are part of the industrial “base.” The net effect is a change in the material and use-value content of industrial commodities, but the use of labor to produce marketable products (chiefly goods) and surplus value contin- ues as before. There is nothing sacred about an industrial base of steel and cement used to produce cars and dams. They may go the way of flax and disappear almost completely, or the way of wheat, which while essential and produced in large volume, occupies only a small fraction of the modern labor force. Industry may con- centrate increasingly on microprocessors and optical fibers for the use of commu- nications and management. But because of the continual replenishment of the base with new products, there is no discernible tendency for commodity production, or even goods production, as a whole, to fade away.

Conclusion The preceding critique has gone in two directions, both aimed at demolishing the flimsy analytics of conventional service theory. Our first line of attack was to show how much of the purported “new economy” of services could be understood in the classic terms of capitalist industrialism. It argued for the considerable degree of con- stancy in the basic framework of the economy, even if certain branches of labor have swollen in size in a more productive, more complex, more geographically dis- persed, more integrated industrial system. It also repeatedly noted the historical roots of current activities, so as to correct the tendency to confuse the contempo- IS THERE A SERVICE ECONOMY? 109 rary with the new. A lot of people in the US have been doing something besides basic production for a long time. In fact, employment in manufacturing in the US has never been higher than 27% of the workforce. The United States has long been a “service-intensive” economy relative to other developed capitalist nations (Singelmann, 1978). On the other hand, there has been continuous upheaval in the shape of indus- trial capitalism, which I have no wish to deny. The second line of argument there- fore spoke to forces for change. That, too, is no surprise given the history of capitalism. We should be prepared for an industrial world that is persistently dis- orienting. This is the same advice that one would have given our grandparents, but is forever forgotten by generations who consider themselves the embodiment of the modern. Capital is ordinarily far bolder and accepting of the new than most intel- lectuals. It cares only that people labor to create surplus value; their concrete tasks and products are simply a means to this end. The revolutionary force of capital has generated dramatic shifts in the division of labor in society. It is this, more than any change in the products or the form of the products, that is at issue in the debate over the “service economy.” The locus of competitive advantage – and of capital accumulation in general – has shifted over the last century from simple productive efficiency among direct laborers to the realm of indirect labor, which augments the productivity of social labor and speeds the accumulation of capital. In the process, the “indirect” economy has increasingly become the focus of production, feeding on itself as an engine of growth. In order to grasp these seemingly contradictory conclusions, we require a supple mode of thinking, capable of seeing change and stasis simultaneously. There is a structural consistency about the last two centuries that is captured by the concept of capitalism as a mode of production. It rests on private property, the extraction of surplus value from workers who sell their labor-power, and the production and circulation of commodities bearing the stamp of value. It remains an industrial capi- talist system, as well, in which such characteristic features of production as the tan- gible “good,” mechanization, and the factory system predominate. It has also long been a corporate-finance capitalist system. While these “constants” do, in fact, change through a continual process of restructuring, they nonetheless remain rec- ognizable beneath the flux of everyday life in a way that specific commodities and jobs do not. There may be good reason to add yet another adjective to contempo- rary capitalism, such as “informational,” “electronic,” “global,” or “indirectly pro- ductive.” But the case must be made on solid grounds that do not blithely dismiss essential relations and the deep insights of Marxist theory. The concept and theory of “services” are so badly misconceived as to merit rejection in further analytic work. As for the political debate over the social implications of economic change and the potential for human liberation, that, too, remains open – and little aided by the contribution of the “post-industrial” theorists. The growing technical prowess, changing division of labor, and developing human potential of capitalist civilization do create historic possibilities for social change (Block and Hirschborn, 1979). The 20th century revolutionary project is not that of the 19th century, just because wage-labor and factory production can be found in both. The dreams of the post- industrial theorists have some basis in reality. But an idyllic future will not be served 110 RICHARD A. WALKER to us, as consumers of history, on a silver platter. If there is to be a new age of enlightenment, classlessness, and human service, it will not be born without strug- gle. And we must all be sobered by the barbaric prospects posed by certain of the weapons, politics, and ideas of capitalist civilization. One sees less liberal optimism about the human prospect in the age of Reagan than when Daniel Bell wrote The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. Alas it is not at all clear that civilization can be much further advanced – or even salvaged – as long as it remains tethered to the short leash of capital and its narrow, exploitive motives. Chapter 7 Uneven Development: Social Change and Spatial Divisions of Labor

Doreen Massey

Uneven Development The concept of uneven development, if it is to have any purchase on the structure and dynamics of economy and society more widely, must refer to more than the fact that there are more jobs in some places than others, or even that there are better jobs in some places than others. Such measures are interesting, and they are impor- tant, but they do not in themselves link that inequality to its causes in the deeper structures of the organization of society. In order to do this, uneven development must be conceptualized in terms of the basic building-blocks of (in this case, capi- talist) society. In this paper those are taken to be classes, and the focus will be quite narrowly on the relations within the economy, as these are assumed to be the primary foundation of class structure. The term “relations” is important, and is actually much more appropriate than “building-blocks.” For the classes are not structured as blocks which exist as dis- crete entities in society, but are precisely constituted in relation to each other. Capi- talist is defined in relation to worker, and vice versa. Different classes in society are defined in relation to each other and, in economic terms, to the overall division of labor. It is the overall structure of those sets of relationships which defines the struc- ture of the economic aspect of society. One important element which any concept of uneven development must relate to, therefore, is the spatial structuring of those relationships – the relations of production – which are unequal relationships and which imply positions of dominance and subordination. It is on this that the paper will focus. The notion of groups/classes being mutually defined by the relationships between them goes beyond the obvious case of capitalist and worker. It is not possible to have work which is predominantly “mental” or “intellectual” (in spite of the fre- quently applied epithet of “knowledge-based society”) without manual work. It is not possible to have supervisory work without there being activity to supervise. It is not possible to have assembly without the manufacture of components. Thus, the different functions in an economy are held together by mutual definition and mutual 112 DOREEN MASSEY necessity. They are the basis of the (economic) division of labor in society and of the unequal relations of wealth and power. Those unequal class relations do not, as the saying goes, exist on the head of a pin. They are organized spatially. And it is contended here that this spatial organization must be an important element in any exploration of the nature of uneven development. One way of approaching this is through the conceptualization of the spatial struc- turing of the organization of the relations of production. Some spatial structures of the relations of production involve the geographical separation, within one firm, of headquarters and branch plant. Although the precise form will vary (branch plants can, for instance, have varying degrees of autonomy), what is at issue here is the stretching out over space of the relations of economic ownership and of possession (the functions of control over investment, of administration and coordination, and of the hierarchy of supervisory control over labor). Such “managerial hierarchies” have become longer and more complex with the development of capitalist produc- tion, and indeed with its increasing geographical spread. Or, again, a spatial struc- ture might involve the geographical separation of the work of strategic conception from that of execution. A classic example here would be the separation of research and development from direct production. Or a production plant may be one in a series within the technical division of labor within a firm, each plant performing only one part of the overall production process. Here the relations between the plants will be planned within the firm rather than determined by the external market. Market relations are also conducted over space and these too may involve systems of unequal power relations, and of domination. Relations between small and large firms come to mind, but unequal power may also exist by virtue of other characteristics which structure the apparently equal relations of market exchange. Highly contrasting degrees of oligopolization between retailing (highly concen- trated) and the production of final consumption goods (often very fragmented between firms) in the UK has long meant the dominance by the former over the latter. Now, the potential variety of actual spatial structures is in principle infinite. Indeed, later sections of this chapter indicate that one of the characteristics of the current structural changes in the economy may well be the spawning of new types. But the point, at least here, is to stress the importance of analyzing the spatial order- ing of the relations of production. For these different dimensions (of internal cor- porate structures, of the relationships of economic ownership and possession, of the technical division of labor) are dimensions along which run relations of power and control, of dominance and subordination. They are also dimensions which develop in systematic ways with the evolution of capitalist society. So, interregional or inter-area relations, as they are so often called, are actually these relations of production stretched out between areas (at any scale of analysis from the very local to the international). To different degrees they are the relations of class power and control. These relations exist between functions within the overall division of labor. Regions or local areas may be specialized in the perfor- mance of a small number of functions and these in turn may be those to which attach power, and strategic control over the operation of the economy, or they may be those which are relatively powerless, subordinated. Most often, there will be a mixture. UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 113

But, further, the performance of particular functions within society is part of what defines groups within the class structure. One of the bases of the definition of classes and social strata is their place within the overall relations of production. The location of headquarters in one region/country/local area and of branch plants in another will be reflected in the social compositions of those places. So will the location of the functions of research and development as opposed to shop-floor manufacturing, or of financial functions as opposed to more direct production. Perhaps more importantly, and to return to the opening theme, to say that one area has all the high-status, white-collar jobs and another all the less well-paid, manual work, while important, is only to capture one element of the full meaning of uneven development. For that distribution of distinct occupational (and social) groups is itself one reflection of a perhaps more fundamental structuring of inequal- ity between those areas – that carried by the organization between them of the rela- tions of production (Massey, 1984). All this immediately has two further implications. First, if these divisions of labor which are stretched out over space (spatial structures) consist, as we have said they do, of mutually defining elements, then the functional (and social) characteristics of some areas define the functional (and social) characteristics of other areas. If one region has all the control functions, and only control functions (to give an extreme example), then other regions must have all the functions which are controlled, the subordinated functions. This clearly has political and policy implications. Second, it means that as far as the characteristics we are considering here are concerned, any local area (region/country) can only be understood when analyzed in relation to the functions in the wider division of labor which are performed within it, and in the context of its place within the wider system of relations of production. These characteristics of “a local area,” in other words, must be conceptualized in terms of the evolution of the wider structures of capitalist economy. There are, then, certain internal necessities to a spatial structure. The distinct elements within it are held together in a mutually defining tension. There are also likely implications: different spatial structures are likely to have different impacts on local areas. But it is also important to note what is not necessarily implied by a spatial structure. First, the fact that a spatial structure of production implies a particular division into functions within the overall relations of production says nothing about which groups in society will actually perform those functions. That is determined by its own set of causal relations only contingently related (though, indeed, probably related) to the logic of the spatial structure. Second, a division into functions does not necessarily imply the social value which will be accorded to the performers of those functions, their precise social status or, for instance, their monetary reward. All this, again, is contingent although, also again, it is likely to be related to the definitions of the functions themselves and to the nature of the groups performing them. Third, and finally, a spatial structure in itself does not say anything necessarily about its actual geography, in the sense of the particular places in which its constituent parts will be located. Once again, however, and as we shall see in a later section, although there may not be necessity in the form of their interrelation, all the elements above may influence each other. 114 DOREEN MASSEY

Finally, the overlapping and interweaving of all these spatial structures is the basis for a spatial division of labor. In the mid-1960s a new spatial division of labor became dominant in the United Kingdom, in which control functions were concen- trated, even more than before, in London, scientific and technical functions were clustered in the southeast (with some outliers in other places), and direct produc- tion, while present throughout the country, was a higher proportion of economic activity in the regions outside of the south and east. That new spatial division of labor was the outcome of a whole series of changes affecting different parts of the economy in different ways. It was contributed to by shifts in the balance between sectors and the reorganization of, and development of new, spatial structures. It was the combination of spatial structures which produced a new spatial division of labor over the country as a whole. One question which the rest of this chapter will address is how much that scenario has changed in subsequent years.

New Directions That period of economic and spatial reorganization of which the full establishment of this new spatial division of labor was a part lasted from the mid-1960s to the mid-1970s. Its ending coincided with further shifts both in the economy as a whole (at national and international levels) and in the political climate (see Massey, 1984). It had been a period in which geographical reorganization, and national economic and regional policy, were dedicated to “modernization.” Moreover, it was a form of modernization which in turn could be interpreted as an attempt to prolong the life in Britain of what has been called Fordist production, broadly defined, and the social relations which went with it. The old, basic industries, such as coal and shipbuilding were “rationalized,” resulting in major job losses and the creation of additional labor reserves in the “peripheral” regions. Older means-of-production industries in manufacturing saw capacity closure and technical change, resulting in employment declines, especially for male skilled and semi-skilled workers, in the conurbations and nineteenth- century industrial areas. New means-of-production industries, especially in elec- tronics, expanded employment. There was growth of R&D and technical occupations, particularly in the southeast, and also of assembly jobs, mainly for women, in all parts of the country, including some decentralization to “the north.” Consumer goods industries grew slowly but did expand, especially those owned by big capital, and continued their longer-established decentralization of employment, including in particular jobs for women, to peripheral regions. Among services it was the public sector which grew most. While employment in the central state exhib- ited the classic divide, with high-status jobs concentrated in the southeast (mainly London) and some decentralization of lower-status and less well-paid employment to the regions, local authority employment both professional and manual, and that in health and education, was geographically more evenly distributed in its growth. Finally, in private sector services, it was producer services which showed the fastest rate of employment growth overall. Once again, the higher-status professional and higher-technical jobs were concentrated in the southeast. The decentralization of manufacturing branch plants to the regions was in some sectors associated with technical change, and with an increasingly sharp technical UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 115 division of labor within production. In other sectors, such as clothing, the move north or west was much more simply a means of cutting labor costs in the face of growing competition in a reorganizing international division of labor. Services, too, began to decentralize, but again it was only the mass-production parts which left the southeast. As an attempt to use spatial reorganization to enable survival in a world where rules were changing, it failed. In those manufacturing sectors where competition was increasingly coming from the Third World, a move to the UK regions was insufficient. The dominant dynamics reshaping UK economy and geography since the mid- 1970s have been different. Not only has the wider economic context changed, so also has the political and ideological prism through which it has been viewed by the prevailing government. Many of the same processes have continued, but in a different tempo or in a different way, and the balance between the processes, and the way they have meshed together, have been distinct from in the earlier period. At a descriptive level, a number of important changes can be picked out. The decline in manufacturing employment, under way since 1966, sharpened dramati- cally during the recession of the early 1980s, though easing somewhat again thereafter. Geographically, the impact of this decline was highly differentiated, the bulk of the jobs being lost in the regions outside the southeast, southwest and East Anglia. In part because of the faster decline of manufacturing, the shift from manufacturing to service employment speeded up. But the nature of the growth in service jobs changed too: since the 1970s it has been overwhelmingly private sector services which have dominated employment growth. Not only is the geogra- phy of services as a whole different from that of manufacturing, but the geography of the two parts of the service sector is also highly contrasting. Since the late 1970s service-sector employment growth has been overwhelmingly in London and the southeast, as part and parcel of the emergence of London and its region as a world city. One process which certainly came to an end in the mid-1970s was the decen- tralization of manufacturing employment. The combination of investment, moder- nization through cutting labor costs, and geographical shift was abandoned in the face of accelerated decline. Whatever the effect of regional policy in the 1960s and early 1970s, it declined thereafter as the supply of potentially mobile investment dried up. Much of the decentralized employment has itself been subsequently lost. But if the process of decentralization from the south and east is no longer impor- tant, the regions of the north and west are still subject to the arrival of branch plants and to branch-plant status. Now, however, they arrive as part of a different process, more often coming directly from abroad. Most importantly of all, the medium of branch-plant status is shifting from manufacturing to service industries. While ser- vices as a whole continued their centralization in the southeast and southwest, the different constituent sectors behaved very differently. There were losses all round in public administration and defense, a continued growth with a (relatively) even dis- tribution across the country in miscellaneous services (which includes education and health), further concentration in distribution (in marginal decline) and professional and scientific services (marginal growth), and evidence of at least some regional decentralization in insurance, banking, finance, and business services. Finally, the 116 DOREEN MASSEY last years of the 1980s indicate some new changes on the horizon, in particular a pushing out of growth from its established bases to colonize new areas. There has been a rediscovery by certain service-sector industries, preceded by the property developers, of selected parts of the inner cities, and some reworking of the north–south divide as growth spreads into some of the more southern, and the more rural, areas of “the north.”

Spatial Structures What insight can be gained about these changing patterns by employing the concepts of spatial structure and spatial division of labor? At the level of occupational structure in the UK as a whole, the changes in direc- tion which took place around the late 1970s seem to have reinforced many of the broad shifts which were already under way. Managerial and professional strata have continued to expand as a proportion of the economically active population; skilled manual workers have continued to decline quite rapidly and semi-skilled and unskilled manual workers together declined more slowly. The geography of the social structure also continued to move broadly in the same direction as previously, although there are some incipient changes, such as the invasion of certain inner-city areas by higher-income groups. But, most obviously, managers, administrators, pro- fessionals, and technicians continued to concentrate in the south and east of the country. In very broad terms, then, the spatial division of labor looks very similar. However, the balance of spatial structures underlying that spatial division of labor has changed somewhat since the late 1970s. There are a number of ways in which this can be illustrated. First, as far as manufacturing is concerned, the regions of “the north” remain very largely dominated by branch-plant structures. Indeed that subordinate status was reinforced during the eighties. But in some ways the nature of the branch plants has changed: the spatial structure of which they are part is different. A higher pro- portion of them are responsible to ultimate headquarters outside the UK. Further, although many of these branch plants are clearly part of production, or part-process, hierarchies, dependent on inputs from other plants in the same firm but based else- where, the way those hierarchies work may be changing. If it is true that just- in-time systems, for instance, are being adopted by more companies, then these branch plants are less likely to be the classic “cathedrals in the desert” of the 1960s. Increasingly, they may demand that components suppliers locate in their vicinity (Oberhauser, 1987; Schoenberger, 1987). In other words, the “branch-plant status” of much northern manufacturing remains, yet there is some evidence of two ways in which it may be being trans- formed – and transformed because of a change in the type of spatial structure into which the branch plants are inserted. The plants are more subject to ultimate control from outside the UK (which may be conceived of as negative) yet they may have rather larger technological multiplier effects locally (usually assumed to be positive). It has to be said, however, that this possibility must be treated highly tentatively. UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 117

Almost all the – anyway fragmentary – evidence comes from the car industry (as it also did, of course, for Fordism). Secondly, and equally still only on the horizon in the late 1980s, is the related possibility that the vertically integrated corporations argued to have been key to the period of Fordism may become rather less important, while more vertically disintegrated, or quasi-integrated, structures may become more important (for example, Christopherson and Storper, 1986). There is, again, little systematic evi- dence yet of this in the UK, but there are developments which could be seen in this light such as the extemalization of certain functions from manufacturing. Thus new parts of the social division of labor, new sectors, are formed out of what were once parts of the technical division of labor within manufacturing-based cor- porations. What were once planned relations within firms are replaced by market relations between them. If these things are happening, then some aspects of the spatial structures which underlie the spatial division of labor within the UK are changing. One element of this is a shift in balance towards a sectoral division between north and south, with financial, technical, and professional service firms concentrated in the south, and away from domination of north by south through the part-process hierarchies of the technical division of labor. It is a shift in balance which would also result from the changing relative importance of different sectors in the economy, in particular the continuingly increasing importance of services in relation to manu- facturing, and the declining relative importance of electronics. We shall see later that the picture is actually much more complex than this; but consider the implications of the argument so far. Such a reemergence of an element of sectoral division between north and south would more than anything else be likely to fuel even further the self-feeding cycle of the growth in the southeast. The presence of control functions in London and the southeast is an important reason for the concentration of business services in the same region. It is HQ which deals with those relations. Moreover, the presence of business services is a further condi- tion for the establishment and growth of other firms, especially small ones where buying in such services is necessary. The presence of the City assures a greater avail- ability of venture capital in the southeast than in other regions (Mason, 1987). Even the higher house prices (a product of the concentration of growth, and of the higher incomes of these groups) mean it is easier to raise initial capital. Higher incomes generate further growth through generalized demand. And so on. It was already a virtuous circle which was further strengthened as financial and business services became the key growth sectors of the economy. In electronics, the tendency to cluster already operated both through firms wanting to be “in on the scene” in a technical sense and through their needing to have access to the main pool of highly qualified labor. With vertical disintegration or quasi-integration, however, there is evidence that the tendency for agglomeration of this upper-echelon type of activity may be increased precisely as a result of the increased importance of market relations and thus of the need to be “in on” the important social networks (Christopherson and Storper, 1986). To the extent that this scenario is correct, it has a further effect, for it reinforces a picture of increasing separation between the economies of the north and the south 118 DOREEN MASSEY of the country. North and south are locked in very different ways into international spatial structures and the international division of labor. On the one hand there is the metropolitan region of the southeast of England, with London as one of the three prime world cities at its heart. It has for centuries been true that the financial City of London looked more outward to the world economy than “homeward” to the UK economy. But it is more true today, and increasingly true of the economy of much of the southeast region (Leyshon and Thrift, 1997). The finance and service sectors which are based in the region, and which are a growing part of its economy, are increasingly internationalized. London and the southeast are the first and often only point of entry to the UK for the globalized business service sector (Daniels, 1988). The economy of London and parts of the southeast is in many ways more in competition with and linked to other international metropolitan regions and world cities than it is with the rest of the UK. In contrast, the factories of the north are linked into, and in competition with, similar factories in similar regions in Europe, and also to some extent the Third World. The foreign investment in the north links the region into the world network of branch plants of production, not global financial systems. And it is not just in terms of spatial structures and systems of competition that north and south are differently linked into the changing international division of labor. The same is true of labor markets. The elite strata of the south and east are increasingly part of international labor markets – indeed “a spell abroad” may be an expected part of the climb up the career ladder. And yet, of course, north and south are linked. One of those links, however, is much the same as the way in which the economy of London is linked to other parts of the world. It is the location of control. If the south is spawning its own economy relatively unconnected to the north, much of the economy of the north is still sub- ordinate to London. Moreover, there are also increasing signs of an expansion northwards of some of the newer and fast-growing service sectors in the south (Leyshon, Thrift, and Twommey, 1989). This tentative relative decentralization to the regions (or rather, to certain cities within them) can take a number of forms including, in a few sectors, indigenous growth. Important, however, has been the expansion into the regions of large firms based in the southeast, either through the establishment of branch plants or through the acquisition of local companies. So, it would seem that the new spatial division of labor which was established in the UK in the 1960s in very broad terms continues its dominance. Since the later 1970s, however, there have been some shifts in its constituent spatial struc- tures. As ever, the spatial structures generating a spatial division of labor will be a mixture (Massey, 1984) but since the late seventies that mixture may have changed somewhat in its balance and in its components. Correspondingly some of the effects within local regions may also have changed. If it is possible simply to summarize the evidence examined here, it indicates that the effects in the late eighties are more likely to produce polarization within local labor markets. Finally, there are the effects on relations between regions: the economies of London and the southeast increasingly integrated into the international spatial structures of financial and commercial services, the economies of the north bound into the very different global structures of manufacturing corporations. The south- east embarked on its own process of cumulative growth, the north still tied in, UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 119 though in ways which are perhaps increasingly complex, to structures of control based in London. It is the ability to grasp these wider relations, that tie local and regional economies in various and changing ways into the evolving structures of capitalist production – the ability to go beyond uneven development as a set of surface distributions – which is provided by an approach through the concept of spatial structures.

The Geography of Social Structures The concept of spatial structures thus provides a way in to the analysis of the eco- nomic relations between regions, the geography of the social relations of produc- tion which underlie any particular form of uneven development in capitalist societies. It also provides a basis for examining the geography of social structure, the geography of class. If class is understood to be importantly (though not solely) defined by place within the relations of production, then the geography of those relations and the places within them, which spatial structures illuminate, begins to define a geogra- phy of class. It is not a deterministic relation, but if class is in any way based in production, then this is a way in. We shall explore just one set of examples here. The fastest-growing occupational groups in the economically active population of the UK are those which fall under the headings managers, administrators, professionals, and technicians. We shall con- centrate here on the upper echelons of these groups. What they mainly represent, in descriptive social terms is a relatively high-income, high-status, and non-manual stratum within society. There is a continuing debate about its precise class defini- tion and character, which cannot be addressed here. The question here is what light can be shed on these groups, and on their geography, through an analysis of spatial structures of production. The first thing to be said is that in fact this broad grouping contains within it a mixture of different groups, each of which has its basis in distinct parts of the divi- sion of labor. Managers are distinct from technicians and specialist professional workers (Massey, 1984), public sector employees from those in the private sector. They belong in different parts of the division of labor. For that reason they also occupy different positions in spatial structures of pro- duction. And indeed they have different geographies. All are clustered into the south and east of the country, but managers are more specifically concentrated in London itself, with a very clear hierarchical ordering, the top echelons being in the capital, lower orders forming a larger proportion in the regions. What evidence there is indi- cates that scientific and technical strata are less focused on the metropolis and more spread through the less urban parts of the southeast region as a whole and its sur- roundings (Massey, 1984). These, then, are distinct geographies of different types of strategic control over British economy and society. Moreover, there have been changes in the balance between the different elements of this group and in their class character. The 1960s and the early 1970s were the era of “big is beautiful,” of public sector growth and of manufacturing. Lash and Urry (1987), indeed, argue that this was the period of formation of what they call the service class in the UK, and they stress the significance of its public sector base. 120 DOREEN MASSEY

It was, precisely, a product of Wilsonian modernization. Today, the emphasis is less on the construction of complex corporate managerial hierarchies, and more on “flexibility” and the promotion of the small firm. This in no way means that real control over society has been dissipated, still less democratized, but none the less the slackening growth of the purely managerial class may be a reflection of the change of emphasis. Similarly, the typical scientist of the 1960s worked in a big cor- porate R&D lab; the equivalent employee in the late 1980s would be more likely to work in a smaller firm, certainly a smaller unit, and to combine with their sci- entific and technical functions some elements of management and even of owner- ship. The class character of the scientific and technical strata appears to be changing, and with it the spatial structures of which they are part. No longer so often are employees buried in corporate structures and, although undoubtedly an elite, with their work subject to “proletarianization,” they are now increasingly combining the power which comes from their monopoly over technical knowledge with some of that which derives from ownership and control. The groups which have been growing fastest of all have been the wide range of private sector “professionals” associated with business, and especially financial services (Thrift, Leyshon, and Daniels, 1987). But what all these groups share, simply as a product of their posi- tion within the unequal division of labor within society, is participation in and pos- session of strategic levels of power and control over the economy as a whole. None of this, however, says anything necessarily about which groups in society fill these different elite positions within the various spatial structures. That is con- tingent to the division of labor itself; it is not necessarily implied by it. However, to take just one characteristic, even the most cursory of glances at the statistics demon- strates that these positions are filled overwhelmingly by men. The reasons vary, but in no case do they follow simply from class relations or the demands of capital. Cockburn (1985) argues that the design and development of the means of produc- tion has always been a peculiarly crucial and powerful function within class soci- eties and she documents the mechanisms by which it has always also been a part of the production system that men, as opposed to simply “capital,” have fought to dominate. She looked at three industries, and reported “the significance of the role we have found women playing in all three new technologies is simple: they are operators. They press the buttons or the keys . . . What women cannot be seen doing in any of these three kinds of workplaces is managing technology, developing its use or maintaining and servicing it” (p. 142, emphasis in original). Another characteristic of this group is the degree of autonomy which it has within the workplace, the degree of control over the labor process (Massey, 1984). But this too has implications. One of them is that people work extremely long hours. As Cockburn argues, “Family commitments must come second. Such work is clearly predicated on not having responsibility for childcare, indeed on having no one to look after, and ideally someone to look after you” (1985, p. 181). It is not inher- ent in the class structure or the technical division of labor that it should not be women who become technologists and have men at home doing the housework. It is, however, in fact men who are the technologists and that fact itself has an impact on the nature of the functions performed, and on how they are performed (Murgatroyd, 1985). UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 121

But if one contingent characteristic of these spatial structures (i.e., which social groups actually fill the variety of positions within them) has not changed much in recent decades, other characteristics have been modified. In particular, the relative privilege of these groups within UK society has considerably increased, in both income and status terms. There is, however, a further contingency to be structured into the discussion. For the actual geography of a spatial structure in terms of where the different elements in the division of labor will actually be located, is not given by the spatial structure itself. It is contingent, that is, dependent on a whole set of other causal systems not necessarily implied by the spatial structure itself. The location in the outer south- east of such a high proportion of these elite, white-collar strata, however, provides a fascinating example of the interaction of all the characteristics summarized above, and one in which spatial form and social form interweave and affect each other. In fact, there is a whole range of factors behind the growth of this area, including near- ness to London as a center of control and of international linkages, the presence of Heathrow and good communications generally, and initially for the electronics industry the concentration there of government defense and research establishments. There is also the fact that the structure of these activities at the moment means that, once established, an area is likely to grow through the tendency to clustering. But another element which consistently shows up in research as being important is that the area itself has status. The question then is, why? The development of the division of labor provides the possibility for these groups to be located separately from direct production. The high status which they have both striven for and been awarded perhaps inclines them to operationalize this possibility, to assert their separateness from the shop- floor and to locate in an area with cachet. But that does not explain why certain areas and not others should be seen in this way, nor indeed why separation from production should be seen as a status asset. The area must be “high amenity” because that is where these people who have choice (“highly-paid, highly-mobile”) choose to go. In fact, of course, such preferences are not innate; they have to be constructed. So what is the attraction of the outer southeast? There is much evidence to suggest that it is mainly about self-assertion and class. It has been argued, for instance, that location in such areas enables self-definition through association with the trappings of some vision of “the gentry” (Thrift, 1988). It is a means of asserting social arrival. Second, however, all this raises the question of whether the “urban–rural shift” was urban–rural at all. Rather, it seems to have been from industrial (meaning manu- facturing) to non-industrial. What really does seem to be at issue is distancing from manufacturing production and from the physical and social context that goes with it. The invasion of the Docklands by the private sector middle class is very differ- ent from the public sector gentrification of other parts of inner London in the 1960s and 1970s. It involves completely clearing the area or refashioning it. Third, however, the particular groups examined here must be set in a wider context. The southeast is home also to a broad range of other groups, which form part of the basis for the social character of the region, and which in turn forms part of the attraction of the region to the groups being analyzed. They range from employees 122 DOREEN MASSEY of the central state to workers in the whole gamut of cultural industries. And in particular they are there because of London, the capital city. But if spatial structures are geographical systems of mutually defining elements, as argued in the first section of this chapter, then this clustering of certain functions in the overall division of labor has other implications. Most obviously, the existence of clusters in particular functions necessitates the existence also of areas deprived of those functions – in this case, within the UK, the northern regions of the country. Indeed, the evidence is that the concentration of this group in the southeast, and their increased relative incomes, is a prime element in accounting for one of the more obvious descriptive indicators of the north–south divide – that of salaries. While the bottom 10 percent of incomes in the different regions of the country do not vary much, the variation in the top 10 percent of male non-manual earnings is considerable, with the income levels of this decile in the southeast being far higher than those in other regions (Massey, 1988). Further, the fact of this spatial cluster- ing itself has social effects. Most obviously, it has resulted in labor shortages for these groups in the southeast, thereby increasing salary levels still further. Yet at the same time those (far smaller numbers) in regions in the north who have the same skills either remain on lower income levels, or cannot find work and/or cannot afford to move south either to find work or to increase their salaries. In this way, the cumulative dynamics of the initial spatial concentration are reinforcing the income advantages of the already privileged in the south, and even producing geo- graphical inequalities within the group as separate northern and southern circuits develop, those in the former on lower incomes and unable to move in even should they want to, those in the latter in increasingly powerful positions in the labor market, moving increasingly rapidly from job to job, bargaining themselves up the income scale, and seeing their wealth grow still further as house prices continue to rise. We have then, changing divisions of labor, both technical and social, with a par- ticular social content and consequences, which have enabled – and apparently in some measure been the cause of – new spatial structures, the location of which in turn has further molded the social character of the constituent groups.

Uneven Redevelopment: Reproduction over Time The structures of uneven development are constantly evolving. While the mid-sixties saw the establishment of a new spatial division of labor, the years since the late seventies have seen some changes in the underlying spatial structures. What seems to be clear, however, is that, although change is continuous, there are also periodic bouts of more thorough-going transformation. There is, in other words, a relation- ship between the periodization of an economy and its regionalization – its forms of uneven development. And it seems clear that the major shift towards a new spatial division of labor, which began in the mid-sixties, is continuing today. If it began as part of an attempt to install one technocratic, social-democratic view of moderni- zation, it is being perpetuated, probably reinforced, by the economic and political changes since the late seventies. What the changes we have been discussing produce is a shifting kaleidoscope of local and regional variation. Both the geographical surface and the demands of UNEVEN DEVELOPMENT 123 industry are constantly changing. To give an example of the former, recent evidence would seem to indicate that some regions of the north and west are no longer seen as having reserves of mainly female labor, as they were in the 1960s and 1970s at the height of manufacturing location there. That characterization of the local labor reserves was a result of the women of those regions being seen as “green” labor and hence potentially vulnerable. Now, however, decades of unemployment, and of des- peration for jobs, and the existence of a new generation of males without trade union experience, indeed often without experience of paid work at all, have trans- formed the male labor markets of these regions from being heartlands of trade unionism to ones where it is possible to introduce completely new forms of labor relations. The male labor of those regions may now also be viewed by industry as a vulnerable reserve. The “geographical surface” and “the demands of industry” always interact. “General processes” only ever exist in the form which they take in particular cir- cumstances. The new spatial structures and their social forms discussed in the last two sections take shape in the context of previously laid down spatial structures and social forms. Each has an impact upon the other. The arrival of vastly increased numbers of white-collar, high-income employees into the outer southeast has trans- formed the prospects of an older working class already living there. Either they have been able, through employment or through housing, to benefit from the influx or they have been marginalized. Just as the concentration of upper-income groups has had some effect on the character of those strata so also it has affected those on below-average incomes. The experience of living on a fixed (for example, state) income in London or the southeast is very different from that in the north. Apart from the fact that the inequality is more visible, and probably that there are fewer supportive organizations, prices are higher, and housing is very difficult to find at an affordable price; the money goes less far. The southeast is the richest region in average terms, but it is the most unequal. “Spatial division of labor” is not an explanatory concept in the sense that it embodies an explanation of any particular form of uneven development. In this it is like any other concept of division of labor. A longer perspective on history indi- cates that the reasons for uneven development taking any particular form will change over time. It is certainly not the case that “labor-force characteristics” are always the dominant consideration. Indeed, patterns of industrial location are not to be explained simply by lists of “factors.” There are broad parameters, the main- tenance of capitalist accumulation chief among them. But the way in which that operates to produce a particular spatial division of labor will depend on a whole host of things. Of supreme importance in explaining the shifting character, over two centuries, of uneven development in the United Kingdom have been the changing relation of the economy to the international division of labor, the (related) chang- ing sectoral structure of the economy, and the dominant modes of technological and industrial organization. It is the structuring together of all these which will influ- ence the kinds of spatial structures developed, the balance between them, and their overall resultant in a broad spatial division of labor. Further, as we have seen, it is also more than this. As well as the maintenance of capital accumulation, the form of uneven development will also reflect battles over the maintenance of class power and will be refracted also through a wider level of politics, including the political 124 DOREEN MASSEY interpretation of what are the requirements of capitalist accumulation. Since the late seventies, for instance, the strategy has been to emphasize and enable a particular dual role for the UK within the international division of labor: a combination of banking center and low-cost production location. It is this, and the ascendancy of particular class strata, which lies behind one of the most important dimensions of uneven development in the UK today. Chapter 8 Flexible Production Systems and Regional Development: The Rise of New Industrial Spaces in North America and Western Europe

Allen J. Scott

In this paper, I examine some relations between forms of production organiza- tion and the dynamics of the space economy in contemporary capitalism. I seek, in particular, to elucidate the locational meaning of certain deeply rooted changes that are currently occurring in the industrial systems of North America and western Europe. These changes consist primarily in a relative decline in the importance of Fordist mass production and an enormous expansion of manufacturing activities based on less rigid and more highly adaptable (i.e., flexible) technological and insti- tutional structures. The same changes are associated with and embedded in a series of wider shifts in what theorists of the French Regulationist School have termed the regime of capitalist accumulation (cf. Aglietta, 1979; Lipietz, 1986). We might say, in brief, that the old hegemonic regime of Fordist accumulation has progressively given way to a new regime of flexible accumulation. With the steady ascendance of the latter regime a number of new industrial spaces have also started to make their decisive historical appearance on the economic landscape, and these now call urgently for analytical attention. As it happens, the current situation is one of considerable complexity, for the old regime is far from having disappeared entirely, and the new one by no means yet universally regnant. Moreover, the geographical outcomes proper to each regime intersect with one another in a sometimes disorderly and confusing manner. Despite the intrinsic ambiguities and analytical difficulties raised by this state of affairs, the old industrial spaces of the Fordist regime and the new spaces of flexible accumu- lation, in their purest and sharpest expression, contrast starkly with one another; and these contrasts are in turn a reflection of the very different patterns of indus- trialization and regional growth that epitomize each regime. In the subsequent discussion, I shall attempt to clarify and substantiate the above remarks about the changing regime of accumulation; I shall briefly delineate some of the main features of the new geography of flexible production; and I shall also identify a few guidelines for an appropriately reformulated theory of location and spatial change. 126 ALLEN J. SCOTT

From Fordism to Flexible Accumulation At the core of all capitalist economic activity lies the institution of commodity pro- duction with its overarching logic of accumulation. This institution is at once an endemic feature of capitalism and yet susceptible to considerable variation in the concrete shapes it assumes at different historical moments. To exemplify the point, we need only reflect on the many contrasts between such historical episodes as the early putting out system, the period of classical factory production towards the middle of the nineteenth century, the forms of heavy industrialization based on coal, steel, and chemicals that dominated at the turn of the century, or the era of mass production that stretched from the early years of the present century down to the 1960s and 1970s. Such episodes constitute more or less specific regimes of accu- mulation, though they certainly do not exhaust the total set of possibilities that is observable in practice or imaginable in theory; they are regimes in the sense that each represents a particular combination of sociotechnical relations through which commodity outputs are secured, the economic surplus appropriated, and new invest- ments ploughed back into the sphere of production. Relations of this sort are materi- alized, moreover, within dominant ensembles of industries that help to impress on each given regime much of its detailed character and dynamics. No regime of accumulation can function over the long run without encounter- ing diverse crises and tensions, many of which may threaten its very existence. Serious threats may spring from such necessary or contingent conditions as class conflict, overproduction, chronic economic depression, foreign competition, and so on. Invariably, however, a web of complementary social phenomena comes into being alongside the regime of accumulation as a means of stabilizing its operation through time. These phenomena consist of a multiplicity of sociopolitical relations ranging from established patterns of consumption, through private and public means of providing education, to governmental legislation on, say, union elections and norms of business activity. Because of their role in helping the regime of accu- mulation to adjust to internally and externally generated crisis conditions, relations of this sort are often referred to in the collective as a mode of social regulation. We can, then, think of specific moments in the historical geography of capitalism as being analytically representable in terms of the intertwined relations between a regime of accumulation and a corresponding mode of social regulation. Observe in passing that I have no intention here of covertly insinuating the functionalist notion to the effect that a given regime of accumulation calls a corresponding mode of social regulation into being because that is what it needs in order to survive. But we may certainly allow ourselves the converse idea that regimes of accumulation that endure over the long run do so because appropriate regulating mecha- nisms have been set in place. And as Lipietz (1986) has pointed out, there are in principle many different possible modes of social regulation for any given regime of accumulation. The Fordist regime of accumulation flourished strongly over the period stretch- ing approximately from the 1920s to the 1970s. Over this period of time it was hegemonic as a type of industrialization, though other types (including, for example, craft production activities) continued to exist alongside it. The main physical base of the Fordist regime coincided with an ensemble of mass production sectors such FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEMS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 127 as cars, capital equipment, and consumer durables. These sectors, in their classical form, are distinguished by a search for massive internal economies of scale based on assembly line methods, technical divisions of labor, and standardization of outputs. The Fordist elements of the system comprise, in their essentials, the deskilling of labor by means of the fragmentation of work while integrating the human operator into the whole machinery of production in such a manner as to reduce to the minimum discretionary control over motions and rhythms of work. Conditions like these were in the past invariably matched by a rigid system of labor relations as manifest in a proliferation of detailed job categories with strong lines of demarcation around each job, and the explicit codification of work rules. As the regime was consolidated in historical terms, so a distinctive and corresponding mode of social regulation was also gradually put into place. In its most fully developed expression, this mode of social regulation comprised both the macroeconomic steer- ing mechanisms of Keynesian economic policy and the socially stabilizing influence of the welfare state. Regulation was further underpinned by a social contract (medi- ated by the state) in which the labor unions offered concessions to management over shop floor controls and overall production strategies in exchange for guaran- teed shares in productivity gains. At the peak of its development, the regime of Fordist accumulation was geo- graphically associated with a series of great industrial regions in North America and western Europe, as represented by the Manufacturing Belt of the United States and the zone of industrial development in Europe stretching from the Midlands of England through northern France, Belgium, and Holland to the Ruhr of West Germany, with many additional outlying districts at various locations. These regions were the locational foci of propulsive industrial sectors driving forward, through intricate input–output connections, dense systems of upstream producers. The same regions also contained innumerable large urban agglomerations rising out of the industrial base and housing the masses of workers employed in the local area. In the residential districts that emerged within these agglomerations, active pro- cesses of collective consumption, community development, and social reproduction – frequently propped up by planning intervention – helped to sustain the viability of the whole socioeconomic system. Also, with steady technological change of the kind described by product cycle models, selected labor processes were periodically resynthesized and deskilled, and as this occurred they were typically reembodied in routinized branch plants and then decentralized to peripheral locations. In this way, core and peripheral regions operated in an interdependent though decidedly unequal relation. For a time, the entire Fordist regime and its associated mass production system functioned remarkably well. With the ending of the long postwar boom in the late 1960s and early 1970s, however, the system entered into an extended period of crisis, which, even now, has not fully run its course. By the early 1970s, the endemic outflow of capital from core regions was becoming an avalanche, leaving behind large pools of unemployed workers and fiscally crippled municipalities. Competi- tion from Japan and the newly industrializing countries became ever more intense and dealt a serious blow to mass production sectors in core regions through- out North America and western Europe. The crisis was intensified by a rising tide of stagflation, for in a situation of declining industrial productivity and rising 128 ALLEN J. SCOTT unemployment, the public expenditures needed to keep the Keynesian welfare-statist mode in operation could not be maintained without corresponding fiscal distortions. By the late 1970s, the whole regime of Fordist accumulation together with its Keynesian welfare-statist mode of social regulation was beginning to unwind in significant ways. This unwinding manifest in the rise of Thatcherism in Britain and Reaganism in the United States, and it was accelerated by the programs of neo- conservative reform these administrations then began to usher in. In the face of the deepening unworkability of the Fordist regime – in its archetypal form at least – governments in both North America and western Europe started actively to dis- mantle the Keynesian welfare-statist arrangements that had helped to regulate it but were now only becoming an additional element of the overall crisis. In the vacuum created by these events, the outlines of an alternative regime of accumulation began to take shape, at first haltingly over the 1960s and early 1970s, and then more assertively in the late 1970s and 1980s. In particular, a number of new flexible forms of productive activity have now appeared (or reappeared) on center stage in all the advanced capitalist societies, and while these often differ markedly from one another in terms of technologies, labor processes, and outputs, they nonetheless share a variety of other basic features in common. Unlike mass production activities which are typically rather rigid in structure, the new forms of production are generally characterized by an ability to change process and product configurations with great rapidity – an ability that is frequently much enhanced by the use of computerized technologies. They are also typically situated in networks of extremely malleable external linkages and labor market relations. By the same token, they tend as far as possible to externalize production processes by buying in services and products that might otherwise be supplied internally, and this some- times leads in turn to concomitant downsizing of individual establishments. Many sectors that display such attributes are, in addition, the sites of a vigorous revival of entrepreneurial behavior, renewed market competition, and active technological innovation. Flexible production activities of this general sort are, to be sure, a recurrent phe- nomenon throughout the history of industrial capitalism (Sabel and Zeitlin, 1985). In their modern guise, however, they possess many unique and novel features, as we shall see. The incipient phases of development of modern flexible production activities coincide with the period immediately following the Second World War, but only of late years have they begun to rival mass production as the dominant core of the advanced capitalist economies. Piore and Sabel (1984) have called this turning point the “second industrial divide” and other commentators such as Cohen and Zysman (1987), Lash and Urry (1987), and Tolliday and Zeitlin (1986) have in their different ways also pointed to the same historical rupture. The forward surge of the new flexible production sectors at the core of the new regime of accumula- tion has been further underpinned by major changes in the mode of social regula- tion. There has been a wholesale dismantling of the apparatus of Keynesian welfare-statism and deepening privatization of social life, a marked renewal of the forces of economic competition in industrial production and labor markets, and (in the United States) a sharp rise in governmental allocations for the purchase of mili- tary and space equipment. These changes are still in many ways in an experimen- tal stage and no doubt their full extent and form remain yet to be determined. They FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEMS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 129 have nonetheless brought in their train numerous significant mutations in the con- figuration of urban and regional development over the last decade or so.

Flexible Accumulation and Patterns of Industrialization The new regime of flexible accumulation is founded preeminently on three major ensembles (or collections) of industrial sectors. These may be enumerated immedi- ately as (a) revivified artisanal and design-intensive industries producing outputs largely but not exclusively for final consumption, (b) various sorts of high technol- ogy industries and their associated phalanxes of input suppliers and dependent sub- contractors, and (c) service functions, and most especially business services. In what follows, I shall deal for the most part only with the first two of these three ensem- bles since they are most germane to the issue of new industrial spaces. Obviously, however, service functions are important in their own right and must eventually be accommodated within the overall terms of reference of the analysis. For want of familiarity with recent economic events in other areas (Japan in particular), I shall restrict my remarks to the cases of North America and western Europe. One of the basic common traits of the flexible production ensembles that have recently made their appearance in modern capitalism is their evident propensity to disintegrate into extended social divisions of labor, thus giving rise to many spe- cialized subsectors. This process is a reflection of the tendency for internal economies to give way before a progressive externalization of the structure of production under conditions of rising flexibility, and it leads at once to a revival of proclivities to loca- tional convergence and reagglomeration. A sort of submerged analytical lineage of key theoretical ideas about these issues can be traced out over two centuries of eco- nomic thought. This is a lineage that begins with Smith (1776) in the eighteenth century, passes through Babbage (1835), Marx (1967), and von Bohm-Bawerk (1891) in the nineteenth century, and then reemerges in the twentieth century in the writings of Marshall (1920, 1932), Young (1928), Coase (1937), Stigler (1951), and Williamson (1975, 1985), with an offshoot in the Italian school of industrial eco- nomics as represented for example by Becattini (1987) and Brusco (1982). A scrutiny of the works of these authors provides many important insights into the problems of the division of labor, the transactional structure of production, the for- mation of external economies, and the emergence of Marshallian “industrial dis- tricts,” i.e., spatially agglomerated production complexes together with their dependent labor markets and intercalated human communities. I shall not attempt to deal here with all of the innumerable theoretical and ana- lytical questions raised by the authors cited above, and in any case, the interested reader can find extensive treatments of these matters elsewhere (A. J. Scott, 1988a). Instead, I shall broadly summarize a framework of reasoning whose inner intrica- cies can readily be filled in on a second round of reflection. The foundation stone of this framework reposes on the proposition that when changes in economic con- ditions bring about intensified uncertainty and instability in production and increased competitiveness in final markets, then internal economies of scale and scope within the firm begin to break down so that the entire production system is liable to display strong symptoms of horizontal and vertical disintegration. Such disintegration enormously enhances flexibility in the deployment of capital and 130 ALLEN J. SCOTT labor for it permits producers to combine and recombine together in loose, rapidly shifting coalitions held together by external transactional linkages. In this way, external economies of scale tend to deepen and widen, and most especially where markets are also expanding so that increasingly specialized service and input sup- pliers are able to find profitable niches within the total production system. Addi- tionally, new industrial subsectors come one by one into existence thereby giving rise to continual extensions of the social division of labor – a process that may be termed dynamic vertical disintegration. A growing production complex thus makes its historical appearance and becomes steadily more variegated in its internal struc- ture. So long as the pool of external economies is expanding, individual producers can find within the organizational structure of the complex increasingly diverse input options at increasingly lower prices; and the complex thus continues to grow recursively by reason of its own inner momentum of falling production costs. There is a countervailing disadvantage that accompanies these external benefits, however. As the social division of labor moves forward, inter-establishment trans- actional structures proliferate, and this immediately encourages certain kinds of costs to rise. These costs comprise the direct expenses of transport, communication, information exchange, search, scanning, and so forth, as well as indirect financial losses caused by the diminished velocity with which circulating capital moves through the whole system. The greater the spatial dispersion of producers, the more onerous these costs will be. The immediate consequence is that selected sets of pro- ducers with particularly elevated intragroup interaction costs will tend to converge around their own geographical center of gravity and thus to engender definite nodes of economic activity on the landscape. With the increasing installation in recent years of just-in-time delivery systems, this tendency to agglomeration has been much accentuated (cf. Cusumano, 1985). Hence, via the play of centripetal locational adjustment, external economies of scale (a non-spatial phenomenon) are eventually transmuted into and consumed in the specifically spatial form of agglomeration economies. The counterpart of rising flexibility in the organization of production is rising flexibility in labor markets. Two main points may be quickly sketched out in this regard. First, vertical disintegration (due primarily to instabilities in production and exchange) is reinforced where employers seek to externalize their consumption of selected labor inputs and thus to head off possible internal upward drift of wages and benefits. This strategy is especially favored among employers with a core of skilled, high-wage workers but who also have a demand for various low-skilled workers. Employers tend frequently to farm such work out to subcontractors ensconced in secondary labor markets. By means of this device, they effectively put bounds around the possible spillovers on remuneration levels that might otherwise occur within the firm from high-wage to low-wage employment segments. One result of this sort of structural response is sharpened dualization of local labor markets. Secondly, where flexible production arrangements are in place, they are frequently accompanied by much fluidity of local labor markets, as manifest, for example, in elevated rates of turnover, extensive part-time and temporary work, and high proportions of politically marginal workers such as immigrants, women, and adolescents in the labor force (Boyer, 1988; Brusco, 1982). In other words, employ- ers attempt to tune their payroll numbers as sensitively as possible to the ups and FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEMS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 131 downs of production, while cultivating fractions of the labor force whose potential for political resistance to this process is likely to be low. All such labor market flu- idity is enhanced as the size of the local pool of jobs and workers increases for where this occurs, information and search costs tend to fall and a rising stock of employ- ment alternatives helps to compensate workers for the instability of individual jobs (hence discouraging out-migration of labor). There are therefore strong agglomera- tion economies in local labor markets and these intersect with and underpin the basic agglomeration economies that arise out of the organizational structure of production. These different outcomes have an especially intense association with sectors dom- inated by small and medium-sized firms, though large multiestablishment corpora- tions have also been considerably affected by the recent turn to flexibility in patterns of industrialization. Thus, strategic reductions in make-to-buy ratios and the search for fluid employment practices are apparently becoming an ever more insistent element of the modern corporate world. Even mass production sectors have not escaped these pressures (cf. Abernathy et al., 1983; Cohen and Zysman, 1987). Pro- ducers in many of these sectors have been experimenting on a major scale with such aids to flexibility as robotized equipment, workers’ quality circles (and other neo- Fordist labor practices), increased subcontracting activity, and just-in-time delivery systems. The managements of mass product industries have also engaged over the last several years in highly successful attacks on the work rule rigidities and enti- tlements secured in an earlier era by strongly unionized workers. These trends to increased flexibility have been much encouraged by intensified product differentia- tion and competition in high volume markets and by the importation back into older mass production regions of the regressive labor market norms and practices now being hammered out in the flexible production complexes that form the cores of the new growth centers of the world system.

New Industrial Spaces We have seen that the emergence and expansion of flexible manufacturing systems has stimulated massive though selective reagglomeration of production. Where, we may ask, has this reagglomeration occurred? How precisely has it come about? And what are its peculiar geographical forms? A salient feature of the new flexible ensembles of productive activity identified above is that in their incipient phases of development in the 1950s and 1960s there was little to keep them attached locationally to the old centers of Fordist mass pro- duction. They had no especial demand for the types of inputs and labor available in such centers, and they were at the outset relatively free to locale in a variety of geographical environments. Moreover, the old centers with their high levels of worker unionization and their relatively politicized working-class populations – leading to stubborn rigidities in both the workplace and the local labor market – constituted hostile milieux in several respects for the new flexible ensembles. It may be said that for a time at least, a window of locational opportunity opened widely as the new regime entered onto the scene of modern capitalism. As a consequence many, but by no means all, of the producers in the new ensembles began to seek out alternative kinds of locational environments uncontaminated by previous 132 ALLEN J. SCOTT historical experience of large-scale manufacturing activity and Fordist employment relations (cf. Scott and Angel, 1987; Scott and Storper, 1987). In such environments new and experimental kinds of sociotechnical structures of production can be estab- lished with minimum local obstruction. This is doubly important where both avoid- ance of rigidity and the institutionalization of flexibility are primary goals. Accordingly, over the last few decades, many new industrial spaces have sprung into existence on the landscape of capitalism. These spaces are the outcome of a twofold process involving a tendency for modern flexible production systems to avoid older centers of accumulation combined with a dynamic of locational implo- sion resulting from increasing levels of externalization. For the most part, these spaces comprise either (a) a number of enclaves within older manufacturing regions, or (b) more importantly, a series of areas that have hitherto largely coincided with the extensive geographical margins of capitalist industrialization. The first of these categories includes many inner-city areas in large metro- politan regions with their revitalized craft industries, such as clothing, furniture, jewelry, leather goods, and, in the case of Los Angeles, the film industry (Storper and Christopherson, 1987). It includes, too, suburban extensions of the same metropoli- tan regions where high technology industrial complexes may be sometimes found. The outstanding example of the latter phenomenon is the Route 128 industrial complex in Boston’s western suburbs (Dorfman, 1983). In all such enclaves, firms usually attempt actively to exclude the traditional male working class from their labor force, and they tend instead to satisfy their demands for unskilled manual labor by prefer- ential employment of recent immigrants and women (cf. Morgan and Sayer, 1985). In the second category are the diverse sunbelt areas and third development zones of North America and western Europe. These are areas that were formerly peri- pheral or semi-peripheral zones bordering the old core regions of Fordist indus- trialization. Their economies have traditionally been based to a large degree on agriculture, trade, and small-scale industry (complemented in some cases by decen- tralized branch plants), and urban settlement has until fairly recently been com- paratively restrained. In many instances (in the US sunbelt above all) these areas possess a sociocultural environment that is relatively free from previous direct contact with big industry and large national unions, and they have thus been espe- cially attractive to industrial sectors that could evade the locational pull of older established industrial centers. These erstwhile peripheral and semi-peripheral areas now constitute many of the new industrial spaces of the regime of flexible accu- mulation, and numbers of them are presently growing with exceptional vigor as freshly created agglomeration economies begin to build up within them, though there are, to be sure, important differences in patterns of growth between indivi- dual cases. To illustrate some of the similarities and differences between these new industrial spaces, let us briefly consider a few empirical examples drawn from Italy, Britain, France, and the United States. In the so-called “Third Italy” there has been a great expansion of localized pro- duction complexes based on highly flexible kinds of artisanal industry over the last two or three decades (Bagnasco, 1977). This part of Italy lies in the northeast and center of the country with its core area focused on the administrative regions of Emilia-Romagna, Marche, Tuscany, and Veneto. In the heyday of Fordist accumu- FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEMS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 133 lation in the postwar decades, the Third Italy lay conspicuously to one side of a ter- ritorial system organized around the large mass production complexes of the north and the decentralized branch plants of the Mezzogiorno. The industrial base of the region has traditionally consisted of clusters of craft production activities distri- buted over a dense network of small and medium-sized towns. Today, this base con- stitutes one of the most dynamic segments of the modern Italian economy. Its principal strength resides in its many specialized agglomerations of artisanal firms producing design-intensive product-differentiated outputs in short production runs, and with remarkable adaptability of organizational and labor market relations. Some representative examples of such agglomerations are Arezzo with its gold jewelry industry, Bologna with its machinery industries and high-performance car production, Carpi with its knitwear factories, Prato with its woolen textiles, Sassuolo with its ceramics, and the region of Marche with its furniture and shoe- producing centers (cf. Russo, 1985; Solinas, 1982). In direct contrast to the US sunbelt, many municipalities in the Third Italy are politically to the left. In spite of this circumstance, local administrations have tended to welcome “non-monopolis- tic” artisanal forms of industry, and the sort of class polarization characteristic of mass production regions is largely absent. On these foundations, industrial pro- ducers in the area have prospered remarkably well in recent years – even over the crisis period of the 1970s – and in cooperation with specialized marketing organi- zations they have been able to create and dominate innumerable international market niches. In many ways, the lessons to be learned from the contemporary industrialization of the Third Italy are just as important as those of Japan. In Britain and France, agglomerated high technology industrial complexes are now thriving at such isolated centers as Cambridge, Grenoble, Montpellier, Sophia Antipolis, and Toulouse. These complexes, like those of the Third Italy, tend to be made up of small, interlinked establishments, though in some cases they are also functionally focused on large propulsive plants. In general, the scale (and hence internal differentiation) of these complexes is rather modest by comparison with American standards as final markets for British and French high technology products are themselves comparatively smaller. That said, two major suburban technopoles in Britain and France have been developing with great rapidity since the 1970s, the one aligned along the M4 corridor between London and Reading, and the other located in the Scientific City in the southernmost portion of the Greater Paris region. Even though they are adjacent to major metropolitan regions, these two technopoles are interpenetrated by semirural tracts of land with much unspoiled open space, and they are in social terms far distant from earlier foci of accumulation. In this environmental setting, production and local labor market activity based on sectors such as electronics, computers, biotechnology, software development, and other sorts of high technology industry is now apparently enter- ing an intensive phase of evolution. Of late years, French regional policy-makers have started to play a particularly active role in the development of national technopoles. Much of this role has focused on attempts to stimulate agglomeration economies in selected areas through publicly funded regional technology innovation and transfer centers and generous subsidies to innovative firms. Finally, in the sunbelt of the United States a pattern of agglomeration of high technology industry can also be observed at isolated urban sites and in suburban 134 ALLEN J. SCOTT technopoles. The first of these two types of location may be exemplified by centers such as Albuquerque, Austin, Boulder, and Colorado Springs, each representing a particular stage in the process of new high technology industrial growth. The second locational type is strikingly exemplified by Orange County and Silicon Valley, uncontestably two of the world’s densest and most dynamic high technology pro- duction complexes (cf. Saxenian, 1983; A. J. Scott, 1988a). These representative cases are all subject to advanced vertical disintegration of production processes combined with extreme labor market instability, not just among secondary workers, but among many kinds of qualified technical and scientific cadres too. In research reported on elsewhere, I have shown how both Orange County and Silicon Valley have grown insistently on the basis of a deepening social division of labor giving rise to dense constellations of interdependent producers and subcontractors situated at the core of burgeoning multifaceted labor markets (A. J. Scott, 1988a; Scott and Angel, 1987). In turn, these industrial complexes have become the functional and spatial hubs of a renewed process of rapid urban growth. Analogous phenomena of flexible industrialization and reagglomeration have been reported in southern Norway, Denmark, Flanders, Bavaria and Baden Württemberg in West Germany, the Jura region of Switzerland, northeastern Spain, central Portugal, and elsewhere. Some of these areas are growing on the basis of rejuvenated craft production; others have become centers of high technology industrial development. The point must be stressed once more that each of these areas represents a unique configuration of social and political life, which means that each is also caught up in a unique developmental trajectory. That said, a common underlying system of structural dynamics can be detected in virtually every case. These dynamics, as we now know, revolve for the most part around the social divi- sion of labor, the formation of external economies, the dissolution of labor market rigidities, and the reagglomeration of production. Moreover, those places that made an early start down the path of flexible industrialization have tended to forge insis- tently ahead on the basis of their rich and endogenously formed spatial advantages. In this fashion, the window of locational opportunity alluded to above has started in several cases to close again, as firms in flexible production sectors find it increas- ingly difficult to dispense with the intensifying agglomeration economies now avail- able at particular locations in the new industrial spaces of North America and western Europe. Each particular space is the site of an evolving polarized complex of production activities, local labor market phenomena, and social life, in which each element (including educational institutions, residential neighborhoods, the apparatus of local government, and so on) contributes in one way or another to the total process of local territorial reproduction. No doubt, detailed historical ex- egesis of the origins of any given complex are of interest, as in the case, for example, of the standard accounts of the role of Shockley, Terman, and Stanford University in the early development of Silicon Valley; however, such exegesis can never explain subsequent long-run patterns of growth, and in any event, there are likely to be as many different anecdotes about these matters as there are individual cases. What is interesting and significant in theoretical terms are the inner dynamics of each local- ized complex as congeries of interconnected producers and associated local labor markets. FLEXIBLE PRODUCTION SYSTEMS AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT 135

The new industrial spaces that have come to the fore over the last couple of decades are developing at an increasingly fast tempo. Their developmental thrust is all the more forceful given the selective widening of markets for many of their pro- ducts. Thus, for example, the design-intensive outputs of the Third Italy are now being aggressively exported throughout the world, and in the United States both military and civilian demands for high technology industrial output continue to rise upwards. We must not overlook the circumstance, however, that such conditions are historically reversible. Markets may shrink or give way to outside competition; dramatic resynthesis and routinization of production technologies and work organization may come about; locational decentralization and dispersal may start to undermine the process of agglomeration; and formerly thriving industrial com- munities may fall into stagnation and decay, just as they have done at previous times over the course of capitalist economic and social development.

Towards a Theoretical Synthesis Modern capitalist production systems have evidently been evolving over the last couple of decades away from relatively rigid Fordist industrial structures towards more flexible forms of production organization. This evolutionary tendency is enmeshed within concomitant changes in the regime of accumulation and mode of social regulation. The geographical corollary has been a partial but pronounced dis- placement of the locational foundations of modern capitalism. As these events were gathering momentum over the crisis years of the 1970s, there seemed to come about a corresponding crisis of urban and regional theory. The old accounts of the forms of spatial development associated with the regime of Fordist accumulation and its cognate mode of Keynesian welfare-statist regulation were patently no longer very satisfactory as descriptions of underlying realities; and an alternative theoretical framework capable of fully assimilating the emerging new contours of capitalist society into its universe of discourse failed signally to make its appearance. Even yet, it can scarcely be claimed that a new theoretical consensus about the current situation has formed. One of the evident responses in human geography to this predicament has been a certain disillusionment with theoretical work in general and a radical return to empirical investigation, the multiplication of case studies, and an insistence on the significance of the local at the expense of the global and universal. This reaction is entirely comprehensible, and it has provided us with many new insights about the detailed workings of contemporary capitalism at both intermediate and micro-scales of analysis. There does, nonetheless, appear to be a burning need to reopen macrotheoretical questions about the logic of capitalist society as a whole. An especially urgent task is to investigate more thoroughly the formation, characteristics, and historical course of flexible accumulation and its attendant mode(s) of social regulation, for only by clarifying these issues can we also effectively explain detailed geographical outcomes currently occurring on the ground (cf. Harvey and Scott, 1988). It is my hope that the arguments deployed above may suggest some potentially fruitful avenues of reconciliation between theoretical and empirical work in human geography as the trend to flexible production organization in modern capitalism deepens and widens. 136 ALLEN J. SCOTT

Meanwhile, we are also faced with the need to provide a meaningful account of the contemporary conjuncture in the space-economies of North America and western Europe, with their conflicting and confusing crosscurrents. These cross- currents spring in large degree from the copresence of an aging regime of Fordist accumulation alongside an ascending regime of flexible accumulation, giving rise in turn to an intricate pattern of old and new industrial spaces imbricated in a widen- ing international division of labor. Whatever the future evolutionary path of this system may be, it is evident that the landscape of capitalist production is today dras- tically different from what it was even a couple of decades ago. In this paper I have developed some outlines of a suggested framework for thinking about these changes. There remain innumerable detailed research tasks of conceptual infilling, empirical analysis, and reevaluation. Chapter 9 Global–Local Tensions: Firms and States in the Global Space-Economy

Peter Dicken

These are exciting and challenging times in economic geography, as we grapple with the problem of understanding the major transformations in the way economic activities are organized and reorganized. Not only does the pace of change pose difficulties, but the complex interplay among processes operating at different, but related, geographic scales has become increasingly intricate as well. I want to frame my argument in the specific context of the “global–local nexus.” This is far more than merely a question of the geographic scale at which economic processes occur. More fundamentally, it is a question of where power lies, and it is a central prob- lematic facing both firms and states. Analysis of these processes is made more difficult by the uncertainty surround- ing the interpretation of the current structure of the world economy. Making sense of the present is, of course, always more difficult than making sense of the past, because we do not really know where we are. Throughout history, most observers of the contemporary scene have been tempted to argue for the “specialness” of their own times; the present day is no exception. But, by definition, we cannot know which of the current developments and changes are permanent and which are purely ephemeral. Considerable disagreement exists over the interpretation of current developments in the organization of economic activities at the global scale and their implications for firms and states. The crux of the debate is the extent to which we are moving toward (or already live in) a globalized, rather than an international, economy. Robert Reich’s view is that

We are living through a transformation that will rearrange the politics and economics of the coming century. There will be no national products or technologies, no national corporations, no national industries. There will no longer be national economies, at least as we have come to understand that concept. (1991, pp. 3, 8)

While Reich appears, at least implicitly, to support the view that we are now in a globalizing, if not a globalized, economy, Hirst and Thompson (1992) are more skeptical. On the basis of a comparison between two ideal types of structure – a 138 PETER DICKEN globalized international economy and a worldwide international economy – and from an analysis of empirical trends in trade, investment, and political restructur- ing, they conclude, “we do not have a fully globalized economy; we do have an international economy and national policy responses to it” (Hirst and Thompson, 1992, p. 394). Both Reich and Hirst and Thompson agree, in their different ways, that the relationships between firms and states have been drastically changed. Stopford and Strange (1991) express this in terms of mutual dependence, which, they argue, can be explored in terms of a triangular nexus of interactions compris- ing firm–firm, state–state, and firm–state relationships. The aim of this paper is to explore some of these complex interactions between transnational corporations (TNCs) and states in the context of the global–local debate through a review of a wide variety of literature drawn from different disci- plines. It is important to emphasize that the terms “global” and “local” are not fixed scales; rather, they represent the extreme points of a dialectical continuum of complex mutual interactions.

Firm–Firm Competition: The Changing World of the Transnational Corporation TNCs today are restructuring their activities in ways that involve (1) reorganizing the coordination of production chain functions in a complex realignment of inter- nalized and externalized network relationships; (2) reorganizing the geography of their production chains internationally and, in some cases, globally; (3) redefining their core activities and repositioning themselves along the production chain, with a particular emphasis on downstream, service functions. These developments reflect the nature of TNCs as highly embedded interacting networks involved in competi- tive struggles in which a diversity of competitive strategies is used. Such strategies are, themselves, the outcome of contested power relations both inside the firm and, externally, with the constellation of institutions (including the state) with which TNCs interact. Until relatively recently, much of the business and management literature pro- jected a simplistic sequential path of TNC development. In fact, there is – and always has been – considerable diversity in TNC strategies and in the kinds of organiza- tional coordination and geographic configuration employed to implement them (see, for example, Perlmutter, 1969; Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Martinez and Jarillo, 1989). Bartlett and Ghoshal (1989) identify three different organizational models, each with distinctive structural, administrative, and management characteristics. Their multinational organization model is characterized by a decentralized federation of activities and simple financial control systems overlain on informal personal co- ordination. The company’s worldwide operations are organized as a portfolio of national businesses. Each of the firm’s national units has a considerable degree of autonomy; each has a predominantly “local” orientation. Their international organization model involves far more formal coordination and control by the cor- porate headquarters over the overseas subsidiaries. Whereas multinational organiza- tions are, in effect, portfolios of quasi-independent businesses, international organizations clearly regard their overseas operations as appendages to the GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 139 controlling domestic corporation. Thus the international firm’s subsidiaries are more dependent on the center for the transfer of knowledge and information, and the parent company makes greater use of formal systems to control their subsidiaries. Their “classic” global organization model is based on a centralization of assets and responsibilities. The role of the local units is to assemble and sell products and to implement plans and policies developed at headquarters. Thus, overseas subsidiaries have far less freedom to create new products or strategies or even to modify existing ones. Although each of these three ideal-type models developed during specific his- torical periods, there is no suggestion that one was sequentially replaced by another. Each form has tended to persist, to a greater or lesser extent, producing a diverse pop- ulation of transnational corporations in the contemporary world economy. Although we can continue to identify these forms of TNC, new forms of transna- tional organization are also emerging that may – although not inevitably – replace some of the existing forms. Bartlett and Ghoshal argue that each of their three ideal types of organization possesses specific strengths, but each also has severe contra- dictions and tensions. Thus, the global company capitalizes on the achievement of scale economies in its activities and on centralized knowledge and expertise. But this implies that local market conditions tend to be ignored, and the possibility of local learning is precluded. The more locally oriented multinational organization is able to respond to local needs, but its very fragmentation imposes penalties for efficiency and for the internal flow of knowledge and learning. The international company “is better able to leverage the knowledge and capabilities of the parent company. But its resource configuration and operating systems make it less efficient than the global company, and less responsive than the multinational company” (Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989, pp. 58–9). As Bartlett and Ghoshal point out, the dilemma facing firms – especially large firms – in turbulent competitive environments is that to succeed on a global scale they must possess three capabilities simultaneously. They need to be globally efficient, multi- nationally flexible, and capable of capturing the benefits of worldwide learning all at the same time. A key diagnostic feature of such complex global organizations is their integrated network configuration and their capacity to develop flexible coordinating processes. Such capabilities apply both inside the firm (the network of intrafirm rela- tionships which, it is argued, is displacing hierarchical governance relationships) and outside the firm (the complex network of interfirm relationships). A central feature of these models of contemporary production organization is that they place particular emphasis on the rich variety of external relationships within production networks. At the international scale, most attention has been devoted to strategic alliances, which, as Kindleberger (1988) has observed, are by no means a new phenomenon. Such relationships are frequently multilateral rather than bilateral, polygamous rather than monogamous. Collaborative ventures are a long-established form of international business organization that, in the past, involved specific relationships between conventionally organized, hierarchically structured firms as just one element in their competitive strategies. The argument now is rather different: not only have collaborative ventures in the more traditional sense moved to the center of firms’ strategies, but also – and more controversially – new forms of collabora- tion are embedded within a much looser network structure, or webs of enterprise 140 PETER DICKEN

(Reich, 1991). This view, however, is very much a Western perspective. Japanese business organizations have long been embedded in a complex structure of inter- organizational alliances, epitomized by the horizontal and vertical keiretsu (Gerlach, 1992; Eli, 1990; Helou, 1991). Seductive as these various ideas about new forms of international business organi- zation undoubtedly are, we face a major problem in distinguishing what is actually happening (and may happen in the future) from the hype and the rhetoric. When we turn to the hard world of empirical reality we meet up with the intractability – and even total absence – of comprehensive data. The only variable on which we have (reasonably) comprehensive data is that of foreign direct investment (FDI), which, unfortunately, exclude coverage of most non-equity relationships and activ- ities, the very ones that are becoming especially important. Within their limitations, however, FDI data provide an important, though partial, indicator of changing levels and patterns of TNC activity at a global scale (Dicken, 1992a; Dunning, 1993). The recent temporal pattern of FDI growth displays a major upsurge during the 1980s, on a scale exceeding even that of the 1960s. Julius (1990, p. 6) estimates that “whereas in the 1960s FDI grew at twice the rate of GNP, in the 1980s it has grown more than four times as fast as GNP.” Not only has FDI been growing faster than GNP, but it also has been growing at a much faster rate than world exports, particularly since 1985 (UNCTC, 1991). This figure alone suggests that FDI has become a more significant integrating force in the global economy than the tradi- tional indicator of such integration, trade (Julius, 1990). Indeed, because TNCs are themselves responsible for a large proportion of international trade (much of this as intrafirm transactions), their global significance becomes even more marked. Another notable trend has been the massive internationalization of services, much of which has been driven by FDI (Dicken, 1992a). Spatially, a number of important FDI trends can be identified:

(1) Origins have diversified geographically, not only within the industrialized countries, but also from several of the newly industrializing economies (NIEs), notably in East Asia but including some Latin American countries. (2) Although the United States still accounts for the largest share of the world’s stock of FDI, Japan is now the world’s leading foreign direct investor on an annual flow basis. The collapse of Japan’s “bubble economy,” however, caused a substantial contraction (and geographic reorientation) of Japanese FDI. (3) There has been a major intensification of cross-investment between the indus- trialized economies, an increasingly high level of TNC interpenetration of national economies (Julius, 1990). Overall, the relative importance of TNCs (both foreign and domestic) in each major economy has greatly increased, while the global pattern of FDI has become strongly concentrated in the triad regions. (4) The intensified concentration of FDI in the industrialized economies means that the share going to developing economies remains low: some 18 percent of the world total compared with more than 60 percent on the eve of World War II. Within the developing countries, the distribution of FDI is extremely uneven: a mere ten countries, primarily the Asian NIEs and “proto-NIEs” and some GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 141

Latin American countries (OECD, 1993), account for 75 percent of the FDI inflow. (5) The recent political developments in the former Soviet Union and in Eastern Europe have unexpectedly opened up investment opportunities for foreign TNCs.

When we turn from FDI to other modes of TNC activity, we face a serious paucity of empirical data and a reliance on case studies and anecdotal evidence. Most strik- ingly, the majority of strategic alliances are among competitors. Of the 839 agree- ments analyzed by Morris and Hergert (1987) between 1975 and 1986, no less than 71 percent were between two firms in the same market. In addition, although alliances are certainly not confined to particular sizes or types of firms, they are undoubtedly especially common between large TNCs with extensive interna- tional operations. Geographically, most alliances in the Morris and Hergert study were between firms from European Community (EC) countries (31 percent) or between EC and US firms (26 percent). A further 10 percent of the alliances were between EC and Japanese firms and 8 percent between United States and Japanese firms. Empirical evidence on the existence and nature of the kinds of dynamic network that are becoming especially important in the global economy is even sparser than that on the more conventional collaborative ventures. Here, we are limited to a small number of cases, the most notable being the Italian clothing company, Benetton (Elson, 1989), and the US athletic shoe company, Nike (Donaghu and Barff, 1990). The clear message is that transnational reality is one of a spectrum of forms of TNC organization, a diversity of developmental trajectories in which consciously planned global operations exist side-by-side with firms that have internationalized in an unplanned, often adventitious, way. Across the spectrum, complex restruc- turing is occurring at all geographic scales, from the global to the local, as strate- gic decisions have to be made regarding the organizational coordination and geographic configuration of production chain functions. Decisions to centralize or decentralize decision-making powers, or to cluster or to disperse some or all of the firm’s functions in particular ways are, however, contested decisions (Stopford and Strange, 1991), the outcome of power struggles within firms, both within their head- quarters and between headquarters and affiliates, and they reflect differences in goals and objectives. How they are resolved depends very much upon the location and nature of the dominant coalition. Such decisions also have to be seen within the context of the fundamental tension facing all firms that operate at a global scale: whether to globalize fully or to respond to local differentiation.

State–State Interaction: The Emergence of the “Competition State” Having discussed one element of the triangular nexus of interactions identified earlier – firm–firm competition – I now want to address the second element: com- petition between states. Here, I deliberately avoid discussion of the nature of the state, while accepting that the competitive aspect of state behavior is itself deeply 142 PETER DICKEN politically, socially, and culturally embedded. My basic approach is that the state in the contemporary global economy may be legitimately regarded as a competition state, whose problem is one of facing “major adjustments to shifts in competitive advantage in the global market place” (Cerny, 1991, p. 183). In this respect, states take on some of the characteristics of firms as they strive to develop strategies to create competitive advantage (Guisinger, 1985). Both are, in effect, locked in com- petitive struggles to capture global market shares. Specifically, states compete to enhance their international trading position and to capture as large a share as pos- sible of the gains from trade. They compete to attract productive investment to build up their national production base, which, in turn, enhances their competitive posi- tion. In particular, states strive to create, capture, and maintain the higher value- adding elements of the production chain. All states perform a key role in the ways in which their economies operate, although they differ substantially in the specific measures they employ and in the precise ways in which such measures are combined. Although a high level of con- tingency may be involved (no two states behave in exactly the same way), certain regularities in basic policy stance can be identified. Dahrendorf (1968) distinguished between two ideal types of political economy: the market-rational and the plan- rational. He equated the latter with the state socialist command economies. Johnson (1982), in his seminal work on the growth of the Japanese economy, argued that these command economies were better described as plan-ideological systems, and he applied the term plan-rational to the economies of East Asia, notably Japan and the then-leading NIEs, particularly of South Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore. Recently, Henderson and Appelbaum (1992) have suggested that a fourth ideal type can be recognized: the market-ideological, which, they suggest, was epitomized by the Reagan and Thatcher “new right” administrations. As always, such simpli- fied typologies require a “health warning,” which Henderson and Appelbaum duly provide: “These four constructs (market rational, plan rational, market ideological, and plan ideological) should be regarded as ideal types; actual existing political economies combine them in various historically contingent ways. Still, for any par- ticular society, one will typically dominate, facilitating an overall characterization of its prevailing political economy” (1992, p. 20). Allowing for these caveats, it is not unreasonable to regard many of the current politico-economic tensions in the global economy as being a reflection of a clash between competition states occupying different positions within the market- rational/plan-rational space. Certainly, the smoldering – occasionally incandescent and inflammatory – disputes between Japan and many Western economies (notably the United States and the European Community) can usefully be set within this context. The various trade disputes between the United States and the European Community and the broader negotiating differences among nations within the Uruguay Round of the GATT can also be interpreted in this way. The position of states is not necessarily fixed. In this respect, one of the most notable developments of the last few years has been the growing pressure within the most dominant market-ideological state, the United States, for a more overtly strategic policy orientation. The demand in the United States in particular is for a shift away from “free” trade toward “fair” trade – “fairness” being defined by the United States itself. An early sign of this shift in emphasis was apparent in the 1974 GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 143

US Trade Act; it became quite explicit in the 1988 Omnibus Trade and Competi- tiveness Act, especially in the so-called “super 301” clause, which aimed to achieve reciprocal access to what the United States defines as unfairly restricted markets. The difference between the 1974 and 1988 Acts is that the clause now applies to entire countries and not, as before, to specific industries. These shifts toward a more strategic policy are particularly evident in high-technology sectors, seen to be at the center of a country’s future competitive position. The basic rationale is that, in imperfectly competitive markets, governments must intervene in favor of their domestic firms (Encarnation, 1992; Ostry, 1990). As Ostry (1990) points out, the argument is based upon two issues: “the ‘first mover advantage’ that a country or firm captures by preempting foreign rivals . . . (which) ...provides the opportunity for firms and countries to consolidate and extend their competitive advantage” (p. 60), and the issue of externalities or spillovers that enhance the competitiveness of other parts of the domestic economy. Within market-rational/market-ideological economies like the United States, the pressures for adoption of a more strategic oriented policy emanate from a variety of interest groups (primarily specific industry and labor union lobbies) that may have a particular geographic dimension. Wade and Gates’s (1990) analysis of the 1987 vote in the House of Representatives on the Gephardt Amendment to the 1988 Omnibus Trade Act revealed a reordering of the historical regional divisions over trade policy. “Although the old industrial core in the North Atlantic and Great Lakes remains the most protectionist area, the once dependably liberal South now contains much stronger protectionist sentiment than was ever true in the past. And the historically protectionist West, particularly the Northwest, has displaced the South as the regional nucleus of liberal trade opinion in Congress” (Wade and Gates, 1990, p. 297). One of the diagnostic characteristics of the market-rational (and market- ideological) state is its concern with the regulatory structures in the economy. In such states, a marked feature of the past 10 to 15 years has been the drive toward the deregulation of specific sectors as a competitive weapon. As Cerny (1991) has perceptively observed, however, the process of deregulation is extremely complex; what is propounded as deregulation may actually involve re-regulation in a differ- ent form or at a different geographic or political scale. Each of these measures – from the piecemeal use of trade, industry, and foreign direct investment policies in market-rational/ideological states to their more coher- ent application in plan-rational states – reflects the diverse attempts by competition states to operate in the volatile environment of the global economy. States, like firms, pursue competitive strategies, although their strategic tool kits are, of course, some- what different. Another parallel between the competitive behavior of firms and states is that just as firms, especially TNCs, have shown an increasing propensity to enter into collaborative agreements with other firms, so, too, do many nation- states display the same collaborative propensity. As in the case of firms, interstate collaboration can range from the simple bilateral arrangement over a single issue to the complex collaborative network of a supranational economic bloc. Although there are many examples of supranational trading blocs in the global economy, most are relatively ineffectual and some are little more than paper agreements. Such groupings are essentially discriminatory and defensive. They represent an attempt 144 PETER DICKEN to gain advantages of size in trade and investment by creating large multinational markets for their domestic producers within a framework of protection. As such, they may either create or divert trade, and it is this latter potential that produces apprehension, and possible counteraction, by nonmembers. One of the major developments in the global economy in recent years has been the strengthening of supranational economic integration in two of the three “global triad” regions and at least the hint of a similar future development in the third. The trend toward increased supranational economic integration is a further aspect of the operation of the competition state. But there are political counterpressures allegedly at work in which increasing emphasis is being placed on the local and regional (i.e., subnational) level. Particularly in Europe, as the momentum toward European integration has increased, the calls for greater degrees of local/regional political and economic autonomy have also grown. The idea of a “Europe of the regions” rather than of nation-states has considerable currency in some quarters. The notion of a shift toward the “local economy,” or even the “local state,” is embedded in the idea of a transition from Fordism to post-Fordism, the new dynam- ics of flexible accumulation, and the alleged emergence of new industrial districts (Moulaert and Swyngedouw, 1989; Moulaert, Swyngedouw, and Wilson, 1988; A. J. Scott, 1988b). Suggestive as these ideas are of, on the one hand, a shift toward supranational integration or, on the other, a move toward greater local economic autonomy, they do not signify the demise of the nation-state as a significant global actor. There is a real need, as Gertler has argued, to “reinstate the nation-state”:

it should be pointed out that, in contrast to the rhetoric of free trade, countries will continue to retain many powers and markets will not be completely and unequivocally “opened up.” Although the more subtle powers to harmonize social and economic poli- cies across nations will be strong, the intensified competition expected to prevail will, if anything, enhance the importance of fostering a supportive national system for inno- vation. Consequently, it is difficult to see how the rise of supranational blocs will under- mine these particular powers of the nation-state. (Gertler, 1992, pp. 270–1)

Firm–State Interactions: Dynamic Bargaining Relationships The third element in the triangular nexus of international interactions is that between firms and states. This is not as straightforward as it may seem, because the actual processes and forms of firm–state interactions at an international scale are deeply intertwined with firm–firm and, especially, state–state interactions. For example, much of the friction between the United States and Japan is actually a dispute between firms, between states, and between states and firms as perceived agents of states. Similar to the situation in the 1960s, when the activities of United States TNCs were seen by many as being a direct extension of United States foreign policy, so today the behavior of Japanese firms is perceived (especially in the United States) as being part of a Japanese strategy of world dominance. The relationships between international firms and nation-states are a complex mixture of conflict and collaboration. The TNC seeks to maximize its freedom to locate its production chain GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 145 components in the most advantageous locations for the firm as a whole in its pursuit of global profits or global market share. At the same time, the individual state wishes to maximize its share of value-adding activity. As a result, the relationship between firms and states is inevitably an uneasy one (Gordon, 1988; Pitelis, 1991; Stopford and Strange, 1991). Firm–state interactions tend to differ according to whether the relationship is between a firm and its home country government or a host country government. This does not imply that the former relations are necessarily harmonious and the latter necessarily conflictual. Indeed, many bitter disputes between firms and states have occurred where a state fears that its “domestic” firms are shifting operations overseas or, conversely, where firms allege that their home country government pro- vides inadequate support against external competition. The position, therefore, is extremely complex. My basic position – contrary to that of Reich (1991) or Ohmae (1990) – is that a TNC’s domestic environment remains fundamentally important to how it oper- ates, notwithstanding the global extent of some firms’ operations. TNCs are not placeless; all have an identifiable home base, a base that ensures that every TNC is essentially embedded within its domestic environment. Of course, the more exten- sive a firm’s international operations, the more likely it will be to take on additional characteristics. Few, if any, major TNCs have moved their ultimate decision-making operations out of their country (often their community) of origin. The argument that, in effect, there is no longer any real relationship between a firm and its home base is, like many statements in the popular business literature, a considerable exag- geration. Of course, as organizational structures have changed, as hierarchies have “flattened,” as network forms have become increasingly significant, things are no longer as simple as they once were. Nevertheless, despite many decades of opera- tion as a TNC, Ford is still essentially a US company, ICI a British company, Siemens a German company. As Stopford and Strange (1991, p. 233) point out, “However great the global reach of their operations, the national firm does, psychologically and sociologically, ‘belong’ to its home base.” This is not to argue that TNCs necessarily retain a “loyalty” to the states in which they originated. The nature of the embeddedness process is far more complex and national economic welfare is no longer necessarily equated with the perform- ance of national companies (Reich, 1991; Tyson, 1993). But the point I am making is that TNCs are “produced” through a complex historical process of embedding (Dicken and Thrift, 1992), in which the cognitive, cultural, social, political, and economic characteristics of the national home base play a dominant part. TNCs, therefore, are “bearers” of such characteristics, which then interact with the place- specific characteristics of the countries in which they operate to produce a particu- lar outcome. But the point is that the home-base characteristics invariably remain dominant. This is not to claim that TNCs of a particular national origin are identical; this is self-evidently not the case – but, rather, to argue that there are greater similari- ties than differences among such firms. Insofar as the nation-state acts as a “con- tainer” of distinctive institutions and practices, it remains significant as an influence on the nature of the TNC. Whitley’s (1992a, 1992b) work on comparative business 146 PETER DICKEN systems is especially relevant. Whitley’s concern is to counteract the views of the “economic rationalists” that “competitive markets select efficient forms of business organizations and destroy inefficient ones . . . that underlying market pressures ensure that the firms which survive by competing successfully in international markets will converge to the same efficient structure, practices and strategic decisions which ‘fit’ particular technology and market imperatives” (Whitley, 1992a, p. 2). In contrast, Whitley develops the concept of the “business system,” which he defines as “particular arrangements of hierarchy market relations which become institutionalized and relatively successful in particular contexts” (1992a, p. 10). Whitley’s analysis, based upon a detailed multidimensional comparison of business systems in East Asia and in Europe, helps to explain international variation in firm structures and behavior, including, for example, the marked dif- ferences between Japanese (and other East Asian) business structures on the one hand and those found in the Anglo-Saxon and continental European systems on the other. It adds some depth to the ideal types of political economic system discussed in the previous section. Taken together, these concepts help to clarify our under- standing of the complex relationships between firms and their domestic environ- ments, as well as the conflictual economic relationships between firms and states. They illuminate such issues as different state attitudes toward their home firms, including the issue of the “national champion” (Amin, 1992; Reich, 1991) and the bases of such distinctive organizational forms as the Korean chaebol and the Japanese keiretsu. The persistence of distinctive business systems, organized pri- marily (although not exclusively) within national boundaries, is an important under- lying cause for the persistence of distinctive differences between TNCs of different national origins. The second aspect of firm–state interactions I want to address is the response of firms to state regulatory structures (Dicken, 1992b). For the TNC, the two most critical aspects of state regulatory policy are, first, access to markets and/or resources (including human resources) and, second, rules of operation for firms operating within particular national (or supranational) jurisdictions (Reich, 1989). An obvious assumption would be that TNCs will invariably seek the removal of all regulatory barriers that act as constraints and impede their ability to locate wherever, and to behave however, they wish. The ultimate preference for TNCs would seem to be removal of all barriers to entry; freedom to export capital and profits from local operations; freedom to import materials, components, and operate services; freedom to operate unhindered in local labor markets. Certainly, given the existence of dif- ferential regulatory structures in the global economy, TNCs will seek to overcome, circumvent, or subvert them. Regulatory mechanisms are, indeed, constraints on a TNC’s strategic and operational behavior. Yet it is not quite as simple as this. The very existence of regulatory structures may be perceived as an opportunity available to TNCs to take advantage of regu- latory differences between states by shifting activities between locations according to differentials in the regulatory surface – that is, to engage in regulatory arbitrage (Leyshon, 1992). One aspect of this is the propensity of TNCs to stimulate com- petitive bidding for their mobile investments by playing off one state against another as states strive to outbid their rivals to capture or retain a particular TNC activity GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 147

(Dicken, 1990; Encarnation and Wells, 1986; Guisinger, 1985; Glickman and Woodward, 1989). More generally, TNCs have a somewhat ambivalent attitude to state regulatory policies (Picciotto, 1991; Rugman and Verbeke, 1992; Yoffie and Milner, 1989). For example, Picciotto (1991) notes that

TNCs have favoured minimal international coordination while strongly supporting the national state, since they can take advantage of regulatory differences and loopholes . . . While TNCs have pressed for an adequate coordination of national regulation, they have generally resisted any strengthening of international state structures. . . . Having secured the minimalist principles of national treatment for foreign-owned capital, TNCs have been the staunchest defenders of the national state. It is their ability to exploit national differences, both politically and economically, that gives them their competitive advantage. (1991, pp. 43, 46)

Pitelis (1991) proposes that the relationship between TNCs and nation-states should be analyzed within a rivalry and collusion framework, arguing that “the degree of rivalry and collusion will depend heavily on whether the relationship refers to TNCs’ own states or ‘host’ states as well as whether the states in question are ‘strong’ or ‘weak,’ DCs or LDCs” (p. 142). Whether or not a particular situation is one of rivalry or collusion, the essence of the TNC–state relationship is one of overt or covert bargaining (Doz, 1986; Gabriel, 1966; Kobrin, 1987; Poynter, 1985; Stopford and Strange, 1991). As Nixson points out, “it is this process that in large part determines the extent, nature, and distribution between the participating agents of the costs and benefits that arise as a result of direct foreign investment” (1988, p. 318). Little progress has been made, however, in providing either a satisfactory conceptual or empirical basis for understanding these complex relational processes. Stopford and Strange (1991, pp. 134–6) are especially critical of the current litera- ture on bargaining processes in the international relations and international busi- ness literature. Part of the problem, of course, is that such bargaining is itself the complex outcome of a myriad of negotiating and bargaining processes within both firms and states as different interest groups and stakeholders themselves attempt to influence the larger-scale bargaining position. Virtually all the relevant research into TNC–state bargaining relationships has focused on only one set of relationships, those between TNCs and host governments. In such circumstances, the outcome will be a function of the interaction between three elements: (1) the relative demand by each party for resources which the other controls; (2) the constraints on each that affect the translation of potential bargaining power into control over resources; and (3) the negotiating status of the participants involved. It is important to emphasize that the nature of the bargaining process and of the outcome will probably differ according to which part of the production chain is involved. The bargaining stakes on both sides will be much higher for the scarcer, high value-adding functions than for the more ubiquitous functions. Ultimately, however, as Gabriel states so succinctly,

The price which the receiving country will ultimately pay is a function of (1) the number of foreign firms independently competing for the investment opportunity; (2) the 148 PETER DICKEN

recognized measure of uniqueness of the foreign contribution (as against its possible provision by local entrepreneurship, public or private); (3) the perceived degree of domestic need for the contribution. The terms the foreign investor will accept, on the other hand, depend on his [sic] general need for an investment outlet; (2) the attrac- tiveness of the specific investment opportunity offered by the host country compared to similar or other opportunities in other countries; (3) the extent of prior commit- ment to the country concerned (e.g. an established market position). (Gabriel, 1966, p. 114)

The problem, of course, is that the whole process is dynamic; the bargaining rela- tionship changes over time. In most studies of state–TNC bargaining the conven- tional wisdom is that of the so-called obsolescing bargain, in which, after the initial investment, the balance of bargaining power shifts from the TNC to the host gov- ernment. This is the situation found most commonly in natural resource-based investments in developing countries. It is less certain, however, that such a rela- tionship will apply in sectors in which technological change is rapid and/or where global integration of operations is the norm (Kobrin, 1987). Even in the case of TNC–host country relationships the current state of research is far from adequate; in the case of bargaining between TNCs and home countries the literature is even sparser.

Conclusion: The Global–Local Debate Revisited The thread running throughout this paper has been the fact that, within a volatile competitive environment, both firms and states as competitive institutions are subject to fundamental global–local tensions. But precisely what is meant by “global” and “local” is itself problematical and has different meanings for firms, and states. To the firm, the global–local tension is expressed as the question of whether to “globalize” or to “localize” or whether to strive to combine the two in a stance of “global localization.” In this case, “local” generally means “national”; the issues are those of the autonomy and responsiveness of national components of the international firm. From the nation-state perspective, the global–local problem- atic means something rather different. The pressures toward certain kinds of puta- tive supranational organization at one extreme are counterpoised against a pressure toward greater degrees of local political autonomy at the other. The current debates within the European Community around the issue of “subsidiarity” are a reflection of this, as are the growing demands of local states for greater independence. But it is the interaction between international firms and nation-states that gives the global–local problematic a particular twist. To the international firm, the division of the global political map along nation-state boundaries, with the extent of market and factor differentiation this implies, constitutes the major pressure to be sensitive to local differences even while pursuing a global strategy. To the nation-state, the international firm is one of the major channels through which globalizing forces are directed. The relationship between TNCs and states (at whatever level) is, self-evidently, a power relationship. There is little doubt that, in general terms, the relative power of TNCs and states has shifted, but the position is far less straightforward than has GLOBAL–LOCAL TENSIONS 149 often been supposed. In view of the complexity and degree of contingency of the bargaining process, it is difficult to make broad generalizations about the relative “balance of power” between TNCs and states. There is no doubt that in some areas, most notably that of financial policy, states have become increasingly less able to determine, with impunity, such things as the external value of their currencies. The development of a global financial system, facilitated by electronic trading mecha- nisms, has vastly increased the exposure of state financial policies to external specu- lative forces. Some very unwise generalizations have been made over the years, however, which have been used to write the premature obituary of the nation-state. In contrast, Stopford and Strange’s view is that

governments as a group have indeed lost bargaining power to the multinationals. . . . Does it follow that firms as a group have increased their bargaining power over the factors of production? Here, the argument becomes complex, for the power of the indi- vidual firm may be regarded as having also fallen as competition has intensified. New entrants have altered the rules and offer governments new bargaining advantage. One needs to separate the power to influence general policy from the power to insist on specific bargains. (Stopford and Strange, 1991, pp. 215–16)

It is this issue of the “specific bargain” that is most relevant to the question of what the processes discussed in this paper mean for the “really seriously local,” the local community or region currently being buffeted by the stormy seas of global economic change. The problem facing the local community, in the global scheme of things, is that it is relatively powerless except in very specific circumstances (for example, where it possesses a unique or scarce resource that gives it some leverage). The idea that the transformations that are occurring in the organization of production systems (notably the growth of network organizations and relationships) will auto- matically lead to a general enhancement of local economic opportunity and well- being is a pipe dream. The evidence that changes in customer–supplier relations (both inside and outside the firm) will lead to greater local integration is mixed. As McGrath and Hoole (1992) show, global sourcing is far from dead. It is certainly true that customer– supplier relationships do involve a greater emphasis on long-term, closer relation- ships based upon a high level of mutual trust and that this may be facilitated by geographical proximity. Firms are, however, increasingly operating an upper tier of preferred suppliers that are closely integrated at all stages of the production process, from design to final production. For any one firm, such preferred suppliers are relatively few in number and unevenly distributed geographically. Not every local economy, therefore, can hope to participate in the new integrated networks (Amin, 1992; Amin and Malmberg, 1992). Ultimately, therefore, it may be that, because of the immense asymmetry of power between TNCs and local institutions, there is little that such institutions can do on their own other than to provide an attractive business environment or to attempt to stimulate the kinds of local businesses that might eventually be embedded in a TNC network. Although much depends on the extent to which a national political system is centralized or decentralized, virtually all effective bar- gaining power lies not at the local level but at the national level or, in cases like the 150 PETER DICKEN

European Community, at a supranational level. To that degree, therefore, the prospects of local economies will be influenced as much, if not more, by national policies as by local actions. Within the global–local nexus, the key interactions, in a power sense, remain at the level of the TNC and the nation-state; in that respect, the “seriously local” is a serious problem whose solution requires a broader policy framework. Chapter 10 The Politics of Relocation: Gender, Nationality, and Value in a Mexican Maquiladora

M. W. Wright

To study changes in corporate decision-making is also to consider the processes for forming social relations and culturally constructed understandings which influ- ence patterns of authority, status, and the meanings of value (Schoenberger, 1997). For example, when emphasis lies on cutting labor costs and enhancing worker pro- ductivity, corporate decision-makers often rank the human resources found in dif- ferent places by correlating certain identities, such as national and gendered ones, with labor skills, innate abilities, and militancy, to name a few features. These methods for comparing the intrinsic traits of one pool of labor against another located in another place reveal how human resources are understood and evaluated through dynamic processes of social construction inside the firm. In this paper my argument rests on the assumption that corporate managers have, as a group, social power for connecting certain kinds of people with the produc- tion of certain kinds of value in the firm. However, their power in the class struc- ture of a capitalist workplace is not independent of the other social relations of power, such as gender and race, that contribute to the formation of hierarchical dif- ferences among people within a particular context. In elaborating this assumption, I attempt to illustrate how the managers of a multinational maquiladora establish patterns for correlating the national and sex differences which they identify among their employees with the manufacture of valuable goods. By concentrating on these two social characteristics, I do not intend to imply that others, especially age, race, and wellness, are not of issue in the workplace I explore. Rather, in narrowing my focus to the interplay of nationality, gender, and value, I show that the production of valuable commodities is a social process interwoven with the social construction of differential values in people, and that this process has an impact upon the inter- nal structure of the firm. This sort of argument emerges from a theoretical dialogue between Marx’s cri- tique of the labor theory of value and a poststructuralist feminist emphasis on the productive power behind establishing social identities and their differences (see also Joseph, 1998). Through his critique of capital, Marx reveals a visceral connection linking the manufacture of commodities with the conceptualization of people as 152 M. W. WRIGHT embodiments of a specific value which can be transferred to inanimate objects that no longer belong to them. The value of the capitalist good depends upon an ability to imagine people also in terms of value. However, as feminist scholars across dis- ciplines have shown, a strict class analysis limits any inquiry into the complex con- nections binding the value of things to the people who make them (Kondo, 1990; McDowell, 1997; J. Scott, 1988b). They emphasize how the evaluation of a worker’s value to the firm rests upon discourses that regulate the interpretation of the meaning of that worker as a social subject. The performance of work is not inde- pendent of one performance, say, as a gendered, sexualized, and raced subject, as the value of one’s work emerges through lenses bent on interpreting the value of one’s other features. For this reason, in my study of the politics of relocation within a multinational maquila, I combine a Marxist with a poststructuralist feminist approach to explore how the vicissitudes of value found in people can complicate corporate managers’ habits of finding value in their products. A disruption to their historical patterns of recognizing value in people and in the things they make is enough, at least in my estimation of what happened in the case I explore, to justify their costly decision to relocate a critical operation out of Mexico and back to the USA. The material for my argument originates with a ten-month ethnographic project I conducted between 1993 and 1994 in the maquiladora which I shall refer to as Mexico On the Water (MOTW). This facility represents the Mexican location of a multinational US firm, On the Water (OTW), which manufactures motors, boats, and other water-sporting equipment in operations located in Asia, Europe, South America, and in the USA. MOTW set up shop in Ciudad Juarez in the early years of maquiladora development. It was the first maquila actively to seek male employ- ees at least a decade before it was deemed necessary to compensate for a shortage of female workers in the local labor market. In an interview conducted in 1992, the first General Manager of MOTW had explained that he intentionally excluded women from the labor force: “This is a tool shop, and the girls out here are not the right kind of worker for what we do. Our products are men’s products, and I think the men, here or anywhere, understand the work better.” In the early, 1990s, however, MOTW expanded its operation to include electronic assembly and began hiring women. This transition raised some harrowing challenges for the MOTW managers. At MOTW, I studied how managers faced the challenge of producing quality goods with labor which they understood to be lacking in quality. This challenge takes on a particularly gendered and national dimension. These managers need to produce goods for a market which places a premium on American masculinity, a marker of quality in MOTW, and they evaluate their goods in terms of whether they reflect this desired condition. Yet, the MOTW managers attempted to accom- plish their goal with laborers who, in their view, represented the opposite of this valuable masculine American condition. In an apparently contradictory move, they had hired Mexican women for a particular new operation specifically because these employees continue to be broadly construed as “dexterous,” “patient,” and “docile” enough to work under the exigencies of electronic assembly (Salzinger, 1997). At the same time, these women are also widely recognized throughout the industry as “cheap,” “unprofessional,” and not worth the trouble to train (Wright, 1997). The THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 153 hiring of such workers signified a shift at MOTW from a factory with a purposely male labor force to one with a sizeable proportion of women. And this transition played havoc with their well-worn customs for recognizing value in MOTW products, peoples, and in the spaces of production that ultimately contributed to decisions about corporate location.

Theoretical Dialogues In my inquiry into what was at stake when MOTW began hiring women I rely on a Marxist critique of the social construction of value in a capitalist setting. Capital, says Marx, is not concerned with producing just any kinds of things, but of par- ticular things that embody value. This value can only be seen, recognized, and, in effect, valorized under the particular circumstances for evaluating different people as embodiments of a similar kind of value calculated as a condition of their labor. Marxist scholars have elaborated on Marx’s critique of the capitalist labor theory of value to emphasize the importance of understanding that the issue is not only about the construction of value in things, but also about its construction in the people who make those things. As David Harvey has put it:

“The paradox to be understood is how the freedom and transitoriness . . . of living labor as a process is objectified in a fixity of both things and exchange ratios between things.” (1982, p. 23)

With this statement, Harvey pushes us to ask how the myriad energies that people express in their activities and in their thoughts can be understood as the conditions of a similar kind of value, which lends itself to quantification and qualification of a trait found in inanimate things. Thus, this is a process for viewing people as well as objects. Feminist scholar Diane Elson emphasizes how this sort of question involves “seeking an understanding of why labour takes the form it does, and [asking] what are the political consequences” (1979, p. 23, my parentheses). These Marxian concerns are germane to my analysis, as the question that inter- ests me here is not why Mexican women are paid so little for their labor but, instead, why does cheap labor assume a female Mexican form. How does a Mexican woman’s labor take on a cheap fixity, and what is at stake in this transformation? Yet even though I formulate this question with these Marxian critiques in mind, I cannot approach them from a strictly Marxist viewpoint. Feminist scholars have shown that any evaluation of labor as something of value courses through an evaluation of the different kinds of people who embody different properties of labor (Hanson and Pratt, 1988; Pratt, 1990; Rose, 1993). These feminist interventions have forced us to address how the historical constitution of women and racial minorities as laborers of inferior degrees of value have underscored the long-held industrial traditions of paying them less and of not recognizing the skill in what they do. Taking these feminist interventions as a point of departure, I rely upon a par- ticular kind of feminist scholarship to explore the dilemmas raised by Harvey (1982) and Elson (1979), in relation to certain events at MOTW. Of specific interest to me is Judith Butler’s poststructuralist views on materialization: she argues that the social 154 M. W. WRIGHT construction of the subject is not an end in itself (1993, 1997). Instead, the con- structed subject contributes to a productive continuum, in which the particular iden- tity of the subject is both a product and a producer. The subject is a thing with reverberating productive effects that do not necessarily travel in one particular direc- tion. So, although I look at the social construction of the Mexican woman as the living standard for low-quality production in an American maquila, I do not view this construction of her as a terminus for productive flows. Rather, as the embodi- ment of low quality, she produces low quality if traces of her are found in the things she makes. In other words, she is not simply marked as a paragon of low value, she marks other things as the bearers of low value. And within the historical MOTW framework for manufacturing quality boat parts, her image as the low-value laborer extends to all products that bear her mark. The trick, therefore, for MOTW man- agers, is to guarantee that she disappears from the things that she makes. When they fail in this endeavor, they prefer to ship out the product line rather than risk devaluation. In what follows, I present my material juxtaposing my observations with con- versations and interviews conducted over a protracted period of time. The ethno- graphy amplifies the ambiguous details behind the decisions which managers explain as cost-saving or market-enhancing treasures. In the firm I explore here, I had an office located in the administrative area where I was granted unlimited access to meetings, files, and to employees as much as they would tolerate my inquiries. Through conversations and more formal interviews, my informants exposed the politicized negotiations over the meanings of the very categories which are factors in the assessments of corporate efficiency and cost effectiveness, especially with regard to the assessment of people as some kind of valuable resource. Instead, I focus on how managers describe their laborers, with an eye to understanding how their own evaluations of people and the kinds of value they embody and manufac- ture affect their decisions governing the internal structure of the firm.

Making American Even though MOTW is a Mexican subsidiary of its parent corporation, the corpo- rate literature reinforces the idea that not only is MOTW an American business, but that all MOTW products are American, no matter where they are produced. The authors of one of the official biographies of the company chronicle “the progress of this American institution” from the patriotic application of OTW tech- nology, motors, and boats in US war efforts, to MOTW’s commitment to support- ing the US sportsman tradition, and to fighting Japanese “incursions” into the global market. The General Manager of MOTW operations, Steve, explained: “This is an American company to the core.” To visualize the Americanness of this Mexican sub- sidiary, I will begin with the spatial layout of the facility. Within the spatial rela- tions of production, we find determined efforts to buttress the functioning of an American system and the production of unmistakably American things by Mexican laborers. MOTW consists of two facilities: plants I and II, each with its own production manager, engineering, and American-led supervisory teams who oversee 42 pro- duct lines and almost 800 Mexican employees. A Human Resources Manager, THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 155

Materials Manager, and Engineering Manager are responsible for the operations of both facilities and answer to the General Manager, who is the primary liaison with clients and other corporate offices. The MOTW administrative area is separated from the production area by a solid wooden door, which is guarded by a security officer who prevents unauthorized individuals from passing into the administrative interior. Inside this protected space, English is the dominant language. As Roger, the Production Manager of the Plant II facility said to me: “This is an American company, so you’ve got to expect the administration to be English-speaking.” The production area, by contrast, is a world of Spanish, where the bulk of MOTW’s employees, who are monolingual Spanish speakers, work. However, managers explain that, even though the vast majority of MOTW’s pro- duction employees are Mexican, the factory is American by virtue of American control over the labor process. “This is the brains of the operation,” the former General Manager told me when describing the administrative area, “we control everything from here.” The people in charge are to be American at all times, as is reflected in the corporation’s policy which does not allow for any Mexican to hold a position of authority over an American: “You would expect the top people to be American employees here,” said Burt, the Manager of Plant I; “We make American products and we need people who understand that.” Corporate policy mandates that all those in management-positions at MOTW be either US citizens or possess a US green card and reside in US territory. Therefore any nonnative US citizen must apply for residency and a green card and pay taxes to the US government in order to qualify for a promotion into management. As a result, a Mexican national promoted into management is, for all intents and pur- poses, an American employee. Under these rules, it is thus impossible for a Mexican employee to wield corporate authority over an American one. And in those cases where an American and a Mexican employee share the same title, the American employee receives higher wages and supervises the Mexican supervisor. Under- standing the national border within the corporation’s division of labor is key for individual career strategies in a place where to “Americanize” is to climb and to “Mexicanize” is to descend the social ladder of power and prestige (see Wright, 1998). When I asked Steve, the General Manager, if he thought the company would ever have Mexican managers – that is managers who were classified as Mexican per- sonnel – he replied: “If we ever try to get into the Mexican market, sure. But as long as we’re selling these boats in America, I don’t see it happening.” Within the logic internal to MOTW, there was a connection linking the national identities of MOTW employees with the marketability of MOTW goods. Even though all labor is technically absorbed in the product, and thereby made invisible according to Marx, the identity of this labor is brought to the surface through marketing strate- gies that emphasize national content such as “Made in America.” MOTW pro- ducts, in the end, bear the mark “Made in America,” the boat and engines undergo final assembly for the US market in the United States. Steve and the other MOTW managers, however, felt a need to guarantee that the internal operations of the factory did not disrupt the identification of MOTW products as American made. The labor itself might be invisible, but its social identity is part and parcel of the process for manufacturing value. For this reason, any identifiable traces of female 156 M. W. WRIGHT

Mexican labor within MOTW goods were especially dangerous according to MOTW managers.

The Invisible MOTW Women Whereas the “Americanization” of the product is assured by the American brains behind its manufacture, the masculinity of the product is protected by the mas- culinization of the labor process. On my first tour of MOTW in 1992, the then- General Manager, Bob, guided me through the carburetor-assembly area, which he called “the heart” of the operation, which dominates the one large room in Plant I, and then through the “computer numerical control” area that dominates the space in the other part of the building. We observed engineers at their computers and desks, and we walked through the painting section that was soon to be transferred out of the facility. With the exception of the secretarial staff, all of the employees I saw were men. And it was not until the following year, when I began my ethno- graphic study, that I discovered the women, who then composed about 35% of the production labor force and worked behind the male labor processes. Off in the corners and against the back walls they assembled ignition switches, horns, drive shafts, and fuel systems. They cut and spliced wires and manufactured gauges for dashboards. When I asked the Manager of Plant I, Burt, in 1994, why the former General Manager had not shown me those female work areas, he said, “Bob was proud of our carburetor and tooling operations. We were the first maquila to have those type of operations and to be successful ...We have the girls in electronic assembly but that’s not what we’re known for.” The spatial arrangement of male and female workspaces successfully squirreled the women out of view and away from the “heart” of MOTW production. This spatial practice both revealed and embraced a managerial discourse of MOTW as a “man’s shop,” while the women worked invisibly behind dust-proof doors and against rear walls to fashion the “incidentals” of motor-boat production. The current General Manager, Steve, explained: “We think of ourselves as a tool shop. And across the industry the belief is that men are better at this work than females. It’s a macho place. No doubt about it.” Such explanations contributed to a representation pervasive through the maquilas of the Mexican woman as (a) especially suited for unskilled electronic assembly of low-end goods, and (b) particularly unsuited for engineering work, skilled jobs, or any tasks deemed “physical” (Salzinger, 1997). Still, in 1993 women were already putting together many of MOTW products, and by 1997 about half of the 800 pro- duction workers were women – a shift having to do with the other pervasive con- struction of Mexican women as dexterous and innately deft with tedious hair-splitting tasks. Roger, the Manager of Plant II, said, in 1994, “Things are defi- nitely changing here. Plant II is mainly electronic work, and we’ve just got that going over the last three years. That means we’re hiring more female workers because they’re good at this work.” Steve said, “I think when we decided to put the electronic operations down here it was because we knew that women in Mexico had experience with electrical assembly. And it made more sense to do it here for a lot less money than we were doing it in Europe or in the US.” The Human THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 157

Resource Manager, Rosalia, explained that MOTW actively pursued female workers for the electrical assembly operations: “Women here are very good with electrical assembly. They have more patience and are better with their hands,” she told me. The hiring of women to work in electrical assembly raised a paradox for the managers of MOTW. Although their labor process had shifted from a purely “man’s tool shop” to one including “women’s” electrical assembly work, the product, a decidedly man’s product, had not changed. When I asked Steve if he thought OTW customers knew that Mexican women were assembling some of their products, he said, “No, and it’s my job to make sure they don’t find out.” The social construc- tion of Mexican women as naturally suited for electronic assembly did not shift their construction as not suited for making MOTW products. If anything, it intensified the managerial conviction that their control over the labor process was even more critical. Now they would not only have to concern themselves with the Americanization of the product, they would also have to supervise its masculinization. This challenge can be seen in light of the twofold problem raised by the social constructions of MOTW products and of Mexican women as entities of contrast- ing values. First, the process of social construction is never complete. In order for MOTW products to be seen as “American” and “masculine” they had continually to be seen as the opposite of “Mexican” and “feminine.” This process gained backing from managerial efforts to explain that the value in MOTW products was other than the typical value found in electronic feminized maquila production. As the managers reiterated how their products were of a superior caliber compared with an assembly-line television, they repeatedly emphasized how those products associated with female Mexican labor were of inferior quality and value, as opposed to the masculine ones emerging from MOTW. Second, and related to the first problem, the construction of the Mexican women as incapable of producing masculine value also exercises a productive effect. As Judith Butler (1993) argues, there is no reference to a body that is not, at the same time, a further production of that body. It can then be said, in the case of labor, that there is no reference to someone’s labor power (that is, what is exchanged for wages) without further producing a quality of his or her labor. As a result, to view the Mexican woman as naturally adept with electronic assembly and cheap because she has no skills, is at once a construction of her labor as cheap, even as its cheap- ness generates more wealth for capital. The trick is to take advantage of cheap labor power without jeopardizing the value of the product. At MOTW, this challenge means guaranteeing that no evidence of Mexican women is found in the things that they make. The value of their labor power resides both in its cheapness and in its disappearance from MOTW’s quality products. The complexities underlying this task become clear in the following elaboration of gauge production at MOTW. In this case, we shall see how concerns over the inner workings and outer marking of the Mexican woman’s body lead to fears that Mexican women, in electronic assembly, are infiltrating the male spaces of MOTW production and authority and, thereby, threatening the masculine products and the masculine firm with contamination and devaluation. 158 M. W. WRIGHT

The Gauges The events surrounding the short-lived gauge-production operation at MOTW reveal the contradictions inherent to manufacturing a product of high quality with a labor process full of low-quality people. And this transformation absorbed man- agers from its beginning. Gauge production is a critical operation, with ramifica- tions for client safety and the overall esthetic appeal of the boat. This critical operation had been sent to Mexico from one of the US facilities after Steve, the General Manager, won what he called “a bloody turf battle” with his counterpart in MOTW’s China facility. Questions were raised over whether the Mexico facility could handle the task. Steve convinced them that, under his watch, gauges would be up to standard: “My neck is on the line,” he told me. MOTW sought young women for this operation. Rosalia explained: “The younger girls have flexible hands. This area involves a lot of work with fine wires and small pieces.” However, expectations for these young women’s careers were not high. “I don’t think many of them will be here for a long time,” Rosalia continued, “Most will come and go. They will start families. These aren’t the workers who have the discipline to learn and go through training. That’s how it is in the maquilas with electrical assembly. It’s not the workers who really want to learn and improve themselves.” MOTW brought in a female American supervisor, Mary, to work with these “unskilled” and nonambitious “girls” to produce the quality-sensitive gauges. MOTW had another woman supervisor in the horn and ignition assembly areas, located against the back wall of Plant I, but Mary was to be the first woman to super- vise a “critical” area. Like the other American supervisors, Mary was Mexican- American, bilingual, and had previous experience in manufacturing. When she accepted this position she came out of retirement after a twenty-year career as a super- visor in a clothing maquila. Steve explained why they hired her: “She had experience with sewing operations and had a good reputation. And we knew that this operation would have mainly females because it is electronic assembly.” “I always like a chal- lenge,” Mary told me as she described why she came out of her brief stint as a “full- time grandmother” helping her daughter with childcare, “My family is a working family.” In the summer of 1993, Mary returned to the maquila labor force. “They told me I would be in a sensitive area. That our quality would have to be very good. I knew I was working with young kids. ...You always do in the maquilas.” Her job was to supervise 35 employees, mostly women in their late teens and early twenties, in the start up of the gauge-production line. The making of gauges entails a painstaking inspection process. Almost half of the workers were inspectors of some sort. They either tested product functions, inspected for paint consistency, or ran durability tests. The production line began when an automatic winder wrapped fine copper wire tightly around a bobbin; this would then be tested for current flow and placed in a housing, after which more wires would be attached, more tests run, and then the painted dial face connected. Only two operators had the delicate task of stamping on the dial face – a process requiring a steady hand and unwavering attention to detail. Two more inspection steps preceded the sealing of the gauge, which was followed by a final test before they would be packaged and shipped to the final assembly plant in Georgia. THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 159

Isolated behind the dust-proof doors and in a windowless room, the laborers in gauge production did their work beyond the notice of the rest of the facility. “I guess you could walk around this plant,” said Roger, “and never know those girls are back there.” And Mary had explicit instructions not to allow the workers to leave their area without permission, and to stagger restroom breaks so that no more than one worker left the area at a time. All of the gauge workers wore gender- distinguished uniforms, and all the women had to cover their hair completely with hair nets – a policy which was only sporadically enforced for the few men in the area. Men wore the nets like caps, over the top of their heads, whereas the women pulled the nets completely down to their necks. Mary explained this preoccupation over women’s hair: “Well they’re all supposed to wear the nets. But we let the guys just sort of stick them on top ‘cause it bothers them more. They don’t want the girls’ long hair getting in the paint or in the wires. It’s the girls we worry about the most.” This heightened attention to evidence of femininity, such as long hair and miniskirts, extended to other body parts as well. Mary described the policies regard- ing female appearance: “The girls can’t wear fingernail polish . . . and we don’t want pregnant girls in here. The fumes aren’t good for them.” Indeed, as in many maquilas, a policy both for refusing to hire pregnant women and for encouraging those who became pregnant to leave their job was tacitly enforced, although such practices violate federal legislation, prohibiting discrimination on the basis of preg- nancy. “We all know we’re not supposed to hire pregnant girls. It’s that way in all the maquilas,” said Mary. Roger, Manager of Plant II, echoed the sentiment behind these practices when he said: “We don’t want pregnant women here. It’s not good for the company and it’s not good for them.” Consequently, the young women who worked in MOTW gauge production and who were subject to the practices concentrating on control of their hair, their nails, their clothing choice, and their wombs as they manufactured gauges in the back room of Plant II, also reinforced the traditional gendered pattern for delineating the social hierarchy of the MOTW division of labor. According to the payrolls of MOTW, the women in electronic assembly and gauge production received the lowest wage rates and, over time, had the highest turnover rate. Ramon, a supervisor in carburetors said: “The girls in electronic assembly are important but individually not as important as the guys out here. We need to work with them and try to keep them. The girls come for some experience and then leave when they want a family.” Training, in short, is wasted on them. This view of the female employees as not worth training and as likely to leave because of their personal circumstances, rather than because they are not offered wage and training incentives, again reinforces a discourse, pervasive in the maquilas, of the inferior value of the female worker’s labor. Mary had to work with this assumption that training for women in electronic assembly was not warranted. “They put me in with a roomful of girls who didn’t have any experience and expected us to do it right the first time,” she said. “That’s the problem, they want American quality, without the time.” Steve explained: “I expected a slower system, but the quality needs to be up to standard. This is an American operation . . . and it’s Mary’s responsibility to make it work.” 160 M. W. WRIGHT

Female Contamination In October 1994, after three months of production, almost two of every three gauges were defective and, making matters worse, demand for gauges was at a high as the company readied for the holiday season. Steve was receiving calls on an almost daily basis from his client – the final production assembly plant in Georgia – to discuss the gauges and predictions for a resolution of the problems. He in turn called meet- ings with Mary and her immediate boss, Roger. “We’re shipping out Mexican product,” he said in one such meeting, “And that’s got to change.” Mary explained that the problem lay in technological systems and in the lack of training. “It’s too much to learn and get good at in two months,” she exclaimed in one meeting. In order to “make an American operation out of this,” to use Roger’s words, they agreed to take the following measures. Roger would tell maintenance that gauges were top priority and Mary would work overtime until things were back on track; within ten days, however, Steve was informed that not only was MOTW still shipping what he would call “Mexican” quality, but that also the lack of accept- able gauges had idled almost 100 workers in the Georgia facility. “I won’t be shut- ting down Georgia!” he announced. By this time, Mary and the operators in her area were putting in 50 to 60 hours in a 6-day, and occasionally 7-day, work week. After a month of overtime in an anxious climate, the operators started to quit. In one week alone, Mary lost more than half of her employees and was spending more time on training new hires than anything else. One operator, an eighteen-year-old woman who had worked at MOTW for about six weeks, said: “We’re killing our- selves in here. . . . They’re always yelling at us and telling us that we’re not doing it right. But they don’t even give us time to learn how to do it.” Mary asked Steve for some more time to bring the workers up to speed and to lessen the pressure on everyone: “I’ve got more new workers than old ones,” she said “And it’s hard to teach them what to do and get everything out.” Steve explained the impossibility of more time. “At this point,” he said, “we don’t have any time.” He and the other managers repeatedly stressed the reasonableness of their expectation that Mexican women ought to be able to pick up this work with little training as this was the kind of work that comes naturally to women. As Burt said, “These girls do electrical assembly all the time.” Mary, exasperated with her bosses’ refusal to allow her more training time, decided to take matters into her own hands. She made some de facto amendments to the work rules in the gauge area as a way of introducing some flexibility into the labor process while still expecting overtime from the workers. “I had to do some- thing, or everyone would have left,” she told me. Without her managers’ authority, she immediately relaxed the uniform requirements. Everybody still had to wear the smocks, although she did not object to the women wearing male smocks, which some found more comfortable, and she allowed workers to remove their hairnets as long as their hair was pulled back. “Those things itch,” she said, “and after a few hours you’re ready to tear them off.” She promised coffee and donuts for every- one on Saturdays and announced that anybody working on weekends could work a half day during the week without losing their production or attendance bonuses. They simply had to arrange with her in advance which day they should take. She THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 161 also took measures to relax the working environment by allowing them to bring in music and by loosening rules governing restroom and water breaks. Over the next couple of weeks, the turnover rate stabilized and the defect rate improved. Mary was optimistic: “You can’t ask these kids to put in six or seven- day weeks without a break . . . Things got better right away.” Although they were not completely out of the woods, the crisis had seemed to pause. The Georgia operation was back in business, and calls had slowed as more gauges were passing the inspection tests of their clients. Mary was not being sum- moned for daily emergency meetings. And Steve told her: “Whatever you’re doing is working.” However, he would soon change his mind even though, by Georgia’s standards, products were continually improving. One morning, in a private meeting, the Human Resource Manager, Rosalia, alerted Steve to the fact that things were getting “out of control” in the gauge area. She was concerned that Mary’s tampering with the attendance schedules would disrupt the attendance and punctuality policies of the company, introducing Mexican chaos into their professional American system. “This is not a Mexican ,” she said, “She can’t just change it around when it’s convenient.” Steve decided that he would talk with Mary about the attendance policy on the following Saturday, when she came in for an overtime shift. “I agreed with Rosalia, we have to stick with policy. We need to follow the rules like any American company, but I didn’t think it was an emergency.” What he encountered, however, when he went to speak with Mary in the gauge area on Saturday morning, shocked him: “I thought I’d walked into a Mexican fiesta,” he said, “The only thing missing was a pinata.” According to Steve, after he pushed through the set of dust-proof doors sepa- rating the gauge area from the rest of the plant, he saw women talking loudly and walking around the work area with no apparent regard for their work stations. Music, he said, was blaring from a jam box next to the empty donut box located atop a work table. Mary, he said, “looked just like a Mexican grandmother.” His American supervisor was beginning to look femininely Mexican in his eyes. Steve described his alarm at the next Tuesday rooming staff meeting: “I don’t know what she’s doing in there, but there are girls running around everywhere. And they want to bring their children . . . There’s no telling how many babies those girls have.” Mary described the scene in this way: “Steve came in ready to jump all over me for not telling Rosalia about our scheduling changes and then he has a heart attack because I told him that one of the girls had asked to bring her baby on Saturdays.” She had not let her. During the staff meeting, concerns over the gauge area shifted from the quality of the product, as it was measured by performance tests, to apparent loss of control by American managers over Mexican females. They agreed that the product was sure to suffer. Burt said that they could not “tolerate” a “Mexican occupation” of the gauge room. Roger raised the issue of fingernail polish. “Some of those girls wear fingernail polish,” he said, “Just what we need is a call [from corporate head- quarters] asking how purple fingernail polish gets into the gauges.” They discussed the dangers of not enforcing the hairnet policy. Roger was sure that hair would slip into the paint and said: “We should just stamp ‘Made in Mexico’ across the 162 M. W. WRIGHT speedometer.” They talked about the significance of allowing female operators to wear male uniforms. They voiced doubt over the prudence of allowing the workers to roam the main areas without supervision. And they agreed that, given how things were going, it was only a matter of time before Mary would let someone bring their baby to work. “That’s a liability issue,” said Steve, “We’re not in the day-care busi- ness.” Burt summed up the meeting by saying: “The thing that bothers me is that we don’t know what type of product they’re putting together in there. Now that’s a problem.” Throughout this meeting, no one mentioned that, as far as their client was con- cerned, the product was approaching corporate standard. The managers, however, were alarmed over the quality of their gauges, not because of the performance of the gauges in inspection tests, but because they feared that the telltale traces of Mexican women could be identified in them. They made the connection between seeing women roaming the workspaces and relaxing their uniform standards and a loss of managerial control over the labor process. Their lack of control, in turn, meant that the product would not emerge as planned, but instead as a product of undisciplined female and Mexican labor. Steve implied this connection when he said “What I don’t want is for someone . . . to walk in this plant and find a bunch of Mexican girls running around . . . I’ll hear that we’re going Mexican on them and our product going to hell.” The root of the problem, they decided, was that Mary was not “American” enough to “Americanize” the labor process, and was not disciplined enough to keep the feminine influence within its proper bounds. Roger was assigned the task of speaking firmly to Mary about the situation and of advising her that she was being placed on probation. According to Roger, he was trying to be as diplomatic as he could when he told Mary that she needed to “represent the corporation out there” and perform her job to the standards of “American professional behavior.” He said, “I told her that we were worried about the product.” Mary was furious. She said, “I told him (Roger), ‘I am as American as you are’. I can’t believe he said that to me. I know he’s saying that I’m not up to their stan- dards. That’s what it means when they say something is ‘Mexican’.” Soon there- after, the managers decided to demote Mary for being, as Roger recorded on her evaluation form, “unprofessional,” “failing in the performance of duties,” and not producing quality product. In addition, they demanded that she attend three hours of supervisory-training classes offered by the University of Texas El Paso every week on top of the overtime she was continuing to perform. He also denied her a routine salary inflation compensation. Mary’s demotion put her on equal footing with the other Mexican supervisors. She was the only American supervisor who worked under the supervision of another supervisor. Mary begrudgingly attended the super- visor classes. “It’s an insult,” she said, “they’re putting me in there to humiliate me. As far as I can see, they’re the ones who aren’t being very American. You know they want top quality work without paying for it or even giving enough time for training. And then they turn around say it’s because Mexican females don’t do good work.” On the heels of her demotion and salary cut, and with mounting evidence that Mary would not mend her attitudes, the managers decided to fire her. When I asked Roger why the managers focused so much on Mary’s supervisory style rather than THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 163 on the obvious improvements, according to performance tests, she made in pro- duction he said: “We want a good product. That’s what this is about really. It’s a long-term issue ...We’re an American operation. We’ve got an American pro- duct . . . Mary doesn’t understand.” Shortly after Mary’s departure, the gauge- production line was returned to a US facility. The politics over Mary’s supervisory methods, the uniforms, fingernail polish, hairnets, and whether or not MOTW would turn into a daycare facility had taken its toll on the organization and its budget. The women who could not be placed in other electronic-assembly positions were encouraged to leave. Eventually, the line was out-sourced to an external pro- ducer. “This makes us look bad,” Burt said, “losing a line means something’s gone seriously wrong.” Mary sued the company in court and received some back pay. Steve explained that, despite all of the turmoil, he had no regrets over his actions: “I’d rather lose a line than ship out inferior products,” he said.

Conclusion Clearly, one of the key issues at play in the events surrounding the relocation of the gauge operation is how the production of value at MOTW works out through the processes for identifying nationality and gender. And this calculation revolves around the continual efforts of MOTW managers to resolve the perplexing paradox described, to some degree, by Harvey (1982). How will they turn the vibrant ener- gies of Mexican women into a feature of male, American goods? Another way of putting this question is, how will they manage cheap people in the manufacture of quality goods? We need to recognize the social construction of Mexican women within MOTW as cheap people to understand the difficulty the managers faced when they hired them for their nimble fingers and in the belief that training was not required. The managers knew they were bringing in the worker who had always represented precisely the kind of people MOTW did not employ. If we adjust the Harvey paradox to address Elson’s question – how does labor acquire the form that it does – then we can see that the Mexican woman was acquiring a contradictory constitution. On the one hand, she represented the kind of worker whose exclusion reinforced MOTW’s superiority among maquiladoras. On the other, she was becom- ing a member of the MOTW team because of her natural ability to assemble elec- tronic components. The historical social construction of the Mexican woman as a non-MOTW employee had served a useful purpose for the company because it exercised further productive effects. To use Butler’s views on this process, we could say that the mate- rialization of the Mexican woman as cheap labor personified was not an isolated event, but rather one interwoven with how value materialized within MOTW goods and within the company itself. The Mexican woman made the recognition of value in MOTW possible by establishing the parameters for recognizing what it was not. She cast the shadow of nonvalue and, against her, value came to light. In MOTW, this relationship of the Mexican woman to the value of company products and people was explained in the designation of the labor process as a masculine one – within an American system for creating American men’s goods. Anything that revealed the energies of Mexican women, in their view, such as televisions, was not 164 M. W. WRIGHT a thing of quality in comparison with MOTW goods, which revealed American inge- nuity that transformed a Mexican labor process into a top-notch tool shop. The decision to hire women into the MOTW labor force demonstrates the con- tinuous pattern for protecting the labor process from the influence of cheap Mexican women. Although MOTW was expanding in the area of electric assembly, man- agers still described the principal operations as those involving carburetor assem- bly, tooling, and engineering – all male-dominated occupations in the factory. The women worked in windowless interior rooms, out of the view of the major pro- duction space. Their movements were to be carefully monitored, along with their clothing, reproductive cycles, and personal hygiene habits. These regulations were part of the plan for integrating Mexican women into the labor force without con- taminating the MOTW labor process or its products with evidence of their pres- ence. Perhaps they could protect the value of their products by keeping the women’s contribution to it secret. Steve had guaranteed his executive officers that he could produce quality gauges at the same time that he was committed to making sure that customers would never know that Mexican women built parts of their boats. In this way, the labor of Mexican women could be turned into something that reified American masculinity. Problems occurred when Mary subverted the traditional methods for guarantee- ing that these vibrant energies of Mexican women could be transformed into the fixed properties of male American goods. In stressing the need to train the women with flexible procedures, she appeared to dismantle both the American system that protected the Americanness of the operation and the masculine domination of MOTW workspaces and procedures. In so doing, she violated the codes for recog- nizing quality in this workplace. She declared that these women were worth train- ing if quality was what was expected. In fact, it was the only way that this result could be achieved. But her bosses, rather than seeing a group of workers learning and improving over time, encountered the troubling vision of Mexican women getting out of control while their American supervisor was “Mexicanizing” in front of them. Their traditional pattern for connecting the value of people to the value of MOTW goods was unraveling. The MOTW case also broadly reveals that capitalism is, in the first instance, a local phenomenon. The ideas behind it may have a global dimension, but the working out of capitalism occurs when individuals are identified to represent varying kinds of capitalist subjects, their dimensions being drawn and understood in the local landscape (see Gibson-Graham, 1996). The evaluation of the quality of the gauges demonstrates this point. Just as the final-assembly facility in Georgia was increasingly satisfied with the gauge quality, the MOTW managers were less so. Both sets of managers equate product quality with product value. However, their criteria for evaluating these conditions differed and, as a result, that which held value for one was lacking in value for the other. The value in the gauges depended upon who was performing the evaluation, and on how they recognized the evidence for value in people and products. Finally, the benefits of an ethnographic approach to exploring the dynamics of corporate behavior ought not to be underestimated. For, had I only conducted inter- views with MOTW managers in order to understand why they made particular deci- sions, I doubt that the kind of story I present with the ethnographic material would THE POLITICS OF RELOCATION 165 ever have materialized. Likely as not, I would have heard that the decision was made based on the budget and the lack of skills among the Mexican workers. These are the sorts of explanations that abound when a maquila operation fails to function as expected. There is, of course, some validity to both of these contentions, as I think the MOTW case demonstrates, but it is in the conceptualization of the inter- play between value, labor, Mexicans, and women that the terms of such explana- tions come together at MOTW.

Part III Resource Worlds

Editors’ Introduction: Producing Nature

Trevor J. Barnes, Eric Sheppard, Jamie Peck, and Adam Tickell

The term resources conjures up those sometimes grainy textbook photographs appearing in secondary school geography or social studies texts: drooping bunches of bananas in Caribbean plantations; an oil well gushing black in the Kuwaiti desert; a log boom floating down a Canadian river flanked by forest; a steeply terraced paddy field of rice set among the lush tropical vegetation of Indonesia. These images of resources, as raw commodities given by nature and ripe for extraction, are also how the first economic geographers conceived them. Indeed, at its institutionalization in the late nineteenth century, economic geography was in effect the geography of resource worlds. The first economic geography textbook in English by the Scottish geographer George Chisholm, Handbook of Commercial Geography (1889), provided a meticulous account of the multifarious types of resources found in the world, their geographical distribution, and the natural con- ditions sustaining them. For Chisholm (1889, p. 1), lying behind resource produc- tion is “the great geographical fact . . . that different parts of the world yield different products, or furnish the same product under unequally favourable condi- tions.” To understand resources, therefore, one must understand differences in natural conditions across the globe. It is this “great geographical fact” that creates the mosaic of resource production that Chisholm, and others of his generation, were so keen to claim as economic geography. With the increased importance of manufacturing during the twentieth century, economic geography shifted emphasis away from resources per se, but they were still present. Even in the late 1930s, well after Henry Ford pioneered his assembly- line techniques, paving the way for mass production more generally (see Sheppard and Barnes, 2000, ch. 1), the American geographer Richard Hartshorne (1939) was still arguing that the fundamental geographical unit was the region, defined princi- pally by its natural resource base. For Hartshorne the world is a patchwork quilt of different economic regions, where each region is a closely delineated complex of interconnected elements that cohere around resource production of which the exem- plar is agriculture, and resting on the family farm (it’s not surprising that Hartshorne lived all of his working life in the American Midwest). 170 TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL

The emergence of spatial science in late 1950s Anglo-American economic geo- graphy, however, pushed Hartshorne’s regionalism aside (Barnes, 2000), and in the process marginalized the study of resources. Partly, this was because spatial science upheld general theoretical explanation against the unique description that defined Chisholm’s and Hartshorne’s approach to resources (all those detailed figures, all those maps, all those lists, facts, and typologies). And partly, it was because the very assumptions under-girding general location theory, especially within the “model- ing tradition” (Plummer, 2000), effectively effaced any economic geography of resources. In order to derive simple, tractable mathematical solutions of the kind cherished by spatial science, simplifying assumptions were required. One of the most widespread was the isotropic plain, an infinitely large flat surface undisturbed by resource differentiation. Such an assumption ruled out by default any serious exami- nation of resources, and as a result, they were treated as merely complicating factors, the analysis of which was promised but often indefinitely postponed. Ironically, perhaps, resources returned to economic geography’s agenda in the mid-1970s through Marxism. On the face of it, Marx does not have much to say about resources and nature beyond the philosophical point of dialectical material- ism: that human society depends on the material environment. Marx’s foci were the Dark Satanic Mills of nineteenth-century industrial capitalism, places where, as in Charles Dickens’ description of Coketown, “Nature was bricked out.” David Harvey’s (1974) influential Economic Geography essay, “Population, resources, and the ideology of science,” changed that view, however. Closely following Marx, Harvey argued that resources and nature are not asocial givens, but significant only in so far as they are embedded within a particular set of social and economic imper- atives such as found under capitalism. As Smith and O’Keefe (1985, p. 80) later put it: “for Marx, nature is related to social activity. He meant that materially as well as ideally; the entire earth bears on its face the stamp of human activity.” Consequently, the earlier interpretation, held by Chisholm and Hartshorne, that resources are given naturally, gave way to one emphasizing their social constitution, and affiliated conflicts, power struggles, and politics. Neil Smith (1984) even spoke of the seemingly oxymoronic “production of nature.” Of course, one needs to be careful about that term “production.” It doesn’t mean that capitalism’s social relations defy the Laws of Thermodynamics and create something where nothing existed before. But it does mean that when capitalism emerged on to the scene it transformed preexisting nature (sometimes called “first nature”). Nature still exists, but how it is exploited, used, thought about, and represented is now completely different. Castree (1995, p. 20), following Cronon (1991), provides a useful example: “the ‘natural’ regions of . . . the Midwestern United States, cannot be understood simply as preexistent natural grasslands, as the traditional notion of ‘first nature’ would imply. Instead . . . they must be seen as constructed natural environments evolving out of decades of intensive, profit-driven conversion into what they are presently are.” Hartshorne’s natural economic regions, including those of his native American Midwest – “the corn belt,” “the hog belt,” “the dairy belt” – were therefore not natural at all, but a consequence of deeply inscribed social relations. The term “second nature” is often used to describe how even the most apparently pristine “natural” ecosystems are now been profoundly shaped by capitalism. INTRODUCTION TO PART III 171

The view that natural resources are social artifacts, rather than simply natural, is the central theme running through the five essays gathered here. This Marxist insight is now ingrained. Debate remains, however, around which kinds of compo- nents to include within the social: is it only class relations, the classic Marxist view, or are there other important elements like gender, ethnic allegiance, or environ- mental discourse? There is no single answer. In large part it depends upon the par- ticular type and context of the resource itself, represented in the essays that follow by: late nineteenth century fur sealing in the Bering Straits; Spanish waterscapes in the first part of the twentieth century; oil exploitation in Venezuela, Iran, and espe- cially Nigeria in the 1970s; rice and vegetable cultivation in postcolonial Gambia; and coffee production in contemporary Peru. The other debate running through the papers turns on the degree to which resources possess a power to assert themselves independently of social relations. One criticism of the orthodox Marxist position is that it gives too much importance to the social; i.e., nature appears malleable, taking any form dictated by capitalism. But doesn’t nature resist human wiles, at least sometimes, often responding to human intervention in ways that confound the conceit that we can control the earth’s biophysical system? Each author attempts in various ways, and to very different degrees, to give natural resources some agency, an ability to act outside of prevailing social relations. Noel Castree examines the Bering Straits fur seal industry of the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, coming closest to the standard Marxist account of nature and resources. Hunting seals in the North Pacific began systematically around 1870, and by 1911 they were almost extinct. They were saved from eradication only by a treaty signed by the principal sealing nations. Castree asks how we should explain the perilous state of the fur seal hunt. He poses two alternatives. Orthodox economics attributes the crisis to market failure. Because fur seals cost nothing to produce and are not owned by anyone – they are a public good in the language of economics – the normal price mechanism regulating their allocation and use does not apply. Individual capitalists, concerned only with self-interest, will then ration- ally expropriate the resource as long as revenues exceed costs, eventually wiping it out, and producing what Garrett Hardin (1968) famously called the “tragedy of the commons.” In this interpretation, the specific qualities of the good itself, under- mining the operation of the market, creates the problem, and not the wider system. Marxism, by contrast, lays the blame entirely at the door of the wider social system, capitalism. Marxists argue that by virtue of its very social constitution capitalism reaps where it sows, destroys what it creates. In particular, Castree traces the destructive impulses of the sealing industry to social class relations, namely, the necessity of capitalists to exploit and to expropriate in the name of profit and accu- mulation. While following the classical Marxist line, towards the end of the paper Castree adds an interesting wrinkle around what he calls “ideologies of nature.” The issue is why didn’t the social relations of capitalism, which in so many instances have proved so destructive, carry out the final coup de grace, and eliminate the fur seal. For Castree, the existence of a discourse of preservation (“an ideology of nature”) blunted the raw, undiluted social relations of capitalism, allowing a less destructive outcome to occur. Note that social relations are still at work here, but they are just not so narrowly defined. It is the broadening of social relations to include “ideologies of nature” that is Castree’s special contribution. 172 TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL

Castree provides little autonomy to the seals themselves. In fact, in response to anthropocentric criticisms of Marxism, i.e., that Marxism is too human focused, he says “that it is not possible to ‘speak for’ ‘nature’ in any unmediated way.” In con- trast, Erik Swyngedouw’s analysis of the production of the Spanish waterscape, 1890–1930, also written from a Marxist perspective, provides a much greater sense of water having agency, of resisting, and sometimes defeating, the social forces arrayed against it. In part, this is because Swyngedouw adds to the Marxist theo- retical canon conceptual arguments taken from researchers in science studies, writers like Donna Haraway and Bruno Latour. Their work is centrally concerned with the relationship between nature and society, which they portray as a hybrid; that is, an inextricable mix of society and nature, interacting and blending, making it very hard to know where society ends and nature begins. Swyngedouw gives hybrids a Marxist gloss through a dialectical interpretation; nature and society are not coherent and separate spheres, but are interrelated through manifold, constantly shifting flows (Harvey, 1996). But less characteristically Marxist is Swyngedouw’s willingness to recognize the independent power of water as a resource, whether in the shape of river basins, lakes, aquifers, or the hydrological cycle, as it forms hybrid relations with an emerging social modernity. Modernity is a key term for Swyngedouw, and the moving force behind a political, economic, and cultural movement, “Regenera- cionismo,” that sought to break through conservative, entrenched interests by fun- damentally altering the Spanish waterscape from the late nineteenth century onward; through the provision of dams, canals, and irrigation schemes, it pushed traditional Spanish (rural) society into the twentieth century. But it was hard, not only because of resistance from the old political guard, but also because of the engi- neering task itself, and the very agency of water. Modernity required the conjoin- ing of a myriad of social relations with physical geographical ones, and only then was the reshaping of Spain’s hydrological morphology possible. It is not natural resources on the one hand, and society on the other, but both/and, “socionature,” hybridity. Hybridity is there if not in name in Michael Watts’ richly drawn and powerfully narrated essay on oil and money, an account of the 1970s oil boom in the “high- absorption” (oil and population rich) developing countries of Venezuela, Iran, and especially Nigeria. Also written from a Marxist sensibility, he joins together, hybrid- like, all manner of different events and entities – the oil itself, mega urban projects, military coups and kidnappings, politics and money, stallions and stereos, Freud and Simmel – in recounting “the spectacle of black gold.” What a spectacle! And that’s Watts’ point. Oil, and the vast sums of money with which it is associated, never stands alone, isolated, but gains meaning from being part of a larger social narrative. The basic lineaments of the story are well known. A cartel, the “Orga- nization of Petroleum Exporting Countries” (OPEC), began flexing its muscles in the early 1970s, resulting in oil prices quadrupling within a year, and increasing the oil-based revenues of OPEC states tenfold within a decade. While this massive infu- sion of money was supposed to bring development and prosperity, generally it didn’t, creating instead dislocation, corruption, massive social inequality, and insta- bility (“social disintegration”). Nigeria is the extreme case, for which Watts relates a hideous downside; oil money becomes “the devil’s excrement.” As Watts writes, in Nigeria “oil money – as social power, as state corruption and degeneracy, as blind INTRODUCTION TO PART III 173 ambition and illusion – has eroded sociability, turning everything it touched into shit: oil money as deodorized faeces that was made to shine.” To understand how this happened, Watts turns to Marx and Georg Simmel, an early-twentieth-century Marxist theorist of money. Their story is the same one about resources: money is necessarily embedded within a matrix of social relations, mirroring, mediating, and transforming all at the same time. So, when OPEC states like Venezuela, Iran, or Nigeria were inundated by filthy lucre, inevitably it besmirched and muddied them. More generally, Watts’ essay powerfully shows that the natural endowment of rich economic resources such as oil means very little by itself. That’s why Chisholm’s copious tables of regional resources are in the end also unsatisfactory. Resources take on meaning only when implanted within a set of social relations. Again, natural resources like oil are never simply natural, and sometimes not even a resource. In Nigeria, oil was an anti-resource, creating mal-development, social discord, and political mayhem. Michael Watts during the early 1980s was a pioneer of political ecology (Watts, 2000). Frequently set within studies of agriculture in developing countries, political ecology argued, in line with the general thesis here, that social relations are key to understanding many ecological problems, particularly stressing inequitable relations of power around land and resource ownership. Watts’ later work, such as the essay on oil, retains the general thrust of political ecology, although it is not about ecology per se. Judith Carney’s chapter is more typical of the political ecology tradition. Her significant contribution is broadening its remit by incorporating gender – a neg- lected theme in the other essays. Carney shows that gender is a vital component of the social in her case study of rice and vegetable farming in the Gambia. The gen- dered nature of social relations forcefully shapes the resources that are produced, the methods by which they are produced, and their degree of success in potentially realizing nation-wide development. In many ways, her story turns on the unintended consequences of aid in the postcolonial period. Under British colonialism, men prac- ticed monoculture in the uplands, farming the cash crop of peanuts, while women worked in the swamplands of the river valley producing rice and vegetables mainly for family subsistence. As a “reward” for contributing to the family household, women were given access to some of the family’s land holdings (in a system known as kamanyango). Women controlled how that land was used, and could keep finan- cial benefits that accrued. Other land holdings of the family, however, were subject to maruo. Here the male head of the household strictly controlled land use and ben- efits. The end of colonialism was accompanied by a series of aid projects that funded irrigation schemes, especially within the swampland area. They were compromised, however, by gender conflict over the right to control the redeveloped land, and thus income and power within the household. Men claimed the land as maruo, while women argued that it is kamanyango. The conflict led women to withdraw their labor, reducing land productivity, and undermining the national goal of self- subsistence in rice. Carney’s point, then, is that examinations of how social rela- tions make a difference to resource provision must take gender as seriously as other dimensions of social difference and inequality. Whatmore and Thorne move farthest away from traditional political economy, pursuing instead the writings of Bruno Latour (also discussed by Swygedouw). Latour is especially associated with actor-network theory (ANT). The gist of this 174 TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, JAMIE PECK, AND ADAM TICKELL complex theory is the assertion that things happen only by “enlisting” or “enrolling” a large number of entities or elements within a larger network, making them work together to produce the desired outcome. That outcome might be the identification of the anthrax bacillus by Louis Pasteur (Latour’s favorite example), or it might be the export of coffee from Peruvian farmers to British cafés (Whatmore and Thorne’ case study). Persuading entities (“actors”) to work together is always difficult, though, and with no guarantee of eventual success. Both Pasteur and repeatedly struggle to maintain their respective networks, fending off rogue “actors” like a contaminated petri dish, or frost in Brazilian coffee fields. Such networks are thus always an achievement, taking a lot of resources, hard work, and dedicated effort; there is nothing natural about them. Also, there is nothing natural, as Whatmore and Thorne argue, about how networks spread. Just because Pasteur identified the anthrax bacillus in a culture flask in his rue d’Ulm Paris lab, it doesn’t mean it became instant, universal knowledge, with the tech- nique of pasteurization immediately unfolding. Likewise, because a group of con- cerned young people gathered in London in 1964 to discuss how to alleviate poverty among developing countries through fair trading practices, there was no necessity for it to become a network that now includes farmers from Latin America to Africa. To effect geographical reach, “action at a distance,” requires a whole series of medi- ating relationships among people and things. Whatmore and Thorne follow Latour in arguing that, rather than making hard and fast geographical distinctions between, say, nature and society, local and global, or cores and peripheries, it is better simply to speak of chains of connections that are more or less long, and more or less strong. More generally, their purpose is to unsettle the political economic privileging of the social over natural resources (and multinational agro-industry over organic small- holders). The social doesn’t always get what it wants – networks are precarious and fragile – and there is always more than the social going on. Non-humans also need to be enrolled to achieve results, from machines and tools, to the weather, to the coffee beans themselves. To put it all down to unfettered forces of social relations is both conceited and geographically naive. The British literary critic Raymond Williams (1976, p. 184) said, “nature is perhaps the most complex word in the language.” Consequently, resources must be one of the most complex terms in economic geography, straddling between society and nature. Some of the questions the term raises, and which also emerge from the essays, are: What is the role of nature in the definition of a resource? In the social- based definition that was at the core of our review, has nature dropped out, or is it still there, and if so how? In fact, what do we mean when we say a resource is socially defined? What counts as the social? And why should the social be privi- leged in the first place? Further, how does the work of people in science studies like Donna Haraway and Bruno Latour, who are not economic geographers and are concerned only with science and the material world it studies, bear on how eco- nomic geographers should study resources? What are the practical precepts being offered by the mix of theories used in an essay for concrete studies of resources? How, if at all, does adoption of a particular perspective change such studies? Chapter 11 Nature, Economy, and the Cultural Politics of Theory: The “War Against the Seals” in the Bering Sea, 1870–1911

Noel Castree

Introduction The last few years have seen the rapid development of a number of approaches to understanding natural resource problems from the perspective of Marxian political- economy. Despite the evident tensions between “red” and “green” thought (well summarized by Eckersley, 1992, ch. 4), several authors have recently sought to fashion a distinctively Marxist approach to environmental questions. More speci- fically, they have done so by returning to the texts of Marx himself. The work of Elmar Altvater (1993, 1994), Ted Benton (1989, 1991, 1992), Reiner Grundmann (1991, 1992), David Harvey (1993b), and James O’Connor (1989a, b, c) are all attempts to enrich in more ecofriendly ways our understanding of what Neil Smith (1984) provocatively called “the production of nature” from within the horizon of classical Marxism. The originality of earlier (and by now well known) exegeses of Marx’s understanding of nature were twofold. First, they showed that for Marx nature is not separate from society, but is materially produced by it within a “crea- tively destructive” capitalist system. The dualism of nature and society is thus dis- solved in the labor process, which becomes the flashpoint for social-natural unity centered on capitalist production of “second nature” (Schmidt, 1971; Smith, 1984). Second, they showed that accompanying this process of material transformation, nature was also produced discursively. In particular, Smith’s (1984) dissection of what he called “ideologies of nature” illuminated the way in which representations of nature can serve to either conceal or legitimate the often rapacious material pro- duction of nature at the hands of capital (see also Fitzsimmons, 1989; Redclift, 1987; Williams, 1980). Overall, this dual focus on the simultaneously material and discursive production of nature defines an overarching critical research program in which “the major analytical issue . . . becomes the question of how nature is (re)pro- duced, and who controls this process of (re)production in particular times and places” (Whatmore and Boucher, 1993, p. 167). The more recent ecofriendly com- mentaries on Marx and nature have enriched this research program by offering a theoretical explanation of the conditions under which capitalism has a specific 176 NOEL CASTREE liability to generate environmental problems, as well as an appreciation of the reciprocal effects these produced problems have upon society (see Castree, 1995). However, these abstract accounts must be supplemented by more detailed historical-geographical investigations. Additionally, with few exceptions (e.g., Harvey, 1993b), the new wave of ecologically-minded Marxist approaches have said little about the discursive production of nature, the hegemonic representations through which nature and environment are understood. There is, in other words, still much to be done. In this essay I present a Marxian account of the formation and resolution of a major natural resource problem in both its material and its discursive dimensions. That problem was the near total destruction of the north Pacific fur seal (Callorhi- nus ursinus) in the short space of four decades (1870–1911). My overall aim is to suggest the usefulness of Marx’s political economy for making critical sense of this episode in the violent life of capitalism in both its material and discursive dimen- sions. After describing the genesis of the fur seal crisis, I then seek to explain it using neoclassical and ecoMarxist ideas respectively. By exposing the weaknesses of the former I hope to show the perspicacity of the latter, a contrast particularly appo- site given the current popularity of market based approaches to environment. Having examined the material destruction of environment, I then consider critically the discursive dimensions of the fur seal conflict. In particular, I focus on the con- structions of “nature” proffered by radical American environmentalists which were crucial in saving the Pribilof seals. I seek to show both the effectiveness of those constructions, but also their dissimulated ideological dimension: for their success depending on further silencing an already marginalized Pribilof Aleut population sold into what Dorothy Jones (1980) calls a “century of servitude.” However, having utilized the Marxian critique to make sense of the fur seal crisis and its resolution, I end by registering the limits of that critique. As Donna Haraway (1991) has insisted, theoretical vision is always partial and its privileges are also its blind spots, leading to what Sparke (1995, p. 1066, emphasis added) describes as a “use- fully dynamic notion of the (im)possibility of fully adequate critique.”

“The War Against the Seals” The north Pacific fur seal is triply remarkable. First, in the mid-nineteenth century it was probably the most numerous sea mammal on the planet at around 3.5 million animals. Second, its annual migration pattern from the Bering Sea to the central/ north Californian coast is exceeded among mammals only by the great whales. Third, despite its size, the seal herd breeds on only a few small rocks: the Pribilof Islands, which provide some 80% of the total, Russia’s Commander Islands, Robben Island off Sakhalin, and the northern Kuriles. The annual cycle begins anew early each summer on just a few miles of rocky Pribilof beaches, the species’ principal home. Between April and early June the bulls arrive, mature adult males 7–8 feet long and weighing 400–600 pounds. In June much smaller and lighter pregnant females arrive who are quickly corralled by these “beachmasters” into “harems” of up to 100 seals. The females give birth, nurse their pups, forage far and wide for food at sea, then come into heat and get pregnant again. In July and August the immature males and females arrive for their relatively brief stay, and by October NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 177 most seals – newly born pups included – have left the rookeries for an elliptical migration 2000 miles and 6–8 months in length during which time landfall is rarely made. The Pribilof seals were barely touched by humans until Russian fur traders dis- covered the two main Pribilof Islands (St George and St Paul) in the fog-bound and icy waters of the Bering Sea in 1787. Although not as fine as the pelt of the north Pacific sea otter (which had been hunted virtually to extinction by the late 18th century), it was quickly recognized that the seals’ fur, with a density of 300,000 hairs per square inch, could be made into excellent capes and coats. After an early period of unregulated killing, commercial harvesting was eventually consolidated under the control of the Russian-American Company in 1805, whereafter, through a process of trial and error, the management of the seal herd was relatively suc- cessful. However, in 1867 Russia ceded the Pribilofs to the United States as part of the $7.2 million sale of Alaska, after which the management of the seals entered a new, dynamic, and dangerous period. Congress granted the Treasury Department control of the islands on condition that it lease out exclusive rights to harvest seals to a private firm. In 1870, after considering more than a dozen tendered bids, the Treasury granted a twenty-year lease to the recently formed American Commercial Company, an amalgamation of largely San Francisco-based financiers interested in pursuing commercial sealing. The lease stipulated that no more than 100,100 seals could be taken each year, that only non-breeding males be killed, and that killing take place only between June–July and September–October. In return, the Company paid the government a $2.625 royalty on each skin shipped as well as an annual rent of $55,000. The killing and counting were all to be done under the supervision of a Treasury Agent with legal responsibility for the herd, agents serving for a few years at a time. Finan- cially, the ACC lease was a stunning success for both Company and government. Between 1872 and 1889 the Company paid an average dividend of $46.50 per face value $100 share. With an average annual commercial kill over the life of the lease of 92,020, the 1,840,364 skins sold by the Company yielded approximately $27,800,000. From this the US government received just over $6,000,000 (consid- erably more than the costs it incurred on the islands) which, after deducting sealers’ wages, company overheads, and transport costs (approximately $2,000,000), left a net Company profit of $18,102,140 or just under $1,000,000 per year. As Busch Cooper (1985, p. 114) rightly puts it, “even in the age of ‘robber barons’ this was success to end all successes.” The success is relatively easily explained. From the 1870s onwards, the monied classes of Europe and the US were willing to pay handsomely for fur skin coats and capes, which had become the height of bourgeois fashion. At the London auction of the C. M. Lampson Company (the main destination for Pribilof furs) skins fetched an impressive average of $14.67 each over the lease. With this assured market, monopoly control of the herd, and relatively small costs, it was not hard for the Company to thrive. And yet there was a dark side to this success. In 1889 govern- ment agent Charles J. Goff sent a report on seal numbers so alarming that the Trea- sury sent a special investigator, Henry Elliott. Elliott was considered an authority on the north Pacific fur seal after having first surveyed the Pribilof seals for the Trea- sury in 1872 when he made an influential, but as it eventually turned out highly 178 NOEL CASTREE spurious, estimate of the herd size, putting it at approximately 4,700,000 animals. Alarmingly, his 1890 estimate was a mere 20% of this earlier calculation, and, warning that the herd was on the brink of extinction, he accused the ACC of over- harvesting males. When the Pribilof lease expired in 1890, it was awarded to the North American Commercial Company which used its close connections with the Harrison Admin- istration to fend-off a higher bid from the ACC. The new lease was also for twenty years, but the tax raised to $9.25 per skin and the rent increased to $60,000 per annum. The annual quota was reduced and now determined by the Treasury agent yearly. And yet to the frustration of both the NACC and the Treasury seal numbers continued to decline. Over the NACC’s lease the average annual commercial kill was just 17,000 seals per annum, a far cry from the ACC average, with the 1910 harvest down to just 13,500 animals (Riley, 1967). Nonetheless, the NACC enjoyed a remarkable profit rate of 45% over the lease, amounting to $4,390,917. Despite the reduced quotas, demand for fur-seal garments in Europe and America exceeded supply, proving once more what a durably lucrative enterprise commercial sealing could be. But, the herd decline could not be ignored, and by 1890 the real source of the problem had already become apparent: pelagic sealing. Given the phenomenal pro- fitability of commercial sealing the US monopoly could not survive for long, and from the early 1880s onwards a substantial sealing fleet grew up in Victoria, British Columbia and later in Japan. Again figures are imprecise, but Rogers (1976) esti- mates that approximately 1,311,000 pelagically-taken skins were sold in the London market between 1872 and 1911 (most taken 1885–1905). This vastly exceeds the approximately 360,000 skins taken by the NACC over its twenty-year lease (Riley, 1967). But even this does not give true measure of the impact of pelagic sealing. Shoot- ing (and spearing) seals at sea was a remarkably inefficient practice: more often than not the seals sank before they could be recovered, or escaped wounded, only to die later. Even a conservative estimate is that for every seal successfully taken at sea, two were lost. On this basis, then, the total pelagic kill was nearer 4,000,000 seals. Consequently, it is not surprising that by 1910 the herd was down to just a few tens of thousands and heading towards extinction unless something was done quickly. There had been an early attempt to address the seal herd decline, leading to heightened geopolitical tensions, and resulting in the “Bering Sea crisis,” as it became known. It would take a multilateral agreement to solve the seal problem: the North Pacific Fur Seal Convention of 1911. The events leading up to the signing of the Convention were complex, as were the negotiations that produced the final document. Apart from the alarmingly low numbers of seals in the rookeries, a new and conciliatory US government under William Taft, the imminent expiration of the NACC lease, and pressure from a new and influential US conservation movement combined fortuitously to encourage the American government to at last resolve the seal problem. Under the aegis of Secretary of Commerce and Labor Charles Nagel, the US, Britain, Canada, Japan, and Russia met in 1911. The resulting treaty has been described as a “historical landmark” (Busch Cooper, 1985, p. 152) and a “splendid bargain” (Gluek, 1982, p. 179), and with good reason. Not only was it the first international and multilateral agreement to conserve a species of marine NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 179 wildlife; it was also remarkable in satisfying almost all the parties concerned. All pelagic sealing was to be banned (except by aboriginals) and only land-based har- vesting permitted. The US, Japan, and Russia thus secured recognition of their island ownership of the seals. But in return for Canada and Japan relinquishing their right to harvest at sea, they would receive 15% of America’s Pribilof catch and Russia’s Commander catch, with Japan compensating each of the other three nations with 10% of its Robben Island catch. Within a decade seal numbers had recovered and the seals were successfully and profitably harvested more-or-less under the terms of the original agreement for several decades to come (for a history of Pribilof fur seal management see Roppel and Davey, 1965).

Economy and Ecology: Two Paradigms How, then, are we to make sense of this resource problem and its resolution? Two paradigmatic explanations suggest themselves, orthodox and critical respectively, which have the interesting characteristic of having been formulated at around the same time as the seal crisis developed as well as being, over a century later, very important in the contemporary struggle to explain environmental degradation. In what follows I narrate the seal crisis and its resolution through each paradigm in turn in order to suggest the power of the latter, Marxian political economy, over the former, a free market approach inspired by neoclassical thinking.

A common tragedy? In the 1870s a theoretical perspective was being developed in a continent far from Alaska – Europe – designed to comprehend a whole spectrum of economic action: namely, neoclassical economics. Over a century later it is that very same perspec- tive, or at least a number of its central precepts, which is currently de rigueur within resource management and environmental economics. Seen through this theoretical lens, the near extinction of the north Pacific fur seal is a classic case of what Garrett Hardin (1968) famously called a “commons” problem. And its resolution seems a stunning confirmation of the solution proffered by the environmental embodiment of the neoclassical approach – what Eckersley (1993, p. 1) terms “free market envi- ronmentalism” – that creating property rights and markets in natural resources pro- tects them. Let me begin, then, by narrating the seal crisis in terms of this paradigm. At the heart of the neoclassical approach, of course, is the idea of the maxi- mization of individual satisfaction. Economic activity is seen as a series of volun- tary transactions between sovereign individuals who come to market with goods and services to sell or to buy and with particular preference orderings conditioned by resource scarcity. In a “perfect” market, each individual is able to maximize their welfare through rational decision-making. Under these assumptions, free market processes yield an optimum of social welfare, or Pareto optimality, where the latter is defined as the sum of individual welfare maximizations. From this perspective, the fur seal crisis is a case of “suboptimality” or “inefficiency” due to so-called “externalities.” Externalities refer to a set of effects of transactions which under- mine the capacity of economic actors to freely achieve their desired ends. And in resource management those externalities are, of course, formalized in a model 180 NOEL CASTREE intended to explain a wide range of resource problems: namely, the “commons” model. There is no need to rehearse that model here in any detail (see McCay and Acheson, 1987). Put simply, Hardin’s “tragedy” develops under three assumptions (Berkes, 1985, p. 200). First, that resource access is freely open to any user; second, that selfish individualism prevails; and third, that exploitation rates exceed renewal. Under such circumstances, open access ensures that people do not experience fully the costs of their own resource use because they are able to pass a large portion of the costs on to others. This is a case of so-called “market failure.” The unintended consequence, or what Elster (1986, p. 24) calls “counterfinal” result, “is said to be a free for all, with users competing with one another for a greater share of the resource to the detriment of themselves, the resource, and society as a whole” (Ciriacy-Wantrup and Bishop, 1975, p. 713). At first sight the commons model appears to explain the fur seal crisis very well, for two reasons. First, the seals were a “fugitive resource”: that is, because they were mobile they did not respect territorial or legal boundaries. Second, for this reason they were effectively a “common” or “open-access” resource which no body owned exclusively. As resource economists like H. Scott Gordon (1954) would later point out, the disjuncture between rights of access to a fishery and responsibility for its overall management created powerful incentives to overharvest. The “tragedy of the commons” develops because each pelagic harvester knows that if they leave a seal in the water someone else will appropriate it and hence the associated profit. As McEvoy (1986, p. 10) puts it, “in a competitive economy no market mechanism ordinarily exists to reward individual forbearance in the use of shared resources.” The overall result is the neoclassicist’s “externalities” or what R. H. Coase (1960) called “social costs”: as individual actors try to maximize economic gain the social result is resource overexploitation, even exhaustion, and so every- one loses. Seen in this light, the fur seal case is an early, dramatic, and thus classic exemplar of the open-access problem that has bedeviled most twentieth-century commercial fisheries. However, what makes it of further interest for devotees of the commons approach is its resolution: the 1911 Fur Seal Convention. This brings me to “free market envi- ronmentalism,” to which the commons model is closely affiliated. The commons tragedy admits of two types of solution. One is governmental intervention through taxes, subsidies, or direct regulation of resource use, an approach with theoretical roots in the work of Pigou (1920). The other, more laissez-faire, is to make the resource in question the private property of individual resource users, who via the “invisible hand” will manage the resource in society’s best interest. The latter is the distinguishing feature of “free market environmentalism,” one important strand of contemporary orthodox approaches to environment which traces its lineage from Coase (1960). Here, as Eckersley (1993, p. 4) puts it, “environmental externalities are seen to arise not from ‘market forces’ or self-interested behaviour but rather from an absence of well-defined, universal, exclusive, transferable and enforceable property rights in respect of common environmental assets.” By creat- ing such enforceable (and perhaps tradable) property rights in the commons, and thereby excluding outsiders, externalities are in theory internalized and the market becomes savior not culprit. The consequence of this privatization, again in theory, NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 181 is that environmental degradation will be averted and Pareto optimality achieved (see Helm and Pearce, 1991; Jacobs, 1994). As Naughton-Treves and Sanderson (1995) recently pointed out, enforcing pro- perty rights in fugitive resources is frequently very difficult: witness the problems of operating Individual Transferable Quotas, especially in international fisheries. For this reason the success of the 1911 Convention seems a striking, if unusual, vindi- cation of the property rights approach in relation to an international resource issue. I say “unusual” for two reasons. First, rather than deploying, say, an ITQ system, the Convention made the seals the sole and exclusive property of the US, a “priva- tization” made possible by the fact that unlike most commercial fisheries the fur seal spends part of its migration on land. Second, the seals were not – contra the recommendations of free market environmentalism – owned by a private company or individual after 1911, but by a public body, the US government. However, when harvesting resumed in 1916, the US ran sealing as a purely commercial operation and thus effectively acted as a private enterprise. With these caveats in mind, the Convention might thus be claimed as a powerful illustration of the success of the free market approach. Not only did it save the seals. It also – through the ingen- ious idea of both compensating the Canadian and Japanese seal fleets and sharing the profits of the seal trade equitably between four nations – arguably satisfied the neoclassical precept that social welfare be maximized so far as was possible in what, in this case, was a messy geopolitical resource conflict. Together, finally, these two points seem to support the idea, loudly proclaimed by free market environmental- ists, that the “market” corrects itself through a negative feedback mechanism in which, when externalities are felt, action is taken to restore economic optimality. In short, the market knows best.

The political-economy of resource exploitation So far so good. Except the commons approach and free market environmentalism, with their neoclassical precepts, are not so much “wrong” as, I think, insufficiently penetrating in their assessment of the seal crisis and its resolution. It is, however, possible to draw on an alternative theoretical tradition, also inaugurated in Europe around the time of the Bering Sea controversy, that deriving from political eco- nomist Karl Marx. Building on Marx’s theoretical legacy, the recent rise of an environmentally focused Marxian political-economy arguably provides a more encompassing and fundamental explanation of the seal case and its consequences (cf. Roberts and Emel, 1991). It is thus to that alternative paradigm that I now turn. At the heart of an ecologically sensitive Marxism is the idea that “nature” is “produced” within the social relations of capitalism (Smith, 1984). This does not amount to the ludicrous suggestion that society makes the environment, down to the very last atom (Castree, 1995, pp. 19–20): after all, there could have been no sealing without fur seals, which of course preexisted Euro-American exploita- tion. Rather, it means two things. First, that “natural” resources only become re- sources through historically and geographically specific social appraisals. Second, it means that those resources are materially appropriated by human labor power. Thus, rather than existing as a pristine “first nature” quite other to society, the 182 NOEL CASTREE environment–society dualism is dissolved through the medium of labor which binds the two into a practical unity. As Smith (1984, p. 18) puts it, “the relation with nature is an historical product, and even to posit nature as external to society . . . is literally absurd since the very act of positing nature requires a certain relation with nature.” Overall, then, the basic Marxist proposition on environment is that as soon as “first nature” is brought into what Marx called a “metabolic” relation with society through labor then it loses its firstness and originality and becomes a socially produced “second nature.” In economic terms this is all familiar theoretical terrain of course, but it is the ecological dimensions of capitalist growth that have become the subject of recent concern within the Marxian fold. The premise of an ecological Marxism is that eco- nomic and ecological transformation are but sides of the same coin. This follows from Marx’s well-known argument that labor has the “dual character” of being both concrete and abstract at the same time, just as commodities are simultaneously both specific use-values and exchange values capable of general exchange on a world market. As Altvater (1993, p. 188) puts it, this insight “creates the possibility of grasping economic processes at once as transformations of values (value formation and valorization) and as transformations of materials and energy (labor process, metabolic interaction between man (sic.) and nature).” It is here that the negative effects of the “production” or, as Marx put it, the “creative destruction” of nature become particularly important, for the essence of recent theoretical work by eco- Marxists is that capitalist principles of economic organization have a specific lia- bility to destroy their own resource base. There have been three notable statements of this argument. The first is James O’Connor’s (1989a, b, c) thesis that capitalism underproduces its environmental conditions of production and treats them as if they were available without restriction. The second is Ted Benton’s (1989, 1991, 1992) proposition that the value-maximizing intentional structure of capital accumulation leads to what he calls “naturally mediated unintended consequences” of economic activity, or ecological crises like acid deposition, ozone depletion, and the like. The third is Elmar Altvater’s (1993) persuasive dual argument that discounting the future routinely leads to resource overexploitation, while the removal and abstraction of individual commodities from their ecosystemic context frequently entails a hidden, because unvalued, cost to those wider ecosystems. These points weave their way in and out of what follows. Let me thus narrate the fur seal crisis through the Marxian lens, showing that, what from the abstract and clean lines of free market perspective was a property rights problem success- fully resolved, is for Marxism a dangerous geopolitical problem that arose from an inherently destructive mode of economic appropriation. The narrative begins with a pre-history to seal exploitation, which the free market approach fails even to reg- ister: the sudden intrusion of capitalist social relations into a part of the world that had hitherto been quite peripheral to the major centers of economic power in Europe and the eastern USA. With the purchase of Alaska, the north Pacific quickly entered into the most intimate and transformative relationship with these economic heart- lands, as tens of thousands of fur seal skins began to traffick eastwards. This deserves some critical comment, as it can hardly be accepted as a “normal,” pre- destined or inevitable process. Instead, it was the historically contingent result of two forces. First, as Marx argued, capital pushes beyond all previous barriers and NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 183 batters down “Chinese walls” in its search for profit or what David Harvey (1982) has called a “spatial fix.” This was nowhere more true than in the north Pacific, for profit, even in so remote and marginal a location, was still profit. Second, the north Pacific fur trade was wholly dependent on European and eastern American export markets, which highlights how crucial culturally-specific and socially-created effec- tive demand was to making seal skins a valuable “resource.” So much for the pre- history. By the time of the “Bering Sea crisis” in the late 1880s, the post-Russian seal trade had been established some 20 years. But the trade, contra neoclassical assumptions, cannot be understood abstractly as the activity of welfare maximizing individuals, all equal and sovereign. Rather, those individuals were situated in spe- cific social relations that placed them in structurally different positions on different sides of the world. In Europe and the eastern USA, as noted, consumers sought fin- ished fur seal garments. But in the north Pacific, producers were not seeking to acquire goods in some generalized pursuit of “preference satisfaction” but to maximize profit: and that has altogether different implications for understanding the development of the fur seal crisis. By 1890, with pelagic sealing well developed, the seal trade depended on specific social relations of production and competi- tion. The former entailed Company shareholders reaping the benefits generated by managers and manual laborers working on the Pribilofs, while most schooner owners were petty bourgeois ex-fishermen, ex-sailors, or tradesmen employing crews seasonally out of Victoria and later several Japanese ports, but also Seattle and San Francisco. There were, then, a complex set of class relations here between workers (themselves divided “vertically” by rank and “horizontally” by nation), petty capitalists, and large capitalists. The competition relation, of course, entailed struggle between pelagic sealers of all nationalities and between them and the com- mercial companies. When embedded in their geographical and temporal context, these production and competition relations, underpinned by the logic of accumula- tion for accumulation’s sake, reveal commercial sealing to have been a highly con- flictual process with serious human, economic, and ecological costs impacting on real people and real environments. Let me elaborate. Market theory posits an abstract, “pinhead economy” which is spaceless and timeless. Yet in reality the spatial and temporal dimensions of resource over- exploitation become crucial moments in understanding its development. To begin with, for production to take place, capital, as Harvey (1985b, p. 43) has persua- sively argued, “must represent itself created in the form of a physical landscape in its own image.” In other words, production complexes are necessarily place-specific and geographically localized. The Pribilofs, of course, formed one site of produc- tion in the fur seal case, while Victoria, like its American and Japanese equivalents, formed a quite different site as a port whose rapid growth in the 1880s and 1890s was based in large part upon pelagic sealing. It was this differentiated geography of production, in tandem with the national borders between the three nations in question, that provided much of the dynamic for competition in the fur seal case. As fur seal numbers declined throughout the 1890s, then, the cause was not simply preference-maximizing individuals generating externalities which were economically “inefficient,” but instead intense competition between place-based class constituen- cies each seeking to defend their real interests and distribute potential economic sur- pluses in their favor. Finally, of course, there were the seals themselves. The 184 NOEL CASTREE commons model, betraying its neoclassical basis, is only concerned with environ- ment to the extent that its degradation sets up effects felt as “economic” conse- quences. The Marxian approach, however, directs attention to the systematicity of that degradation, seeing it as more than just a hiccup in otherwise well-functioning markets. It also, importantly, points to the irrationality of that degradation and thus invites an ecological critique of capitalist principles of resource exploitation. From this perspective, the unregulated slaughter of seals at sea was the horrendous out- come of a mode of economic appropriation whose “normal” functioning would have almost certainly extinguished the seal herd unless checked – indeed, at one point, the US government even announced that if pelagic sealing did not cease forth- with then it would slaughter the entire herd on the Pribilofs as a last resort. That such a dreadful course of action was in reality averted was due, of course, to the 1911 Convention. But again, rather than see this landmark agreement as an example of the “self correcting” powers of the market, we might offer a more critical and sober assessment. First, far from being an automatic response to seal herd decline the Convention was the product of years of hard fought diplomacy which persistently broke down as American, British, and Canadian administrations changed and as other international issues were used as bargaining chips in the fur seal negotiations. Second, it is worth remembering just how unusual the Convention was in suc- cessfully conserving the resource: for, arguably, it was successful only because of the ecological peculiarity that unlike most other fugitive resources the seals came ashore and could thus be counted and reliably harvested. In sum, then, an orthodox account of the seal crisis and its resolution is not so much wrong as profoundly inadequate. A “commons” problem based on the absence of well-defined property rights cer- tainly did exist in the north Pacific, but its basis lay in a capitalist mode of resource exploitation whose spatial and temporal dynamics and socio-ecological conse- quences were more substantial and dangerous than neoclassical precepts or free market concepts can comprehend.

The Discursive Production of Nature Many greens would broadly concur with this Marxian critique as part of the broader struggle to displace currently popular laissez-faire approaches to environ- ment. But they would depart from it insofar as Marxism is frequently seen as being too anthropocentric and so, it is claimed, it fails to respect and defend “nature” in its own right. There is, however, a powerful Marxian response to this argument, which is that it is not possible to “speak for” “nature” in any unmediated way. In the Marxian view, representations of “nature” say less about the environment rep- resented and more about the social assumptions of those doing the representing. This is why Smith (1984) talks of “ideologies of nature,” to register that represen- tations of nature are both socially produced and invariably geared towards achiev- ing specific social ends. The fur seal case is particularly interesting here, as the formulation of the 1911 Convention, which saved the seals, was crucially influenced by a neophyte preservationist lobby articulating some of the very same concerns as present day greens. Let me, then, now critically examine that preservationist agita- tion and its effects. NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 185

When the Convention was signed in 1911 there was no mention of a morato- rium on land-harvesting. Rather, with pelagic sealing banned, Pribilof harvesting would continue, but at levels set by the US Fur Seal Advisory Board. The Board was chaired by eminent biologist and President of Stanford University David Starr Jordan, and consisted of biologists and seal experts. It followed closely the then influential Progressive doctrine that resources should be used efficiently, without wastage, and, if possible, in a renewable way (see Hays, 1959), and enjoyed the support of influential men like George Bird Grinnell (editor of Field and Stream). For these reasons Secretary Nagel, whose department was now entirely responsible for the seals, followed closely the Board’s advice on harvesting. However, in addi- tion to these establishment conservationists, Nagel also came under pressure from a new and radical preservationist group led by “verbal hit-man,” as Dorsey (1991, p. 34) calls him, William T. Hornaday. Hornaday was a wildlife writer who had previously worked in Brooklyn Zoo and was author of such popular titles as Our Vanishing Wildlife, written for lay audiences in America and beyond. His “advisor” was none other than Henry Elliott. As Stephen Fox (1981) argues, the rise of preser- vationism as a complement and rival to conservation was largely a new phenome- non in turn of the century USA, and thus Hornaday’s outspoken defense of the seals represented a more radical form of environmental thought and politics than had been seen before in government circles. This new and strident preservationism quickly proved itself a force to be reck- oned with. In alliance with the conservationists, Hornaday and Elliott persuaded Nagel not to issue a new twenty-year lease in 1910 and to buy up the Pribilof operations. However, upon the signing of the Convention, Hornaday was incensed that the US government still intended to continue harvesting on land. As Hornaday asked Nagel in a typically overblown rhetorical outburst, “Did the President ...or the US Senate, intend for one moment that you go right on in the bloody killing business? No! A thousand times, no! And you know it.” His objection was, however, well founded. Fur seal management was still an imprecise science. With margins of error uncertain, continued sealing, as recommended by the Fur Seal Advisory Board, was potentially very risky. Although opposed to any sealing whatsoever, Hornaday recognized that if he could not stop it, he could at least give the herd a breathing space so that it could recover. It was here that the preservationists had their great- est impact. Through intense lobbying of Congressmen in a new Democratic House, Hornaday and his allies managed to secure a five-year closed season on land seal- ing when the enabling legislation for the Convention was formulated in Congress. This was a daring and dangerous move because it breached the conditions of the Convention and thus gave Canada and Japan a pretext for opting out of it. However, fortunately that eventuality did not materialize and the moratorium, although strongly opposed by Taft, Nagel, and Jordan, was arguably vital in securing the herd’s future, since when sealing resumed in 1916 seal numbers were up dramatically. The discursive production of nature was crucial here. I say this because it was the concatenation of a set of powerful and emotive preservationist representations of the seals that swayed the opinions of several Congressmen into supporting a five- year closed season. Moreover, this was, I will suggest, an effective “ideology of nature” whose success depended on a dissimulation of its social constructedness. 186 NOEL CASTREE

Through verbal harrying, numerous letters, and written publications both official and popular, Hornaday and his associates created a battery of images of the Pribilof seals forming what might be called a “discourse of wildest nature.” In this discourse, the seals appeared as wild, pristine, and majestic animals, as part of the “natural order” and thus not to be sullied by the grubby machinations of human commerce. This discourse, rather than innocently reflecting “nature,” actively constructed it in interested ways. The preservationist agenda was saving the seals and, accordingly, the animals were “staged” in such a way as to make killing them unthinkable. To say that “nature” is discursively constructed in this way is not, of course, to deny the reality of the seals. But it is to draw attention to what cultural critics call “the materiality of representation.” Discourse is proactive and productive, not simply passive, because spoken words and inscriptions on a page can be of world chang- ing consequence. This was particularly so in the seal case, because the preserva- tionists were representing an animal most of them (Elliott excepted) had never personally seen in a part of the world they had never even visited. The preserva- tionists thus deployed what Stephen Greenblatt (1992, p. 23) calls “an immense mimetic machinery” in which representation claimed to “mirror” nature as it was, while dissimulating its construction of that nature. This, then, was a politics of truth masquerading as more-or-less innocent languages of empiricism. But it was no less effective for that because it was precisely the claim to truthfulness which allowed the discourse of wildest nature to be so successful. In short, the representation of “nature” was as vital to protecting the seals as had been economic processes in causing seal overexploitation in the first place. Or, as Greenblat (1992, p. 6) aptly puts it, “representations are not only products but producers, capable of decisively altering the very forces that brought them into being.” But there was a dark side to this success, and here the Marxian insight that rep- resentations of nature are always socially situated and directed becomes particularly useful. EcoMarxists recognize that representations of nature can have a materiality and effectivity that is vital in protecting environments from economic over- exploitation, just as it did in the fur seal case. In other words, “ideologies of nature” need not always be directed to exploitative ends. But the Marxian view also recog- nizes that because those ideologies are aimed at achieving very particular ends, they may conceal as much as they reveal, even when directed to positive goals like envi- ronmental protection. In the case of the Pribilof seals this was particularly impor- tant: because the preservationist discourse of “wildest nature” largely remained blind to an Aleut population integrally tied to the American seal economy and sold into what historian Dorothy Jones (1980) calls “a century of servitude.” Despite the thousands of words written about the Pribilofs, Hornaday and his associates – like the US government and the other signatories to the 1911 Conven- tion – said remarkably little about the condition of the Pribilof Aleuts. Symptomatic of this was the Pribilofs’ alternative name, the “Seal Islands,” a title implying that their defining feature was their occupation by wild sea mammals. Yet the Pribilofs were also home to a Pribilof Aleut population without whose labor power the American seal trade simply could not have prospered. The Aleuts had been forcibly transported to the Pribilofs from Fox Island by the Russians in the late eighteenth century. Part serfs, part wage laborers, they were retained by the RAC to undertake NATURE, ECONOMY, AND THE CULTURAL POLITICS OF THEORY 187 much of the annual killing, skinning, and salting of seals. When the Americans pur- chased Alaska in 1867, serfdom was abolished and the Aleuts were paid for all their labor by the ACC and NACC respectively. But this shift to an apparently fair and free system of wage labor concealed a darker side which made the treatment of the Aleuts one of the scandals of US–native relationships. True, the Aleuts received wages comparable to those of the average American worker. But they were paid in credit, not cash, and forced to buy from a limited range of goods at the Company stores at marked-up prices. It is also true that the Companies were required to provide schooling and housing for their Aleut workers. But schooling was based on the white American model and the speaking of the Aleut language was discouraged. Likewise the provision of “free” housing entailed destroying traditional Aleut barabaras (turf-roofed, half-underground dwellings) and replacing them with wooden structures which were harder and more costly to heat. In addition to these relations with the Companies, the Aleuts were overseen by the Treasury Agent, who exercised enormous power on the islands. Movement within and between the islands was severely restricted. No unauthorized vessels or visitors could leave or land there. And modes of work- and public-behavior were closely regulated through financial penalty, with wages docked or fines levied for “improper” conduct. In short, even though paid an “acceptable” wage, the Aleuts were to all intents and purposes a captive population regulated and controlled to a degree that abrogated all accepted standards of liberty and equality. Not surprisingly, with little opportunity or power to articulate their claims and grievances, the condition of the Pribilof Aleuts was little known. So while the discourse of preservationists helped prevent the seal herd disap- pearing, it did so at the expense of not improving the condition of those to whom the seal economy was bound. This, I think, has implications for the present. For much of modern day North American environmentalism repeats this effacement of the social habitation of what are constructed as purely “natural” landscapes (see Willems-Braun, 1997).

Conclusion: The Cultural Politics of Theory In seeing the “production of nature” as an overarching process, in which material relationships and discursive representations are both vital and intertwined, an eco- Marxian approach reveals a complex political economy to seal exploitation that laissez-faire environmentalism misses and which ecocentrists may only partly grasp. It also emphasizes the fact that environmental problems emphatically begin and end in the realms of human practice: there is no representation of “nature” outside social interests and political agendas. But for all its usefulness, the Marxian approach must also be vigilant about its own blind spots and aporias. This returns me to the Pribilof Aleuts. Over the last few years a number of postcolonial critics have drawn attention to what Shohat and Stam (1994) call the “buried epistemologies” of Western critical theory, namely the presuppositions they smuggle in to their attempts to comprehend the world. Marxism, in particular, has come under fire in this regard because of its Eurocentrism, that is, its imposition of European categories of criti- cal thought onto non-Western settings where they may not be so appropriate (Serequerbehan, 1990; Slater, 1992). In the case of the Pribilofs, a Marxist optic 188 NOEL CASTREE usefully directs our attention to the imbrication of Aleuts and seals in an exploita- tive and ecologically destructive political economy. But in so doing it paradigmati- cally frames the Aleuts as class subjects, whose main defining feature is their place in social relations of production. As a corollary, it would also have us recover the class agency of the Aleuts and so reveal a history of exploitation and conflict that for too long remained hidden. These paradigmatic maneuvers are important and necessary – for the Aleuts were undoubtedly exploited along rather obvious class lines and did engage in quotidien acts of resistance – but they are not sufficient. I say this for two reasons. First, the subjection of the Aleuts exceeded class exploita- tion. The array of exclusionary practices and oppressive restrictions they encoun- tered were very much bound up with their “non-white” status and so equally tied to an economy of racial and ethnic discrimination. Second, where Marxism would have us recover the agency and consciousness of the exploited – rather as E. P. Thompson did for the English working classes – postcolonial critics point out the problems with such apparently well-intentioned “recovery.” As Spivak (1988) argues in her controversial essay “Can the subaltern speak?,” recovering “sub- altern” voices is complicated by the fact that those voices are always already written by those in power. In this case, our understanding of Pribilof Aleut agency a century ago is almost exclusively scripted by the resident Agents and, as such, filtered through the terms of the dominant culture on the islands. In other words, the his- torical archive already comes to us infused with the power relations that marginal- ized Aleuts in the first place. For these two reasons, any critical project to adequately reconstruct the history of seal exploitation on the Pribilofs in all its dimensions cannot be based on Marxian precepts alone. Chapter 12 Modernity and Hybridity: Nature, Regeneracionismo, and the Production of the Spanish Waterscape, 1890–1930

Erik Swyngedouw

I am planning something geographical. (Klaus Kinski, the film Fitzcarraldo, directed by Werner Herzog)

The Hydraulic ordering of the territory constitutes a structural necessity of Spanish society as an industrial society. (Ortí, 1984, p. 11)

Spain is arguably the European country where the water crisis has become most acute in recent years. Since 1975, demand for water has systematically outstripped supply and, despite major and unsustainable attempts to increase pumping of ground water and to develop a more intensive use of surface water, the problem has intensified significantly. The recent 1991–1995 drought, which affected most of Central and Southern Spain, spearheaded intense political debate, particularly as the cyclical resurgence of diminished water supply from rainwater coincided with the preparation (since, 1985) of the Second National Hydrological Plan (MOPT, 1993; Ruiz, 1993; Gómez Mendoza and del Moral Ituarte, 1995; del Moral Ituarte, 1996). The political and ecological importance of water is not, however, only a recent development in Spain. Throughout this century, water politics, economics, culture, and engineering have infused and embodied the myriad tensions and conflicts that drove and still drive Spanish society. And although the significance of water on the Iberian peninsula (see Figure 12.1) has attracted considerable scholarly and other attention, the central role of water politics, water culture, and water engineering in shaping Spanish society on the one hand, and the contemporary water geography and ecology of Spain as the product of centuries of socioecological interaction on the other, have remained largely unexplored. Yet very little, if anything, in today’s Spanish social, economic, and ecological landscape can be understood without explicit reference to the changing position of water in the unfolding of Spanish society. The hybrid character of the water landscape, or “waterscape,” comes to the fore in Spain in a clear and unambiguous manner. Hardly any river basin, hydrological cycle, or water flow has not been subjected to some form of human 190 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW

Atlantic Ocean Santander F R A N C E Oviedo PAIS ASTURIAS VASCO Santiago de Pamplona Compostela Vitoria CANTABRIA NAVARRA GALICIA Logrono N RIOJA CATALUÑA CASTILLA Y LEON Zaragoza Barcelona Valladolid ARAGON

MADRID Madrid

Toledo Valencia Palma de EXTREMADURA CASTILLA- Mallorca P O R T U G A L LA MANCHA Mérida ISLAS VALENCIA BALEARES

Murcia Mediterranean Sea ANDALUSIA MURCIA Savilla

Boundary of autonomous region 150 miles Capital city

Figure 12.1 The Iberian Peninsula, Spain, and its Autonomous Regions

intervention or use; not a single form of social change can be understood without simultaneously addressing and understanding the transformations of and in the hydrological process. The socionatural production of Spanish society, I maintain, can be illustrated by excavating the central role of water politics and engineering in Spain’s modernization process. I intend to situate the political-ecological processes around water in Spain in the context of what Neil Smith (1984) defined as “the production of nature.” In par- ticular, I shall argue that the tumultuous process of modernization in Spain and its contemporary condition, both in environmental and political-economic terms, are wrought from historical spatial-ecological transformations. Modernization in Spain was a decidedly geographical project that became expressed in and through the intense spatial transformation of Spain in this century. This transformation is one in which water and the waterscape play a pivotal role. The contradictions and ten- sions inherent in the process that is commonly referred to as “modernization” are, I maintain, expressed by and worked through the transformation of nature and society. The “modern” environment and waterscape in Spain is what Latour (1993) would refer to as a “hybrid,” a thing-like appearance (a “permanence” as Harvey [1996] would call it) that is part natural and part social, and that embodies a multiplicity of historical-geographical relations and processes. MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 191

The main portion of the paper is divided into two parts. In the first, I develop a theoretical and methodological perspective that is explicitly critical of traditional approaches in water-resources studies, which tend to separate various aspects of the hydrological cycle into discrete and independent objects of study. The traditional hydrological, engineering, geographical, political, sociological, economic, and cul- tural perspectives on water have produced a piecemeal perspective that maintains a particular water ideology, one that is increasingly less able to contribute in creative and innovative ways to the mitigation of growing problems associated with con- temporary water practices (Ward, 1997). My perspective, broadly situated within the political ecology tradition, draws critically from recent work by ecological his- torians, cultural critics, sociologists of science, critical social theorists, and political economists. Although researchers working within mainstream perspectives pay lip service to considering the hydrological cycle as a complex, multifaceted, and global network, one that includes physical as well as human elements, they rarely over- come the dualisms of the nature/society divide, and they continue to isolate parts from the totality (see, for a review, Castree, 1995; Demeritt, 1994; Gerber, 1997). My main objective is to bring together what has been severed for too long by insist- ing that nature and society are deeply intertwined. In the second part of the paper, I excavate the origins of Spain’s early-twentieth- century modernization process (1890–1930) as expressed in debates and actions around the hydrological condition. The conceptual framework presented in the first part helps structure a narrative that weaves water through the network of socionat- ural relations in ways that permit the recasting of modernity as a deeply geographi- cal, although by no means coherent, homogeneous, total, or uncontested, project. If the social and the natural cannot be severed, but are intertwined in perpetually changing ways in the production processes of both society and the physical envi- ronment, then the rather opaque idea of “the production of nature” may become clearer. In sum, I seek to document how the socionatural is historically produced to generate a particular, but inherently dynamic, geographical configuration.

On Hybrids and Socionature: Flow, Process, and Dialectics Contemporary scholars increasingly recognize that natural or ecological conditions and processes do not operate separately from social processes, and that the actually existing socionatural conditions are always the result of intricate transformations of preexisting configurations that are themselves inherently natural and social. For example, David Harvey (1996) insists that there is nothing particularly unnatural about New York City. Urban areas, regions, or any other outcome of sociospatial processes or conditions exist in a network of interwoven processes that are simul- taneously human, natural, material, cultural, mechanical, and organic. The myriad processes that support and maintain social life, such as, for example, water, energy, food, or computers, always combine society and nature in infinite ways; yet simul- taneously, these hybrid socionatural “things” are full of contradictions, tensions, and conflicts. They are proliferating objects that Donna Haraway calls “cyborgs” (Haraway, 1991) or that Bruno Latour refers to as “quasi-objects” (Latour, 1993); these hybrid, part social/part natural – yet deeply historical and thus produced – objects/subjects are intermediaries that embody and express nature and society and 192 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW weave networks of infinite liminal spaces. For example, if I were to capture some water in a cup and excavate the networks that brought it there, “I would pass with continuity from the local to the global, from the human to the nonhuman” (Latour, 1993, p. 121). These flows would narrate many interrelated tales, or stories, of social groups and classes and the powerful socioecological processes that produce social spaces of privilege and exclusion, of participation and marginality; chemical, physi- cal, and biological reactions and transformations, the global hydrological cycle, and global warming; capital, machinations, and the strategies and knowledges of dam builders, urban land developers, and engineers; the passage from river to urban reservoir, and the geopolitical struggles between regions and nations. In sum, water embodies multiple tales of socionature as hybrid. The rhizome of underground and surface water flows and the streams, pipes, and canals that come together in water gushing from fountains, taps, and irrigation channels is a powerful metaphor for a deeply interconnected socionature. The excavation of the production of these hybrid networks and their prolifera- tion with the intensification of the modernization process entails a constructionist view in both a material and discursive sense. In both the Grundrisse and Capital, Marx insisted on the natural foundations of social development. Any materialist approach necessarily adheres to a perspective that insists that nature is an integral part of the metabolism of social life. Social relations operate in and through metabo- lizing the natural environment which, in turn, transforms both society and nature and produces altered or new socionatural forms (see Grundmann, 1991; Benton, 1996). While “Nature” (as a historical product) provides the foundation, social rela- tions produce nature’s and society’s history. Of course, the ambition of classical Marxism was wider than reconstructing the dialectics of historical socionatural transformations and their contradictions. It also insisted on the ideological notion of “nature” in bourgeois science and society, just as it claimed to uncover “Truth” through the excavation of underlying socioecological processes (Schmidt, 1971; Benton, 1989). By concentrating on the labor process per se, however, many Marxist analysts tended to replicate the very problem they meant to criticize. In particular, by rendering nature as the substratum for the unfolding of social relations, espe- cially labor relations, they maintained the material basis for social life, while rele- gating natural processes to a realm outside of social life and, hence, outside history. I would argue, with Latour (1993), that the process of separating and purifying things natural and social resides in the conceptual and discursive construction of the world into two separate, but profoundly interrelated realms – nature and society – between which a dialectical relationship unfolds. The debate, then, becomes a dispute about the nature of this dialectical relationship, its implications, and the absence or presence of an ontological foundation from which nature and the social are distinguished and distinguishable. This form of dialectical argumentation runs as follows. Humans encounter nature, with its internal dynamics, principles, and laws, embedded in a society with its own organizing principles. This encounter inflicts consequences on both. The dialectic between nature and society becomes an external one, that is, a recursive relationship between two separate fields, nature and society, which is mediated by material, ideological, and representational prac- tices. The product, then, is the thing (object or subject) that is produced out of this dynamic encounter. MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 193

Neil Smith (1984, 1996), in contrast, insists that nature is an integral part of the process of production or, in other words, that society and nature are integral to each other and produce permanencies (or thing-like moments) in their unity. The notion of “the production of nature,” borrowed and reinterpreted from Lefebvre (1991), suggests that socionature itself is a historical-geographical process (and therefore time/place-specific). It insists on the inseparability of society and nature and main- tains the unity of socionature as a process. In brief, both society and nature are pro- duced, and are hence malleable, transformable, and potentially transgressive. Smith does not suggest that all nonhuman processes are socially produced, although he insists that all nature, including social nature, is a historical-geographical process (see also Levins and Lewontin, 1985; Lewontin, 1993). He argues instead that the idea of some sort of pristine nature (“First Nature” in Lefebvre’s account) becomes increasingly problematic as new “nature” (in the sense of different forms of “nature”) is produced over space and time. It is this historical-geographical process that led Haraway and Latour to argue that the number of hybrids and quasi-objects proliferates and multiplies. Indeed, from the very beginning of human history, but accelerating as the modernization process intensified, the objects and subjects of daily life became increasingly socionatural. If we maintain a view of dialectics as internal relations (Olman, 1993; Balibar, 1995; Harvey, 1996) as opposed to external recursive relationships, then we must insist on the need to transcend the binary formations of nature and society and develop a new language that maintains the dialectical unity of the process of change as embodied in the thing itself. “Things” are hybrids or quasi-objects (subjects and objects, material and discursive, natural and social) from the very beginning. By this, I mean that the “world” is a process of perpetual metabolism in which social and natural processes combine in a historical-geographical production process of socionature, whose outcome (historical nature) embodies chemical, physical, social, economic, political, and cultural processes in highly contradictory but inseparable manners. Every body and thing is a mediator, part social, part natural (but without discrete boundaries), which internalizes the multiple contradictory relations that redefine and rework every body and thing. Figure 12.2 summarizes this argument. None of the component parts is reducible to the other, yet their constitution arises from the multiple dialectical relations that swirl out from the production process itself. Consequently, the parts are always implicated in the constitution of the “thing” and are never outside the process of its making. In sum, then, the above perspective is a process-based episteme in which nothing is ever fixed or, at best, fixity is the transient moment; nothing can be captured in its entirety as the flows perpetually destroy and create, combine and separate. This particular dialectical perspective also insists on the nonneutrality of relations in terms of both their operation and their outcome, thereby politicizing both processes and fluxes. It also sees distinct categories (nature, society, city, species, water, etc.) as the outcome of the infusion of materially discursive practices that are, each time, creatively destroyed in the very production of socionature. The above perspective will guide my narrative on the production of the modern Spanish waterscape at the turn of the century, when a distinct discourse and rhetoric of modernization emerged. This modernization drive, which permeated the whole of Spanish society, would generate the anchoring framework for key social, 194 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW

Representational practices

Discursive constructions Language

Ideological Hybrids Social practices Quasi-objects relations

Bio-chemical Cultural practices physical processes

Material practices

Figure 12.2 Hybridization: the production of socionature political, cultural, and technical debates and practices until the present day. Multi- ple narratives that move around the spiral presented in Figure 12.2 will be woven together to reconstruct the relations of power inscribed in the discursive, ideologi- cal, cultural, material, and scientific practices through which the Spanish waterscape became constructed and reconstructed as a socionatural space that reflects Spain’s contested modernization process and the relations of power inscribed therein.

The Production of Nature: Water and Modernization in Spain I shall not begin by analyzing the Spanish water map from the available hydrolog- ical data and the physical characteristics of the water basins. Such an entrée would surely be important, but prioritizing these things would miss the central tenet of the argument outlined above. Indeed, these very physical conditions and characteristics are not absolute, stable, and God-given characteristics. On the contrary, the history of Spain’s modernization has been a history of altering, redefining, and transform- ing these very physical characteristics. What is more, Spain’s hydrological charac- teristics have been infused with social practices, cultural meanings, political and economic ideologies, and engineering principles for a very long time. It was not until the late nineteenth century that the socionatural production process of contempo- rary Spain accelerated. From that moment onwards, Spain – belatedly, somewhat reluctantly, and almost desperately – launched itself on a path of accelerating modernization. Of course, modernization through socionatural changes always takes place within already constructed historical socionatural conditions. On occa- sion, I shall refer to and highlight these conditions. For the present purposes, which are to document and substantiate the notion of the production of nature and to elaborate how Spain’s modernization process became, and remains, a deeply geo- graphical project, it will suffice to chart the tumultuous, contradictory, and often MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 195

100 NORTE 50 F R A N C E 0 132 4 5

Norte 100 EBRO 100 50 N DUERO 50 0 1234 5 0 1234 5 Duero

Ebro

100 TAJO 50 100 JUCAR 0 50 1342 5 0 1234 5 Tajo 100 Main rivers GUADIANA 50 Hydrographic P O R T U G A L 0 Confederation 1234 5 100 SEGURA boundary 50 100 0 GUADALQUIVIRGUADALAQUIVIR 1234 5 Key to charts 50 Guadiana Number of 0 1234 5 dams constructed 100 50 100 1 = Before 1900 SUR 0 50 2 = 1900–1935 1234 5 3 = 1936–1970 150 miles 0 Time period in history 1234 54 = 1971–1986 5 = After 1986

Figure 12.3 Evolution of dam construction in Spain for each of the Hydrographic Confederations (river basin authorities). Data excludes Islas Canarias and Pirineo Oriental Source: Ministerio de Obras Públicas y Urbanismo (1990). Plan Hidrólogico – Síntesis de la Documentación. Madrid: Dirección General de Obras Hidraulicas, pp. 32–33. very complex historical-geography of Spain’s modernization through water engi- neering. Today the country has almost nine hundred dams, more than eight hundred of which have been constructed in this century alone (see Figure 12.3). Not a single river basin has not been altered, managed, engineered, and transformed. Water has been an obsessive theme in Spain’s national life during this century, and the quest for water continues unabated (del Moral Ituarte, 1998). From the turn of the century onwards, water rapidly became a prime consideration in national political, socio- economic, and cultural debates.

Modernization as a Geographical Project: The Production of Space/Nature The dominant form of socioeconomic development in Spain until the late nineteenth century had combined colonial trade with domestic farming. The latter was based on primarily southern large-estate dryland-culture by latifundistas whose economic position depended on a protectionist stance. The effects of increasingly liberalized 196 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW international trade after 1880 (Carr, 1983), combined with the loss of the last Spanish colonies in 1898, led to disastrous socioeconomic conditions and rapidly rising social conflicts that intensified already sharp social tensions in the country- side (Fontana, 1975; Garrabou, 1975). The traditional agricultural elites were faced with the emergence of modernizing elites, both agricultural and industrial, who began to challenge the political-economic and ideological dominance of the lati- fundistas. The proletarianization process, combined with sharpening crisis condi- tions, intensified class struggle in both the city and countryside. Industrialization, mainly focused in Catalonia and in the Basque Country (Angoustures, 1995), intensified the city/countryside divide, accentuated already long-standing interregional conflicts, and fed demands for greater regional auton- omy. Containing and working through these tensions without revolutionary trans- formation necessitated a vision around which the modernizing social groups could ally through a project of national regeneration. This revitalization, which became formulated as a project of geographical restructuring, combined major environ- mental change, socioeconomic restructuring, and moral revival, all of which were linked in a regeneracionist ideological discourse. Driever (1998, p. 37) summarizes: “Spain was portrayed as part of a new world order in which Spaniards had to inter- penetrate with their natural environment and geographical space in order not to perish as the international marketplace reordered the world through economic competition.” This national geographical project would revolve around the hydrological/agri- cultural nexus. Spain’s “geographical problem” became the axis around which the sociocultural and economic malaise was explained, and where the course of action resided. One of the key protagonists articulating this revival-through-modernization was Joaquín Costa (1846–1911), the most prominent and visible figure of the radical regeneracionism promoted by the intellectuals. Born the son of a poor peasant from Aragon, he was a self-educated intellectual whose influential and prolific writings covered politics, social reform, education, and agricultural and hydraulic policies, among many other themes. His relentless struggle against poverty and the socio- economic and political disintegration of Spain propelled him to the forefront of the public debates at the time (see Ortega, 1975; Carr, 1983; Pérez, 1999). In 1892, he wrote that state-organized hydraulic politics should be a national objective “capable of reworking the geography of the Fatherland and of solving the complex agricul- tural and social problems” (Costa, 1892, p. 88). For Costa, fusing the production of a new geography with a revolutionization of the internal operation of the state would help mitigate social tensions and provide the basis for a promodernist and popular petty-production-based development process (Ortí, 1994). The realization of such an ambitious project of mobilizing resources and educating the people demanded thorough geographical knowledge, though of a particular kind. As Gómez Mendoza and Ortega Cantero (1987, p. 80) argue, “the real patriotism is the bedrock of the regeneracionist project and this patriotism flows from the exact knowledge of the geographical reality of the country” (my translation). In 1918, Rafael Altamira (1923, p. 168–69), another leading intellectual, wrote that the description of Spain’s geography offers a great lesson in patriotism, while Azorín (José Martínez Ruiz) concluded in 1916 that “the basis of patriotism is geo- graphy” (Azorín, 1982, p. 512). In this view, the only means by which to solve the MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 197 national problem was through the problem of the land – the physical nature of the territory. This project to remake Spanish geography as a part of modernization combined a decidedly political strategy, a particular ideological vision, a call for a scientific- positivist understanding of the natural world, a scientific-technocratic engineering mission, and a popular base rooted in a traditional peasant rural culture. Plenty of evidence can be found for this in Costa’s work and in that of his contemporaries (for a review, see Pérez De La Dehesa, 1966; Tuñon De Lara, 1971; Ortí, 1976). The revolution in the state – but certainly not of the state – was effected through a politics of spatial and environmental transformation that would center around the defense of the small peasant producer-cum-landowner, communal (state) control of water, educational enhancement, technical-scientific knowledge, and the leap to power of an alliance of small holders and the new bourgeoisie that hitherto had been largely marginalized by the aristocratic landowning elite and their associated administrators in the state apparatus. At the same time, the focus on restoring or, in fact, expanding landownership through “internal colonization” fostered growth in and concentrated the efforts of an “organically” organized state that brought reformist intellectuals, some worker movements, and the nascent industrial bour- geoisie together in a more or less coherent vision of reform against the traditional- ists (Ortega, 1975). The geographical project became, as such, the glue around which often unlikely partners could coalesce, while excluding both the more radical, left-wing revolutionaries and the “radical” conservatives. Surely, the sublimation of the many tensions and conflicts within this loose alliance of reformists, when accom- plished through a focus on reorganizing Spain’s hydraulic geography, served the purpose of providing a discursive vehicle to ally hitherto excluded social groups without defining the problem purely in class or other conflictual social terms (see Nadal Reimat, 1981).

Water as the Linchpin to Spain’s Modernization Drive Los Pantanos o la Muerte! [Dams or Death!] (Pérez, 1999, p. 504)

If the “remaking” of Spain’s geography became the great modernizing adagio, then water and hydrological engineering were its master tools. Joaquín Costa became one of the prime advocates and potent symbols of this broad social movement for modernization through geographical restructuring. His “hydrological solution” would be the substratum for fostering growth by permitting social and land reforms and encouraging cultural emancipation (Ortega, 1975). His writings would be invoked time and time again by a wide variety of social groups to defend and legit- imize national hydraulic programs and the policy of land reform through “internal colonial” settlements. The regeneracionist project became formulated as a “hydro- logical correction of the national geographical problem” (Gómez Mendoza, 1992, p. 236). For Costa, hydraulic politics sublimated the totality of the nation’s eco- nomic program, not only for agriculture, but for the whole of Spanish socio- economic life. Hydraulic constructions for irrigation purposes were regarded as a progressive alternative to the traditional policy of tariffs and import restrictions, 198 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW which were supported by dryland latifundistas (Torres Campos, 1907). At base, the hydraulic foundation necessitating el regeneracionismo resided in the uneven dis- tribution of rainfall and the torrential and intermittent nature of Spain’s fluvial system, which was said to make the country “the antechamber of Africa” (de Reparez, 1906). The great modernizing drive of the revivalists therefore demanded not only an imitation and use of nature, but its creation: “[increasing] the amount of fertile soil by making a hydraulic artery system cross the whole country – a national network of dams and irrigation channels” (Gómez Mendoza and Ortega Cantero, 1992, p. 174). In “El Problema Nacional,” Ricardo Macías Picavea (1899, pp. 318–20), a leading regeneracionist essayist and intellectual, summarizes the hydraulic mission as a necessary strategy for national development:

There are countries which . . . can solely and exclusively become civilized with such a hydraulic policy, planned and developed by means of designated grand works. Spain is among them . . . And the truth is that Spanish civilized agriculture finds itself strongly subjected to this inexorable dilemma: to have water or to die . . . Therefore, a hydraulic politics imposes itself; this requires changing all the national forces in the direction of this gigantic enterprise. ...We have to dare to restore great lakes, create real interior seas of sweet water, multiply vast marshes, erect many great dams, and mine, exploit and withhold the drops of water that fall over the peninsula without returning, if pos- sible, a single drop to the sea.

This patriotic mission, requiring the convergence of all national forces, fused around the hydraulic program, which then became the embodiment and representation of a collective myth of national development. This project was sustained and inspired by a reformist geographical optimism, which substituted for the social and politi- cal pessimism of Spain’s turn-of-the-century condition (Ortí, 1984, p. 18). The hydraulic utopia of abundant waters for all would not only produce an “ecologi- cal harmony,” but also contribute to the formation of a socially harmonious order. The production of a new hydraulic geography would reconcile the ever-growing social tensions in the Spanish countryside, tensions that were taking acute class forms and that resulted from the adverse and conflictual conditions of scarcity and inequality. According to Alfonso Ortí (1984, p. 12), the symbolic power of this material intervention to achieve “hydraulic regeneration” constituted “a mythical power, a collective illusion, and the imagined reconciliation of diverse ideologies.” This specific form of regeneration served the productionist logic of the new liberal bourgeoisie that aspired to transform society and space according to the principles of capitalist profitability. It was aimed at facilitating Spain’s integration into Europe’s modernization process.

The State as Master Socioenvironmental Engineer “To irrigate is to govern.” (Costa, [1892] 1975)

Such an ambitious perspective to regenerate Spain through a geographical project necessitated concerted action and collective control. The regeneracionists welcomed MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 199 the liberation of international markets and the demise of nineteenth-century pro- tectionism under which the dryland latifundistas of (mainly southern and central) Spain flourished. By 1880, trade liberalization had plunged them into a deep crisis in the aftermath of the expansion of the US wheat export boom. The traditional landed bourgeoisie was economically weakened as a result, but their political com- mitment to maintain their power at both national and local scales did not abate. This control permitted the continuation, if not the reinforcement, of a strong pro- tectionist economic policy framework. The central-state intervened nevertheless to produce a nature amenable to the requirements of a modernized, competitive, and irrigated agriculture (Ortega, 1975). This was considered essential to the implementation of hydraulic works that would “remake the geography of the fatherland” (Costa, 1892, cited in del Moral Ituarte, 1998, p. 121), revive the national economy, and “regenerate the people” [la raza] (del Moral Ituarte, 1998, p. 121). The hydraulic politics were, for Costa (1975), a way to place Spain within a European sociospatial framework, after its loss of influ- ence in the Americas, on the basis of a rural development vision that combined a Rousseauan ideal with a small-scaled, independent, and democratic peasant society. The promotion of the rural ideal on the basis of a petty-bourgeois ideology would become the spinal cord of the liberal state and the route to the Europeanization of the nation (Nadal Reimat, 1981, p. 139; Fernández Clemente, 1990). The growing demand for water and the requirements for a more efficient and equitable distribution of irrigation waters necessitated a fundamental change in the legal status and appropriation rights of water. The liberal revolution in Spain (approximately 1811–1873), which had attempted an institutional (anti)feudal restructuring to promote capitalist forms of ownership and the circulation of goods as commodities, extended also to what Maluquer de Motes (1983, p. 76) called the “depatrimonialization of water.” The existence of seignorial rights over water pre- vented or blocked the development of productive activities that necessitated ever- larger quantities of water. Although the depatrimonialization of land and water reinforced their private character, the growing political and economic crisis of lib- eralism towards the end of the century prevented the state from embarking on a productivist and privately run program to maximize production “to the last drop of water” (Gómez Mendoza and Ortega Cantero, 1992, p. 174). The regeneracionist vision, then, faced with the failure of privatized and commodified water to operate as an efficient allocative and productive instrument, promoted the emergence of a collective spirit (“illusion” in the words of Alfonso Ortí [1984, p. 14]). The latter implied that the supply of the necessary quantities of water was only possible under a public and socialized form of coordination managed through the state. This collective and state-led but productivist and modernizing vision, would eventually also include the state-led production of “great hydraulic works” (Ortega, 1975; Villaneuva Larraya, 1991). In sum, the regeneracionists turned to the state – after the failure of the Liberal project to defeat the feudal elites – as the agent that could generate a sufficiently large volume of capital to mobilize the nation’s natural resources. Moreover, for Costa, the productivist modernization by means of the hydraulic motor would in fact consolidate the liberal state in Spain. In short, a free- market-based, intensive, and productive national economy, whose accumulation process would accelerate on a par with other northern European states, necessitated 200 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW a transformation in the state in a double and deeply contradictory sense. Power rela- tions within the state apparatus needed to change in favor of, first, a more mod- ernist alliance of petty-owners, industrialists, and modernizing engineers, and second, revolutionary social reform supported by the state such that the grand hydraulic works could lay the foundations for a modernizing Spain. These two tasks were of course mutually dependent, and yet irreconcilable. Strong traditional forces fought to maintain control over key state functions and prevented the rise to polit- ical power of the nascent petty-owners and middle classes. This firm hold of the traditional conservative elites blocked most attempts at modernizing the social economy. The mosaic of contradictory forces and the resistance of the traditional- ists would stall state-led modernizing efforts, resulting in more acute and openly fought social antagonisms throughout the first two decades of the century. These would eventually pave the way for dictatorial regimes. Despite the collectivist discourse of much of the regeneracionist literature, it remained deeply committed to a project of insertion into an international capitalist market. Although the state needed to take central control over water and forests, it should do so on the basis of a landownership structure that was essentially private and market-led (see also Fernández Clemente, 1990). The hydraulic agenda of Costa and his colleagues was clouded with revolutionary claims but defended as a reformist route for development against the stronghold of an antireformist, eco- nomically and culturally conservative and protectionist elite. In sum, two models of capitalist accumulation, with evidently different supporting social groups and allies, crystallized around the hydraulic debates at the time. The social, political, and eco- logical consequences and implications of these two models would differ fundamen- tally even while sharing an organicist vision of the world. On the one hand, the traditionalists defended a protectionist economic stance and the continuation of existing political and social power relations. On the other, the regeneracionists advo- cated a more liberal perspective, a rapid modernization of the economy, and a trans- formation of sociopolitical power relations. The issue of land ownership and the role of water therein revolved around the question of who would own and control what part of the land and its waters. For the regeneracionists, for whom petty own- ership constituted the way ahead, the hydraulic route was an essential precondition, while the limited possibilities for accumulation pointed to the state as the only body that could generate the required investment funds on the one hand and push through the necessary reforms in the face of strong and sustained opposition from the landed aristocracy on the other (Ortega, 1975, 1992). At the same time, the very support of at least some sections of the old elites could be secured via this reformist route, since it did not threaten their fundamental rights as landowners but defended rural power against the rising tide of the urban industrial elites and the proletariat. This was indeed quite central to forging the support of the dominant Catholic groups that defended a solidaristic and organic model of social cohesion.

Purification and the Transformation of Nature: Hydraulic Engineers as Producers of Socionature The hydraulic intervention to create a waterscape supportive of the modernizing desires of the revivalists, without questioning the social and political foundations MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 201 of the existing class structure and social order, was very much based on a respect for “natural” laws and conditions. The latter were assumed to be or thought of as intrinsically stable, balanced, equitable, and harmonious. The hydraulic engineer- ing mission consisted primarily in “restoring” the “perturbed” equilibrium of the erratic hydrological cycles in Spain. This endeavor required a significant scientific and engineering enterprise, first in terms of understanding and analyzing nature’s “laws,” and, second, in using these insights to work toward a restoration of the “innate” harmonious development of nature. The moral, economic, and cultural “disorder” and “imbalances” of the country at the time paralleled the “disorder” in Spain’s erratic hydraulic geography, both of which needed to be restored and rebalanced (as nature’s innate laws suggested) to produce a socially harmonious development. Two threads have to be woven together in this context: the pivotal position of a particular group of scientists in the hydraulic arena, the Corps of Engineers (Villaneuva Larraya, 1991), and the changing visions concerning the sci- entific management of the terrestrial part of the hydrological cycle. Both, in turn, were linked to the rising prominence of hydraulic issues on the sociopolitical agenda at the turn of the century. The Corps of Engineers, founded in 1799, was (and remains) the professional collective responsible for the development and implementation of public works. It is a highly elitist, intellectualist, “high-cultured,” male-dominated, socially homo- geneous, and exclusive corporatist organization that has, over the centuries, taken a leading role in Spanish politics and development (Mateu Bellés, 1995). The decision-making structure is hierarchical and all key managerial and institutional bodies, such as the “Junta Consultiva de las Obras Públicas,” the hydrological divi- sions, the provincial headquarters, and various ad hoc study commissions are exclu- sively “manned” by engineers. In line with the emergent scientific discourse on orography and river-basin structure and dynamics, the engineering community argued for the foundation of engineering and managerial intervention on the basis of the “natural” integrated water flow of a basin, rather than on the basis of his- torically and socially formed administrative regions (see Figure 12.4). The emergent geographical regionalization overlaid the traditional political-administrative divi- sions of the country, forcing a reordering of the territory on the basis of the country’s orographical structure. The latter, in turn, was portrayed by the engineers as the crucial planning unit for hydraulic interventions. Cano García (1992, p. 312) suc- cinctly summarizes this scientific perspective: “To revert to the great orographical delimitation for organizing the division of the land represents a contribution made from within the strict field of our discipline [engineering] and at the same time, at least initially, it shows the abandoning of traditional political divisions and the importance of other perspectives and concepts.” The history of the delimitation of hydrological divisions is infused with the influ- ence of the regeneracionist discourse on the one hand and the scientific insights gained from hydrology and orography on the other. The attempt to “naturalize” political territorial organization was part and parcel of a strategy of the moderniz- ers to challenge existing social and political power geometries. The construction of and command over a new territorial scale might permit them to implement their vision and bypass more traditional and reactionary power configurations. The complex history of the formation of river-basin authorities and their articulation 202 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW

F R A N C E

P O R T U G A L

N

Autonomous region 150 miles Hydrographic Confederation

Figure 12.4 Boundaries of the Autonomous Regions and the Hydrographic Confederations with other political forms of territorial organization, in particular the national state, is a long, complicated, and tortuous one. “Nature” would become inextricably con- nected to the choreography of power, while the scientific discourse on nature was strategically marshaled to serve power struggles for the control over and manage- ment of water. The river basins would become the scale par excellence through which the modernizers tried to undermine or erode the powers of the more tradi- tional provincial or national state bodies. Therefore, the struggle over the territo- rial organization of intervention expresses the political power struggles between traditionalists and reformers. While the river-basin defenders would become the founding “fathers” of the regeneracionist agenda, the traditional elites held to the existing administrative territorial structure of power. The regeneracionist engineers thereby incorporated the naturalized river basins into their political project. Cap- turing the scale of the river basin as the geographical basis for exercising control and power over the organization, planning, and reconstruction of the hydraulic landscape was one of the central arenas through which the power of the tradition- alists (and the scales over which they exercised hegemonic control) was challenged. In fact, this rescaling of the state and the articulation of different scales of gover- nance became one of the great arenas of struggle for control and power. The mod- ernizers attempted to take hold of the hydrological divisions and develop them as MODERNITY AND HYBRIDITY 203 pivotal institutions for instigating the hydrological revolution, while the national scale remained more firmly in the hands of the traditional elites. The bumpy history of the hydrological divisions records this struggle. The instability of their adminis- trative and political organization reflects the relative power of the traditional power brokers. It would await Franco’s dictatorship before this issue was resolved, at which time the hydrological dream and its intellectual bearers, the engineers, were aligned with and incorporated into a new fascist-organicist state structure (Gómez Mendoza and Ortega Cantero, 1992). It was only from 1926 onwards, during the dictatorship of Primo de Rivera, that the current Confederaciones Sindicales Hidrográficas were gradually established as quasi-autonomous organizations in charge of managing water as stipulated by the Water Act of 1879 (Giansante, 1999). The last of these ten Confederaciones was only established in 1961 (see Figure 12.4). What had proven impossible to achieve during the first decades of the century was finally implemented during the dicta- torship. It is also from that moment on that their names reflected the river basins for which they were responsible rather than the previous political-territorial naming. In addition, they acquired a certain political status with participation from the state, banks, chambers of commerce, provincial authorities, etc. At each stage, the engi- neers took the lead roles and became the activists of the regeneracionist project through the combination of their legitimization as the holders of scientific knowl- edge and their privileged position as a politically elite corps within the state appa- ratus. The complex and perpetually changing administrative organization and power structures associated with the successive attempts to establish river-basin authorities, and their relative lack of power until the 1930s, reflect the failure of the early modernizers to fundamentally challenge existing power lineages and scales (Mateu Bellés, 1994, 1995). It is only from the later 1920s, and in particular during the Franco era, that the regeneracionist project was gradually implemented.

Conclusions In sum, the regeneracionist agenda(s) first maintained that the restoration of wealth in Spain should be based on the knowledge of the laws and balances of nature; second, this restoration required the correction of defects imposed by the geogra- phy of the country and, particularly, its “imbalances in its climatic and hydraulic regimes” (Gómez Mendoza and Ortega Cantero, 1992, p. 173); and third, this enter- prise of geographical rectification could, because of its range and importance, only be carried out by the central public authorities. The hydraulic mission was seen as the solution to the social problems facing Spain at the turn of the century. Failing this, social tensions were bound to intensify, and struggle, if not civil war, would be the likely outcome. Ironically, of course, the voluntarist, powerful, and autocratic hydraulic engineer pursuing a voluntarist program of imposed reform foreshadowed the fascist (falangist) ideology. The latter would gain momentum from the early 1920s onward. Although the debates at the turn of the century indicated a desire to regenerate Spain, conservative forces prevented its actual implementation, and social tension intensified, further destabilizing an already highly fragmented and divisive society. The centralizing fascist regimes that emerged from this turmoil could finally push through the production of a new geography, a new nature, and 204 ERIK SWYNGEDOUW a new waterscape, something the regeneracionists of the turn of the century had so desperately advocated but failed to accomplish. This quasi-object and hybrid thing that, until this very day, embodies Spain’s modernization process, expresses how modernity is deeply and inevitably a geo- graphical project in which the intertwined transformations of nature and society are both medium and expression of shifting power positions that become materialized in the production of new water flows and the construction of new waterscapes. It is the maelstrom of tensions and contradictions that weave the material, discursive, ideological, and representational, together in often-perplexing, always deeply heterogeneous, collages of changing and shifting positions of power and struggle that decisively shaped the production of the Spanish waterscape over the next century. I have attempted to reconstruct multiple and often contradictory narratives that span a broad range of apparently separate instances such as engineering, politics, economics, culture, science, nature, ideology, and discourse through which the tumultuous reordering of sociophysical space is shaped and transformed, and out of which a new socioenvironmental landscape emerges; landscapes that are simul- taneously physical and social, they reflect historical-geographical struggles and social power geometries, and they interiorize the flux and dynamics of sociospatial change. Geographical conditions, this paper has argued, are reconstructed as the outcome of a process of production in which both nature and society are fused together in a way that renders them inseparable, producing a restless “hybrid” quasi-object in which material, representational, and symbolic practices are welded together. Doing geography then implies the excavation and reconstruction of the contested process of the “production of nature.” Of course, this perspective also asks serious questions about who controls, who acts, and who has the power to produce what kind of socionature. The intertwining of nature and society in this production process has indeed profound political implications. As Lewontin (1997, pp. 137–38), a Harvard biologist, maintains:

The constructionist view of organism and environment is of some consequence to human action. . . . Remaking the world is the universal property of living organisms and is inextricably bound up with their nature. ...We must decide what kind of world we want to live in and then try to manage the process of change as best as we can approximate it. Chapter 13 Oil as Money: The Devil’s Excrement and the Spectacle of Black Gold

Michael J. Watts

Introduction Gold which the devil gives his paramours turns into excrement after his departure. (Freud, 1955, p. 174)

I call petroleum “the devil’s excrement.” It brings trouble. . . . The [oil money] hasn’t brought us any benefits. ...We are drowning in the devil’s excrement. (Juan Pablo Perez Alfonso, founder of OPEC, 1976, cited in Karl, 1982, p. 316)

After what has been said money is seen to be nothing other than deodorized, dehy- drated shit that has been made to shine. (Ferenczi, 1950, p. 327)

This black gold [petroleum], the magical elan vital for . . . economic takeoff. (Amuzegar, 1982, p. 814)

Gold by itself is fraught with problems, first of all because of its mysterious origins. It comes from the bowels of the earth. . . . Gold is instant wealth [yet] it produces corruption . . . [it] can signify the loss of the soul . . . it scorches fingers and hearts; it is odorless but it is the “devil’s dung.” (Gille, 1986, pp. 258–9)

In 1975, the founder of OPEC and former Venezuelan oil minister Perez Alfonso wrote a book entitled Hundiendonos en el excremento de diablo (We Are Sinking in the Devil’s Excrement). Oil, says Perez, is the Third World’s black gold. Like gold it brings untold wealth and yet it is a supremely powerful and ultimately uncon- trollable force. Like gold in the world of the alchemist, petroleum is a pure fruit of “the subterranean workings of the telluric forces” (Gille, 1986, p. 258), yet it is a brilliant threat. In Perez’s powerful and compelling vision, the natural bounty of oil had, in the magical and mysterious process of being transformed into money, become a putrid and toxic waste. It was as if the Venezuelan “body” suffered from bulimia; an excessive, orgiastic appetite was matched by periodic sickness, which contaminated the national metabolism. Indeed, for Perez the digestion of petroleum 206 MICHAEL J. WATTS

– what was referred to in Venezuela as “sowing the oil” – gave birth to a weak and corrupt society, decadent and degenerate under the accumulated weight of waste and excrement (Coronil, 1987; Karl, 1997). “Manna or malediction?” was how one Venezuelan commentator opened his discussion of the legacy of petroleum in Venezuela (Izard, 1986, p. 205). Oil had vastly increased the national appetite and the capacity to consume, yet ingesting petroleum only served to contaminate every- thing. Black gold, like the devil’s counterpart, had turned into excrement. As Coronil puts it in describing Venezuela during the oil boom,

Venezuela had lost control over itself; intoxicated by oil as waste it had become trans- formed into waste. . . . The identification of both the nation and individuals with excre- ment became an ever more common short hand expression for everyday problems . . . “somos una mierda,” “es que este es un pais de mierda” (“we are pieces of shit,” “it’s that this country is made of shit”). (Coronil, 1987, p. 233)

At about the same time that Venezuela’s oil wealth was being debated explicitly in terms of waste, corruption, and degeneracy, the Iranian, or more properly the Shah Pahlavi’s, petrolic vision of “the Great Civilization” was being derailed by an Islamic revolution made in the name of disciplined Muslim renewal and an autocratic moral order. Several thousand miles away from Caracas, black gold ushered in the collapse of the world’s most powerful monarchy and, in its wake, a massive bloodletting. Oil wealth, the magical elan vital of economic and social transformation, had proven to be a very mixed blessing.

El Dorado: Oil Wealth as Spectacle, Display and Illusion The spectacle is not a collection of images, but a social relation among people, mediated by images. (Debord, 1978, para. 4)

Oil creates the illusion of a completely changed life, life without work, life for free. . . . The concept of oil expresses perfectly the eternal human dream of wealth achieved through lucky accident. . . . In this sense oil is a fairy tale and like every fairy tale a bit of a lie. (Kapuscinski, 1982, p. 35)

For many commentators and critics, the oil bonanza of the 1970s was seen to presage the dawn of prosperity for the privileged few. As the West looked on in horror, oil prices ran out of control, soaring effortlessly, quadrupling in 1973–4 alone, then reaching their zenith during the second boom of 1980. Government rev- enues of OPEC states mushroomed by over 1,000 percent between 1970 and 1980. Five years after the first boom, nine of the thirteen OPEC members devoted close to 50 percent of their now bloated gross domestic product (GDP) to domestic invest- ment. State treasuries were literally awash with money. So began the era of blind ambition, “the Great Civilization” in Iran and “La Gran Venezuela.” Jahangir Amuzegar describes this sensibility as a “lyrical illusion,” an exhilarating state of euphoria in which state planners, blinded by the refulgence OIL AS MONEY 207 of the great God petroleum, came to believe that oil wealth could solve all prob- lems (Amuzegar, 1982, p. 827). El Dorado was finally located, and it was an oil well. From its inception, the oil boom was a spectacle, with new social relations medi- ated by images (Debord, 1978). Reza Shah predicted that, in a decade, Iran would have the same living standard as Germany and France (Kapuscinski, 1982, p. 53); in twenty years, he bragged, “we shall be ahead of the United States” (Shah Pahlavi, in Zonis, 1991, p. 65). In the era of the Great Civilization that lay ahead, the Shah saw a world of unbridled material prosperity, thousands of electric buses to shuttle well-endowed workers to and from their workplace, and a three-day work week. The monetary deluge that floated this modern utopia was truly biblical in scale. Hector Hurtado, the Minister of Finance in Venezuela, saw money cascading into the state treasury, money “beyond our wildest dreams” (cited in Karl, 1997, p. 2). Boundless money produced boundless ambition, what was dubbed “Pharaohism” by the popular press. During the 1970s, for example, over three- quarters of the top twenty states classified by scale of public investment (the number of projects exceeding US $100 million) were oil producers. Saudi Arabia and Iran each accounted for over 100 projects costing in excess US $1 billion dollars a shot! (Gelb, 1984, p. 33). To add an extra frisson, the cost overruns on each of these Herculean projects averaged 109 percent! Anything was possible, even the defeat of nature. Saudi Arabia, for example, aggressively promoted domestically produced wheat, grown in the most inhospitable of desert environments. After massive production subsidies, Saudi wheat could be purchased for US $1050 per ton. US wheat, of vastly superior quality, could be acquired on the world market for less than US $150 per ton (Chaudhry, 1989, p. 128). Commodity booms are not unusual in themselves, of course. The value of several commodities grew in excess of 20 percent per annum during the 1970s. On a larger historical canvas, the gold and bullion boom in the Americas during the sixteenth century resembles in certain respects the oil windfall four centuries later. Some 450 million pesos of precious metals poured into Spain between 1503 and 1660, stim- ulating feverish activity in the economy. Seville became a world city for a short while, driven by a manufacturing boom and a cycle of inflationary spending and borrowing (see Braudel, 1973; Wallerstein, 1974; Anderson, 1984; Vilar, 1984). The bullion bonanza lasted a century and a half, producing in its wake inflation, debt, and a crippled Castillian state. Some aspects of the oil boom appear strikingly similar. Both commodities were, after all, central to the mercantilist and capitalist world economies of the time and each, in different ways, contributed to state cen- tralization and state building. Naturally, there are also radical dissimilarities. These contrasting forms of money were inserted into vastly different political economies and put to quite different uses. The sheer magnitude, duration, and density of the booms also diverge markedly. None the less, these money booms, and the crises they precipitated, if rooted in their historical and cultural specificities, do both provide an opportunity to illuminate the working of societies into which vast fluxes of money are injected, and by exten- sion enable one to outline the social, cultural, and political contours of money. Oil as El Dorado speaks powerfully to what Simmel (1978, p. 175) saw as money’s 208 MICHAEL J. WATTS specific role in “reified social functions,” as the reified representation of impersonal capitalism. The spectacular manifestations of oil wealth reveal, first, something of the social relations of peripheral capitalisms and, second, how the growth of money in societies often presumed to be partly “traditional” reveals something of how money itself is a “frightful leveler” whose colorlessness and indifference “hollows out the core of things” (Simmel, 1978, p. 414).

Meanings of Oil Money Oil is almost like money. (Robert O. Anderson, Chairman of ARCO, cited in Yergin, 1991, p. 13)

Three categories – the imaginary, the symbolic and the real – correspond to the three functions of money: in its capacity as a measure of value money is “imaginary”; as a medium of exchange, money is “symbolic”; and as an instrument of reserve or of hoarding, money is “real.” (Goux, 1989, p. 52)

A very great difficulty in talking about money arises from its multiple functions and representations. To simplify such complexity greatly, in this chapter I am going to pursue two broad lines of argument. The first starts from Marx’s discussion of the functions of money: as a universal equivalent, as a measure of value, as a medium of exchange, and as social power. But, following Goux (1989), I want to identify these multiple functions as the inseparable symbolic, imaginary, and real aspects of money. Money is both an objectified relation of production (see Marx) and a system of culturally encoded symbols, a sort of transactional order which signifies itself (Smelt, 1980). The specific cultural, social, and historical forms in which these attributes are expressed will vary enormously, giving rise to the multiple meanings of money in capitalist and non-capitalist societies (Zelizer, 1989). Underlying this heterogeneity, however, is a general presumption that money is always in part an abstraction and one that portrays the character, what Simmel (1978, p. 251) called the “modern spirit,” of capitalist society. The second line is taken directly from Simmel’s Philosophy of Money (1978). The central argument here is tripartite in form: first, that the rise of complex and more abstract monetary systems corresponds to a Gemeinschaft-Gesellschaft shift; second, that the growing dominance of money represents a progression towards abstraction and convention, which is itself a reflec- tion of impersonal and abstract social relations; third, money promotes increased personal freedom and social exchange at the same time that it subjects human life to growing calculability, bureaucratization, and quantitative regulation (Turner, 1986). For Simmel, money spoke to estrangement under modernity: reification, alienation, and objectification. I wish to trace these two broad problematics – the symbolic, imaginary, and real unity of money on the one hand, and the simultaneous integrative and disintegra- tive effects of money à la Simmel on the other – as they are played out in oil-based economies awash with money during the 1970s. In this case – and I shall focus primarily on Nigeria – money takes the form of oil rents. There are two particular significances to money as rent. First, oil money – as a form of money – must be OIL AS MONEY 209 theorized in terms of specific forms of state landed property (Haussman, 1981). In other words, as owner of the means of production of petroleum, the state mediates the particular social relations by which oil is exploited (royalties, commissions, state- owned enterprises) and converted into money. Changes in the ownership of the state take place through political transformations in the ruling class alliances that govern the state apparatuses. The second significance of money as rent derives from the dominance of extrac- tive and rentier capitals, which underlie money booms and particular patterns of commodity circulation. In other words, I want to argue that money (or commod- ity) booms based on extractive and rentier activity rather than on productive capital produce a particular sort of money fetishism. Unlike wealth created through indus- trial accumulation – in which there is some direct relation between productive labour, investment, work, and money – oil money is effaced and disguised, appear- ing as it were out of thin air. To put it crudely, the form of capital which corre- sponds to the proliferation of wealth fundamentally shapes the cultural economy, the particular social and cultural constructions and fetishisms, of money itself.

The Midas Touch: Ingesting Petrodollars and Manufacturing Modernity in Iran and Venezuela [Your] old socialism is finished. Old, obsolete, finished. ...I achieve more than the Swedes. Huh! Swedish socialism! It didn’t even nationalize forests and water. But I have . . . my White Revolution . . . believe me, in Iran we’re far more advanced than you and really have nothing to learn from you. (Shah Pahlavi, interview with Oriana Fallaci, New Republic, 1 December 1974, pp. 17–18)

The decision to build a modern industrialized economy was mine. There were others who wanted to move more slowly. But we had to take advantage of this moment given to us, pull Venezuela out of her underdevelopment, and propel her into the twentieth century. (Interview with President Carlos Andres Perez, cited in Karl, 1997, p. 351)

There are about thirty developing countries that are net exporters of oil but they differ markedly in terms of area, size, oil endowment, dependence on petroleum revenues, and economic structure (Watts, 1984). There is a fundamental distinction between the oil-producing city or desert states (Kuwait, Saudi Arabia), which are land and labor poor and in capital surplus, and states such as Iran, Venezuela, and Nigeria, which are large and well-populated, with diversified economies and a sub- stantial domestic economy and home market. In this chapter I shall address oil money in the context of the latter, the so-called “high absorbers” (Gelb, 1984). These petroleum-based economies embarked upon ambitious, and not infrequently disastrous, state-led development programs during the 1970s, ingesting huge quan- tities of oil revenues. A decade later these same economies were plagued by hyper- inflation, economic stagnation, structural balance of payments problems, periodic devaluations, and a massive foreign debt. What the high absorbers have in common for the purposes of my discussion are the following contradictory traits: 210 MICHAEL J. WATTS

• A dependence on oil as a fully internationalized commodity. All transactions are in dollars (oil is money) and the petro-state, as the landlord and entrepreneur, is “internationalized” (i.e., expands its reliance on the world market through a growing monocultural dependence on oil revenues). • The enclave character of the oil industry within oil producing states, which implies an absence of linkage effects to non-oil sectors. The petroleum industry does not constitute itself as a major determinant of the organization of social life. Hence its impact on the national economy will be determined by the landed property relation (the social relations by which oil is exploited) and the realiza- tion of oil rents. What distinguishes an oil country, then, is “not so much the presence of petroleum as the expenditure of petrodollars” (Haussman, 1981, p. 75, emphasis added). • The nationalization of the oil sector such that oil monies flow directly (via taxes, rents, concessions, and sales) to the state treasury, which accordingly acts as a strong centralizing force. Oil accrues to the state as an independent source of revenue, which affords it an unusual degree of political and economic autonomy (i.e., the state is “suspended” from civil society; Katouzian, 1981). • The centralizing impact of oil revenues confers a central role for the public sector (fiscal linkages) via state investment (“the entire system . . . depends on the size and strategy of state expenditure”; Katouzian, 1981, p. 246), and to this extent the state is “domesticated” (i.e., projected into civil society). The state, in other words, takes on the primary role of “localizing” money capital (oil rents).

Both the Accion Democratic government of Carlos Perez (1974–8) in Venezuela and the Pahlavi regime in Iran saw oil as the ticket to modernity on a grand scale. In Venezuela the centerpiece of “La Gran Venezuela” was the US $52 billion indus- trial complex in Ciudad Guayana. For the Shah it was the spectacle of modernism; in 1974 he initiated a monumental downtown project in Tehran bearing his name (Shahestan Pahlavi), not simply the largest concentration of service activities in the world but “the equivalent of the Persepolis” (Costello, 1981, p. 170). Grandiosity rested in both instances on extreme political centralization. It took the form of a monarchical clique under an autocratic Shah in Iran, a small power bloc consisting of family, high-ranking state bureaucrats, and a group of industrial and financial bourgeoisies who surrendered political power as a condition of access to oil monies. Under Perez, a bureaucratic oligarchy supported state ownership but actively promoted a domestic capitalist class, “the big manufacturers, large commercial farmers, construction contractors and real estate interests and the large import-exporters who have received the bulk of the investment funds” (Petras and Morley, 1983, p. 26). The Perez government operationalized a two-prong strategy: sectoral national- ization (iron ore, petrochemicals) and massive investments in upstream sectors (steel); and the redirection of foreign investment into downstream non-oil economic activities (Coronil and Skurski, 1991). The Shah recycled oil money through state development banks which favored large Iranian private capital – in essence a small court clique – particularly in the heavy and capital goods sectors. The small-scale bazaar economy was marginalized and income inequality increased precipitously (Imam-Jomeh, 1985). OIL AS MONEY 211

In spite of the differences of emphasis there are striking macroeconomic empiri- cal regularities. First, oil money fuels a rapid growth and expansion of state expen- ditures and parastatal organizations. A huge share of money capital is, in other words, localized by the state to reproduce itself via expenditures on administration and defense/repressive apparatuses. Second, an urban construction boom is stimu- lated by public investment projects and a vast import boom of both consumer durables and capital goods. Third, there is an increased demand for non-tradables, which promotes an appreciation of the real exchange rate (and hence further stim- ulates imports). Fourth, a deliberate effort is made to encourage local industrial- ization through import substitution behind high tariff walls. Fifth, non-oil sectors lag (the so-called Dutch Disease), especially in agriculture. Finally there is a ten- dency towards “overshooting,” that is to say a difficulty in scaling back lumpy state investments, a process compounded by inflation and additional borrowing to cover project completion. In both Venezuela and Iran, the 1970s witnessed a period of rapid urbaniza- tion, industrial growth, and social change. In both cases what emerged was a sort of rentier capitalism in which the state redistributed oil revenues through rents, subsidies, and outright corruption. Huge quantities of public oil monies were privately appropriated and exported; according to Petras and Morley (1983, p. 15) some US $2.3 billion left Venezuela in 1977 for the purchase of property in southern Florida! Sowing oil monies invariably meant seeding foreign bank accounts. Criminality emerged as the normal, and to a degree acceptable, form of sociality and display. For the popular classes, inflation, real estate speculation, administrative chaos, and escalating costs of living (especially food) defined the lived reality of the oil years. The Shah’s Great Civilization was, as Kapuscinski (1982) noted, “the Great Injustice.” Within several years of the first oil boom, both coun- tries were running substantial balance of payments deficits and were borrowing heavily. Against this backdrop there are three relevant aspects of the oil boom that provide the vantage point for grasping the form, function, and meaning of petrodol- lars. The fetishization of money, and the intense activity, much of which was patently and publicly illegal, focused on the acquisition of wealth without apparent effort. Petroleum came to be synonymous with money and the defining force in society. Second, petro-states emerged as rentier and redistributive in form though their social character is locally specific (autocratic and highly centralized personal monarchical rule in Iran, complex political pacts and alliances orchestrated through a powerful oligarchical bureaucracy in Venezuela). The state appears suspended above society – it is represented as the source of power since oil is power – yet is projected into society as it spends simultaneously to develop and purchase political consent. Finally, the state mediates the contradiction between public petro-wealth and individual appropriation of it. The state distribution of oil monies as rents dominates the investment of money as productive capital. A culture of corruption flourishes in such a way that the state paradoxically becomes the major blockage to develop- ment (understood as systematic capitalist accumulation) at the same moment that the state is the vehicle to promote it. How, then, can money be traced through the various social, cultural, and political circuits of petrolic capitalism as it is constituted through this trilogy of 212 MICHAEL J. WATTS processes? In the remainder of the chapter I shall focus on another high-absorber oil state, namely Nigeria.

Paradoxes of Prosperity: Oil Money in Nigeria Oil is crude or dirty and so are the actions it often inspires. Oil is volatile and so are the expectations that are based on it; oil is a diminishing or vanishing asset, so is the false sense of political power which it could confer. (Festus Marinho, managing director, Nigerian National Petroleum Company, The African Guardian, 5 March 1990, p. 19)

She has been called the Texas of Africa: big, brash, and, for a while, oil rich. For a decade oil flowed out and money flowed in. At the peak of production, the man- grove swamps of southeastern Nigeria pumped two million barrels a day and sold them for US $41 a piece. As in Iran and Venezuela, the oil boom created huge wind- fall profits, a transfer large enough to lay the basis of an economic revolution in Africa’s largest nation. The Nigerians chose a capitalist road, an ambitious import- substitution industrialization strategy that required roads, banks, electrification, capital goods, and a developmental state. What they got was a sort of organized chaos: “a massive foreign debt whose size nobody knows, a mountain of expensive equipment that mostly does not work, and a military dictatorship” (The Economist, 3 May 1986, p. 3). The oil boom unleashed a spasm of consumption and con- struction; money and commodities circulated apace and disreputable salesmen from every corner of the globe competed to sell to all manner of Nigerians artifacts they could not possibly make use of. The proliferation of everything from stallions to stereos suggested a sort of African cargo cult. An independent Nigeria inherited in 1960 an archetypical agrarian export economy dominated by groundnuts, cotton, palm oil, cocoa, and rubber. This economy was starkly regional. Three semi-autonomous regions, each associated with a primary export commodity and a marketing board, tightly circumscribed the power of the federal center. Regional economies were also distinguished by power- ful ethnic and religion identifications which produced a fragile and fractured national polity presided over by the Muslim Hausa-speaking north. Behind the facade of political independence during the 1960s lay vicious interregional compe- tition over political office, public contracts, and state resources. Indeed, this deli- cate federalism exploded into civil war in 1966 and it was into this fragmented political economy, presided over by a military government, that the oil monies of the 1970s were inserted. The oil revenues flowed directly to the state via the Nigerian National Petroleum Company (NNPC), which both centralized and expanded central (federal) power. Federal revenues grew at 26 percent per annum during the 1970s and expanded state activity unleashed a torrent of imports (capital goods increased from N422 million in 1971 to N3.6 billion in 1979) and urban construction (the construction industry grew at over 20 percent per annum in the mid-1970s). The state invested heavily in industrial development and infrastructure – manufacturing output increased by 13 percent per annum between 1970 and 1982 – but the intense OIL AS MONEY 213 competition for public resources along regional and class lines produced unthink- able corruption and administrative chaos. While serious under the military govern- ments of the 1970s, corruption and state indiscipline radically increased under the civilian government of President Shagari between 1979 and 1983. Cities such as Warri, Port Harcourt, and Lagos doubled (and in some cases tripled) in size during the boom. Consumer prices leapt upward, agriculture collapsed, and the real exchange rate rose steadily, feeding the import boom. Nigeria became ever more a monocultural economy; it simply shifted from one oil (vegetable) to another (petro- leum). The collapse of the boom in 1981 exposed Nigeria to the structural weaknesses of oil-based rentier capitalism. A foreign exchange crisis – the visible trade balance in 1981 was N12 billion – was compounded by mounting external debt obligations. By 1982 the President and his advisors talked of the need for sacrifice and denial: the 1970s, they said, had been a time of illusion. They were promptly ousted in a military coup in 1983. By 1984 the boom was over and the watchword was aus- terity. By 1986 Nigeria had signed a structural adjustment program (SAP) with the IMF and the World Bank, and the medicine was bitter. The economy contracted, the naira collapsed from US $1.12 to ten cents, and the real wage of industrial workers was savaged. Money was scarce and popular discontent widespread, as the anti-SAP riots in 1988 and 1989 revealed with some clarity. What began with petro-euphoria and bountiful money in 1973 ended, some fifteen years later, with scarcity, a huge debt, urban looting, and bodies in the streets. Over this period oil money coursed through the Nigerian economy and polity, a sort of a barium meal which charted the decomposing metabolism of Nigerian political economy.

Naira Power: State Degeneracy and the Dikko Affair Oil is a resource that anesthetizes thought, blurs vision, corrupts. . . . Look at the ministers from oil countries, how high they hold their heads, what a sense of power. (Kapuscinski, 1982, p. 35)

If you haven’t got Naira power here, Auntie, you are lost. Money can buy you every- thing, even justice; and as Auntie replies, “Ah yes, you must be ready to bribe your way openly here, or perish.” (Emecheta, 1982, p. 10)

Stansted Airport, 5 July 1984. British customs officers and Scotland Yard’s anti- terrorist squad, responding to a reported abduction in central London, intercept two wooden crates addressed to the Ministry of External Affairs, Lagos, that are about to be loaded on board a privately chartered Boeing 707 purportedly con- taining four tons of catering equipment. In one crate is an Israeli would-be leather manufacturer and a Nigerian employee of the political division of the Nigerian Ministry of External Affairs. In the other, a rather embarrassed Israeli anesthetist by the name of Dr “Lou” Shapiro, and Alhaji Umaru Dikko, former Minister of Transportation and Aviation during the Shagari regime (1979–83), heavily drugged and shackled. Drawn by a “medical smell” that emanated from one of the crates, 214 MICHAEL J. WATTS customs officers forcibly opened the first wooden container to discover Dikko with a tube forced down his throat. As he saw the light of day, Dr Shapiro, a reserve major in the Israeli army, was heard to say: “Well gentleman, what do we do now?” (Africa Now, August 1984, pp. 11–15). Dikko, Nigeria’s “most wanted fugitive” (West Africa, 16 July 1984, p. 1433), had fled Nigeria early in 1984 in the wake of a military coup, hiding out in Lagos for several days and then driving to the Benin border where he ditched his black Mercedes and casually walked across the border at a rural bush location to avoid capture. Subsequently, having taken up residence in Britain and “living comfort- ably” in West London according to the Guardian, he became an outspoken critic of the new military regime, calling for a jihad to overthrow the Buhari military gov- ernment. Rumor had it that Dikko had put aside US $300 million to fund an army to overthrow the military government (Africa Now, August 1984, p. 14). With other high-ranking politicians and “multi-millionaire exiles” – most conspicuously Joseph Wayas (former President of the Nigerian Senate) and arms dealer Isyaku Ibrahim (The Observer, 24 June 1984, p. 12) – Dikko arrived in Britain under a dark cloud of accusation, and quite specifically amid rumor of massive corruption and illicit gain. Dikko himself was estimated to be worth a staggering US $1.4 billion (Daily Sketch, 23 January 1984, p. 1). The Nigerian government denied all knowledge of the kidnapping in spite of the fact that the Israeli abductors claimed to be in the pay of the Nigerian secret police. Extradition orders served by the Nigerian government had placed a good deal of pressure on the Tory Government in Britain to assist in the return of Nigerian exiles to face in camera trials before the Tribunal on the Recovery of Public Property (so- called Decree No. 3). Coupled with the rather dim view of the abduction in the British popular press, the Nigerian generals’ aggressive prosecution of ex-President Shagari’s National Party of Nigeria (NPN) ruling elite produced an extremely tense diplomatic environment in which the “special relationship” between Britain and Nigeria was severely jeopardized. What appears on the surface to be the stuff of B-grade movies and pulp spy novels is, I believe, a manifestation of the, in this case political, visage of petrodollars. Umaru Dikko personified Nigerian politics during the euphoric phase of the oil boom and perhaps more than any other personality captured the ethos of a monu- mentally venal Second Republic (1979–83): the brash and aggressive civil servant- contractor, the corrupt party machine politician, the avaricious rent-seeker for whom public office simply conferred the means to ransack state oil revenues for private gain. The explosion of oil revenues during the 1970s vastly expanded the number and distribution of public offices (there were 850 federal and state paras- tatals by the late 1970s!) but oil rents were channeled through state apparatuses already cross cut by deeply sedimented regional, ethnic, and religious affiliations and identities. As a consequence, the explosive growth of federal petrodollars had the effect of deepening and intensifying competing claims over highly lucrative state offices and resources. Nigerian political scientist Claude Ake put it well: politics was a ferocious contest to gain access to state monies. The Nigerian public sector became, in this sense, a tool to manufacture a sort of political consent through an unstable and delicate web of pacts and alliances purchased by the distribution of rents (import licenses, contracts) and the seemingly endless extension of federal and OIL AS MONEY 215 state-level employment opportunities. To this extent, the more vast (and myopic) the project – the massive new federal capital project at Abuja, a multi-billion iron and steel program – the greater its political attractiveness as a means to lubricate critical constituencies with petroleum monies. Only in this way can one understand why the costs of irrigation projects or state-funded educational construction throughout the oil boom were obscenely inflated, at least 300–400 percent higher than anywhere else in sub-Saharan Africa. The intersection of centralized (state) oil monies and a highly segmented, and regionalized, class structure in which northern Muslims maintained, or endeavored to maintain, a precarious hegemony produced a seemingly insatiable source of rents for the privileged, and corruption and fraud of Hobbesian proportions. Chinua Achebe in The Trouble with Nigeria put the matter starkly: “Nigeria is without shadow of a doubt one of the most corrupt nations in the world” (Achebe, 1983, p. 42). Not only did Nigerian public servants become “more reckless and blatant” (ibid., p. 43) as oil revenues continued to roll in, but in addition there was a con- spicuous failure to apprehend, prosecute, and punish perpetrators. During the Second Republic, the second oil boom in 1979 unleashed a spasm of fraud and rent-seeking in which the state was mercilessly pillaged. Nigeria “lost” US $16.7 billion in oil income (“Oilgate,” so-called) owing to fraudulent activities and smuggling of petroleum between 1979 and 1983 (New African, April 1984, p. 11); US $2 billion (over 10 percent of GDP) was “discovered” in a private Swiss bank account; and government ministries regularly went up in flames, the product of arson immediately prior to federal audits. Special military tribunals set up after the December 1983 coup prosecuted governors and high-ranking politicians for spectacular feats of corruption. Governor Lar accumulated N32.6 million in four years; Governor Attah made N2 million through illegal activities associated with a single state security vote in the Kwara state legislature (West Africa, 2 July 1984, p. 1373, 23 July, p. 1511). Military officers who raided the home of the governor of Kano state, Bakin Zuwo, discovered millions of naira in cardboard boxes piled up in his bedroom. With money, says Marx, “each individual holds social power in his pocket in the form of a thing” (Marx, 1963, p. 986ff). Skyrocketing food prices, corruption in high places, hoarding, and speculation were all manifestations of the pillaging of state oil monies, much of which was of course exported. Capital flight not only produced a lack of investment funds, however, but signaled a state fundamentally incapacitated by corruption and rent- seeking. A hugely overvalued exchange rate, in other words, certainly distorted the economy but highlighted how state apparatuses were functionally crippled by a culture of public theft. The bureaucratic inefficiency and administrative anarchy of Nigerian state organizations is, of course, legendary. Electricity and water became the scarcest national resources; the central bank and federal financial institutions were often incapable of providing basic national accounts data; Chase Manhattan was contracted to try and compute the outstanding Nigerian public debt. This is, in other words, the antithesis of the “developmental state”; the public sector is entirely incapable of laying the foundations for systematic capitalist accumulation (as opposed to a flabby and corrupt “pirate” capitalism). In this regard, the discovery of Umaru Dikko drugged in a wooden crate as part of a pathetic abduction scheme perfectly embodied two features of a Nigerian 216 MICHAEL J. WATTS political economy bloated with oil monies: first, the state as the vehicle for, and obstacle to, capitalist accumulation; second, money as Naira power (to employ the title of Nigerian novelist Buchi Emecheta’s popular novel), a general condition that Marx described as the process by which “social power becomes the private power of private persons” (Marx, 1974, p. 133).

The Oil Bust: Scarce Money and the “Great IMF Debate” Oil kindles extraordinary emotions and hopes, since oil is above all a great tempta- tion. It is the temptation of ease, wealth, fortune, power. [But] oil, though powerful, has its defects. (Kapuscinski, 1982, pp. 34–5)

On 23 April 1984, the Nigerian Chief of Staff, Tunde Idiagbon, announced via a nationwide broadcast that Nigeria’s borders were to be sealed. Simultaneously, all money was to be withdrawn from circulation. Currency exchange was to render worthless the hundreds of millions of naira smuggled out of the country, to force into the open those unscrupulous individuals who accrued untold millions during the civilian binge and who held much of this money outside of the banking system, and not least to squelch large-scale currency counterfeiting. While the Central Bank withdrew N5.3 billion from circulation, it issued only N2.45 billion in new notes, which accordingly generated a huge money scarcity. In the large cities, money was so scarce that the working poor walked to work and pooled food. What was most striking about this disappearance of Nigerian money was that it occurred at a time when the government was rumored to be negotiating a loan from the IMF which involved a substantial currency devaluation. Five years after the second oil boom, Nigeria had a huge external debt and a money that bore no semblance to its value; it was very close to bankruptcy. The oil boom was unequivocally over; 40 percent of the reserves and some US $101 billion in oil revenues had been, to be charita- ble, “used up.” “One of the effects of the oil boom,” said E. C. Edozien, President Shagari’s eco- nomic advisor, in 1982, “is to make it difficult to engender the necessary spirit of self-sacrifice and self-denial” (Wall Street Journal, 2 August 1982, p. 12). The population had simply come to “expect too much from the government.” But why should there be a need for self-sacrifice to begin with, and why should there be denial among those, the countless millions of peasants, workers, and informal sector operatives, who had little to show from oil in any case? And how could money, the much touted petro-naira, come and go, how could its value evaporate? How could the expectation and ambition of the boom turn to the disillusionment and auster- ity of the bust? During the height of the boom, the World Bank classified Nigeria as a middle income country; by the end of the 1980s it was reclassified as “poor.” By 1985, talk in Nigeria was of “oil doom” (West Africa, 26 August 1985, p. 1735). The first austerity package had in fact been introduced in September 1981 fol- lowing a 30 percent fall in oil prices. Further cuts were announced in 1982 but external borrowing increased substantially as the national elections approached. In April 1983 Nigeria initiated negotiations with the IMF to borrow US $2 billion, facing strict conditionalities in the form of devaluation, a tightening of money OIL AS MONEY 217 supply, reductions in current expenditures, and a relaxation in exchange and import controls. Despite progress throughout 1983, three major issues blocked any advance: devaluation, trade liberalization, and petroleum subsidies. By September the parties were stalemated. Three months later the Shagari government was over- thrown by a military coup. The Buhari military government came to power emphasizing discipline, auster- ity, self-reliance, and populist conservatism. Like Shagari before him, Buhari con- tinued negotiations with the IMF but these stalled over devaluation and subsidies. Nigerian officials feared the destabilizing political consequences of inflation induced by devaluation and the elimination of import licenses (i.e., potential rents for key political constituencies). Trade liberalization would crush the manufacturing sector. As a consequence, Buhari decided to go it alone with a domestically hatched aus- terity plan wherein 44 percent of the foreign exchange earnings went to debt service. Rather than borrowing from private banks, Nigeria turned to counter-trading oil for current imports. Faced with crashing oil prices (from a high of US $41 per barrel in 1980 to the low teens by 1985) and a severe deflationary budget package, Buhari turned to authoritarian rule in the name of discipline and patriotic self-reliance. In August 1985 he was overthrown in another military coup. The new Babangida regime immediately confronted the great oil crash; prices slumped below US $10.00 per barrel (in 1986 Nigerian oil earnings were US $6.5 billion compared to US $25.00 billion in 1981) and he declared his intention to break the deadlock with the IMF (Bierstecker, 1988). In an extraordinary populist twist, Babangida took the IMF loan to the people: so began, in October 1985, “the Great Debate.” It consisted of a flurry of speeches, street demonstrations, and extensive debates in the press and news media (see, for example, Ekpo, 1985; ORC, 1985; Usman, 1986; Phillips, 1987). The articulate middle classes represented the IMF in explicitly nationalist terms; Nigeria would be sold for a mess of pottage. Indeed, in spite of the fact that the Babangida regime mounted a campaign for IMF-type reform, within a short time a broad-based opposition to taking the loan began to form and mobilize. The IMF demands – devaluation, liberalization, anti- inflationary measures – were published and subject to a lively critique by students, organized labor, and academics. To live in debt and bondage or not was the issue. What began as a thinly disguised effort to build a corporatist alliance around austerity produced a vociferous resistance to cutting petroleum subsidies and deval- uation. But what also emerged was a strong popular sentiment against any form of borrowing; borrowed money would disappear just as quickly as it had in the past (Lubeck, 1992)! In the wake of popular protest and strikes, the Nigerian govern- ment broke off negotiations with the Fund in December 1985. Yet within two weeks the annual budget speech combined nationalist assertion for economic autonomy with savage austerity taken directly from the IMF blueprint: a “realistic exchange rate,” an 80 percent reduction in petroleum subsidies, large scale privatization. Six months later came Babangida’s new two-year structural adjustment program (SAP): hardship but “Made in Nigeria” as the popular press put it. Within a year, however, the value of the naira had fallen from US $1.12 to 20 cents. By January 1987 an IMF standby loan of SDR650 million had been signed by the Babangida govern- ment along with the full battery of SAP cutbacks. The real minimum monthly wage crashed from US $201 to US $16 (Watts and Lubeck, 1989). 218 MICHAEL J. WATTS

Devaluation eroded what Simmel (1978) saw as the precondition for paper money: inter-social trust and social stability. The Great IMF Debate highlights, I would suggest, a long-standing conflict in Western discourse over the possibility of monetary order and in particular the incompatibility of money as a tool of state action and money as a symbol of social trust (Frankel, 1977, p. 86).

Serious Money If money is the bond which ties me to human life and society to me, which links me to nature and to man, is money not the bond of all bonds? Can it not bind and loose all bonds? Is it therefore not the universal means of separation? It is the true agent of separation and the true cementing agent, it is the chemical power of society. (Marx, 1975, p. 377)

The dense symbolism and imagery of oil money as the devil’s excrement suggests a sort of money fetishism in which extraordinary powers, of a magical and occult variety, are seen to reside in dirty lucre. In this sense it speaks directly to Marx’s concern with money fetishism, money’s obfuscatory qualities, money endowed with fecundity; in capitalism, money breeds money, he said, “much as it is an attribute of pear trees to bear pears” (Marx, cited in Parry and Bloch, 1989, p. 6). But there is also a much larger motif here with a very long history in Western thinking (dating at least to Aristotle), in which money has a dark and sinister face, as a source of evil and moral confusion; in short, money as threat. Marx pursues this line of thinking when he talks of money as the God of com- modities, and it is seen in Simmel’s vision of money as subversive of “moral polar- ities,” “turning what was formerly black and white into grayness” (Simmel, 1978, p. 72); “honor and conviction, talent and virtue, beauty and salvation of the soul are exchanged against money” (ibid., p. 256). For Chaucer money was filth, for Dickens an awful offal, for Edgar Allen Poe gold was death itself. For Hegel money was a “monstrous system” that required “continual dominance and taming like a beast” (cited in Shell, 1982, p. 154). The particular cultural constructions by which this view of money is articulated across time and space are, as is clear from this chapter, extremely varied. But underlying all these articulations is a strong sense of money as eroding the bases of sociability, as an acid that dissolves social ties, and as a dark almost satanic force that tears asunder the integument of the community, giving rise to greed, avarice, and alienation. There is, however, a counterweight, another vision of money which stands in a dialectical relation to money as threat (it is also associated with Simmel, and to an extent with Marx), in which money enhances personal freedom, trust, rationality, calculability, and expanded forms of social exchange (Frankel, 1977; Simmel, 1978; Martin, 1986). The community of money tends to be “strongly marked by indi- vidualism and certain conceptions of liberty, freedom and equality” (Harvey, 1985, p. 4). Rather than a bland grayness, money produces what Emily Martin (1986, 4) calls “the most intense, clear and passionately directed feelings.” Both Marx and Simmel recognized that money can fulfill both these functions – integrative and dis- integrative – simultaneously, which produces complex and contradictory tendencies OIL AS MONEY 219 in social, cultural, and political relations. Martin (1986) has brilliantly argued in a comparison of Taiwan and the USA that in the former money works primarily as a form of social integration and in the latter it creates social disintegration. I have sought to show how the infusion of oil monies in industrializing capital- ist states provides a vantage point from which one can show that money contributes to, and reflects, how social integration and disintegration are at work simultane- ously. In this light, some of the symbolic, cultural and socio-political expressions of money hold money operations within certain social limits. In other respects, oil money – as social power, as state corruption and degeneracy, as blind ambition and illusion – has eroded sociability, turning everything it touches into shit: oil money as deodorized feces that has been made to shine. Oil money provides a means to pry open the black box of society while the structure of society provides the entry point into understanding the complex ways in which money simultaneously medi- ates social relations and provides a fundamental means of experiencing them. Chapter 14 Converting the Wetlands, Engendering the Environment: The Intersection of Gender with Agrarian Change in The Gambia

Judith Carney

The pace of environmental change in the Third World during recent decades has directed increasing attention in regional studies to political ecology, a research framework that focuses on the socioeconomic hierarchies and power relations regulating land use and management (Blaikie and Brookfield, 1987; Bassett, 1988; Zimmerer, 1991; Bryant, 1992). However, the political ecology perspective is most frequently employed in the context of common property regimes in the Third World to refute Hardin’s (1968) free-rider assertion, which attributes environmental degra- dation to unchecked use of common property resources. Challenges to Hardin’s arguments have, as a consequence, overemphasized analysis of land in political eco- logical analysis to the exclusion of other important factors. In this paper, I argue that the relationship of common property rights to Third World environmental change may be better understood by adequately conceptualizing labor. Population growth and consequent pressure on limited land is frequently invoked to explain how common property resources result in environmental change. But the accelerating incorporation of Third World environmental resources into the global economy, particularly evident in recent decades, suggests a different view, in that environmental transformations initiate patterns of income generation by placing new value on land-based resources, which in turn trigger changes in common pro- perty resources. The result is often a shift to centralized resource control without a concomitant tendency toward privatization of land (Berry, 1989). Scarcity of land may be artificially created to gain control over labor for accumulation strategies that differentially benefit members within households. I examine forms of environmental change on the wetlands of The Gambia during the past 25 years. Irrigation schemes play a central role in government policies aimed at diversifying agricultural exports while improving self-sufficiency in food grains. But the intensification of household labor regimes to year-round cultivation is induc- ing unparalleled gender conflict as communities reorient the common property regime to the new economic emphasis on irrigated production. An examination of contemporary changes in the Gambian wetlands illuminates the interplay of environmental transformation, accumulation strategies, and CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 221 women’s work to changing common property regimes. In the Gambian system land is managed for individual use but is not individually owned. A number of users enjoy independent rights of usage, which is to say, individual rights to the benefits of his or her labor. Community land access is regulated by households with rights to exclude nonmembers of that collectivity. This political ecological analysis, which examines labor and rights of access to environmental resources, draws attention to the relationship of Gambian women’s protests against the changing forms of control exercised over community property systems in the wetlands. I use multiple case studies of two forms of wetland conversion: irrigated rice schemes and horticultural projects. Both forms of swamp development began in the colonial period when British officials sought to diversify exports from peanuts, the dominant cash crop, and improve domestic rice self-reliance. The projects failed to break down the gender division of labor in rice and vegetables, traditionally culti- vated by women. Only in the post-independence period, with successful implemen- tation of irrigation projects, did men labor with their wives in rice cultivation. But male participation also heralded an increasing control over surplus production and, frequently, female land dispossession. Nongovernmental organizations responded to women’s declining economic opportunities in rice cultivation schemes by promot- ing irrigated horticultural projects among village women’s groups. Horticultural projects have improved rural women’s incomes but, like rice schemes, are rife with gender-based conflicts over access to irrigated land. Tracing the trajectories of the forms of irrigated development consequently reveals a process of land enclosure within the community property system which permits women’s land access as laborers but denies full claims to the benefits produced. In drawing attention to the labor rights that mediate the community property system, this chapter makes two points. First, new patterns of income generation within community property regimes frequently result in a redefinition of rules of access to, and control over, benefits within the household and community. Second, this redefinition is contested by women and given political expression in their growing militancy and nascent social movements. Such “struggles over meaning” in community property regimes may provide a critical perspective for examining Third World women’s growing militancy over environmental and economic change. Building upon previous research in several Gambian wetland communities, the chapter is divided into five sections. The first presents the environmental context of the Gambian wetlands, the extent and significance of wetland farming, as well as women’s labor in ensuring its productive use. The next two sections provide a histor- ical overview of the environmental and economic changes that modify women’s access to, and use of, wetland resources, as well as recent policy shifts that address the country’s environmental and economic crisis. Two case studies then detail the rela- tionship between economic change and the process of land concentration and women’s resistance. The chapter concludes by analyzing how wetland commodifica- tion has made women’s access to resources increasingly tenuous despite income gains.

The Environmental Context of the Gambian Wetlands The Gambia, a narrow land strip 24–50 kilometers (14–30 miles) wide and nearly 500 kilometers (300 miles) long, encloses a low-lying river basin that grades 222 JUDITH CARNEY

Peanuts, millet, Agro-ecological zones: Central Gambia sorghum

Village Maize Tidal inundation Rice zone Gambia River Uplands Inland swamps Flood plain

Source: Carney, 1986

Figure 14.1 Agro-ecological zones: Central Gambia gradually into a plateau, where the altitude seldom exceeds 100 meters (325 feet). The plateau forms about one-third of the country’s land base and depends upon rainfall for farming (Carney, 1986, p. 21). Precipitation during the months of June to October averages 800–1,100 millimeters (31–43 inches) and favors the cultiva- tion of millet, sorghum, maize, and peanuts. As in neighboring Sahelian countries, the Gambian rainfall regime fluctuates considerably between years and within a season. From the 1940s to 1980s, for example, annual rainfall declined by 15 to 20 percent and became increasingly distributed in a bimodal seasonal pattern (Hutchinson, 1983, p. 7). The recurrence of a two-week, midseason dry spell during the month of August increases cropping vulnerability on the uplands and depend- ence on lowland farming (Carney, 1986, pp. 25–30). The lowlands are critical for understanding human livelihood and survival in the unstable rainfall setting of the West African Sudano-Sahelian zone. Lowland envi- ronments permit a multiple land use cropping strategy that utilizes other forms of water availability, thereby freeing agricultural production from strict dependence on rainfall. Constituting nearly 70 percent of the country’s land mass, the Gambian lowlands make available two additional environments for agriculture: (1) the allu- vial plain flooded by the river and its tributaries; and (2) a variety of inland swamps that receive water from high water tables, artesian springs, or occasional tidal flood- ing (Carney, 1986, 20–21) (Fig. 14.1). The lowlands, which enable an extension of crop production into the dry season or even year-round, are planted to rice, although vegetables are frequently grown with residual moisture following the rice harvest (Dunsmore, 1976, pp. 208–11; Carney, 1986, p. 82). While The Gambia abounds in lowland swamps, not all are suitable for farming. Riverine swamps coming under marine tidal influence are permanently saline within 70 kilometers (42 miles) of the coast, seasonally saline up to 250 kilometers (150 miles), and fresh year-round only in the last 150 kilometers (90 miles) of the Gambia River’s course (Carney, 1986, p. 33). The suitability of inland swamps for crop pro- duction, moreover, depends on the influence of differing moisture regimes for groundwater reserves. Consequently, although The Gambia contains over 100,000 hectares (247,000 acres) of lowland swamps, only about a third can be reliably planted (ALIC, 1981, p. 19; GGFP, 1988–91; CRED, 1985, p. 127). CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 223

Lowland cultivation is thus pivotal to the Gambian farming system, enabling crop diversification over a variety of microenvironments and a reduction in subsis- tence risk during dry climatic cycles. Wetland farming, however, requires consider- able attention to forms of water availability as well as edaphic and topographic conditions. In The Gambia this knowledge is embodied in women, who have spe- cialized in wetland cultivation since at least the early eighteenth century and have adapted hundreds of rice varieties to specific microenvironmental conditions (Jobson, 1623, p. 9; Gamble, 1955, p. 27; Carney, 1991, p. 40). This cumulative in situ knowledge of lowland farming underlies The Gambia’s regional importance as a secondary center of domestication of the indigenous West African rice, Oryza g1aberrima, cultivated in the area for at least three thousand years (Porteres, 1970, p. 47).

Gender, Environment, and Economy: A Historical Overview Although lowland swamps and production are traditionally women’s domain, prior to the mid-nineteenth century men and women were involved in both upland and lowland cropping systems through a division of labor based upon various agricul- tural tasks. Men assisted in field cleaning for rice cultivation while women weeded upland cereal plots (Weil, 1982, pp. 45–46; Carney, and Watts, 1991, p. 657). The abolition of slavery and the turn to “legitimate commerce” led to Gambia’s incor- poration into the world economy through commodity production. By the 1830s peanut cultivation was proliferating on the uplands (Carney, 1986, pp. 77–78). The imposition of British colonial rule by the end of the nineteenth century brought tax- ation and fiscal policies that accelerated reliance on peanuts as a cash crop, resulted in an increasingly specialized use of agricultural space, and led to a more gendered division of labor. These changes became most evident among the rice-growing Mandinka, Gambia’s dominant ethnic group and principal wetland farmers. By the end of the century, Mandinka men’s growing emphasis on peanut culti- vation resulted in a reduction in millet and sorghum production for household sub- sistence (Weil, 1973, p. 23; Jeng, 1978, pp. 123–24; Carney, 1986, p. 92). As women compensated for upland cereal shortfalls by augmenting rice production in lowland swamps, the gender division of labor of became increasingly spatially segregated, with the cash crop concentrated on the uplands under male control and women’s farm work largely oriented to lowland rice, which emerged as the dietary staple (Carney, 1986, pp. 89–91) (Fig. 14.1). The specialized use of agricultural land and concomitant disruptions in the gender division of labor accompanying nineteenth- century commodity production provide the setting for understanding twentieth- century gender conflicts among the Mandinka over commodification of the Gambian wetlands. Policy interest in wetland environments began in the early decades of the twen- tieth century, when colonial officials began documenting farming practices in diverse lowland settings (Carney, 1986, pp. 126–27). The objective was to improve house- hold subsistence security and generate rice surpluses that would feed an expanding pool of migrant laborers, whose seasonal influx accounted for the pace of peanut expansion on the uplands. By the 1960s, swamp development projects had culmi- nated in an expansion of rice planting to some 26,000 hectares (65,000 acres) 224 JUDITH CARNEY

(Carney, 1986, p. 178). But limits had been reached on the degree to which women could carry the subsistence burden. The colonial government’s inability to persuade Mandinka men to take an active part in rice cultivation brought swamp rice devel- opment to a close (Carney, 1986, p. 139; Carney and Watts, 1991, p. 660). In 1949 the colonial government initiated another approach to surplus rice generation by implementing a large-scale irrigation scheme on the site of the present day Jahaly Pacharr project. The Colonial Development Corporation (CDC) scheme departed from the earlier swamp rice improvement project in one important way: land was removed from female rice growers through a 30-year lease program (Carney, 1986, p. 126; Carney and Watts, 1991, p. 666). The project failed due to a poorly designed irrigation system and lack of male or female interest in wage work; yet the CDC scheme is notable for adumbrating the post-independence emphasis on irrigation as well as the gender-based conflicts that would surface in subsequent wetland development projects. These conflicts center on the invocation of customary tenure “laws” by male household heads and village elites to reduce women’s land and labor rights in rice farming or, in Mandinka nomenclature, the conversion of land with individual use rights (kamanyango) to land whose product is controlled by the household head (maruo). When colonial development policies during the 1940s improved swamp- land access and productivity, male household heads and village elites called into question women’s customary use rights. In one case that reached the colonial author- ities, Mandinka men argued that “if women mark the land and divide it, it would become ‘women’s property’ so that when a husband dies or divorces his wife, the wife will still retain the land, which is wrong. Women must not own land” (Rahman, 1949, p. 1). Women’s land access was clearly being contested by male claims that female use rights would alienate swampland from the residence unit. A brief review of the meaning of the two Mandinka terms for property access and use of resources illuminates the issues in dispute. Land in rural Gambia is held in communal tenure but carries several forms of property relations. On a general level, the household landholding is termed maruo and cannot be alienated from the residence group. But maruo additionally refers to a set of labor obligations and crop rights. All able family members are expected by custom to provide labor on household land for family reproduction. Men’s maruo work responsibility is traditionally met on the uplands through cultivation of millet, sorghum and maize, or groundnuts, which may be traded to purchase cereals. Rice production traditionally fulfills Mandinka women’s maruo obligations. Because maruo crops are produced for household sub- sistence, they come under control of the male household head, who arranges their distribution. A second, and important, subset of tenure relations also operates on part of the family landholding. In exchange for providing labor toward household subsistence, junior males and all adult females are given access to some of the family’s land- holding for their own needs. These land rights and plots are known as kamanyango. As long as the farmer remains a member of the household she or he controls the plot’s use and benefits from plot output. Kamanyango labor rights provide subor- dinate family members the means to obtain cash from farming, as they control the rights to the crop produced as well as decisions over its use. Kamanyango plots are a critical issue in Gambia, where rural society is largely polygynous, male and female CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 225 budgets are frequently separate, and women traditionally are responsible for purchases of clothing and supplemental foods crucial for the well-being of their children. The expansion of peanut commodity production during the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, which shifted food cropping increasingly to wetland environ- ments, resulted in a greater concentration of rain-fed land use into de facto kamanyango plots, whether or not it was so termed by male household heads. The reverse process accompanied commodification of lowland environments farmed to rice by women. As colonial rice development projects opened new areas for culti- vation, women’s kamanyango rights were repeatedly contested by male household heads, who placed them instead in the category of maruo. By claiming developed rice land as maruo, men placed the burden of subsistence responsibility on females, thereby liberating themselves from customary obligations. As women shouldered an ever greater work burden, male responsibility toward subsistence – either through cereal cultivation or purchase from ground nut earnings – diminished (Weil, 1973, p. 23). Women’s preexisting labor rights steadily eroded in post-independence irrigation schemes, but with the strikingly different outcome that rural women mobilized to improve their deteriorating situation.

The Environmental and Economic Crisis: Policy Shifts Since independence, in 1965, The Gambia has experienced rainfall declines and accelerated environmental degradation of its uplands, a massive influx of foreign aid for development assistance (1968–88), policy shifts favoring commodification of the wetlands, and an International Monetary Fund (IMF) structural adjustment program (1985–present). These changes have shaped post-independence accumula- tion strategies and the gender conflicts among rural households. Gambia entered independence with a degraded upland resource base and a vul- nerable economy. The results of the long-standing monocrop export economy were evident throughout the traditional peanut basin, once mantled with forest cover but substantially deforested during the colonial period (Park, 1983, p. 4; Mann, 1987, p. 85). Reliance on one primary commodity, peanuts, to finance mounting rice imports grew more precarious in the years after independence; peanut export values fluctuated considerably from year to year, but through the 1980s grew less rapidly than the value of food imports (FAO, 1983, p. 4; Carney, 1986, p. 254). Farmers responded to declining peanut revenues through an intensification of land use – namely, by reducing fallow periods in peanut cultivation or by eliminating them altogether. The result was accelerated land degradation, particularly in the North Bank region, which was oriented to Senegalese peanut markets with generally higher producer prices. Subsequent international development assistance brought far- reaching changes to the critical wetland food production zone. Nearly 4,500 hectares (11,115 acres) of riverine swamps were converted to irrigation schemes and another 1,000 hectares (2,470 acres) of inland swamps to horticultural projects (Carney 1992, pp. 77–78). Although affecting less than 10 percent of total swamp land, these conversions in land use have had profound consequences. By the 1980s, women’s mounting economic marginalization from irrigated rice development resulted in nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) targeting them for 226 JUDITH CARNEY horticultural projects developed on inland swamps. The policy emphasis on horti- culture intensified with the debt crisis of the 1980s and the implementation of an IMF-mandated structural adjustment program in 1985 to improve foreign exchange earnings and debt repayment. Economic restructuring has reaffirmed The Gambia’s comparative advantage in peanuts while favoring the conversion of hydromorphic swamps to horticulture (UNCTAD, 1986; Government of The Gambia, 1987; Landell Mills Associates, 1989; Harvey, 1990, p. 3; McPherson and Posner, 1991, p. 6). The respective policy emphases of the past 20 years have commodified the wet- lands and incurred changes in customary use and access to environmental resources. As the irrigation schemes provide new avenues for income generation within rural communities, women’s access to improved land for income benefits is increasingly being contested. The next two sections present an overview of the two post-drought wetland policy shifts, illustrating how customary laws are being reinterpreted to reduce women’s access to productive resources and the forms of their resistance to such changes.

“Drought Proofing” the Economy: Irrigated Rice Development In 1966, one year after independence from Britain, the Gambian government, with bilateral assistance from Taiwan, initiated a wetland development strategy – the con- version of tidal floodplains to irrigated rice projects. It was to receive increasing donor emphasis following the 1968–73 Sahelian drought. The rationale for this development was to promote import substitution by encouraging domestic rice pro- duction. Rice imports had reached 9,000 tons per annum, and foreign exchange reserves had seriously eroded with declining world commodity prices for peanuts. The 1968–73 Sahelian drought revived the late colonial interest in irrigation and mobilized foreign aid for investment in river basin development, and irrigated agri- culture (UNDP, 1977; CILSS, 1979; Franke and Chasin, 1980, pp. 148–51; Derman, 1984; CRED, 1985, p. 17). Hailed as a way of buffering the agricultural system from recurrences of a similar disaster, irrigation projects also created a steady demand for imported technical assistance, machinery, spare parts, and inputs. The “drought-proofing” strategy embodied in Gambian irrigation schemes targeted rice, whose import-substitution was prioritized by the post-independence government (Government of The Gambia, 1966; CRED, 1985, p. 22). From the 1970s to the mid-1980s the World Bank, the mainland Chinese government, and the Interna- tional Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) continued the Taiwanese devel- opment strategy by implementing double-cropped irrigated rice schemes on more than 4,000 hectares (9,880 acres) of women’s tidal swamps (Fig. 14.2). Despite the contrasting ideological perspectives of the donors involved, all devel- opment strategies adhered to a remarkably similar course by introducing the Green Revolution package for increased production to male household heads (Dey, 1981, p. 109). Developed at a cost of US $10,000 to $25,000 per hectare and inserted into a preexisting gendered form of agricultural production and land use, these schemes failed to deliver their technological promise and added to a growing dependence on imported inputs and spare parts (CRED, 1985, p. 273; Carney, 1986, p. 275). Donor production targets required double-cropping and thus a shift in People’s Republic of China (PRC) 1975–1978 Taiwanese 1965–1974 World Bank Agricultural Development Project 1973–1976 Trunk road

International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) 1984–90

30 km

Source: Carney, 1986

Figure 14.2 Irrigated rice projects in The Gambia 228 JUDITH CARNEY agricultural production to year-round farming. Although male heads of households were taught this new form of production, cropping calendars could only be fol- lowed if women joined their husbands in irrigated rice farming. By placing men in charge of technologically improved rice production, the donors hoped to encourage male participation; instead, they unwittingly legitimized male control over the sur- pluses gained from double-cropping. Control over the disposition of marketable surpluses proved pivotal to the gender-based conflicts that erupted within project households over which family members were to assume the increased work load. Male household heads claimed female labor under the customary category, maruo, but irrigated rice farming meant that the claim was invoked for year-round labor. As maruo labor claims for house- hold subsistence had historically evolved within the confines of a single agricultural season, there was no precedent for women to perform labor obligations during two cropping periods when production would yield men a marketable surplus (Carney, 1988, pp. 341–42). Irrigation projects were commodifying rice production, but income gains depended on female labor availability. Women contested the changing lexicon of plot tenure and the enclosure of traditional kamanyango and maruo swamp into irrigation schemes. “Development” meant the delivery of female labor for intensified rice farming without concomitant income gains. The reinterpretation of customary tenure by male household heads and village elites aimed to ensure continued female access to rice land, but only as workers on plots whose benefits would flow to men as disposable surpluses. The donors’ uninformed view of the Gambian household-based production system was to prove the project’s nemesis. Female rice farmers responded in three principal ways to loss of control over pro- ductive swampland and efforts to augment their labor burden: (1) by relocating kamanyango production to unimproved swamplands where they could generate small surpluses for sale; (2) when alternative swampland for rice farming was not available, by agreeing to perform maruo labor obligations on irrigated rice plots during the dry-season cropping cycle in exchange for using the same plot without irrigation during the rainy season for kamanyango production; or (3) by laboring year-round on irrigated schemes but demanding remuneration in rice for their labor during one cropping season (Carney, 1994). All but the first response involved a substantial increase in women’s labor. The third pattern represented an even more pronounced departure in female access to resources as kamanyango land rights in rice production came to an end and female labor was converted into wage work. The project’s mandate to double-crop as a condition for participation placed intense pressure on household labor, which plot designation as maruo could not easily resolve. Previous irrigation schemes had frequently accommodated women’s kamanyango claims at the cost of year-round pumped production. Because project development had incorporated most of the region’s available swampland, preexist- ing kamanyango land access came to an end. Gender-based conflicts exploded throughout the project area as women resisted the erosion of their right to derive benefits from a greatly augmented work burden and sought to reconstitute the rights embraced by kamanyango in other ways. While ethnicity, class, and differences CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 229 among types of irrigated cultivation available within the project shaped the ensuing patterns of conflict resolution, the third response to loss of land access dominated among Mandinka women (Carney, 1994). Nonetheless, many households failed to honor women’s demand for access to project land for kamanyango cultivation or remuneration in kind for year-round maruo labor, resulting in women’s outright refusal to work on the family’s irrigated plots. These dispossessed women consequently pursued two complementary economic strategies for income generation: the formation of work groups to carry out the project’s labor-demanding tasks of transplanting, weeding, and harvesting; and a shift in kamanyango production to upland cultivation. By organizing work groups for hire, women have managed to bid up their daily wage rate within the project and to take advantage of peanut land made available as men intensified their work in the more remunerative rice scheme (Webb, 1989, p. 66). But their efforts to obtain upland kamanyango plots were not always successful as they came into direct com- petition with the claims of junior males for individual land rights. Women have con- sequently placed considerable effort into gaining the support of nongovernmental organizations to develop village vegetable gardens for income generation (Carney, 1986, p. 311). In summary, wetland development policy unfolded initially on riverine flood- plains. As these areas became technologically improved and commodified, male household heads reinterpreted women’s preexisting crop rights and benefits to gain access to their labor for the intensified work burden. Irrigated rice development simultaneously undermined women’s customary access to rice land for income gen- eration, while enabling male household heads to capture surplus value. By ruptur- ing the relationship between women’s knowledge systems, agronomic expertise, and rice farming, project households are beset with repeated delays in cropping sche- dules as well as an inability to follow agronomic recommendations. By the 1990s the legacy included poor rates of double-cropping, declining productivities, and failure to achieve rice import substitution. Notwithstanding repeated state–peasant and male–female conflicts over rice land, irrigated development remains a governmental priority. Gambian political officials and their foreign advisors are currently reviewing ways to more efficiently restruc- ture the irrigation sector. Alternative cropping arrangements in irrigated farming are being explored whereby farmers more “modern” in outlook may be asked to con- tract irrigated land (Carney, 1994). As policy measures increasingly dictate debt repayment and comparative advantage, the earlier small-scale schemes are being rationalized into larger units for centralized pumping and management (CILSS, 1990). A mounting emphasis is being placed upon crops, like fruits and vegetables, that generate foreign exchange. During the 1980s, the international development assistance community challenged male control over irrigation schemes by funding women’s horticultural projects on unimproved inland swamps previously sown to rice. The explicit “women in development” focus of NGOs and multilateral donors aimed to bolster female income earning opportunities by improving seasonally wet swamps, with wells for dry-season planting. As cropping patterns shifted to export production, the process of commodification was brought to inland swamps, with contradictory implications for women. 230 JUDITH CARNEY

Comparative Advantage and Horticultural Development Shortly after the 1968–73 Sahelian drought the Gambian government promoted economic ventures in inland swamps that grew over the years into a major focus of donor assistance and income generation within the country. During the 1970s, the government encouraged onion-growing schemes among village women’s groups as a means to increase household incomes in the peri-urban corridor and North Bank district, geographically proximate to the capital (Ceesay, Jammeh, and Mitchell, 1982). During the next decade women’s vegetable gardens emerged as a major focus of donor support within the country. By the 1990s over 340 small- (0.5–2 hectares, or 1.1–4.9 acres) and medium-scale (5–15 hectares, or 12.3–37 acres) vegetable gardens were developed by NGOs and multilateral donors (Smith, Jack, and Singh, 1985; Nath, 1985; Sumberg and Okali, 1987; Giffen, 1987; DeCosse and Camara, 1990). The entry of private growers into the burgeoning hor- ticultural sector, along with incipient women vegetable growers’ groups (not funded), accounts for an expansion of market gardening that currently exceeds 1,000 hectares (2,470 acres) (Carney, 1992, p. 79). The boom in market gardening on Gambian wetlands results from the confluence of several policy directions during the past 15 years. Following independence, Gambia began developing its pristine beaches for interna- tional tourism; by the 1990s over 100,000 Europeans were taking a six-hour flight to vacation along the Gambian coast between November and April (N’Jang, 1990). The initial onion projects successfully linked local production to the tourist sector and awakened donor agencies to the possibilities of expanding vegetable production for the dry-season tourist demand. These developments, meanwhile, were unfolding against a growing clamor within the international donor community for women in development (WID) projects. The emergent WID focus in The Gambia was pioneered by NGOs that viewed vegetables, tradi- tionally planted by Gambian females, as the solution to women’s limited economic opportunities. Policy support for diversifying wetland agriculture into horticulture received additional impetus in 1985 with an IMF-mandated structural adjustment program. Geographic proximity to Europe encouraged policymakers to exploit The Gambia’s comparative advantage as a winter fruit and vegetable supplier, as did favorable tariffs and the removal of export taxes on fresh produce (UNCTAD, 1986; Gov- ernment of The Gambia, 1987; Jack, 1990). By the 1990s horticultural production had expanded to rain-fed areas in the peri-urban corridor located near the interna- tional airport, with boreholes dug to reach underground aquifers. With few excep- tions, the projects are operated by the state, senior government officials, and resident Lebanese and Indian landowners and are oriented to European export markets. The same period witnessed the growing involvement of multilateral donors (European Economic Community, Islamic Development Bank, United Nations Development Program, and the World Bank) in women’s horticultural production and marketing along the coastal corridor (Ceesay, Jammeh, and Mitchell, 1982; Government of The Gambia, 1987; Barrett and Browne, 1991, p. 244; Carney, 1992, p. 78; World Bank, 1990). Despite this most recent form of donor support, Gambian women’s horticultural projects remain concentrated in rural areas, on inland swamps of small CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 231 areal extent (0.5–2 hectares, or 1.2–4.9 acres), and oriented to local and regional markets. Although the policy emphasis on converting inland swamps to horticulture dates from the 1970s, Gambian women have long been involved in vegetable production. They were observed marketing vegetables during the dry season as far back as the mid-fifteenth century. Although colonial horticultural programs targeted men, their failure left vegetable growing in women’s hands. Females remained the country’s principal producers, using residual moisture from inland rice swamps early in the dry season to cultivate traditional crops such as bitter tomatoes, okra, sorrel, and hibiscus for subsistence. Donor support for well construction from the 1980s has enabled an extension of the vegetable-growing period in inland swamps. Deeply dug, concrete-lined wells have revolutionized Gambian horticultural production by tapping water tables for dry-season cultivation. Vegetable gardening is no longer a seasonal activity, as it was prior to donor involvement. Women’s village gardens receiving NGO assistance grow vegetables during the entire dry season and, in some cases, year-round. The provision of reliable water supplies through well-digging is central to NGO efforts to implement a rural development strategy aimed at improving women’s incomes. By promoting village gardens for women’s groups interested in commer- cialized vegetable cultivation, NGOs have launched a development strategy that targets women who were ignored in the previous wetland policy approach. Arrange- ments to secure female access to improved village gardens, however, vary between communities and depend on the availability of land locally, as well as the swamp’s land use history. Consequently, in rural communities with NGO-supported gardens, women are granted either year-round usufruct for cash-cropping vegetables or kamanyango dry-season rights, with the plot reverting to subsistence cereal pro- duction in the rainy season. Once access to land is accomplished, NGOs provide assistance for constructing concrete-lined wells and barbed wire fences (for protec- tion from livestock damage). When completed, female growers are credited the seeds and tools for vegetable farming. A labor-intensive process, vegetable gardening during the dry season requires two daily waterings – averaging about two hours per session – weeding, and pest control, as well as transporting the bulky and highly perishable produce to weekly markets. But in a country where rural per capita income averages US $130, efforts are often rewarded (World Bank, 1981). Schroeder (1992, p. 4) records that women vegetable growers in surveyed North Bank villages gross incomes ranging between US $67–265 during the dry season, with more than half of them reporting incomes exceeding their husbands’ earnings from peanuts. These income differentials are the new source of contemporary gender conflict in North Bank vegetable gardens. Vegetable gardening nonetheless remains attractive to women, whose alternative income-earning prospects are limited. While structural adjustment programs have led to a 10 percent reduction in employment within the government sector and have catapulted men into increasing involvement in horticultural production, women have generally maintained usufruct to village land for gardening because donor representatives, located in the capital, are poised to defend them. Proximity to the land border with Senegal and declining peanut production associated with upland environmental degradation underlie the gender conflicts that have emerged in 232 JUDITH CARNEY

North Bank horticultural projects. As with peanuts, most vegetable production flows across the border to Senegal, where horticultural import–export distribution networks are of operator antiquity, internal demand for vegetables is more devel- oped, and prices are higher (Mackintosh, 1989, p. 15). NGO improvement of inland swamps with wells has resulted in new avenues for income generation that sharply conflict with the WID objectives of NGOs. NGO-funded vegetable projects in North Bank communities have transformed the inland swamps and the social relations regulating preexisting cropping and labor patterns. Well construction, in effect, has widened the seasonal window that for- merly regulated vegetable cultivation. Crops are no longer confined to the autum- nal planting period following the rice harvest; vegetables can be planted throughout the dry season, and frequently year-round, since profits from cross-border sales cur- rently compensate for displaced rice production (Schroeder and Watts, 1991, p. 62). As North Bank horticultural projects have considerably augmented women’s earnings, female rights of disposal over their income and access to vegetable land have come under increasing threat. Schroeder reports men deferring to women the burden for costs formerly met by males and their capture of part of women’s earn- ings through unpaid loans. Additionally, male landholders in numerous communi- ties are contesting women’s access rights to vegetable land through the planting of economically valuable trees (e.g., mango and orange) within the vegetable gardens. After five to ten years the canopy closes, blocking the sunlight needed for vegetable growth. Tree planting therefore facilitates the conversion of land use from vegetable gardens to orchards, enabling male landlords to reclaim the improved plots for their own economic strategy based on tree crops within a decade (Schroeder, 1992, p. 9). By making verbal agreements with NGOs for women’s vegetable gardens, land- lords are acquiescing to female demands for kamanyango land rights. But these rights are honored only for limited number of years – those required to capture women’s labor for watering adjacent fruit trees during the initial growth period. The use of economically valuable trees to recapture garden plots as male kamanyango over the long run, however, is not lost on women. Schroeder (1992) notes the gender confrontations that have occurred with orchard planting: women cutting back mango and orange trees as they begin shading out vegetables, deliber- ately setting fires to fatally damage fruit trees, and sending delegations to local officials for legal action. The inland swamps of the North Bank, formerly used by women for subsistence rice production, are being increasingly commercialized to vegetables. But the process is unfolding within a region of limited economic opportunity and severe environ- mental degradation. While NGOs attempted to address the gender equity issue ignored in the first wetland development phase, this second development approach indicates that women’s gains over the long run are indeed precarious.

Conclusion The structural dislocation of a monocrop export economy and attendant food shortages brought government attention to the Gambian wetlands during the late colonial period. The pattern of swamp development implemented during colonial rule foreshadowed the large-scale emphasis on the wetlands that materialized with CONVERTING THE WETLANDS, ENGENDERING THE ENVIRONMENT 233 the influx of foreign capital coincident with the Sahelian drought. During the past 25 years, wetland development through irrigation projects has transformed Gambian agriculture from a seasonal to a year-round activity, enabling agricultural diversification, surplus cereal production, and new avenues of income generation among rural households. The promise of irrigated agriculture, however, depends upon the ability of peasant households to restructure family labor to the dictates of irrigated farming – a labor regime that requires a greater work burden during the entire calendar year. As claims to family labor evolved in the context of a limited wet season, institu- tional mechanisms within household-based production systems were deformed to mobilize family labor for year-round agriculture. Use of the term maruo, for tech- nologically improved swamps, is central to obtaining a female labor reserve for the intensified work burden in irrigated farming. While reaffirming the integrity of the patriarchal family landholding, the naming of developed land, maruo, in practice facilitates men’s claim to benefits produced by female labor. Women contest the semantics of maruo precisely because this new meaning is a mechanism that deprives them of their customary rights. They are acutely aware that the rules of access to, and control over, environment resources are not a codi- fication of immemorial tradition, but rather the outcome of struggle and negotia- tion with husbands, male community leaders, state and donor officials (Berry, 1986, p. 5; Okoth-Ogendo, 1989, p. 14). This awareness has sharpened in the past 25 years with irrigation projects that have imbued wetlands with new economic value. Gambian women are not engaging men in mere semantic discussion as they strug- gle for kamanyango rights – their actions reveal growing recognition that com- modification of the wetlands is steadily eroding their economic and social status within the household and village community. The two case studies of irrigated agriculture illustrate the multiple ways in which women contest and renegotiate their access to resources. Struggles in rice schemes have centered on reaffirming claims to a portion of the surplus by requesting sea- sonal plot use as kamanyango; remuneration in the form of paddy rice for year- round labor availability; or, when labor benefits are denied, outright refusal to work on the household’s irrigated fields and entry into local wage markets for improved rates of pay. Each outcome of women’s struggles, however, has resulted in an inten- sification of female work burdens without commensurate income gains. Women’s fortunes appear much improved in vegetable projects, where females are granted kamanyango cropping rights seasonally or year-round. But female growers find their incomes from garden cultivation being claimed in new ways by their husbands, who, in some cases, refuse to pay back the loans given by their wives or abrogate their contributions toward household expenses (Schroeder, 1992). Moreover, the increasing emphasis on orchards for income generation indicates that women’s kamanyango gardening rights may only be exercised for a limited number of years – equivalent to the time required for hand-watering of trees until the plot’s land use converts to mature orchards (Schroeder, 1992). Despite income gains and growing militancy, women’s earnings in vegetable gardening appear precarious over the long run. These case studies indicate that a process of land concentration is occurring in Gambian wetlands improved with irrigation. Concentration is not the result of 234 JUDITH CARNEY absolute land scarcity and overpopulation but rather a response to household labor shortages and new income opportunities with irrigated agriculture. The designation, maruo, for irrigated land reveals how land is enclosed to create an artificial scarcity for accessing female labor. This unusual form of enclosure permits women access to irrigated land, while denying them benefits from their work. Land concentration consequently involves the conversion of a developed plot from one with multiple female rights to the surplus product to land with a single claim over the surplus produced by multiple female laborers. In outlining the social and historical processes of changing land use strategies on the Gambian wetlands, this paper reveals that more than the environment is being transformed. So too are the social relations that mediate access to, and use of, land within rural households. The contemporary pattern of accumulation unfolding in the Gambian wetlands centrally depends on controlling access to irrigated land by “freeing” women from their customary rights and by imposing new work routines that undervalue and intensify their labor contribution. Women, however, are resist- ing their newly assigned role as cheap labor reserves. Chapter 15 Nourishing Networks: Alternative Geographies of Food

Sarah Whatmore and Lorraine Thorne

[T]he capitalism of Karl Marx or Fernand Braudel is not the total capitalism of the Marxists. It is a skein of somewhat longer networks that rather inadequately embrace a world on the basis of points that become centers of profit and calculation. In fol- lowing it step by step, one never crosses the mysterious lines that divide the local from the global. (Latour, 1993, p. 121)

The spatial imagery of a “shrinking world” and a “global village” are the popular hallmarks of an understanding of the limitless compass and totalizing fabric of con- temporary capitalism that has become something of a social science orthodoxy, known as globalization (Featherstone, 1990; Sklair, 1991). No less heroic than the institutional complexes which it depicts, such an understanding perpetuates a pecu- liarly modernist geographical imagination that casts globalization as a colonization of surfaces which, like a spreading ink stain, progressively colors every spot on the map. This spatial imagery suffuses the political economy of agro-food through ana- lytical devices like “global commodity systems” (Friedland et al., 1991), “agro-food regimes” (Le Heron, 1994), and “systems of provision” (Fine et al., 1996). In the most cogently argued versions, globalization is animated as a political project of world economic management orchestrated by a regiment of capitalist institutions including transnational corporations (TNCs), financial institutions, and regulatory infrastructures (McMichael, 1996, p. 112). But the most potent agro-food expres- sion of this spatial imagery must surely be George Ritzer’s notion of “McDonaldiza- tion.” He coins the term to describe a process of social rationalization modeled on the fast-food restaurant which he argues has “revolutionized not only the restau- rant business, but also American society and, ultimately, the world” (Ritzer, 1996, p. xvii). This is social science at its most triumphant, a rhetorically seductive best- seller which serves up the world on a plate. That some markets indeed have global reach is not in dispute. What we want to emphasize is that this reach makes the corporations and bureaucracies that fashion such markets both powerful and vulnerable, being woven of the same substances as the more humble everyday forms of social life so often consigned to the “local” and rendered puny in comparison. One of the most serious consequences of ortho- dox accounts of globalization, whether of the more rigorous or the more populist varieties identified above, has been the eradication of social agency and struggle 236 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE from the compass of analysis by presenting global reach as a systemic and logical, rather than a partial and contested, process (Amin and Thrift, 1994). TNCs and associated regulatory bureaucracies become magnified into institutional dinosaurs whose scale and mass overwhelms the paltry significance of their social fabric, at the same time as the life practices and milieux of lesser social agents are dwarfed and overshadowed in this colossal landscape. But size, as the dinosaurs discovered, isn’t everything. Our point then, is that there is nothing “global” about such corporations and bureaucracies in themselves, either in terms of their being disembedded from par- ticular contexts and places or of their being in some sense comprehensive in scale and scope. Rather, their reach depends upon intricate interweavings of situated people, artifacts, codes, and living things and the maintenance of particular tapes- tries of connection across the world. Such processes and patterns of connection are not reducible to a single logic or determinant interest lying somewhere outside or above the social fray. This distinction is the difference between systems and net- works; a shift in analytical metaphor which takes up critiques of the globalization orthodoxy, notably within geography and anthropology, as a failure of both social and spatial imagination (Strathern, 1995; Thrift, 1996b). Two complementary influences on the elaboration of these critiques are particu- larly important for our purposes here, the one concerned with rethinking political economy and the other with recognizing space-time. In the first case, economic soci- ology and institutional economics have emphasized the embodied and routinized social practices which constitute markets, corporations, and regulatory bureaucra- cies against accounts (Marxist and neoclassical) which tend to treat these institu- tional complexes as abstracted presences, or the product of some historically teleological process (Underhill, 1994; Thrift and Olds, 1996). Economic institutions and practices are conceived of not as some separate, and still less determinant, “sphere” of activity which articulates with other “spheres” of civic society or governance but as socially embedded and contingent at every turn (Smelser and Swedberg, 1994; Murdoch, 1995). In the second case, poststructuralist ideas have informed theoretical efforts to deconstruct the geometric landscapes – what Barnes (1996) has called the “Enlightenment view” – of political economy. By fashioning the modern world as a single grid-like surface, such landscapes make possible the encoding of general theoretical claims as omnipresent, universal rationalities. In con- trast, critics point to the simultaneity of multiple, partial space-time configurations of social life that are at once “global” and “local,” and to the situatedness of social institutions, processes, and knowledges as always contextual, tentative, and incomplete (Thrift, 1995). Such critiques, especially that derived from institutional economics, have been taken up already by those working in agrarian political economy (see Goodman and Watts, 1994; Whatmore, 1994). While it remains “against the grain,” such work marks the beginnings of an understanding of globalization as partial, uneven, and unstable; a socially contested rather than logical process in which many spaces of resistance, alterity, and possibility become analytically discernible and politically meaningful. In this paper we want to extend these lines of critique, particularly that concerned with spatial recognition, as a basis for exploring alternative geographies NOURISHING NETWORKS 237 of food that have been eclipsed by mainstream political economy accounts (see Arce and Marsden, 1993; Cook and Crang, 1996, for related forays). The title phrase “alternative geographies of food” signals an effort on our part to see the world differently in (at least) two senses. We begin by taking up the geo- graphical implications of actor-network theory (ANT) which both of us have been exploring in work elsewhere (Thorne, 1997; Whatmore, 1997). As the opening quo- tation suggests, this involves the elaboration of a topological spatial imagination concerned with tracing points of connection and lines of flow, as opposed to reit- erating fixed surfaces and boundaries (Thrift, 1996b; Bingham, 1996). In particu- lar, we draw on the work of Bruno Latour (1993, 1994) and John Law (1986, 1991, 1994) to elaborate an understanding of global networks as performative orderings (always in the making), rather than as systemic entities (always already constituted). We then go on to explore some of the analytical and political spaces which such an understanding opens up, by means of a case study of fair trade coffee networks. This case study illustrates the fashioning of social and environmental configurations of agro-food production and consumption that coexist with those of industrial food corporations but which in some way counter, or resist, their institutional values and practices.

Global Networks or “Acting at a Distance” The two extremes, local and global, are much less interesting than the intermediary arrangements that we are calling networks. (Latour, 1993, p. 122)

The work of Latour and Law, and their respective notions of “hybrid networks” and “modes of ordering,” provide ways of reconceptualizing power relations in space from the flat, colonized surfaces of globalization to the frictional lengthening of networks of remote control. In so doing, the key question becomes not that of scale, encoded in a categorical distinction between the “local” and the “global,” but of connectivity, marking lines of flow of varying length and which transgress these categories. To put this question in the terms of ANT, what are the conditions and properties of “acting at a distance”? Formulating inquiry in this way refuses the privileged association a priori between particular kinds of social institutions (notably TNCs) and global reach and, by implication, the pervasive mapping of the conventional sociological binaries of “macro–micro” and “structure–agency” onto that of the “global–local.” Our account builds on the early efforts of geographers to explicate the spatial dimensions of ANT and their import for understanding power as a thoroughly relational process (Murdoch, 1995; Murdoch and Marsden, 1995) and for recognizing the active part of nonhumans in the fabric of social life (Thrift, 1995, 1996b). Where orthodox accounts of globalization evoke images of an irresistible and unimpeded enclosure of the world by the relentless mass of the capitalist machine, ANT problematizes global reach, conceiving of it as a labored, uncertain, and above all, contested process of “acting at a distance,” Law illustrates this conception with the example of Portuguese efforts to expand the reach of European trade in the 238 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE

fifteenth and sixteenth centuries by capturing the spice route to India (1986). This achievement required the Portuguese to refashion contemporary navigational complexes in ways which, as Law puts it, addressed not only the question of social control but also that of

how to manage long distance control in all its aspects. It was how to arrange matters so that a small number of people in Lisbon might influence events half-way round the world and thereby reap a fabulous reward. (Law, 1986, p. 235, original emphasis)

Law’s evocative case study of “acting at a distance” centers on the technological metaphor of “remote control” which tends to conjure the dynamics of networking in the rather conventional geographical binary of core (transmitter) and periphery (receiver). Nor are the implications of this metaphor restricted in his work to this particular case study. The imprint of “remote control” marks his elaboration of ANT more widely. Thus, for example,

heterogeneous socio-technologies open up the possibility of ordering distant events from a center . . . [in which] the center is a place which monitors and represents the periphery and then calculates how to act on the periphery. (Law, 1994, p. 104)

A rather different, and to our mind more promising, exposition of the spatial con- figuration of actor-networks is that derived from Latour’s notion of “network lengthening.” Reminiscent of the nomadic cartographies of Deleuze and Guattari (1983), the idea of “lengthening” not only problematizes the process of “acting at a distance” but also disrupts the bi-polarities of “core” and “periphery.” These generic spaces, like those of “local” and “global,” enshrine a geometric vocabulary concerned with the geography of surfaces. The unilinearity encoded in their rela- tionship makes less sense in a topologic vocabulary concerned with the geography of flows. Here, a network’s capacities over space-time represent the simultaneous performance of social practices and competences at different points in the network; a mass of currents rather than a single line of force. In these terms, actor-networks are best understood as “by nature neither local nor global, but [only] more or less long and more or less connected” (Latour, 1993, p. 122). By implication, the size, or scale, of an actor-network is a product of network lengthening, not of some special properties peculiar to “global” or “core” actors, the “dinosaurs” of our earlier analogy. Furthermore, the power associated with global reach has to be understood as a social composite of the actions and competences of many actants; an attribute not of a single person or organization but of the number of actants involved in its composition (Callon and Latour, 1981; Murdoch and Marsden, 1995). How, then, is this network lengthening achieved? The answer advanced in ANT is that network lengthening requires the mobilization of larger numbers and more intricately interwoven constituents, or mediators, to sustain a web of connections over greater distances. In so doing, it focuses analytical attention on describing this process of mediation and its agents in ways which force a challenging, and sometimes disconcerting, shift in the horizons of social research. As Law notes in relation to his Portuguese case study, NOURISHING NETWORKS 239

if these attempts at long-distance control are to be understood then it is not only nec- essary to develop a form of analysis capable of handling the social, the technological, the natural and the rest with equal facility, though this is essential. It is also necessary that the approach should be capable of making sense of the way in which these are fitted together. (Law, 1986, p. 235)

At once it becomes essential to talk of network mediators other than people, that is other than the human actors on whom the whole compass of conventional theo- ries of social agency (including other social network theories) is built. To be sure, people in particular guises and contexts act as important go-betweens, mobile agents weaving connections between distant points in the network; for example, the sailors in Law’s Portuguese study, or the managerial elites of corporate business today. But, insists ANT, there are a wealth of other agents, technological and “natural,” mobi- lized in the performance of social networks whose significance increases the longer and more intricate the network becomes. Latour calls these agents “immutable mobiles,” such as money, telephones, computers, or gene banks; objects which encode and stabilize particular socio-technological capacities and sustain patterns of connection that allow us to pass with continuity not only from the local to the global, but also from the human to the nonhuman. The more they have prolifer- ated in everyday life the more, it seems, these “objects” have been effaced in social theory leaving us awed by the subsequently fantastic properties of social entities like TNCs. By taking such objects into account “one can follow the growth of an organ- ization in its entirety without ever changing levels and without ever discovering ‘decontextualized’ rationality” (Latour, 1993, p. 122). It should by now be apparent that a move from “globalization” to global net- works as a basis for understanding the conditions and properties of “acting at a distance” is no small step. It is worth rehearsing three major, mutually reinforcing elements of the theory as it is advanced by Latour and Law (and Callon): hybrid- ity, collectivity, and durability. Breaking down the global–local binary through the idea of the lengthening of networks is intricately tied up with breaking down the nature–society binary through the idea of hybridity. Just as the global–local distinction serves to purify processes and entities that are not of themselves confined to any particular spatial scale, so the ontological separation of society and nature purifies the messy hetero- geneity of life. Hybrids represent states of being which fall somewhere between the passive objects of human will and imagination which litter the social sciences, and the autonomous external forces favored in natural science accounts. Following Michel Serres (see Serres and Latour, 1995), Latour designates these in-between states of being as quasi-objects which are as “real as nature, narrated as discourse, collective as society [and] existential as being” (Latour, 1993, p. 89). Returning to the Portuguese study, Law shows how a composite of agents are enjoined as emissaries of network lengthening, including documents, devices, and people fashioned in particular ways. For example, a document called the “Regi- mento” inscribed a distilled and simplified instruction for navigating by stars which permitted the navigator to pass beyond the established envelope of North European travel. Devices included the “carreira,” a ship designed for carrying cargo and avoiding plunder, and “a kind of simplified black box,” the astrolabe. Similarly, this 240 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE effort to act at a distance mobilized people with very particular kinds of skills or embodied social practices, including navigators, sailors, and merchants. This example picks up and illustrates a second key step in understanding the process of network lengthening, the fundamentally relational, or collective concep- tion of social agency that characterizes ANT. Thus, the significance of the “docu- ments, devices and drilled people” in Law’s Portuguese study is the way in which they hold each other in position. “The right documents, the right devices, the right people properly drilled – put together they would create a structured envelope for one another that ensured their durability and fidelity” (Law, 1986, p. 254). Yet the full implications of this conception of social agency are relatively underdeveloped in this early case study. It is in Law’s later work and, more particularly, in the notion of the hybrid collectif (Callon and Law, 1995) that the importance of the active properties of nonhuman agents in the lengthening of networks is most fully explored. For Latour, these agents are a vital part of a network’s collective capac- ity to act “because they attach us to one another, because they circulate in our hands and define our social bond by their very circulation” (1993, p. 89). Thus far we have outlined hybridity and collectivity as necessary corollaries of the process of mediation by which networks are sustained over greater distances. Of equal significance is the question of how such networks are strengthened and stabilized over time or, in ANT terms, how they are made durable. In Law’s book Organizing Modernity, he adapts Foucault’s notion of “discursive practices” to propose modes of ordering as a way of conceptualizing the durability of networks. Modes of ordering are both narrative “ways of telling about the world . . . what used to be, or what ought to happen,” and material, “acted out and embodied in a concrete, non-verbal manner in a network” (Law, 1994, p. 20). He shows how organizations perform multiple “modes of ordering,” which influence the ways in which agents are enrolled in global networks. While these organizational pattern- ings or habits are invariably plural rather than singular, Law argues that “only a relatively small number of modes of ordering may be instantiated in the networks of the social at a given time and place” (ibid., p. 109). In other words the durabil- ity of long-distance networks requires strong fabrics of social organization at all points in the network, making the patterning of social and environmental practices in particular times and places integral to the business of network enrolment.

Fair Trade Coffee: An Alternative Net-Working In this context, alternative geographies of food are located in the political competence and social agency of individuals, institutions, and alliances, enacting a variety of partial knowledges and strategic interests through networks which simultaneously involve a “lengthening” of spatial and institutional reach and a “strengthening” of environmental and social embeddedness. Such networks exist alongside the corporate and state networks of orthodox accounts of globalization, sometimes overlapping them in space-time; sometimes occupying separate sites and establishing discrete lines of connection; and sometimes explicitly oriented towards challenging their associated environmental and social practices. In the case of food, the “devices, documents and drilled people” of Law’s Portuguese example translate NOURISHING NETWORKS 241 into a broader compass of material concerns than that associated with traditional agrarian political economy. These include the encoding of particular agricultural and dietary knowledges in the form of various technologies; the legal inscription of agro-food practices, from patents to health criteria; and the disciplining of bodies, from obese and skeletal people to industrial animals and plants. Using this collection of ideas, and working to avoid the bias of scale in struc- turalist accounts (which inscribe a macro–micro division and then reify the former), we propose that modes of ordering which spin documents, devices, and living crea- tures (including people) as other than passive agents through multiply sited net- works are both possible and extant. In the case study we discuss one such patterning explicitly oriented towards enacting an alternative commodity network, which we have identified as a mode of ordering of connectivity. In this mode of ordering, stories are told of partnership, alliance, responsibility, and fairness, but performed in very different ways to the neo-liberal encoding of these terms (Barratt-Brown, 1993). This is a mode of ordering concerned with the empowerment of marginal- ized, dismissed, and overlooked voices, human or nonhuman. Implicit in this empowering performance is the knowledge that “some network configurations gen- erate effects which, so long as everything else is equal, last longer than others” (Law, 1994, p. 103). The mode of connectivity therefore not only tells and performs but also tries to concretely embody a recursive effect of social, and sometimes environ- mental, embeddedness. With roots in nongovernmental organizations dedicated to alleviating poverty in the “Third World,” the fair trade “movement” has grown in the UK over the past twenty-five years. The charity Oxfam established a wholly owned trading company in 1964 with other organizations gradually emerging as fully-fledged trading com- panies from solidarity markets (for example, Trading Limited), or educational functions (for example, and the Third World Informa- tion Network – TWIN). The recently formed British Association of Fair Trade Shops (BAFTS) consists of shops committed to principles of fair trade. Other organiza- tions do not trade at all but provide support in the form of campaigning and lob- bying (for example the World Development Movement). The point here is that fair trade organizations in the UK are diverse and numerous, with the physical trans- actions of trading only one of their component activities. The institutions, transac- tions, and technologies of fair trade serve to illustrate some of the key concerns highlighted by an analysis of agro-food patterns as hybrid networks. In particular, it shows how the global reach of so-called alternative agro-food networks (or their capacity to “act at a distance”) enrols coincident actants and spaces to those of “mainstream” commercial networks. It is the modes of network strengthening (or making durable) that are analytically distinctive between the orderings of fair trade and capitalist commerce and that open up economic and political possibilities for configuring alternative geographies of food. In this case study we discuss a hybrid network of four UK fair trade organiza- tions and a Peruvian coffee exporting cooperative, although there are many other agents in this network, as becomes clear. In the late 1980s “Oxfam Trading,” “Twin Trading,” “,” and “Equal Exchange Trading Limited” came together to create a consortium called Cafédirect which procures, imports, and markets a brand 242 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE of coffee of the same name, available in ground and freeze-dried forms. The four partners are located in different cities in the UK – Oxford, London, Newcastle-upon- Tyne, and Edinburgh respectively. In the early days, the hybrid network of Cafédirect operated with no central office. Instead, partners had designated responsibilities, for example the buyer working for one organization, the wholesale administration handled by another and so on, with one of the partners, “Twin Trading,” acting as the operational focal point. In 1993 the consortium became reg- istered as a private company which has recently appointed a managing director, and the partners are now “shareholders.” Cafédirect was the second fairly traded product in the UK to receive the Fair Trademark, which legitimizes the product as fairly traded according to criteria set out by , an inde- pendent organization recently given charitable status but originally established by several fair trade organizations, including Oxfam and Traidcraft. Thus the product of the Cafédirect network is given institutional legitimacy by a hybridized form of itself. Cafédirect’s southern partners are small-scale farmers whose coffee trees cling to steep mountain slopes in Costa Rica, Peru, and Mexico, in the case of the Arabica component of the brand, while the Robusta component comes from similar pro- ducers in Tanzania and Uganda. In this case study we restrict our discussion to some of Cafédirect’s partners in Peru, namely the exporting cooperative of CECOOAC- Nor, located in Chiclayo on the northern coast of Peru. CECOOAC-Nor is the central cooperative of nine individual coffee producing cooperatives dotted through the northern Andean mountains. They were all established in the 1970s during a period in which the then military government supported farmers’ cooperatives through an Agrarian Bank. But during the 1980s subsequent governments relin- quished support and the bank became defunct, leaving farmers vulnerable to com- mercial bank interest rates and the purchasing strategies of commercial traders (comerciantes). In the 1970s cooperatives were able to provide services to their members, includ- ing medical and educational services. Since then, these support services have been eroded, adding to the exposure of the cooperatives to renewed economic pressures. As access to cheap credit dried up the cooperatives have struggled to pay for their members’ coffee. The situation worsened in 1989 when the International Coffee Agreement collapsed, leaving prices unregulated. Embedded in a political, economic, and social climate of considerable turmoil, the small-scale coffee producers in the northern Andes were buffeted by the vagaries of the Cocoa, Sugar, and Coffee Exchange in New York (CSCE), which regulates the Arabica futures and spot markets, and the powerful comerciantes for whom credit access was not a problem. In 1990 CECOOAC-Nor made its first sale to a fair trade organization, a key event for its survival. The buyer was a roaster belonging to Max Havelaar, a Dutch- based hybrid network of mainstream coffee roasters who, in exchange for paying a fair price, are able to carry the Max Havelaar trademark on their coffee packag- ing. Sales to Cafédirect followed, the contracts negotiated with both the Cafédirect buyer and the CECOOAC-Nor export manager paying close attention to the daily market prices in New York. The key difference between fair trade buyers and com- mercial dealers is that the former pay a guaranteed minimum price (which protects farmers should the market go into free-fall), and a standard number of points above NOURISHING NETWORKS 243

NORTH AMERICA

??????????

??????????

??????????

?????????? UNITED KINGDOM

London Commodity Exchange

U.K. Banking Institutions

Customs and Excise

Shipping Agents and Port Authorities

Telecommunications Facilities

Organic Certification

LATIN AMERICA ???????????

????? Markets Reuters Commodity Service

??????????

??????????

?????????? Key to space of flows Coffee physicals ?????????? Documents (physical) Telecommunications Facilities Documents and devices (instantaneous) Organic certification People

Figure 15.1 Network “lengthening”: coincident spaces of a fair trade and commercial coffee network the CSCE price when the market price exceeds the minimum (in effect, a 10 percent premium). The CSCE is therefore one of many coincident actants and sites in the hybrid network of fairly traded coffee and the commercial coffee networks (see Figure 15.1). Other such coincidences include the export and import authorities for whom documentation must be in order for goods to be granted passage. Cafédirect pays CECOOAC-Nor using the international financial system (although there may be delays in the release of payments from Peruvian banks for other reasons). The stock exchange, customs officials, and banking clerks are all actants of the hybrid network of fair trade, so too are their computers, telephones, and fax machines. Just as there are coincident actants and spaces between fair trade and commercial coffee networks, so too is there a coincident mode of ordering – 244 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE that of enterprise – pragmatic, opportunistic, and canny (Law, 1994, p. 1). The “Third World” partners of Northern fair trade organizations are not insulated from the disciplines of the market – delivery deadlines, contracts, and quality conditions all have to be met. However, while the mode of ordering of enterprise is present throughout the fair trade hybrid network, it is mediated and re-articulated by another mode of ordering – that of connectivity. The raison d’être of Cafédirect, and the social agency of the fair trade network as a whole, rests on the mobilization of a mode of ordering of connectivity different from that of the cost- minimizing, self-interested individual of neoclassical economic theory. The packag- ing of Cafédirect coffee products makes the discourse of connectivity explicit.

This is a fair trade product. More of the money you pay for Cafédirect freeze-dried goes directly to the small-scale coffee farmers in Latin America and Africa. Fair trade means coffee growing communities can afford to invest in healthcare, education and agriculture.

These words establish a connection between those who grow and those who buy Cafédirect coffee. Connectivity as a mode of ordering establishes the performance of “fairness,” rather than charity, in which the farmer gets a “fair price” and the consumer “gets excellent coffee.” In order to strengthen the network, fair trade organizations must make concrete the telling and performing of connectivity and fairness in the hybrid network. But the story is more complicated because another actant in this network, the coffee, is fraught with variabilities that reverberate through the network as a whole. In order to provide consumers of Cafédirect with “excellent coffee,” the cooperatives must submit only the highest quality beans. If the coffee is of low quality (reasons may include rainfall, “pests,” fermentation) it will not be suitable for the fair trade contracts negotiated by the cooperative export manager and the Cafédirect buyer, and farmers will sell to the comerciantes. If the price on the stock exchange is high comerciantes will pay well even for this low quality, and they will pay in cash. When the CSCE price is high – if, for example, the coffee harvest in Brazil is devastated by frost – farmers may see little benefit in selling to the cooperative. In such circumstances tensions between the modes of ordering of enterprise and connectivity become immediate and tangible as, for example, the warehouse goes unfilled. At each point in the hybrid network there is instability and uncertainty, so that strengthening the embeddedness of the cooperatives is as important to the fair trade network as strengthening consumer support for fair trade coffee through market- ing strategies and educational campaigns. Network strengthening is a process performed both locally and globally (see Figure 15.2). “Strengthening” social and environmental habits of association amongst producers involves the enhancement of essential services – agricultural, medical, and educational. The second key aspect of the mode of ordering of connectivity evidenced in this case study, that of sensi- tivity to interactions between human and nonhuman actants in the network, is accomplished through organic farming practices. Making the soil fertile by cultivating earthworms (lombrices) and mulch, interplanting with shade trees and not burning-off makes coffee growing practices less environmentally destructive. Six of the cooperatives have organic certification granted by the Organic Crop (a) Fair trade coffee network

Administration by All aware of commodity Either cooperatives of premium market prices; but “Fair Trade Market” to establish medical, specifically exporting or marked agricultural, and cooperative and U.K. “Fairly Traded”. educational services fair trade organization May be certified organic close contracts; cooperative aims to keep costs within fair trade contract prices

A C E

U.K. Exporting Consumer Fair trade Producer Cooperative cooperative purchase organization

B D F

Cooperatives buy from Organic production Marketed explicitly producer for contract encouraged and with reference to the price which includes fair enhanced social conditions of trade (& organic) farmers. May also be premium with differential organic certified and for quality. marketed Buying high quality

(b) Commercial coffee network

May, or may not, pay Aims to keep cost of May be certified extra for organically physicals down when organic certified product, to buying, particularly individual farmers. No in relation to premium for social fluctuating commodity programs prices

A C E

Commercial Consumer Producer Dealers company purchase

B D F

Buys centrally or from Growing strategies Brand-related and farm gate if sourcing oriented to crop niche marketing, not difficult. Takes variable maximization with concerned with social quality, offers cash direct or indirect and environmental in hand encouragement of conditions industrial growing practices

Key A = Premium B = Buying strategy C = Relation to commodity market D - Bean E = Certification F = Marketing

Figure 15.2 Network “strengthening”: fair trade and commercial coffee networks exhibit distinctive modes of ordering 246 SARAH WHATMORE AND LORRAINE THORNE

Improvement Association (OCIA International), drawing into the hybrid network yet other actants and sites across the US, Germany, and the UK. The whole process of organic certification is now regulated in law under European Union legislation (yet another coincident actant and space of fair trade and commercial networks offering organic products). The issue of environmental embeddedness, while a key part of the practices associated with the strengthening of alternative food networks, is no less dynamic than their institutional and technological aspects. This brief description of a fair trade network is partial not least because there are other coffee growing organizations selling to Cafédirect, creating more hetero- geneity than this example is able to convey. Nonetheless, it serves to illustrate how alternative geographies of food lengthen their reach using many of the same actants and spaces as their commercial counterparts. What is analytically distinctive, however, is how they strengthen relationships amongst formerly “passive” actants in commercial networks – the producers and consumers – through a mode of ordering of connectivity which works for non-hierarchical relationships framed by “fairness.”

Alternative Geographies of Food What is to be done, then, with such sleek, filled-in surfaces, with such absolute totalities? Turn them inside out all at once, of course; subvert them, revolutionize them. The moderns have invented at one and the same time the total system, the total revolution to put an end to the system, and the equally total failure to carry out that revolution. (Latour, 1993, p. 126)

The tendency to transform the lengthened networks of modern social life into sys- tematic and global totalities generates heroic accounts of globalization which do not recognize their own partiality (Thrift, 1995, p. 24). For Latour, such accounts of the relentless logic of social rationalization belie “a simple category mistake, the confusion of one branch of mathematics with another” (Latour, 1993, p. 119). Where the concepts “local” and “global” work well for surfaces and geometry, they mean little for networks and topology. While Latour’s own style of writing is too supercilious for some – there is nothing simple about this category mistake – it should not detract from the importance of recognizing the power of metaphor and language in shaping economic, as much as scientific, understandings of the world (Mirowski, 1995b; Barnes, 1996); a power that is made flesh in numerous ways. In one sense, such vocabularies become embodied in the performance of individual and collective social identities and practices, both amongst corporate managers and oppositional political movements. In another sense, they become encoded in the authoritative texts and devices of law and science or in the engineered bodies of plants and animals (including humans). In outlining an alternative understanding of global networks, the main points that we take from actor-network theory are that networks, unlike systems, are not self-sustaining; they rely on hundreds of thousands of people, machines, and codes to make the network. They are collective, that is their length and durability are woven between the capacities and practices of actants-in-relation. They are hybrid, NOURISHING NETWORKS 247 combining people and devices and other living things in intricate and fallible ways in the performance of social practices. They are situated, inhabiting numerous nodes and sites in particular places and involving their own particular frictions (cultural and environmental) to network activity. And, finally, they are partial even as they are global, embracing surfaces without covering them, however long their reach. Our approach shifts concern from a predictable unfolding of social structures in space to the means whereby networks of actors construct space by using certain forms of ordering which mobilize particular rationalities, technological and repre- sentational devices, living beings (including people), and physical properties. More than this, unlike the filled-in surfaces of globalization, this approach opens up space- time to the coexistence of multiple cross-cutting networks of varied length and dura- bility, for example in the many coincidences between the institutional spaces and geographical places inhabited by commercial and fair trade coffee networks. TNCs emerge as no longer unique in their substantive capacity for global reach. By explor- ing the role of the unspoken presences (or immutable mobiles) which hold such con- nections in place we can begin to talk about “alternative geographies” of food in the same register, not as some pale specter in the colossal landscape of “capital.” It is the political competence and social agency expressed through the mode of order- ing of connectivity in the fair trade network – including Cafédirect, the exporting cooperative CECOOAC-Nor, and the 3,000 small coffee farmers – which effects the difference.

Part IV Social Worlds

Editors’ Introduction: Bringing in the Social

Jamie Peck, Trevor J. Barnes, Eric Sheppard, and Adam Tickell

One way of looking at the following set of readings is that they each deal with the social context in which the economy operates, since they explore issues like the role of the state, the place of gender relations, and the territorial organization of both capital and labor. They move far beyond the narrowly framed view of the market which characterized the economic geographies of the 1960s and 1970s – as a zone of market forces, supply and demand curves, rational responses to price signals – to delve deeply into the economy’s social fabric, its institutional texture, and its political constitution. The authors, in their different ways, all reject the notion that “the economic” or “markets” represent a separate and pristine realm of existence in which utilitarian and maximizing actions prevail – the world, if you like, of con- ventional (neoclassical) textbook economics. But this is merely a point of departure for the following readings, which like so much of contemporary economic geogra- phy take it as axiomatic that the notion of a self-regulating market is an abstrac- tion that tells us little or nothing about the operation of actually existing markets. It follows that any adequate understanding of “real world” markets calls for a con- sideration of the social relations and patterns of behavior that help to make and shape those markets, since economic relations are also social relations, and eco- nomic structures and processes are inescapably embedded in social and institutional practices and norms. So, prevailing gender orders and patterns of state regulation, for example, do not merely “distort” otherwise perfectly functioning markets, but are themselves fundamental to the way that markets are constituted and the way that they work. It follows that economic geographies reflect more than the working out of overarching, competitive logics – say, the search for least-cost locations – but in fact are the complex outcomes of a host of intersecting social, political, and insti- tutional processes. As Oscar Wilde might have said, the market is rarely pure, and it is never simple. What the following readings do is to point to some of the ways in which eco- nomic geographies are socially and politically constituted. They each draw atten- tion to the various active, enduring, and spatially differentiated forms through which social and political relations shape economic processes, structures, and practices. In 252 JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, AND ADAM TICKELL the essays that follow, each author pursues a different strategy in excavating and illustrating the role of “the social” in the formation of economic geographies. It is notable that the chapters draw only sparingly on mainstream economic theories of any stripe, drawing inspiration instead from a range of other social theories devel- oped by sociologists, anthropologists, state theorists, and management scientists. The influence of Karl Polanyi’s (1944) The Great Transformation is evident in some of the chapters, while others draw widely on economic sociology, urban social theory, management and organization studies, feminist theory, and political economy. For example, O’Neill’s contribution on the role of the state in economic geography engages with the work of political sociologists Claus Offe, Bob Jessop, and Fred Block, while the starting point for Hudson and Sadler is a critical inter- rogation of Anthony Giddens’ theories of social action. If the economic geography of the 1970s was rather narrowly concerned with the dynamics of manufacturing activity and related questions of regional development, over the course of the past two decades economic geography’s field of vision became increasingly global, in every sense of the word. So, research in contemporary eco- nomic geography encompasses issues as diverse as service work, consumption, sus- tainable ecological development, state restructuring, discourses of business, social reproduction, welfare reform, and so on. In the process, prevailing conceptions of the economic have also become substantially enlarged and enriched. Whereas the focus of economic geography was once the search for systematic patterns of “loca- tion in space” (Lloyd and Dicken, 1977), now the (conceptually determined) bound- aries of the economy have been loosened and the very conception of the space economy has been transformed. The restrictive focus on the market and on manu- facturing has been progressively displaced by more complex, integrative, and all- encompassing conceptions of socially embedded, socially regulated, and socially constituted economies (see Lee and Wills, 1997). Increasingly, the task of contem- porary economic geography is meaningfully to connect and integrate the economic and the “non-economic”, in pursuit of richer and more grounded forms of expla- nation. For example, this might involve locating the strategies of firms within the context of a supportive milieu of trust relations and institutionalized behavior pat- terns; it could entail uncovering the gendered nature of local employment practices, or it might mean tracing the dynamic effects of changes in financial, environmen- tal, and labor regulations. As all the readings that follow point out, but as Fincher, McDowell, and O’Neill argue quite explicitly, this is not simply a matter of “adding on” social, political, or institutional concerns to economic geography’s preexisting research agenda. Instead, it implies a radical rethinking of this research agenda. In O’Neill’s approach, for example, it involves beginning with the understanding that the state and the market are inescapably and necessarily enmeshed, albeit with enormously variable outcomes. “Markets” are not historically and logically prior to the moment of state “intervention,” but the relation is one of continual mutual engagement and co- production. The complex and continuous roles performed by the state in making and managing markets – for example, in protecting private property rights, regu- lating working conditions, or discouraging the formation of monopolies – are crucial both for the operation of markets and the strategies of the state. In practice, the policymaking process cannot be reduced to a “firefighting” role, in which the state INTRODUCTION TO PART IV 253 acts as a distant “overseer,” occasionally moving to attend to market “failures.” Instead, state and market are tangled together; their boundaries are not fixed, but porous and mobile. Markets are not self-constituting and self-regulating phenom- ena, but in an important sense are socially and politically constructed. Orthodox thinking about market forces and economic processes – particularly in this supposed “era of globalization” – is quite different to the social worldview found in the subsequent essays. The contributions from both Storper and O’Neill make the point that “globalization talk” tends to perpetuate the myth that economic forces, like the weather, are naturally occurring and effectively uncontrollable. In conventional presentations of this argument (for example, Ohmae, 1990), these forces of apparently infinite market extension are also extra-terrestrial in the sense that they are reckoned to overrule and override all other “earthly” forces, such as those associated with government action or local political movements. Behind this caricature, which incidentally serves neo-liberal political interests particularly well, is an infinitely more complex and institutionally cluttered reality. Storper seeks to move beyond the misleading orthodox image of globalization, to parse out con- ceptually those kinds of economic activities that are “territorialized,” in the sense that they depend on resources or relations that are geographically proximate and/or place specific, and those that are not. In carefully probing this flipside of the glo- balization process, Storper is able to document some of the typical corporate strate- gies and policy positions associated with different forms of territorialization and deterritorialization. One of his underlying points is that the resultant picture is much more variegated and nuanced than the straightforward stories of globalization- as-homogenous-marketization would suggest. Globalization processes are not as totalizing as many commentaries in the business literature would have us believe, and they do not produce unitary responses such as cutting costs and overheads, getting lean and mobile, and ever staying on the lookout for cheaper locations (see also Dicken, Part II). Moreover, the heterogeneous organizational terrain described by Storper calls attention to a wide variety of policy options beyond the one-size-fits-all neo-liberal prescription of deregulation, tax-cutting, cost-stripping, and privatization. While some local policymakers may have little room for maneuver in the face of genuine threats of relocation from “footloose” local businesses, others confront situations in which key sectors of the local economy are more or less territorialized, that is, embedded in local networks, relations, and resource linkages. Here, the local policy options and challenges are quite different to those facing classically “globalized” localities, which are pitched into a daily battle to win, or retain, local jobs and busi- nesses. The reality of globalization processes is consequently very different from the politically loaded vision of flat-earth market rule. The way in which the economy is conceived consequently shapes the way in which it is politicized, and the way in which policy “problems” are defined and addressed. In fact, as Hudson and Sadler demonstrate, there are places and moments in which such circumstances of economic vulnerability can create basing points for new forms of political mobilization. Their contribution shows how, in many single-industry communities, threats of plant closure and large-scale job losses were associated with distinctively localized reconfigurations of class politics. Political identities, in this sense, are not “fixed” according to the positions of 254 JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, AND ADAM TICKELL workers in the production process, but can be remade and re-imagined at the local level, often with far-reaching consequences for the conduct of local politics and the formation of (re)development strategies. And it follows that local economic fortunes are not predetermined by factor endowments or levels of productive efficiency, but are also a function of politics and institutional relations. Again, the emphasis in Hudson and Sadler’s contribution is on the socially creative strategies by which com- munities respond to changing economic circumstances, even in situations where alternative job opportunities may be in limited supply. Through this discussion they also reveal some of the ways in which place complicates class analysis. Indeed, the contributions here from the 1980s – Hudson and Sadler’s paper on responses to plant closures and Fincher’s paper on local gender relations – both take as their point of departure the limitations of conventional forms of class analysis. It is important to recall that one of the first means by which the social was brought into economic geography, back in the late 1970s and early 1980s, was in the form of a wave of industrial restructuring studies (see Lovering, 1989; Sayer, Part I), a defining feature of which was the key explanatory role attached to workplace social relations. In these studies, capital–labor (or class) relations at the point of produc- tion – focused on issues like technical change, job redesign, and industrial relations – provided the privileged point of entry for understanding distinctively capitalist forms of industrial restructuring (see Bluestone and Harrison, 1982; Massey and Meegan, 1982). The locational dynamics of industries, it was argued, could not be reduced to an endless search for least-cost production sites, but were also related to the ongoing imperative to control labor, for example, by evading heavily union- ized regions and/or seeking out “greener” or more pliable local labor supplies. By the mid-1980s, those working within this broad framework were beginning to develop less class-centric accounts of economic change, a moment captured in Hudson and Sadler’s contribution (see also Massey and Allen, 1984; Gregory and Urry, 1985). Yet the highly influential collection in which Hudson and Sadler’s chapter was published, Scott and Storper’s (1986b) Production, Work, Territory, remained unmistakably production-centric, it being the editors’ contention that “the most viable point of departure for an analysis of territorial development in modern capitalism is an investigation of the production system as an articulation of techni- cal, social and political relationships” (Scott and Storper, 1986a, p. 301). While as points of departure, critical studies of production relations continue to provide compelling bases for theories of territorial development – as Storper’s con- tribution to this volume, for example, shows – there is no longer such a broad con- sensus on where the “explanatory center” lies in economic geography. Indeed, in a companion volume to Production, Work, Territory, Dear and Wolch (1989, p. 4, original emphasis) would subsequently argue that there was equal analytical valid- ity in focusing on the linkages between “reproduction and territory [encompassing] the wide range of social relations and social practices which derive from, and which serve to protect and maintain, the basic structures of capitalist society.” Their col- lection, which included the contribution by Fincher reprinted here, would explore issues like the production of collective and public services, the gendered nature of labor-market restructuring, the reorganization of welfare systems, the changing form of the voluntary sector, the regulatory activities of the state, and so on. In delving deep into community politics, the state, and the sphere of social reproduction, the INTRODUCTION TO PART IV 255

Wolch and Dear collection purposefully stretched prevailing conceptions of “the economic,” and in so doing clearly breached the established boundaries of economic geography. Their purpose was not to develop a functionalist rationalization of these apparently extra-economic phenomena – accounting for their existence and their form solely in terms of the narrow requirements of capitalist (re)production – but instead to develop a broader explanation, in which the “formation of territorial out- comes is contingent upon the essentially unpredictable interactions of the spatial with the economic and the political and social/cultural spheres” (Dear and Wolch, 1989, p. 4, original emphasis). The reading from Fincher reflects these broad objectives, since it sets out to explore some of the ways in which the organization of “social reproduction serv- ices,” like childcare and elderly care, impact on patterns of participation in, and attachments to, the wage labor market. Focusing on the nexus of the local state and the local labor market, her analysis suggests that the geographically uneven nature of service delivery impacts the spatial constitution of job markets. Moreover, the types of jobs that are created in a local economy – what economists understand as “labor demand” – are not just a function of the technical requirements of produc- tion, but also reflect prevailing conceptions of “appropriate” work for different groups of men and women. Just as McDowell emphasizes in her reading too, jobs slots are not “out there,” waiting to be filled by whomever is available, but the design and functioning of employment systems is instead profoundly gendered (see also Wright, Part II). Again, social relations – on this occasion, gender relations – represent more than a colorful backdrop against which market processes – in this case, labor market processes – operate. Rather, these market processes are them- selves understood to be socially structured and socially constituted. So the economy is not a separate sphere with its own logic and dynamics, but its logic and dynam- ics are inescapably shaped by the social, political, and institutional relations in which all markets are embedded. And the variable nature of this embedding process is one of the principal causative factors behind the uneven spatial development of the economy, local differences in the ways in which markets operate having been related to phenomena like the structure of the local state, in Fincher’s account, or the institutionalized pattern of “untraded” interdependencies between firms, as Storper emphasizes in his contribution. Incorporating a deep understanding of the social constitution of economic prac- tices does not simply mean displacing analyses of the “hard economic fundamen- tals” with a new emphasis on the “fuzzy social context”; it means overcoming this binary distinction altogether. This is one of the reasons why so many contemporary economic geographers draw on economic sociology and institutionalist traditions that emphasize the essential unity of socioeconomic processes. “Bringing in the social” is consequently not a one-time event relating to an enlargement of the ana- lytical boundaries and empirical horizons of economic geography, but entails a con- tinuous, recursive process of relating the economic to the extra-economic. The point is not to develop a less materialist and less economistic economic geography for its own sake, but to put this socioeconomic sensibility, and the enlarged field of vision with which it is associated, to work in explanations of the complexity, diversity, and geographical unevenness of economic phenomena. So McDowell observes, for example, that the initial concern in her research on the merchant banking industry 256 JAMIE PECK, TREVOR J. BARNES, ERIC SHEPPARD, AND ADAM TICKELL was with the everyday practices that constitute gender relations in and around the workplace, not with what some might consider the “harder” economic phenome- non of interest rate-setting or regulatory reform. But she would discover in the course of the project that the gendered employment relations that were the princi- pal focus of her study were in fact decisively implicated in the very structure and practices of this industry. The ways in which business is practiced in merchant banking reflects, remakes, and reproduces gender relations. In reading the following contributions, therefore, a number of questions can use- fully be borne in mind. What are the authors’ points of entry into the discussion of the social and the economic – for example, the firm, the global economy, local gov- ernment, the industry, political events or movements? In what senses does each of the chapters extend the reach of economic geography beyond a narrow concern with market relations? Which institutions, social relations, and political actions are iden- tified as relevant to the formation of economic geographies, and with what kinds of economic effects are they associated? Are these relationships quantifiable, for example, and is it appropriate to talk about “degrees” of state involvement in the economy, or “more” or “less” gendered employment systems? In what sense do the different contributions identify a role for explicit social agency – thoughtful and meaningful interventions from social actors like policymakers, corporations, indi- vidual workers, or union leaders? Chapter 16 Bringing the Qualitative State back into Economic Geography

Phillip M. O’Neill

Introduction It is commonly argued that there has been substantial erosion of state power during the past two decades. This is seen to have occurred as a direct result of changes in the nature of capitalist accumulation which, in turn, are perceived to be driven by enhanced and extended circuits of capital. This chapter will advance three argu- ments to illustrate how this view of the state is inadequate. First, it is shown that the conception of the state as a totalized entity with centralized structures and purposes is erroneous. It is a conception that fits neatly with periodized views of capitalism (monopoly capitalism, Fordism, post-Fordism, and so on) but which provides little assistance in the analysis of contemporary economic change, at any scale. It is argued in this chapter that a more powerful understanding of contem- porary economic change can be derived from depicting the state as a domain where a complex and heterogeneous state apparatus is engaged in constant interplay with non-state institutions and agents, including those from other nations, in an irre- solvable contest over accumulation and distributional goals. Second, the chapter challenges the politically charged discourse that markets are capable of a separate, private existence beyond the actions of the state’s apparatus. Rather, a qualitative view of the state is preferred. In this view, the state is seen to play an indispensable role in the creation, governance, and conduct of markets, including at the international scale. Consequently, arguments about the extent of state intervention are seen as being feeble. Because the state is always involved in the operation of markets, the salient debate should be about the nature, purpose, and consequences of the form of state action, rather than about questions of mag- nitude of intervention. Third, the chapter shows the depowering outcomes of arguments that the macro- economic powers of the state are being eroded. At the heart of the neo-liberalist project, for example, is a discourse that promotes a form of capitalism, laissez-faire, which thrives under conditions where economic transactions are conducted outside the realm of state action. In this view, it is the very absence of state action that 258 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL produces the best conditions for the efficient allocation of productive resources and the most desirable distributional outcomes. Similarly, accounts of contemporary economic change such as globalism and certain variations of regulation theory argue that there is a relentless hollowing of nation-state structures and powers. In short, capitalists are seen as being able to accumulate how and where they wish and, there- after, states intervene to alter distributional outcomes. With the alleged collapse of nationally organized regimes of accumulation, however, opportunities for state-led redistributions are thought to be fading as state effort is redirected into shoring up the conditions for successful accumulation by national capitals in the face of growing international competition. In this contest, extant distributional positions are seen as being bargained away in competition for increasingly mobile investment projects. A qualitative construction of the state can avoid this immobilizing view of distributional possibilities. Since capitalism is incapable of operation outside the realm of the state, and since each and every step in the accumulation process involves distributions, then the state is ever involved in the distributional processes of capitalism. These arguments are developed through the four sections of this chapter. The first section reviews the way that the state is perceived in economic geography, referring to three theoretical contexts in which formulations of the state are advanced. These contexts are neo-liberalism, globalization, and regulation theory. The second section of the chapter demonstrates that by decentering the way in which we portray the state and by concentrating on the interactions between the state’s apparatus and capitalist processes, the distinction between state and market is broken down and issues of accumulation and distribution become inseparable. The third section of the chapter applies these arguments in an examination of the role of the state at new scales, in the context of rapid growth in international economic transactions. The final section examines distributional implications and new opportunities for intervention to achieve more desirable distributional outcomes.

State–Economy Relations One of the major difficulties in undertaking an analysis of the role of the state in the construction of economic geographies is finding common answers to the ques- tion, What is the state doing? On the one hand, many economic geographers argue that, as a result of liberalized international financial flows over the past two decades, a global economic sphere has emerged which is beyond nation-state control (see Martin and Sunley, 1997). On the other, a small number of empirical analyses show how the nation-state plays a major role in both managing and promoting interna- tional financial flows (e.g., Leyshon, 1994; Martin, 1994; Hutton, 1995; O’Neill, 1997). It seems, then, that the major problem with attempts to generalize about the changing role of the modern state on the basis of empirical study is that there is almost always a case study of national economic change available somewhere in the world to match a writer’s particular view of the state. Compare, for instance, the Hudson and Williams’ (1995) view of an increasingly restricted British state to the active and purposeful state roles depicted by Webber (1994) in the Northeast Asian economies or Enderwick (1997) for the New Zealand state, irrespective of political hue. BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 259

Neo-liberalism Neo-liberalists argue that freely operating private markets are the most capable instrument for maximizing output (technical efficiency), welfare (allocative effi- ciency), and ease of adjustment (dynamic efficiency). Neo-liberalists see the state as an outsider to the processes of real production and believe that it should constrain private activity to promote public interest only in situations of market failure – where desired goods and services are not supplied at acceptable prices. Yet, even in these circumstances, neo-liberalists point to a dilemma in placing the responsibility for corrective action in the hands of the state apparatus. They argue that the moti- vation of public regulators is not to maximize public interest but rather they will seek out exclusive benefits (or rents) for themselves and the groups which have secured their patronage. This view is encapsulated in public choice theory (Stigler, 1971) and represents the attempt by neo-liberalists to impugn the principle of public service and the existence of public goods. Neo-liberalist discourse frustrates the development of state distributive actions by arguing, first, that state intervention is best minimized and, second, that it will be corrupted in any event. It is axiomatic, according to neo-liberalism, that the absence of state interven- tion is the market, that market failures are never failures of the market per se, and, therefore, they can only ever be failures of the state (drawing on Hayek, 1948). The political consequence of this view is the drive to deregulate, since modern states are thought to be incapable of managing either the social or the private economies – only through deregulation and privatization can the preconditions of economic growth be reestablished (Francis, 1993). This apparent displace- ment of a state’s distributional functions has meant that not only does the dis- course of neo-liberalism drive the accumulation strategies of many nations but, ipso facto, it has become the dominant distributional tool. The important point to be made here is that the neo-liberalist vision of “less state” is entirely illusory. Neo-liberalism is a self-contradicting theory of the state. The geographies of product, finance, and labor markets that it seeks to construct require qualitatively different, not less, state action. Neo-liberalism is a political discourse which impels rather than reduces state action (Hirsch, 1991; Bonnett et al., 1990; Tickell and Peck, 1995).

Globalism Internationalization and more recently its descendant, globalism, have been por- trayed by economic geographers, and others, as all-powerful tendencies of capital- ism which have had major impacts on the role of the state. During the 1970s and 1980s, international capital was commonly seen as controlled by stateless multina- tional corporations which aimed to penetrate the capital and consumer markets of every country and every region. Analysis drew heavily on the theory of the inter- national division of labor (Fröbel et al., 1980), and privilege was accorded to those events seen to operate at the global scale (e.g., Thrift, 1986; Dicken, 1992a; Chase- Dunn, 1989). In an extreme version of this tale, Ross and Trachte (1990) advise that global capitalism dominates all economic spheres, leading to the crippling of nation-states, whose meager resources shift from the pursuit of legitimation goals 260 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL

(especially social welfare) to the accumulation goals of once-national capitals in their global ventures. Common to the inexorable-rise-of-global-capitalism accounts of contemporary crisis is the portrayal of the state in classical Marxist form: an organizational unit which serves the dominant classes which, in the contemporary scene, are the con- trollers of global fractions of capital. Two rebuttals of this position can be made. The first acknowledges that states, acting through autonomous state agents and apparatus, maintain sufficient economic authority and purpose to produce “dis- continuous” economic and political spaces (Dicken, 1992a, 1994). The state remains capable of producing “location-specific” supply and demand conditions within nations – and these conditions are more than the passive response to glob- ally mobile fractions of capital; they are conditions which drive foreign investment itself. Certainly, there is ample evidence that Keynesian macroeconomic manage- ment powers are eroded by globalization processes, but one cannot conclude that a powerless nation-state has been left as residue. Inevitably, states are developing new capacities and structures to exert new forms of political and economic power, even across the territories of different states (Dicken et al., 1997). The second rebuttal of the inexorable-rise-of-global-capitalism-and-decline-of- the-nation-state story is based on distinguishing between globalization as discourse and evidence (or lack of evidence) for the existence of globalization as a general trend (Cox, 1992; Dicken et al., 1997). There is growing understanding that the rise of the vocabularies of globalism has been based on their use for coercive pur- poses in framing national economic strategies, in reformulating workplace practices, and in garnering community support for national and local economic reforms. These vocabularies necessarily portray the state as a depowered entity – for obvious reasons. Yet there is a difference between a loss of state role contained in the glob- alism story and a shift in state role which a qualitative view of the state would assert. However, if indeed the shift in state role is qualitative, then what is chang- ing? What new state capacities and structures have emerged? And what guides their formulation and reformulation? The following section demonstrates the inadequacy of one version of regulation theory in answering these questions.

Regulation theory and the hollowed-out state One of the major impacts of recent regulation theory on thinking about the state has been the idealization of the postwar Keynesian welfare state and its positioning as a historical yardstick against which subsequent state roles are measured. In par- ticular, regulation theory assigns a nanny role to the postwar state: alleviating crisis in the Fordist economy and nurturing capitalism’s drop-outs. Peck and Tickell (1994), for example, argue that the decline of the Keynesian state is a fundamental cause of contemporary economic crisis, a crisis which persists because a stable replacement regulatory order has yet to emerge. In this context, the nation-state is simultaneously coerced by international economic forces and driven by the accu- mulation needs of its domestic economy (Tickell and Peck, 1995). Similarly, Jessop (1994) argues that the “hollowing-out” of the nation-state is a feature of the con- temporary period. Jessop maintains that, at the same time that nation-states have abandoned demand management in favor of supply-side initiatives, supranational BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 261 state apparatuses have emerged as the new regulators. Activities at the nation-state level are seen to be driven by global economic trends (Jessop, 1994). These include the development of new legal forms to support cross-national cooperation and strategic alliances, the reform of currency and credit systems, rules for technology transfer, trade governance, intellectual property negotiations, and the regulation of international labor migration. At the same time, according to Jessop, investment policies have been devolved to the local state, resulting in new cross-national group- ings of regions. A residual nation-state thereby is left to engage in the development of work practices and other measures to promote international competitiveness, a situation which Jessop labels as the Schumpeterian workfare state. Jessop’s hollowed-out metaphor, then, is an account of shift in rather than diminution of state role with complex new relationships emerging between state apparatuses at different scales. Yet, irrespective of the original conception, it has become commonplace for the hollowed-out metaphor to be used in the literature to represent a universal condition of state depowerment. The metaphor has come to represent an extreme paralysis of the nation-state, different from the shift process described by Jessop. Putting aside these misinterpretations of regulation theory, to what extent does regulation theory provide an enduring explanation of state process and behavior? Regulationists Tickell and Peck (1995) are ambivalent. Certainly, they use regula- tion theory effectively to explain the role of the state in the construction of social regulation as a stable form of governance during the Fordist period. Yet they acknowledge that regulation theory offers little explanation for the key processes of transition (Tickell and Peck, 1995), which, surely, have been the key concern of nation-states for at least the past two decades! Regulation theory has insufficient to say about the crucial role of the state in moving societies from one period of stable economic conditions to the next, beyond describing them as intervals of crisis. Much of this inadequacy stems from regulation theory’s attempt to totalize the economy in its form, its history, and its methods of governance. Further, accumu- lation crisis is portrayed by regulation theory as a singular, totalized event. There is no possibility in regulation theory for a multitude of unrelated economic events, in different cycles of growth and prosperity, under different forms of governance. There is no allowance for incremental, strategic, state-driven economic restructur- ing and transition such as has been the hallmark of East Asian economic change since the 1960s; and there is an underlying denial that conflict and tension in the operations of state apparatuses may be normal events. Further, as a result of presenting an idealized (and nostalgic) view of the social and economic outcomes of Keynesian–Fordist state management, regulation theo- rists have a tendency to conflate successful accumulation with successful distribu- tional outcomes. The theory assumes that the successful management of national accumulation processes is the most important coercive tool in securing state legiti- macy. This view is almost the opposite of the view of many state theorists, such as Claus Offe (see Offe, 1984), and is denied by considerable empirical evidence. Bakshi et al. (1995), for example, point to the racialized and gendered history of the British state in the context of successful national accumulation during the Keynesian–Fordist years. Social compliance was never earned through long periods 262 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL of economic growth, and fair and reasonable distributions of national income were not automatic for each social group. It is argued, then, that there is an absence of a theory of the state in regulation theory stemming, first, from the way regulation theory idealizes the form and func- tions of the contemporary state and, second, from a heavy reliance on observations of the UK experience – an experience which Hutton (1995) admits is unusual. Regu- lation theory fails to acknowledge that national economic strategies must be con- tinuously managed and renegotiated since, per se, they are continuously involved with both accumulation and distribution questions. Better abstractions of state process are needed. These need to draw on a multitude of state experiences and situate the realm of the state within accumulation processes. Further, there needs to be greater understanding of the ongoing nature of distributional processes, thereby avoiding the crippling placement of the state in a position where its capacities are limited to ex post income transfers through welfare assistance. In summary, what is needed is a theory of the state which says something about (a) the way the state functions; (b) how it stabilizes and transforms regimes of accumulation; (c) how it operates through geographic scales – not simply how it is constrained by scale; and (d) how it is, and should be, involved with redistribution.

The Qualitative State This chapter advances the paradigm of the qualitative state as a way towards a theoretical position which rejects the possibility of a privately constructed realm of freely operating markets and which asserts the indispensable role of the state in pro- viding the means (inter alia) for privately performed production and consumption. Block (1994) notes that a qualitative view of the state rejects the assessment or measurement of state role by degree of intervention. Wherever, and whenever, commercial transactions occur, the state plays a key role. The new state paradigm begins by rejecting the idea of state intervention in the economy. It insists instead that state action always plays a major role in constituting economies, so that it is not useful to posit states as lying outside of economic activity. (Block, 1994, p. 696; emphasis in original) Qualitative conceptions of the state draw strongly from the historical works of Karl Polanyi (1944). Polanyi demonstrated how, on the one hand, the rise of indus- trial capitalism could never have been a purely private process and, on the other, that economic institutions are inevitably political creations. He exposed the myth of spontaneous emergence of free-market relationships in post-feudal society. Instead, the emerging modern state is shown to have established crucial conditions for the operation of capitalist relations including exclusive property rights, a legal system based on the inviolability of contracts, the establishment of large national markets (through administrative structures, monetary systems, and common stan- dards such as in food purity, weights and measures), and the means for the pene- tration of other national markets, especially through imperialism (Block, 1990; Cerny, 1990). The chief message that state theorists have drawn from Polanyi is that markets simply cannot operate in a laissez-faire environment. Block (1994) presents a detailed summary of views of the state which have led to the emergence of the qualitative state paradigm. This is based on four major BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 263 tenets. First, economy is necessarily a combination of three events: markets, state action, and state regulation. A corollary of this constitution is that there is an infi- nite number of ways in which an economy can be organized. Second, although eco- nomic efficiency is dependent on markets, markets are state-constrained and state-regulated and thereby incapable of operating in a laissez-faire environment. Third, neither capital nor the state is capable of achieving its goals simultaneously nor independently. Finally, it should be recognized that any coherence that exists about the idea of economy derives essentially from our cultural beliefs, which (in Anglo cultures at least) have led to constructions of economy being overlain with the dichotomy of planned versus market, which, in turn, has had the effect of denying the existence of multiple forms of economy. This is an extension of the Marxist recognition of the power of economic ideologies to make particular eco- nomic arrangements appear as natural and inevitable. These tenets stand opposed to the basic assumptions of what Block (1994) terms the “old state paradigm.” Various forms of the old paradigm construct the state as occupying a position (a priori) external to the main economy. The idealized (or nor- mative) public goods state, for example, describes the state as having the duty to provide the goods and services, such as blood or policing, which private markets are incapable of supplying efficiently and universally. The macroeconomic stabiliz- ing form of the state intervenes to adjust market aggregates, especially consumer demand, in order to move equilibrium (or market-clearing) positions of private markets closer to full employment. Certainly, markets remain the best available device for aggregating individuals’ commercial preferences. At the same time, state involvement is inevitable so that markets can be formed and operate efficiently. A common set of roles can be drawn up for all states in all economies. These include the maintenance of a regime of property rights; the management of territorial boundaries; the establishment and administration of legal frameworks to ensure economic cooperation; the provision of basic infrastructure; the creation and governance of financial markets and product markets; ensuring of the production and reproduction of labor; controlling macro- economic trends; and the conduct of legitimation activities to secure the economic system through time. Table 16.1 details the role of the qualitative state in the con- struction and maintenance of modern economies and demonstrates the vast and complex operations common to all Western states. The analysis so far has been concerned with what the qualitative state does. Con- sideration must also be given to the structures and mechanisms of the qualitative state which enable the performance of the roles identified. Offe’s (1975, 1976, 1984) work provides valuable insights into the processes by which the state engages with capitalism. There are two major thrusts in Offe’s work. The first is his search for a useful theoretical analysis of economic crisis which incorporates the general ques- tions of state authority and legitimacy as well as the functional problem of how states actually achieve their fiscal and welfare goals. The second is Offe’s concern with the question of whether the state is capable of producing the means of over- coming the contradictions of capitalist production. For Offe, state involvement is more than the actions of public institutions on various societal groupings. Rather, the state participates directly in the domains of other institutions and associations such as political parties, trade unions, and corporations, and in the processes by 264 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL

Table 16.1: Roles of the qualitative state in a modern economy

A Maintenance of a regime of property rights i. maintenance of private property rights ii. recognition of institutional property rights iii. basic rules for the ownership and use of productive assets iv. basic rules for the exploitation of natural resources v. rules for the transfer of property rights (between individuals, households, institutions, and generations) B Management of territorial boundaries i. provision of military force ii. economic protection through manipulation of: • money flows • goods flows • services flows • labor flow • flows of intangibles iii. quarantine protection C Legal frameworks to maximize economic cooperation i. establishment of partnerships and corporations ii. protection of intellectual property rights iii. the governance of recurring economic relations between • family members • employers and workers • landlords and tenants • buyers and sellers D Projects to ensure social cooperation i. maintenance of law and order ii. undertake national image-making processes iii. other coercive strategies E Provision of basic infrastructure i. Provision or organization of: • transportation and communications systems • energy and water supply • waste disposal systems ii. assembly and conduct of communications media iii. assembly and dissemination of public information iv. land use planning and regulation

which social and economic interests are represented to government. Not surpris- ingly, therefore, social turbulence and political resistance – threats to both capital accumulation and state legitimacy – are seen to be continuously internalized within the state apparatus as it seeks to manage and distribute resources in ways that con- tribute not just to the achievement of economic growth but also to prevailing notions of justice. Offe’s point is that the state is neither an arbiter nor a regulator nor an uncritical supporter of capitalism, but is “enmeshed” in its contradictions. Capital- ism is anarchic, requiring the state to sustain the processes of accumulation and protect the private appropriation of resources. The social processes necessary for the reproduction of labor, private ownership and commodity exchange, then, are regulated and sustained by permanent political intervention. The state is therefore constituted by continuous administrative, legal, bureaucratic, and coercive systems BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 265

Table 16.1: continued

F Creation and governance of financial markets i. rules for the establishment and operation of financial institutions ii. designation of the means of economic payment iii. rules for the use of credit iv. maintenance of the lender of last resort G Creation and governance of product markets i. regulation of the market power of firms ii. the selection and regulation of natural monopolies iii. the promotion and maintenance of strategic industries iv. the provision of public goods v. the provision of goods unlikely to be supplied fairly H Production and reproduction of labor i. demographic planning and governance ii. provision of universal education and training iii. governance of workplace conditions iv. governance of returns for work v. social wage provision vi. supply and governance of childcare vii. provision or governance of retirement incomes I Control of macroeconomic trends i. fiscal policy ii. monetary policy iii. external viability J Other legitimation activities i. elimination of poverty ii. maintenance of public health iii. citizenship rights iv. income and wealth redistribution v. urban and regional development vi. cultural development vii. socialization viii. enhancement of the environment that not only build relationships between the state and other groups in society, but also heavily influence relationships within and between these groups. Further, it should not be surprising that different states have different levels of power. The point is that these differences are produced less by extant economic conditions and more by the capacities of states to create or strengthen their organizations, to employ enough appropriate personnel, to co-opt political support, especially through pro- grammes to assist economic enterprises, and to facilitate social programs (Skocpol, 1985). Further, these capacities are in no small part due to historical attitudes to governance and state role. That is, qualitative differences in states arise and are sus- tained by prevailing and historical structures and conditions influencing the state’s apparatus.

The National State and the Supranational Scale This section explores the impact on the state of the growing proportion of market transactions which are international. It is argued that international transactions 266 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL reinforce the structure and importance of the nation-state, rather than diminish them (see Cerny, 1990). The emergence of global marketplaces has transformed the states’ role, and there is ample evidence that global marketplaces themselves are transformed by the involvement of nation-states in the creation and operation of supranational governance regimes and structures. Examples include nation-state involvement in the prudential supervision of international financial transactions through the Bank of International Settlements, the supervision of quality and safety in traded products through the operations of the International Standards Organi- zation, and, of course, the governance of access to domestic product markets by the World Trade Organization. Thus the rise of a more prominent supranational tier of governance has required the increased involvement of nation-states, including, in many circumstances, new participation by apparatuses of the state at the level of local and regional governments, development agencies, sectoral-industrial and finan- cial instrumentalities, and so on. Paradoxically, then, pressures arising from an increasingly integrated world marketplace reinforce and reconstruct state role rather than usurp it. The nation-state has also played a key role in the trend towards international regionalism as an avenue for successful international accumulation. Hay (1995) notes that this trend has been accompanied by the emergence of supranational state structures such as the North American Free Trade Agreement, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, and the European Union. In contrast to the Jessop argument that the emergence of supranational state structures is part of the hollowing-out process of the nation-state, Hay argues that tendencies towards strengthening supranational power structures are constrained by “the fact that the inter-state bargaining required . . . is driven by the exigencies of maintaining national legitimacy bases” (Hay, 1995, p. 403; emphasis in original). In other words, national state agents pursue national rather than international interests in the global political arena. The irony, according to Hay, is that supranational bodies are inca- pable of intervening in the circulation of capital unless they are constituted by vibrant national state power. Moreover, global capital circulations require state structures in order for accumulation to proceed without persistent chaos. To assist their supranational operations, nation-states are devising methods which strongly contest both the depowering images of globalism and the growing con- testability of domestic markets. Commonly, the nation-state moves to strengthen what its populations see as “national.” It is involved increasingly in coercive strate- gies seeking societal approval of national economic change and to legitimize the adoption or reconstruction of a national accumulation strategy. These strategies build on preexisting national identities which are historical products of myriad state policies dealing with immigration, foreign investment, sport, the arts, school cur- riculum, telecommunications, and so on. And, not surprisingly, many strategies are erroneous, for they involve the performance of relatively new roles to address new problems in new operational domains. Further, new state actions are not neces- sarily designed to produce more acceptable distributional outcomes. The argument here is simply that increasingly open and integrated national markets do not so much threaten or undermine the operation and effectiveness of state apparatuses as require that they undergo qualitative change. Critically, this qualitative shift is not optional, for it is fundamental for the continuation of successful accumulation processes and, BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 267 in the absence of oppression, for the production of distributional outcomes that maintain legitimacy. Along the way, the process of adjustment produces problems which few state managers relish and which require much experimentation in ideas, management structures and cultures, and policies (Cerny, 1990). Some discernible adjustment trends in the current period include a preference for micro- rather than macro-interventions; a shift from the protection of selected industries in specific market segments to the construction of internationally competitive conditions across markets; the adoption of enterprise cultures which promote innovation and compe- tition, including in the public sector; and a shift in state expenditures towards the maximization of economic outcomes rather than the maximization of social welfare. Not surprisingly, there is considerable discontent among progressive groups in all nations with the distributional consequences of these trends. Two consequences of thinking about the supranational scale in these ways emerge. The first concerns the role of the nation-state in translating activities from the supranational domain to production and consumption activities which take place within national boundaries. Not only does the state create the basic com- petitive conditions essential for successful accumulation, including trade rules, property rights, and exchange rate stability, it also blends these conditions with emerging apparatuses from the supranational scale. Critically, though, the success- ful blending of domestic and supranational domains to produce stable national and international circuits of capital with desirable distributional outcomes depends fundamentally on nation-states combining to agree on common objectives and implement common regulations and standards (Hirst and Thompson, 1996). The second consequence is pointed to by Cerny (1990), who notes that national economic openness in trade, finance, information flows, and communications pro- duces an “overloaded state.” This overload consists of problems which arise from the international transmission of recession, the incorporation of both private and public economic goals into an international context, and from struggles to main- tain the political legitimacy necessary for national economic management when the traditional tools are found wanting. For example, a common constraint to the main- tenance of legitimacy is the persistence of chronic public funding deficits which absorb national savings and exacerbate current-account imbalances. Another con- straint is the incompatibility between centralized labor regulation and actions by firms to reduce real unit labor costs through labor shedding, new shift patterns, and outsourcing. A third constraint stems from demands for state assistance in main- taining or restructuring unprofitable economic sectors especially through direct subsidy and microeconomic reforms. Cerny concludes that alongside growing inter- nationalization, “the total amount of state intervention will tend to increase, for the state will be enmeshed in the promotion, support, and maintenance of an ever- widening range of social and economic activities” (Cerny, 1990, p. 230; emphasis added). However, Cerny (1990, p. 231) adds that “The domestic redistribution of wealth and power, which is at the heart of the social democratic welfare state, will become more difficult and complex to achieve.” Continued crisis in capitalism, then, maximizes, rather than reduces, the demands for state intervention. Predominantly, however, state intervention seems to favor the types of accumulation practices which involve distributions of incomes in favor of capital – an outcome at the heart of neo-liberalist discourse. The “overloaded state” 268 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL is faced with addressing distributional problems through targeted welfare assistance from a distressed public budget. In contrast, a reconstructed discourse which takes the view that the state and its apparatus are inherent to the processes of produc- tion and consumption, and not lying outside them as detached overseer, regulator, or undesirable intruder, offers opportunities for the identification and manipulation of distributional outcomes at the point of the accumulation process.

Propositions about Distribution Because capitalism is incapable of an existence outside the realm of state action and because capitalist processes involve distributive processes per se, then the state is always involved in redistribution activities. Hence, the argument that the interna- tionalization of the world economy is a natural tendency of modern capitalism resulting in depowerment of the nation-state is simply a restatement of a coercive discourse designed to defer or deny the benefits of restructuring to particular groups. This section of the chapter advances this argument through three propositions about the distributional opportunities of the paradigm of the qualitative state. The first proposition is that the state and its apparatus constitute an arena for the struggle over distribution (see Offe, 1976, 1984, 1985). Importantly, though, at the same time as being enmeshed in capitalist production and exchange, the state is driven by the need to preserve its own autonomy and power as the arbiter of class conflict and the sustainer of decommodified social production. Accordingly, it is not because of its being a servant of capitalism that makes the state interested in suc- cessful accumulation; successful accumulation is critical for the sustenance of the state’s own interests, not the least reason being the state’s reliance on economic growth for the provision of taxation revenues particularly for redistribution pur- poses (O’Connor, 1973). A struggle then ensues. The state seeks to fund fiscal actions promised to the electorate. Capital resists regulations which inhibit capaci- ties to secure advantage over competitors, to extract surplus value from labor and to minimize its distribution to consumers. Thus the state’s dilemma is the mainte- nance of the accumulation process (which ideally seeks minimal state intervention) while successfully pursuing legitimization goals (which ideally require maximum state intervention). In other words, the state has to engage simultaneously in com- modification and decommodification. It can be concluded from this reasoning that, while only the state has the power and apparatus to organize economic spheres of action, the state’s redistributive actions inside marketplaces are continuously opposed by agents of capital which claim that economic spheres should be held as “natural and inviolable” (Offe, 1976, p. 395). On the other hand, the state’s “natural” domain is seen as being within social systems such as education, health, and welfare which render the “ingredients of a ‘decent’ life” (Offe, 1975, p. 256). The agents of capital contend that the state’s functions should be funded by the state’s appropriation of revenue after the redis- tribution processes inherent to accumulation have occurred. Company taxation, for example, is levied on the basis of net income flows following a financial year of eco- nomic activity. Accordingly, when the state accepts a position of ex post distribu- tor, it will always suffer fiscal crisis during downturns in the economic cycle when BRINGING THE QUALITATIVE STATE BACK INTO ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY 269 there are increased distributional demands and falling revenues. Hence, the successful simultaneous performance of state functions is impossible for any length of time. A second proposition that must be inserted into thinking about the qualitative state and its inherent distributive functions is that the state plays a critical role as a coercive instrument during periods of economic restructuring. Globalization pres- ents an attractive image or story to conservative politicians especially in the parts that argue that local labor needs to acquiesce to the demands of international capital and world competitive pressures. This discourse displaces traditional national social democratic strategies and active macroeconomic policies. The point is that the con- struction of the idea of a market economy that is rational, self-constituting, self- regulating, and independent of the political sphere is a normative prescription. This, in turn, is consistent with the view that only a minimalist, non-interventionist, night-watchman state can accompany a maximum performance economy. Thus, the state is at the center of discourses of economic restructuring which, in turn, generate distributional outcomes. A third proposition picks up from Jessop (1994) and argues that since interna- tionalizing processes involve an expansion of nation-state organization, then inter- nationalization presents greater, not fewer, opportunities for state intervention into distributional outcomes. There is growing evidence that global circulations of capital, goods and services, ideas, and people require supranational state structures and apparatuses. In turn, these depend on the vibrancy of nation-states for legiti- macy and power. Only nation-states have territorial authority to deal with the social outcomes, including conflict, which inevitably follow internationalization processes. Obviously, the discourse of internationalization used by nation-states is critical here. Finally, local and regional authorities have little chance of pursuing their inter- national interests unless nation-states “suture” the supranational domain to the national territory. Greater realization of the role of the nation-state in internation- alization processes can lead to improved distributional outcomes in regions which have often suffered from the timid explanation that events causing local economic devastation arise from an uncontrollable global capitalism.

Conclusion Thinking about the qualitative state offers new opportunities for invigorated state action for more desirable distributional outcomes. It involves accepting the auto- nomy of the state; accepting the crucial role of the state in the governance of private markets; accepting that the state is not a homogeneous unit but exists as a contested domain continuously interacting with society; and accepting that internationaliza- tion is not a singular logic of capitalism as investment (allegedly) flees collapsing Keynesian–Fordist national economic spaces. Thinking about the qualitative state also involves rejecting the notion of a hollowed-out state in the sense that interna- tionalization has made the nation-state redundant as a macroeconomic manager; and rejecting the logic that redistribution is an act which follows accumulation processes, the extent of the former being dependent on the success of the latter. Finally, the idea of the qualitative state is not a question of bringing the state back 270 PHILLIP M. O’NEILL in. Close examination shows that the state never departed. The crucial question con- cerns the ways in which we have represented the state during the recent decades of economic crisis when commercial transactions have become increasingly interna- tionalized. New discourses about the qualitative state have the potential to enhance opportunities for intervention into economic processes and make them more successful – especially when judged by their distributive outcomes. Chapter 17 Territories, Flows, and Hierarchies in the Global Economy

Michael Storper

Globalization and the Institutions of Economic Development In recent years, the flows of goods, services, information, capital, and people across national and regional lines have increased greatly, giving rise to the notion that modern economic activity is somehow becoming “globalized.” Do these pheno- mena mean that contemporary economies are becoming placeless, mere flows of resources via corporate hierarchies, which are themselves not rooted in national or regional territories and therefore not subject to territorially based state institutions? Though many commentators assign territorially based institutions, especially nation-states, a continuing role in the global economy, the balance of power is thought to be tipping in favor of globalized organizations, networks, practices, and flows. Hence, the locus of control over important dimensions of the economic devel- opment process – both in the narrow sense of formal decision-making and resource deployment and in the larger sense of influences to which we must respond – is passing from territorialized institutions such as states to deterritorialized institutions such as intrafirm international corporate hierarchies or international markets that know no bounds (Gilpin, 1975; Ohmae, 1990; Reich, 1990). The perfection of hier- archies and markets, as management systems and transactional structures, is said to be gaining on territorial barriers, specificities, and frictions (Julius, 1990). There is another view, of course, and it comes from the rich literature on differ- ent ways that organizations and markets are shaped by political and business insti- tutions. The “Japanese model” and J-firm, the “German model,” and the like, are different ways that advanced capitalist activity can be organized (Albert, 1993). There is a competition between such territorially based institutionally organized pro- duction systems for world market share in many sectors. These two views correspond, in many ways, to the two main disciplinary discourses that deal with globalization – economics and political science. Much of the former implies that economic development is becoming deterritorialized, while there is a strong body of research in the latter that indicates continued territorial specificity in development patterns owing to the institutions alluded to previously. 272 MICHAEL STORPER

Political economists and political scientists have begun to consider the effects of global capitalism on the margin of maneuver left to nation-states (Carnoy, 1993), but curiously have devoted less attention to scrutinizing how globalized capitalism really is. As a result, the theoretical meaning and practical impact of economic glob- alization remain obscure. In this chapter I propose to sketch out what a confrontation between the terri- torialization of economic development and the emergence of global hierarchies and flows would look like. The reason for this confrontation is the hypothesis that the ability of territorially bounded states and other institutions to bargain with hierar- chical global business organizations, and to shape the development process in general, should rise with the territorialization of economic activity. Territorializa- tion thus becomes the analytical key to the debate about the politics and econom- ics of globalization.

Defining territorialization in economic terms Territorialized economic development may be defined as something quite different from mere location or localization of economic activity. It consists, for our pur- poses, in economic activity which is dependent on resources that are territorially specific. These “resources” can range from asset specificities available only from a certain place or, more importantly, assets that are available only in the context of certain interorganizational or firm–market relationships that necessarily involve geo- graphical proximity, or where relations of proximity are markedly more efficient than other ways of generating these as set specificities. Geographically proximate relations constitute valuable asset specificities if they are necessary to the genera- tion of spillover effects – positive externalities – in an economic activity system. So territorialization is often tied to specific interdependencies in economic life. Prox- imity would also be a basis of valuable specific assets insofar as these latter are nec- essary to the efficient functioning of the firm under normal circumstances, where the firm cannot replace them, either by internalizing functions or by carrying out its external relations in a way that does not involve proximity in them. The assets to which we refer can be hard – labor, technology – or soft – information, conven- tions of interaction, relation-specific skills. We shall develop this notion of rela- tionally specific assets further as we go along (Asanuma, 1989). An activity is fully territorialized when its economic viability is rooted in assets (including practices and relations) that are not available in many other places and that cannot easily or rapidly be created or imitated in places that lack them. Loca- tional substitutability is not possible, and feasible locations are small in number, making locational “markets” highly imperfect. This definition of territorialization thus does not cover all cases of agglomeration or localization or urbanization, but a distinctive subset of those cases.

Mainstream Arguments about Globalization and Their Silences As noted, huge research efforts have been devoted to the behavior of firms in a global economy; to consequences for markets, and to the ways that institutions TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 273 shape markets and firms. There are major lacunae in these efforts because they do not pose the question of territorialization clearly.

Who is us? Markets versus hierarchies In the United States, the early 1990s debate over the national economy in a global economy illustrates this conceptual lacuna well. On one side, it was argued that development-inducing investment will flow to those areas that possess appropriate factors of production, which, in the global economy, means high-quality labor (“symbolic analysts”), infrastructure, and so on (Reich, 1990). The argument, then, was implicitly about the importance and mobility of foreign direct investment, and that ownership of assets – the nationality of firms – is unimportant. The role of regions and nations is to develop appropriate factor supplies so as to attract this highly mobile investment. But the argument said nothing about whether those factors are territorialized or not, in the sense defined here. As such, it can be inter- preted either as an endorsement of globalization as placelessness or of globalization as the attraction of capital to territorialized economic formations. On the other side of the debate, it was claimed that ownership – the nationality of firms – is important (Tyson, 1991). It is necessary for political reasons to have firms that produce all technologies essential to national security, and even major multinational firms concentrate their core technology-producing activities in their home territories. Even without security concerns, the existence of technological spillovers means that for an economy to carry out certain innovation and develop- ment processes, it must possess a complement of other capacities. Both these claims are probably quite sound, in and of themselves; but they do not say much of any- thing about globalization. On one hand, the argument does not show why even major multinationals continue to concentrate their principal technology-based activ- ities at home and therefore why the factor/market-attraction argument is not valid (see also Amendola, Guerrieri, and Padoan, 1992; Carnoy, 1993; Patel and Pavitt, 1991). As a result, it could still be claimed that investment is becoming increasingly mobile and that the observed rootedness of major multinationals in their home economies is a transitory, not necessary, condition. On the other hand, while it cor- rectly suggests interdependence-through-spillover as key to many of the most impor- tant forms of innovation, it does not say why such spillovers should be localized within a national economy, except for security reasons. There is no economic rea- soning about the territorialization of such spillovers, in other words. So the debate over “who is us?” tells us little about who we really are in a global economy.

Commodity trade The growth of commodity trade figures prominently in claims that the economy is globalizing. Rising intra-industry trade is said to be evidence of globalization as firms create a global functional division of labor. One possibility is that intra-industry trade is accompanied by the advent of global oligopolistic supply structures for many commodities and for knowledge inputs (Ernst, 1990). The big firms who dominate these supply chains benefit from entry barriers due to scale and 274 MICHAEL STORPER the firm-specific assets they deploy on a global scale. This argument, however, says nothing about the problem of territorialization per se. Global supply structures, even highly oligopolistic ones, could reflect (1) an internalized supply structure of assets, in which case it could be considered deterritorialized (Dicken, 1992a); or (2) an attempt by firms to optimize access to factors of production in order to produce the inputs to their global supply structures (Reich, 1990), another form of deterritori- alization, in the sense that regions and nations must simply make themselves attrac- tive to mobile investments; or (3) also an attempt by firms to optimize access to territorialized factors of production (which meet the criteria of our definition). The point is that without a conceptual apparatus specific to the problem, the existing evidence can be made to reveal little about it. Note that the oft-cited rise in foreign direct investment, which is the vehicle of rising intra-industry and intrafirm trade, suffers from the same conceptual void (cf. Julius, 1990). It suggests a rise in activ- ity by major world firms, and the development of a finely grained world division of labor, but little about the meaning of globalization-as-deterritorialization.

The global business hierarchy Much attention has been devoted to the apparent rise of global business hierarchies, the organizations that manage global supply structures. From theorizing about the “multinational,” “transnational,” or even “multidomestic” firm in the 1960s and 1970s, concern has shifted to organizations that manage global production and investment systems in “real time,” involving simultaneous manipulation and opti- mization of manufactured inputs, capital, information, and marketing (Ballance, 1987; Dicken, 1992a; Glickman and Woodward, 1989; Ohmae, 1990). There was considerable optimism about the possibility of such organizations in the late 1970s and early 1980s. Ford Motor Company announced its intention to build a “world car”; General Motors (GM) invested tens of billions of dollars in telecommunications and other infrastructure intended to permit not only worldwide supply and market coordination, but also worldwide concurrent engineering (i.e., innovation and knowledge production). Some analysts label the outcome of such systems the global “hypermobility” of capital, as firms search for ever-better deals from presumably substitutable locations. The importance of such an approach is the notion of a production system spread across the world, involving intrafirm trade in inputs, between locations lacking specificities (Fröbel, Heinrichs, and Kreye, 1980; Hymer, 1976). Were such a model to become dominant, we would expect intermediate products to account for a very high share of world trade; but this is not the case, as can be seen in Table 17.1. We would also expect international sourcing to be very important, and it is in some industries; the problem is that we cannot know whether such sourcing emanates from substitutable locations or territorialized locations. Further, we would expect that finished product trade, which is high in some industries, would be the result of such locationally substitutable sourcing in intermediates, and not the result of territorialized sourcing, knowledge production, and assets. The statistics shed no light on these issues. Anecdotally, the results of attempts to build worldwide, locationally substi- tutable, sourcing systems have been mixed, in that the coordination of such an Table 17.1: Pattern of globalization of the surveyed industries

Industries included Trade Direct investment Cooperative agreements in the survey Finished Interm Intl. Intrafirm Flows AFFs M&As Equity Devel. Prod. Market prods. prods. sourcing (%trade) (%gfcf) sales (%ops) parts purpose purpose purpose (%sales) (%sales) (%tot.ste) (%gfcf) (%ops) (%agrs) (%agrs) (%agrs) Pharmaceuticals 10 8 10–30 70 50–70 40–50 52 48 38–68 13–29 19–41 Computers 26 14 20–60 50–80 30–40 50–60 43 57 50–70 15–28 17–32 Semiconductors 20 n.a. 10–40 70 15–25 20–25 39 61 n.a. n.a. n.a. Motor vehicles 21 13 25–35 50–80 15–25 10–20 33 67 24–48 39–66 9–20 Consumer 55 30 10–40 30–50 20–35 20–30 39 61 24–40 35–62 12–33 electronics Nonferrous metals 21 21a 30–50 30 20–35 15–25 45 55 n.a. n.a. n.a. Steel 27 35–45b 15–25 5–10 5–10 15–25 72 28 n.a. n.a. n.a. Clothing 25–30 25–30c 10–40 5–10 15–20 5–15 n.a. n.a. (limited)

Note: Data from OECD, Industry Division compilation (1993). Elaborated from data sources used for the sector case studies. Please note that gfcf = gross fixed capital formation; ops = overseas partners; agrs = agreements; AFFs = all foreign firms; M&As = mergers and acquisitions; and tot.ste = total sub- contracting and exports. a Unwrought aluminum. b Iron ore, coking coal, scrap. c Textiles. 276 MICHAEL STORPER organization has proven to be much more problematic than was initially envisioned. Ford and GM have substantially cut back their earlier ambitions in favor of highly regionalized operations (Morales, 1994). Still, the management literature suggests that it is the ultimate ideal of many firms in both manufacturing and advanced serv- ices (Caves, 1982; Dicken, 1992a; Ohmae, 1990; Vernon and Spar, 1989). It would seem that the possibility is limited to a set of special cases, however: certain kinds of assembly and fabrication activities carried out at high scale, involving low levels of firm or industry-specific human and physical capital, and therefore highly sub- stitutable locations for global sourcing. But these operations certainly do not add up to hypermobility-as-deterritorialization of contemporary capitalism as a whole. Indeed, they likely constitute a relatively modest share of the economic process today, by any measure (Carnoy, 1993). The same is true for discussions of global business hierarchies in the generation of knowledge and technological innovation. It appears that many forms of innova- tion require investments so great that even the biggest firms, to earn a decent return, attempt to monopolize returns on global markets (Dunning and Norman, 1985; Krugman, 1990). Once such knowledge is developed, it often becomes a global state- of-the-art in product or process. It rests on temporarily non-rival and excludable firm-specific assets which firms use as the basis for earning temporary superprofits (Grossman and Helpman, 1991). The character of these assets encourages firms to internalize them. But does this mean deterritorialization? Not necessarily. The pro- duction of firm-specific assets might occur only via use of complementary territori- alized resources, that is, the mobilization of territory-specific resources in the firm’s core location that permit it to invade world markets by virtue of technological su- periority; it could then be made firm-specific via intellectual property rights, and thereby serve as the basis of a global, monopolistic supply structure, deterritorial- ized from the areas that receive it (Dosi, Pavitt, and Soete, 1990; Patel and Pavitt, 1991). This interpretation is consistent with the fact that intrafirm trade accounts for a high proportion of foreign direct investment in high-technology industries (Table 17.1). Things are not unambiguous even in these cases, however, for the very same set of risks pushes firms to enter into risk and cost-sharing strategic alliances with other major firms; some such alliances come about because firms want to tap into other firms’ expertise in order to avoid the concomitant risk of technological lock-in (by making the wrong, very expensive, firm-specific asset choices) (Mytelka, 1992). Where does such expertise come from? Perhaps from those firms’ deterritorialized, fully internalized capabilities, but just as likely from the territorial contexts in which they are inserted. Clearly, the deployment of advanced technology and knowledge, especially if it is firm-specific and where access is subject to significant legal or eco- nomic barriers to entry, means major developmental power in today’s world, and the global business organization seeks such power of deployment. There are major effects on receiving economies. But the search for this power, again, says little about territorialization or deterritorialization of technology and knowledge generation in the world economy; and much more about corporate supply of such knowledge and technology once developed. Indeed, in place of the model of the international firm as vertically integrated worldwide business hierarchy, much recent reflection about the organization of TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 277 global business has turned on the notion of the firm as the central node in a variety of global linkages, ranging from ownership to alliance, and including cross- investment, technology and production partnerships, and research and development (R&D) collaborations (Mowery, 1988; Mytelka, 1992). This may well be a new kind of “nexus” business organization, whose impacts on economic development processes we have barely begun to glimpse; but such a model of the global firm does not so much imply deterritorialization of the economic process as a recasting of the role of territories in complex, intraorganizationally and interorganizationally linked global business flows.

Foreign direct investment I have left the most obvious category of globalization for consideration until now because, as can be readily seen, it is a chaotic conception. Foreign direct investment is a catchall category that refers to the volume of international investment in sub- sidiary operations of firms. It leads to intra-industry, inter-industry and intrafirm trade, but, then again, it may reduce commodity trade when it leads to installation of locally serving final output capacity in major markets, so-called “regional” or “Triad” locational patterns. So foreign direct investment may be a vehicle for or substitute for trade. It may reflect firm strategies to control foreign markets via intrafirm trade, but then again it may reflect the need to tap into intermediate inputs produced by firms, through alliances and local trade. It may reflect global supply oligopolies in goods, intellectual property, or technology, but, then again, it may reflect needs to be in contact with territorially rooted foreign contexts of goods or technology development. The statistic reveals little about the territoriality of economic dynamics. Another argument, which underlies much of the claim that the global economy is deterritorializing in favor of global business organizations, has to do with cor- porate power. It has been correctly observed that the biggest global firms are getting bigger: there is ongoing concentration of capital. It has also been remarked that there is a certain centralization of capital, in that the shares of the largest 100 or 500 corporations in global output are greater than they were 20 years ago. These large organizations, so it goes, are increasingly powerful across territorial bound- aries. Their deployment of investments can shape markets, determine which tech- nologies get developed, and, above all, exercise influence on national and regional governments (Harrison, 1994). Power, in this sense, probably does have impacts on territorialization as we have defined it. But we need to examine precisely how. One of the paradoxes of global- ization, in the sense of interpenetration of markets by companies from different nations, is that many market structures in many industries have actually become less concentrated over the past 30 years; there are more competitors in them than when such markets were composed of national or regional firms, though at a world level the first 10 or 20 companies control high proportions of output in many indus- tries, especially technology-intensive ones. Global firms, while constituting a small club, especially in industries with very high barriers to entry, are therefore locked into competitive battle; they do not rule their world markets in any straightforward 278 MICHAEL STORPER sense, as any major automobile, computer, clothing, or chemical company will readily attest. Still, their power to shift vast quantities of capital, technology, or human capital across territorial borders, into different product markets, into R&D programs, is considerable. These firms can obviously shape the development of markets by shaping supply structures through their decisions. And they can bargain with terri- torially rooted states in so doing. But the image of nations and regions as Davids facing the global Goliaths cannot be straightforwardly assumed by the mere exis- tence of global firms, for the latter are subject to all the complexities of territorial- ization described in preceding paragraphs.

The poverty of categories The traditional categories in which the globalization debate has been framed – foreign direct investment, commodity trade, the global business hierarchy, the global supply structure of commodities, knowledge, and technology – seem instinctively to indicate the steady deterritorialization of economic power. But upon closer observation, these conceptual categories are inadequate to the job of shedding light on the question of territorialization and deterritorialization. It is, indeed, quite curious that a fundamentally geographical process labeled with a geographical term – “globalization”– is analyzed as a set of resource flows largely without consider- ing their interactions with the territoriality of economic development.

Reframing the Question: Territories and Flows In order to see what the terms territorialized and deterritorialized might mean with respect to the global economy, we can imagine two polar opposite cases, a fully deterritorialized “economy of flows and substitutions” and a fully territorialized “economy of interdependencies and specificities.” In constructing these images, we will combine reasoning about organizations (firms), assets, markets, and places.

A pure flow-substitution economy Imagine the extreme case of a fully realized global supply oligopoly. Resources would flow between parts of a firm, between places, without having any particular dependence on any particular place. Such assets – whether goods or information – would be producible in so many different places as to constitute a true (almost) perfect “market” in locations for their production. This sort of economy could be the result of two possible developmental processes. On one hand, activities that are well developed in a wide variety of places make necessary productive resources avail- able in near ubiquity, but have historically been separated by transport barriers or differentiated tastes. Improvements in transportation, standardization of tastes, or increases in the possible scale of production open up this wide variety of locations to global business organizations, who then profit from a huge potential locational choice and ubiquitous markets, but they are bound by no locational specificities or local interdependencies. On the other hand, such organizations perfect production processes that eliminate the need for locationally scarce specific assets: technologi- TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 279 cal change via product standardization and routinization of production processes does the job. In both cases, a pure flow form of globalization becomes possible. It matters little whether the flows are via markets or hierarchies: global firms could purchase locally and sell through global commodity trade, for example. It matters little whether the flows concern intermediate or finished products. Those considerations, well ana- lyzed through industrial organization theory, are simply different forms that the global flows of resources and optimization of factor use and capacity may take. The essential condition for a pure flow economy is that locations offer factors of pro- duction that could potentially be substituted by a large number of other locations. This case of nonspecific, locationally substitutable, and perfectly elastic factor supplies is probably not found in pure form anywhere. But in some sectors, notably certain manufacturing industries and consumer services, these conditions are increasingly close to reality. Low-wage, low-skill, low sunk-cost manufacturing processes; certain highly standardized consumer durable manufacturing (where sunk costs are higher, but modular and widely available equipment is used); and certain consumer services where centralized production can be combined with local delivery come to mind. One could imagine a pure market version of this globalization process, where numerous local economies, characterized by relatively small firms, competed with each other on global markets. Purchasers, armed with perfect information and highly developed and very flexible marketing networks, could switch from one local- ity’s product to another almost instantaneously. Hierarchy is not necessary, then, to the flow economy’s definition, in contrast to the image of oligopoly = globalization often implied in the literature. In reality, however, this ability to switch tends to be associated with scale in marketing and an ability to coordinate supplies from different, substitutable sources. The potential political consequences of flow economies are what bother many of the critics of globalization (e.g., Harrison, 1994). Instead of seeing such flows as the means to resource optimization at a world scale, their point of departure is that economic progress has always depended on political economics, where everything ranging from the distribution of income between labor and capital to the correc- tion of a wide variety of market failures is carried out by territorially rooted insti- tutions such as nation-states. The advent of deterritorialized flow economies would seem to reduce the margin of maneuver of such nation-states dramatically, in favor of that of the private sector and thereby to open up a number of unfavorable con- sequences in both distributional and efficiency terms.

A pure territorial economy of interdependencies and specificities A fully territorialized economic activity would satisfy conditions quite opposite to those just described. The essential condition of territorialization is that the activity be dependent on resources with specificities that are strongly territorialized and where the supply of these resources is subject to important inelasticities. The tradi- tional case of scarce natural resources is a pure example but little relevant to most productive activity, where “resources” are mostly produced inputs such as labor and technology. We know that for many labor and technology inputs, there are no 280 MICHAEL STORPER functional substitutes at any price, but even though such labor and technology are highly product-specific (heterogeneous is the accepted term), in many cases they are nonetheless widely available or easily produced, at rather different prices. In this case, territorialization is not in evidence. Where they are not widely available at any price, however, that is, where scarcities or inelasticities are in evidence, then not only localization but territorialization exist due to the geographically limited conditions of their production. It is really with respect to special meanings of the term “labor” and “technology” that territorialization becomes most relevant in today’s economy. Certain kinds of labor qualities are different from mere skills. There are many contexts where nonroutine judgments are made and where the success of the judgment depends on how a condition of uncertainty that involves other people is interpreted, or where noncodified traditions and ways of doing things are essential to the job. The former corresponds to demands for creativity or convention, the latter to learned custom. In all these cases, labor qualities are produced in what may be called a relation-specific fashion: they are produced and are exercised via insertion into a system of relations, whether it be interpersonal or bounded by specific, not-fully-codifiable rules of the game (Asanuma, 1989). These skills are not only specific in nature but subject to important supply inelasticities in the medium-run (Amin and Thrift, 1997). Analogous observations may be made about technology, if what we mean by this is not merely hardware, but know-how, especially know-how that involves an outwardly moving and unknown scientific frontier (as in high technology) or an uncertain movement around such dynamics as product differentiation (for many low-technology or fashion-dependent industries and services). It is likely to involve asset specificities and supply inelasticities (Dosi et al., 1990). This probably understates the extent of relation and place-specific assets in pro- duction. Many production systems turn on an intricate web of external interfirm transactions or internal, intrafirm transactions. In some cases, there are – at one moment or another – various sorts of standard economizing reasons for such trans- actions to be carried out across limited geographical distances: in these cases, terri- torialization is the result of necessary relations of proximity in the production system, which limit the number of sites at which production can be carried out. Over time, however, such cost barriers tend to be eroded due to transport improve- ments or to change in the nature of the transactions themselves, which lead to higher scale, greater certainty, and lower costs of covering distance. But cost barriers are not the only reasons for the existence of relations of prox- imity in production systems. Many such relationships – buyer–supplier interfirm relations, or R&D–producer relations, or firm–labor market relations – come to be structured in ways that are highly specific to a given, initially geographically bounded, transactional context (usually regions or nation-states). Over time, they become more and more specific as unwritten rules of the game (conventions), formal institutions, and customary forms of knowledge are built up and become indispen- sable to admission to the producers’ community and to efficient interpretation of how to reciprocate via transactions with other agents under conditions of uncer- tainty. In other words, regional or national production systems become nexuses of interdependencies between organizations and persons which involve relational asset specificities (Amin and Thrift, 1997; Storper, 1997; Storper and Salais, 1997; TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 281

Saxenian, 1994). These interdependencies must, of course, be efficient in some sense (e.g., a factor in cost minimization or innovation-improvement). Territorialization is thus not equivalent to geographical proximity or agglomer- ation, although such agglomeration may be at some times cause and at others effect territorialization: it is an effect when scarcities and specificities of key resources such as labor and technology draw producers to a place, and when nonsubstitutabilities keep them there; it is a cause when the transactional structure of production draws producers into an agglomeration, and then key dimensions of the production system become relation-specific and key to its ongoing efficiencies. There are very few industries where pure territorialization, in the sense of a unique possible efficient location for the totality of the industry’s output, exists; in this case, there would be a localized global supply monopoly. But the condition of territorialization, in the sense of a few possible locations for significant parts of the industry’s output, can be found quite frequently. Certain very high quality goods, those that involve technological innovation or ongoing rapid differentiation, or highly specialized services come to mind as examples. There are two very different versions of this territorialization. One concerns activities that serve such localized tastes that the localized supply structure corresponds to a unique localized demand structure. The more interesting case, of course, is that where the localized supply structure satisfies a national or global demand, and where there is therefore the pos- sibility of entry by competitors in other places. This is likely to show up as a case of commodity trade exports, whether intra- or inter-industry. It is analytically indif- ferent to ownership (that is, the definition says nothing about whether ownership of territorialized assets must be local). In practice, most such cases of multinational corporations who have core activities in their home country and in a specific region of that country also have national ownership (Patel and Pavitt, 1991; Tyson, 1991), but counterexamples, such as Sony’s ownership of Columbia Pictures, are reason- ably abundant. Territorialization, therefore, cuts across the standard terms of the globalization debate, such as “who is us?”

The Dynamics of Globalization What should be clear from the preceding is that global capitalism is being con- structed through interactions between flow economies and territorial economies. Internationalization of capitalism has long been measured simply as a function of the increasing intensities of flows, but little was said about territories. Globaliza- tion is said to refer to something qualitatively different, in the sense of an economy or its subsystems that operate globally. That is, globalization should involve not merely international flows of resources, but economic systems that operate as inter- national flow economies, as they have been defined here. If globalization is truly gaining on territorial economic organization, then we should find evidence not merely of increasing international flows of resources, but also of decreasing territorialization. Some of the possible interactions are represented schematically in Figure 17.1. On the horizontal axis is the degree of territorialization of economic activities, and on the vertical axis the level of international flows associated with these activities. The first case (type 1) comprises those activities that are both highly territorialized 282 MICHAEL STORPER

Territorialization of Production System

High Low

(type 1) (type 2) Intrafirm trade with asset specifications International divisions of labor Intermediate outputs of FDI (e.g. in routinized manufacturing) Intermediate markets served from International markets territorial cores (e.g. in consumer services) Industrial districts Interfirm and interindustry trade Interfirm and interindustry trade without territorial core

(type 4) (type 3) Locally serving production to Local commerce in basic services specialized tastes with low Low High not delivered via big-farm international competition hierarchies International Flows in Production System

Figure 17.1 Territorialization and internationalization

and highly internationalized, territorially specific, nonsubstitutable assets are involved, but there are relationships that are not bound by such territorialization. Examples include the high-technology production system where the firm has certain important territorialized activities, but engages in intrafirm trade in intermediate inputs, and intrafirm trade for its worldwide marketing network. Intermediate inputs might be sourced for cost reasons alone (in which case this part of the system is effectively deterritorialized) or because the firm is tapping into territorial contexts of expertise elsewhere. Other examples are the now-famous industrial districts, where localized production systems serve world markets. Both interfirm and inter- industry trade, within complex social divisions of labor, can involve highly territo- rialized production for international commodity chains. Foreign direct investment is a means to carry out some of these processes as well. The second cell (type 2) describes cases of low levels of territorialization and high levels of international flow, and includes territorially dispersed commodity chains where no nonsubstitutable locations are involved (where technological standardi- zation has reached a high level of development, generally) (Fröbel et al., 1980; Hymer, 1976). It also includes dispersed production systems oriented to interna- tional markets, as in many consumer services. Note that this category would lead to interfirm, intrafirm, and inter-industry trade, as well as foreign direct investment. The third cell (type 3) consists of systems with low territorialization and low levels of international flow, that is, such things as local commerce in basic services that are not provided by far-flung big-firm hierarchies. In this cell we would find the industries of yore, which were localized due to transportation barriers but not truly territorialized; today we might find them there because of very low economies of scale, but less so due to transport barriers. TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 283

Finally, in the last cell (type 4), there are highly territorialized systems with few international connections. These are not simply localized due to insurmountable cost barriers to serving other areas from the local production system; they are territorialized because of nonsubstitutable local assets, as in the case of industries producing to specialized regional tastes. The caricatural version of globalization is based on the notion that advanced cap- italism has substituted type 2 production systems for type 3 production systems; and some of this has indeed come about with the progressive reduction of trans- port barriers, increase in scale of delivery of commodities and services, and changes in trading regimes. Many manufactured goods, including both durables and non- durables, that were formerly produced in isolated regional economies, were first converted to national production systems in the postwar period (most especially in Europe), and then to commodity chains that are now, at least in part, internation- alized (Vernon and Spar, 1989). An even more extreme set of cases is that of type 4 becoming type 2, that is, for- merly territorialized and mostly closed production systems now becoming interna- tional commodity chains. This is in evidence because as more internationalized, middle-class ways of life and tastes sweep their way across many places, old place- specific tastes disappear and with them the economic reasons for local asset speci- ficity. When needs are redefined, so is demand, which can then be served via other kinds of products, furnished by production systems with assets available at many different locations, and without territorial cores. Crucial to this set of events is not changes in transportation, nor even scale, but actual product substitutions – the culture of demand is the key causal mechanism. Many sophisticated analyses also call attention to a transformation of produc- tion systems from type 1 to type 2: this is the movement from “internationaliza- tion” of production to its true “globalization.” Now it can be seen that the real claim here is not simply that there are high levels of international flow, of whatever sort, involved in the operation of these systems; in and of themselves, they do not transform these production systems into deterritorialized flow economies. The claim is rather that substitutability of locations increases; and territorially specific assets decrease dramatically in their importance to competitive production (Dunning, 1992). Two other important cases, however, seem to characterize the current era. The first is transformation of type 3 and 4 production systems not to type 2, but to type 1 systems. Formerly highly territorialized but not internationalized systems can become internationalized as they gain the ability to market their products around the world, without losing their locationally specific assets. This requires develop- ment of demand for their products beyond local or regional borders. This is pre- cisely what appears to have happened in the cases of many European industrial districts in the postwar period: the product qualities once prized locally have become desired elsewhere, and the relationally specific assets that exist in producer regions now permit those regions to meet broader demands through downstream interna- tionalization, but not through internationalization of production itself (Bianchi, 1993). Perhaps even more important is the transformation of type 2 production systems into type 1 systems: from highly internationalized but not especially territorialized 284 MICHAEL STORPER systems, to ones increasingly territorialized and internationalized. The mass pro- duction industries of the postwar period, for example, seemed at one point to be on the road to ever greater standardization and, with it, locational substitutability, but forces such as increased product differentiation, and newly revived product- based technological learning have given a new lease on life to locationally specific relational assets in production. Indeed, the principal trend to which we can call attention today is that in many sectors, there is simultaneous and ongoing development of the characteristics of both type 1 and type 2 systems: the latter as ongoing standardization of tastes and tech- niques occurs, the former as technological learning, product differentiation, and the separating off of new branches of production, materials, and processes occur, all of which are causes of locational specificity, but also precisely outcomes of the inter- active processes permitted by the locationally specific relational assets that underlie territorialization. This form of territorialization is qualitatively quite different from that of type 4 systems, in that it is not developed as the result of “tradition via iso- lation,” but via what might be called the ongoing reinvention of relational assets in the context of high levels of geographical openness in trade and communications. The formation of this global context of trade, investment, and communications and organized networks of human relations in production is perhaps the clearest dimension of globalization. The global economy is being constructed as an increas- ingly widely spread and accepted “grid” of these sorts of transactions, akin to a new global lingua franca of commerce, investment, and organization, based on his- torical and secular advances in transportation and communication technologies, and the development and diffusion of modern organizational “science,” both of these in the context of the increasingly global political order of trade. But the paradox is that it is precisely this global grid or language that leads both to type 2 and to type 1 outcomes. In the former case, it breaks down barriers of taste, transport, and scale. In the latter case, it opens up markets to products based on superior forms of “local knowledge”; it consolidates markets and leads to such fantastic product differentiation possibilities that markets refragment and, with them, new special- ized and localized divisions of labor reemerge; and it in some ways heats up the competitive process (albeit among giants), creating new premia on technological learning that require the same firms that become new global supply oligopolists to root themselves in locationally specific relational assets. The point is that global- ization and territorialization are not just about the geography of flows and its tech- nological or organizational determinants, but are in some cases dependent on the ways production systems and their products are changed by new patterns of com- petition unleashed by territorial integration. To summarize, four principal territorial-organizational dynamics can be isolated from these complex, intersecting forces. In some cases, the opening up of interter- ritorial relations places previously existing locationally specific assets into a new position of global dominance. In a second set of cases, those assets are devalued via substitution by other products that now penetrate local markets; this is not a straightforward economic process, however; it is culturally intermediated. In a third set of cases, territorial integration permits the fabled attainment of massive economies of scale and organization, devalues locationally specific assets, and leads to deterritorialization and widespread market penetration. In a fourth set of cases, TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 285 territorial integration is met by differentiation and destandardization of at least some crucial elements of the commodity chain, necessitating the reinvention of territory-specific relational assets.

Hierarchy, Regulation, and Competition: Institutional Dilemmas State institutions exercise their authority over limited territories. But they do so in fields of forces – whether political or economic – that extend well beyond these borders. At least in matters of economic affairs, for much of the postwar period the economic authority of nation-states and the substantive power to back it up was considerable within the national territory. Globalization of economic processes seems to have weakened that substantive power, if not the formal authority. The global business organizations that control certain important international resource flows seem, in many cases, to be deterritorialized, and thus not directly dependent on processes that states, whether regional or national, can effectively regulate. Yet, as we have seen, the mere existence of large-scale international flows does not lead directly to a conclusion that a productive activity is deterritorialized. Like- wise, we can now see that the mere existence of territorialization does not mean that local or national states can exercise strong regulatory control over the economic development process (Carnoy, 1993; Dunning, 1992). Territorialization is a neces- sary, but not a sufficient, condition for a strong state role, because territorialization itself may involve hierarchies that are in turn inserted into larger contexts. We now want to sketch out some of the complex interactions between territorial economies and flow economies, and the ways they may mix hierarchical, market, and network forms of governance of production systems. Territorially based state institutions are now forced to confront these sorts of interactions in undertaking economic development strategies. Figure 17.2 shows different ways of governing production systems, in the context of different levels of territorialization and international flows. Forms of governance where authority is largely internalized within large business organizations are labeled “hierarchies,” while those that are carried out via high levels of external relations of large numbers of agents, where no single or small number of agents is dominant, are labeled “networks and markets.” These represent two fundamentally different nexuses of decision-making power, centralized and decentralized. It can be seen from the top half of the Figure 17.2 that for productive activities with high levels of international flow, there is evidence of both territorialization and deterritorialization: high levels of flow do not necessarily imply deterritorialization. Moreover, there is a great diversity of institutional arrangements that govern both the primary dynamic of the production system – that is, investment and technology or knowledge dynamics – and their international flows. For example, many global high technology firms manage extensive intrafirm supply chains, but at the same time are inserted into one or multiple territorialized production systems where network or market relations are dominant. Their power is more absolute with respect to their international flows than it is with respect to the other firms in their industry’s territorial core. In certain other industries, global supply oligopolists are highly territorialized and interact locally via hierarchical relations, but then must compete on international markets with other such oligopolists, or they may enter 286 MICHAEL STORPER

Territorialization of Production System High Low

Hierarchies Networks/Markets Hierarchies Networks/Markets

Global supply Territorial core oligopolists with Isolated captive Intrafirm trade, systems world division suppliers to where firm has (especially if of labor global territorial core high tech (manufacturing oligopolists industries) and services)

Global supply, Global supply Isolated specialist oligopolists, Industrial oligopolists with suppliers or strategic districts few intermediaries contractors alliances

Global supply Local champion oligopolists via firm(s) with little franchising and internationalization brand name strategies International Flows in Production System High Low

Locally serving Local commerce production to in basic services specialized tastes Hierarchies Networks/Markets Hierarchies Networks/Markets

Figure 17.2 Hierarchies, territories, and flows into strategic alliances for marketing or for certain input supplies. The paradox is that while such oligopolists may exercise considerable power over those local sup- pliers and partners, to the extent that they depend on locationally specific relational assets, the state in those places may have considerable potential bargaining power with them. Industrial districts are frequently characterized by strongly territorialized network relations in the core region, and by networked markets internationally: the institutional construction of international market networks is critical to them. We know from experience that states can play strong roles in supporting the competi- tiveness of such districts (Bianchi, 1993). The classical image of globalization is, of course, the global supply oligopolist which has a low level of territorialization and a high degree of hierarchical control over its inputs and markets on a worldwide basis (Hymer, 1976). This can be found TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 287 as a tendency in certain manufacturing industries and certain consumer service sectors. Isolated captive suppliers to these global oligopolists also have little terri- torialization and are subject to the strong hierarchy of these firms in their sales rela- tions (semiconductor assemblers in Asia or clothing firms in developing countries are examples). Global supply oligopolists with few intermediate inputs and little ter- ritorialization are likely to have little intrafirm trade and foreign direct investment, and instead are likely to internationalize through global sales via markets (Dunning and Norman, 1985). Isolated specialized suppliers or contractors, on the other hand, will interact internationally via networks or markets, as they do with any local suppliers, the terms of their interactions being set by the degree and nature of substitutability of their products by the purchasing firm. At the bottom half of Figure 17.2 may be found cases of low levels of interna- tional flows, and various combinations of both their territorialization and gover- nance. Local champion firms, for example, who dominate a market, will tend to govern their territorialized production systems in a hierarchical way and have little internationalization, whereas other forms of localized production, for localized and specialized tastes, will probably correspond to the nonhierarchical system of tradi- tional local firms. They may export some of their excess output, but this will likely be a small proportion of the total. Global supply oligopolists may not always have high levels of international flow oligopoly can be attained through control of intel- lectual and intangible assets, such as knowledge and brand names, but carried out through franchising; hence, low flows but hierarchically governed. These are just a few of the many possible examples of complex configurations of institutions with respect to territoriality and flows in production systems. Small firms can enjoy relatively great market, network, or even hierarchical power, some- times territorially and other times globally; while big firms can be subject to the forces of other big firms or markets they do not control, whether in their territori- alized or their global interactions.

Policy problems Many dilemmas of aligning the governance of production systems with efficient and desirable patterns of territorialization and flow present themselves in the contem- porary world economy; these are problems faced not only by territorially bound state institutions, but also by the private sector. The most obvious set of problems concerns the cases on the right-hand side of Figure 17.2. Where territorialization is low or declining, that is, where locational substitution becomes more and more possible, there is often a “race to the bottom” for territorially defined states, a competitive bidding war for economic activity that transfers increasing amounts of benefit from the public to the private sector. In the United States, this has been the history of postwar routinized manufacturing, encouraged not only by federalism but by the passage of the Taft–Hartley Act in the late 1940s, which enabled states to make a big institutional concession to employers by making unionization locally more difficult. More recently, such bidding has become a frenetic activity of states and localities. There is evidence that similar trends are developing within the European Union, and we can certainly see them on broader international scales within North America and Southeast Asia. 288 MICHAEL STORPER

Moreover, this dynamic is no longer limited to manufacturing. Corporate head- quarters learned that they could demand concessions for remaining in New York, for example, in the 1970s, and since then have generalized these demands. Holly- wood film productions now expect to be wooed to locations in order to shoot films there. Corporations involved in relatively routine administration, such as in the consumer service or retailing sectors, now also regularly demand concessions or threaten to move. The demands of firms are usually less naked when territorialization of activity is strongly in evidence, precisely because they have less locational substitutability, at least in the short run. Nonetheless, the fact that certain kinds of productive activ- ity are territorialized does not mean that they are wedded permanently to one single territory. Global companies do not just scan the globe for single locations; some interact with multiple territorial economies. To some extent, these territorial economies cannot be substituted by these firms, since the latter are inserted into them in order to tap into the technological or knowledge specificities of such terri- torial systems. The firm thus has a division of labor that involves multiple territo- ries, which are functionally specialized. For the moment global technology firms remain mostly attached to territorialized resources in their nations of origin (Dosi et al., 1990). But one could imagine that for inputs that are not on the cutting edge of technological knowledge, such firms could over time develop parallel territories, in the same way that mass production firms in the 1970s developed parallel assem- bly or fabrication plants. Developmental states in Southeast Asia, for example, have had some successes in helping their firms to build up territory-specific relational assets, and these assets are now enjoyed by firms from elsewhere. The paradox here is that states participate in a kind of competitive endogenous development, which creates new forms of capital mobility even in the territorialized parts of the con- temporary economy. A second concern is that when major hierarchical global business organizations interact with different territorial economies, there may be little harmony between the rules by which such firms intend to relate to these environments and the rela- tional assets already built up in those places. Problems of this nature, however, only become apparent over time, and when they do, multinational firms may not have the commitment required to work them out. And they are problems that are not generally technical, but relational in nature and thus slow to resolve. We might think here of subcontracting policies established by such firms, which are designed to economize for them, but at the medium-term price of the region’s subcontracting tissue as a whole (Dunning, 1992). A third concern has to do with territorialized developmental spillovers. Territo- rial economies exist as such in part because there are knowledge or technology spillovers between activities, and the overall developmental trajectory of a territo- rial economy is strongly influenced by such spillovers. But firms whose primary loy- alties lie outside a particular territorial economy or firms with a highly elaborate interterritorial division of labor may inadvertently make decisions that undercut development of such spillovers, precisely by territorially dividing what might better (from the territory’s and technology’s standpoint) be kept in proximity. This is not a problem unique to “foreign” firms, but to all multilocational, multiterritorial firms. TERRITORIES, FLOWS, AND HIERARCHIES IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY 289

A corollary is that when territorialized technological spillovers exist, there is an efficiency rationale for targeted technology policies, even from the standpoint of global output. Where such spillovers do not exist or are not territorialized, however, technology policies tend merely to transfer technological performance from one place to another, usually at a high overall cost (Grossman and Helpman, 1991). The problem is to construct such policies where the community of subjects of the policy is not only local but global; many firms operate in many different institutional and conventional contexts. Such policies therefore have to be “translated” for them, and these global business organizations must find ways to reconcile operations in very different contexts. Chapter 18 Contesting Works Closures in Western Europe’s Old Industrial Regions: Defending Place or Betraying Class?

Ray Hudson and David Sadler

In the 1950s and 1960s, major plant closures in northeast England in most “tradi- tional” industries, but above all coal mining, were largely uncontested by those who were directly or indirectly affected by the accompanying loss of jobs (Hudson, 1986). By contrast, the late 1970s and early 1980s in the same area saw a series of campaigns to contest decisions concerning works closures or major employment losses. By no means all such decisions were challenged, but those that were con- centrated in places where the region’s “traditional” (and by then often nationalized) industries such as coal mining, iron and steel-making, shipbuilding, and heavy engineering were the major, even sole, source of industrial employment. These anti- closure campaigns were characteristically organized around the threatened works and the community (village or town) reliant upon it for employment and wage income. Furthermore, it was clear that such campaigns were by no means confined to this particular region, as similar ones developed or revived in other “old” indus- trial regions elsewhere in Great Britain (Scotland, Wales) and in continental Western Europe (Lorraine and the Nord in France, the Ruhr in West Germany, Wallonia in Belgium). In contrast to northeast England, where anti-closure campaigns tended to remain confined to the particular groups of workers, works, villages, or towns directly affected, in several of these other cases protests became generalized within an industry at regional – even national – level, and throughout particular regions across a wide spectrum of social groups. Several of these campaigns, then, were characterized by attachments to place and class becoming contingently conjoined in a variety of often-complex ways, so that these became complementary rather than competitive bases for social organization in defense of place. What was emerging was a series of territorially based campaigns, the aims of which may be summarized in a phrase borrowed from one of the campaign slogans in Longwy (France) in the late 1970s: to defend the right to “live, learn, and work” in particular places, though the ways in which these objectives were pursued and the degree to which they were successfully attained were highly varied. These campaigns were not simply evidence of a deeply felt, and to varying degrees collectively shared, attachment to place that was grounded in the spatially defined routine of everyday life, but also of the active CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 291 involvement of working people, their families, friends, and neighbors in the restruc- turing of capital and the changing geography of industrial production as their par- ticular places were deemed no longer to be (sufficiently) profitable locations in the context of an increasingly internationalized system of production and trade. How, then, is the emergence of such territorially based protests, at these particular times and in these particular places to be understood? Finding satisfactory answers to this theoretical question took on pressing practical significance as we became actively involved in some of these campaigns in northeast England and sought a better under- standing of past practices with a view to informing existing struggles against further closures. Some preliminary clues were provided by the historical geographic development of this particular set of traditional industries. Frequently they were (a) associated with “one-industry” towns so that the effects of major closure were heavily spa- tially concentrated (unlike, say, textiles, where aggregate job losses had been very extensive but spatially more diffused); (b) characterized by either public ownership or a high degree of state involvement at national and/or supranational European Community level, so that closure decisions were often transparently “political,” while (c) in contrast to the 1960s, by the late 1970s the promises of “alternative jobs” via reindustrialization programs had worn distinctly thin. These provided no more than some general indications, however, and certainly offered no explanation of the rise and variety of territorially based campaigns in defense of place. Much of the existing literature dealing with attachment to place and capitalism’s uneven development provided at best partial insights. For example, much of the debate on nationalism and attachment to the “imagined communities” (Anderson, 1983) of national states is of limited relevance, focusing on issues (such as linguis- tic distinctiveness) that were of little importance for the defense of particular villages or towns against catastrophic industrial decline. This conclusion holds a fortiori for those analyses which pose the issue in terms of territory (nation) versus class (for example, Hobsbawm, 1977), for the precise characteristic of several of the campaigns considered here was their fusion of place and class (at least for a while). While the writings of humanistic geographers (such as Tuan, 1977) on attachment to place and related issues focus more on the spatial scales of village or town, they tend only to describe individuals’ experience of place. They do not relate this to the context and structures of the societies in which such people live; to their membership of social groups and classes through which they learn shared meanings, including those relating to the places in which they live and with which they identify. Conversely, the varied contributions within the Marxist tradition on the spatial uneven development of capitalism address themselves to the causally determining powers of unobservable structures (for example, Sayer, 1982b), but tend to neglect the role of people as rational agents affecting change within the limits that these structures impose and reproducing them via their actions. The more sophisticated of these analyses (for example, Harvey, 1982) halt at the point of specifying the structural boundaries to a capitalist society and possible tenden- cies toward spatial uneven development within them. The cruder versions of such analyses (for example, Carney, 1980) go so far as rather mechanistically to deduce forms of political organization in defense of place from the inner logic of the capitalist mode of production explicitly rather than implicitly reducing people to 292 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER their ascribed roles of bearers of structures, to the status of “cultural dupes” (Giddens, 1981, pp. 71–2). A more sophisticated theoretical approach is required in order to begin to grasp the bases for, and character and political potential of, the various campaigns in defense of the right to “live, learn, and work” in particular places. This sophisti- cated approach is required in order to comprehend more satisfactorily the links between people’s knowledge of and feelings about space, their patterns of behavior and social practices, and the spatially uneven development of capitalist societies, and so reveal rather more about the processes of uneven development themselves. This approach views people as active, conscious agents, who are rational in that what they do makes sense to them in terms of their own understanding of their indi- vidual and collective interests, while recognizing that the way in which they per- ceive these interests, and the possibilities that at any time are objectively open to them, will be conditioned by (though not determined by) those deep structural forces that shape the societies in which they live. Seeking to integrate the way in which places and the spatial patterning of (capitalist) societies come to have socially endowed meanings for people presupposes the creation of some significant theoreti- cal space for conscious and meaningful human behavior in the reproduction of uneven development. In so far as it creates this theoretical space it also potentially creates political space within which people can begin to change the societies within which they live.

The Reproduction of Societies as Capitalist Agency, structure While in many respects provocative to certain strands of both bourgeois and Marxist thought, Giddens’ “theory of structuration” (1981) forms a useful starting point for discussion and is one which accepts the kernel of Marx’s arguments about the essen- tial character of capitalist societies. A recognition of the decisive importance of the class structural relation between capital and labor does not imply that the actual development of capitalist societies revolves only around this axis, however. In brief, we must not only recognize the fundamental contradictory relation between capital and labor. We must also recognize the existence of competition between capitals in search of surplus profits. Further, we must acknowledge competition between groups within the (structurally defined) working class, for example on the basis of differ- ences in sector, industry, or occupation. We must also take account of the possibility of conflict between capital(s) and/or groups within the working class and social groups either located outside of capi- talist social relations or located within them, but organized on issues and dimen- sions other than those of production: gender, race, or an ecological concern for the natural environment, for example. Although the proximate basis of social organi- zation may not be a class issue (in the sense of directly deriving from capital–labor relations of production), it has nevertheless been argued that the capacity of such groups to realize their aims is conditional upon their class location (Wright, 1978). What this suggests is that the relationships between social practice and the repro- CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 293 duction of the class structural relation between capital and labor are complicated and contingent ones. Central to Giddens’ analysis of the links between agency and structure are two related notions: the distinction between system and structure and the duality of structure. He summarizes these points as follows (1981, pp. 26–7):

A distinction is made between structure and system. Social systems are composed of patterns of relationships between actors or collectivities reproduced across time and space. Social systems are hence constituted of situated practices. Structures exist in time-space only as moments recursively involved in the production and reproduction of social systems. Structures have only a “virtual” existence. A fundamental postulate of the theory of structuration is the notion of duality of structure, which refers to the essentially recursive nature of social practices. Structure is both the medium and outcome of the practices which constitute social systems. The concept of duality of structure connects the production of social interaction, as always and everywhere a contingent accomplishment of knowledgeable social actors, to the reproduction of social systems across time-space. (emphases in original)

In this way, Giddens stresses the relations between temporally and spatially situated social interaction and societal reproduction, and emphasizes that the actions of indi- vidual agents, pursuing their individually or collectively defined interests, are at once shaped by and reproduce the “basic principles of organization” of societies, above all in capitalist societies that of the fundamental class relationship between capital and labor; and that they do this as a routine, taken-for-granted element in their behavior as rational agents. Whether we are conscious of them or not, and contrary to appearances, structural relationships are not immutably given to us in a manner that renders them unchangeable (or changeable only over time, when the continu- ing development of the forces of production within the social relations of capital- ism attains a critical pitch, after which capitalism somehow mysteriously changes itself into something new and better). The point is that structural relations are rou- tinely socially produced and reproduced in the course of everyday life. This being so, a central task of a critical social theory is to uncover that which is unquestion- ingly taken for granted, discursively to reveal the real basis of “practical con- sciousness . . . ‘knowing how to go on’ in a whole diversity of contexts of social life” (Giddens, 1981, p. 27; emphasis in original). For it is in the unquestioning, perhaps even unconscious, acceptance of the legitimacy of the rules governing every- day life that the structural reproduction of capitalist societies is grounded. Of par- ticular importance is the routine acceptance of the legitimacy of wage labor and of going to work in a particular place as a normal feature of such societies, for in this is grounded the reproduction of the class structural capital-labor. Another important point in Giddens’ analysis of the relationships between agency and structure for our purposes is that, while social agents act in a rational manner, it is vital to acknowledge that as a matter of routine they engage in social interac- tion in circumstances that in part are unknown to them and that, partly because of this, their actions can have outcomes in addition to or other than those that they intended. Furthermore, in pointing out that “the knowledgeability of actors is always bounded, by unacknowledged conditions and unintended consequences of 294 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER action” (Giddens, 1981, p. 28), Giddens’ conclusions highlight the chronic gap between the intentions and outcomes of the policies of capitalist states.

Place, class Capitalist societies are simultaneously riven with conflict and dissension on several planes. Yet as societies they do hold together with sufficient cohesion and in such ways that capitalist social relations are reproduced; precisely how and on what bases such social class groupings form, how the balance of class and other social forces fluctuates, and how capitalist societies are contingently reproduced can only be resolved via theoretically informed empirical investigations. Nevertheless, it is clear that capitalist states, which in practice largely means capitalist national states, play a decisive role in mediating between the claims of competing classes and interest groups (see Jessop, 1982). Virtually from the outset, capitalist societies have been constituted in the form of competitive national states (Anderson, 1983). From the genesis of the capitalist mode of production, there has been a territorial element in the definition of actual class interests. More generally, an important dimension to the historical processes of social class formation in capitalist societies, to divisions between and within the (structurally defined) classes of capital and labor, is the influence of place. This may form a basis for the formation of groups which specify their unifying interests in terms of shared location, either within or cutting across structurally defined class boundaries. Thus space, place, and the organization of social groups, united by a concern with or attachment to a particular locality (be it a factory, neighborhood, or national state), can and in practice persistently and almost without exception do play a key role in the historical processes of social class formation and organization. Differentiation on the basis of location in space thereby ceases to be something to be appended following the completion of a class analysis, and comes to be regarded as a potentially decisive element in the identification of class interests. It is the recognition of the potentially central role of territorial attachments in actual class formation in Giddens’ work that makes it of interest here. While stressing the necessity to ground analysis of capitalist societies in their time-space constitution, Giddens does not focus upon the relationships between spatial uneven development within (as opposed to between) national states, attachment to localities, and the processes of capital accumulation in the way that we seek to do here, however. Loca- tion in space must cease to be one way of differentiating between groups within a class once the latter has been formed; rather, the point of departure is a recognition that class interests, organizations, and practices actually (and usually) within capi- talism are formulated at least in part with respect to particular localities. This is especially so at a time when capitals’ strategies for internationalizing production are accelerating so that the options available to them in fragmenting opposition by playing off workers in an increasing number of areas are growing rapidly. From this perspective, an important dimension of differentiation (and so a pos- sible basis for competition) between capital and labor, between capitals, or between groups of wage laborers and those linked to them, is location in and attachment to place. Similarly, identification with national territories or supra or subnational ter- CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 295 ritorial units can form the basis or bases for a cross-class identification of interests. It is important to acknowledge, however, that the mechanisms involved in the devel- opment of attachment to and identification with territorial units will vary with scale and that even if these all constitute “imagined communities” what is crucial is “the style in which they are imagined” (Anderson, 1983, p. 15). The way in which such communities are “imagined” is grounded in the daily routine of life in those places, perhaps most vividly in single industry towns (for example, Williamson, 1982; Douglass and Krieger, 1983). It is perhaps not surprising, therefore, that territorially defined competition within the (structurally defined) class of labor can be particularly acute. What is surprising is that much Marxist writing upon issues such as the uneven development of capitalism, while accepting a differentiated view of capital as many competitive capitals, tends to cling (even if only implicitly) to a utopian view of a working class as unified across ter- ritorial boundaries by a recognition of its real class interests. While at a deep struc- tural level, this unity of class interests undoubtedly does exist within and across capitalist societies, the real point at issue is to explain why it is not seen in these terms by the relevant agents who perceive their interests in different ways, which then become the basis for particular forms of social organization and practice that become a central element in the uneven development of capitalism.

Defending Places: The Strategies of Capital, Labor, and the State The necessity for an appropriate theoretical specification of the links between agency, structure, and attachment to place and class is sharply revealed when cap- itals restructure their activities so as to combat their own crises or to further their own self-expansion. For as Harvey (1982, especially pp. 425–31) has put it, deval- orization is and must be place-specific. The validity of this proposition has been sharply brought home to groups of workers throughout the history of capitalism, but it has been particularly accentuated since the transition from a long-period phase of expansion to one of recession in the capitalist world economy in the last decade or so (for example, Mandel, 1980; Frank, 1980). It is this transition, and with it the growing recognition that the option of reindustrialization via state regional poli- cies, which could be presented as having some credibility in the 1960s but is widely seen as having no possibility of success in the “old” industrial regions in the 1980s, that has been important in triggering anti-closure campaigns. Seen from the point of view of workers, their families and dependents in such places, the only feasible solution often appears to be to fight to preserve their factory, their mine, for their community or region, in the sure knowledge that should their struggle be an unsuc- cessful one then the jobs lost will not be replaced, while the price of success will be the closure of some other factory or mine, a threat to some other group of workers and their community, their place. Accepting the competitive ethic of capitalism in this way as a legitimate terrain, and fighting on a territorially defined basis within it, rather than posing broader questions as to why restructuring is regarded as either necessary or justified given its extensive social costs, has the precise (albeit unin- tended) effect of reproducing the basic structural relations of capitalism. Groups of workers consequently compete with one another, sometimes on the basis of cross- class territorial alliances, for the privilege of being able successfully to sell their 296 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER labor-power in the marketplace and their places on the place market (Robinson and Sadler, 1985). Put another way, a concern with more general class solidarity, even if this is recognized, is subordinated to a more immediate concern with living and working in a localized, spatially delimited community, in a particular place. The place-specific campaigns to contest steel closures in the European Commu- nity (EC) in recent years illustrate the variety of ways in which this defense of place has been contested, in the course of which identification with place and class have been contingently combined in different times and places, and in which capitals and states have sought to secure their interests in closing steel capacity and restructur- ing production (Hudson and Sadler, 1983a, 1983b; Morgan, 1983). For in relation to changes in the global pattern of accumulation and the international division of labor in bulk steel production, Western European steel producers have attempted to restore competitiveness and profits, or at least stem hemorrhaging losses, by closing capacity and/or drastically cutting employment in localities which, because of the historical development of the steel industry, depended very heavily upon steel production as a source of wages and employment. The high level of state involvement in the EC – both at the level of national states and the embryonic supranational EC itself – has meant that the locationally concentrated collapse of employment has frequently been perceived, correctly, as a transparently “political” decision rather than simply as the outcome of the logic of “economic” processes and the forces of the market. This deep attachment to such places, built up through generations living, learning, and working in them, was largely taken for granted until such times as the threat of major employment loss with the prospect of no comparable replacement became apparent. For this (and other) reasons such job losses have generally been contested in a variety of ways. These protests have them- selves become an active moment in the restructuring process, in shaping which steel- works will close as steelworkers have been divided, or more accurately, have divided themselves, on a plant or regional or national basis to fight for the survival of their works at the expense of others. A particularly stark example of this process was the unsuccessful campaign mounted in 1979 and 1980 to save Consett steelworks in northeast England. This was confined solely to the town of Consett itself and saw steelworkers there isolated both from a wider basis of support within the region and from other steelworks in the northeast and elsewhere, as the “Save Consett” campaign was contested solely on the grounds that it was a profitable steelworks, that its closure was “a grave commercial error” (J. Carney, cited in Hudson and Sadler, 1983a) and, by implication, that it should remain open and some other steelworks within the British Steel Corporation (BSC) should close. At no stage in the campaign was the decisive reason for its proposed closure, BSC’s plans to cut overall capacity, and their relation to the political strategies of the UK central government raised or con- tested. Moreover, even in those cases where there was initially a more marked degree of unity between steelworkers at national level, as in France in the late 1970s where protests against plant closures in Lorraine and the Nord were supported by national strike action, this subsequently crumbled to leave individual plants at best fighting in isolation, at worst competing with one another for survival. In this case, the poli- cies of the French state in terms of differential redundancy payments, differential allocations of resources supposedly to attract new industries and alternative employ- CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 297 ment in areas affected by steel closures, and so on played an important role in frag- menting steelworkers on a plant and regional basis (see Hudson and Sadler, 1983b). In general, the ways in which steelworkers in these localities identified their inter- ests as place specific and organized to protect them ultimately involved setting them- selves in competition with other groups of steelworkers in an attempt to secure some employment. The particular ways in which these campaigns evolved cannot be divorced from the history of trades union organization in the steel industry in France and the UK, with the latter case in particular being characterized by strong tendencies to inter-plant competition and regional chauvinism. Nevertheless, despite the rather specific combination of contemporary and historical circumstances sur- rounding the steel industry in these two nations in the late 1970s, it would be extremely misleading to leave the impression that territorially based competition between groups of workers is an atypical form of contesting proposed plant clo- sures. Quite the reverse, in fact; it has become increasingly the norm as plant com- petes with plant, increasingly across not just regional but national boundaries and within a particular transnational corporation. Furthermore, as the recent history of the steel industry within the EC makes clear, competition between groups of workers in different localities is by no means the only approach to contesting closures. For such closure proposals can also come to form the basis of territorially based alliances, formed for the specific purpose of opposing closures, embracing a broader spectrum of social groups and interests and cutting across (structurally defined) class boundaries. Such alliances can be con- structed, for example, because locally based and tied small capitals in retailing and various private service sector activities become aware of the threat to their existence as capitals in those particular places, one that is posed by the imminent precipitous decline of purchasing power that accompanies mass job loss. Once formed, their subsequent development or dissolution becomes integrally involved in the com- petitive struggles to preserve particular plants as the defense of place, of common territorially defined interests, transcends, at least for a time, (structurally defined) antagonistic class relations. Three examples will be given of this. The first concerns opposition to steel closures in Lorraine, in France. Partly reflecting a strong sense of regional identity of being Lorrainese, a result of the region’s history of being alternately transferred between France and Germany, the regionally based bourgeoisie recognized the threat to their interests posed by steel closures and began to organize against them before the steelworkers and unions did. An organization, the Avenir du Pays Haut (APH), was formed with the specific intention of protecting the Lorrainese economy. It played an important role in broadening the social basis of protests against steel closures, at least until February 1979, after which time the onset of violent protests by autonomous groups of steel- workers operating outside the structure and authority of the steel unions challenged the legitimacy of the French state’s monopoly of the means of violence. From this point, the APH increasingly distanced itself from the anti-closure protests (Hudson and Sadler, 1983b). The second example relates to the defense of Ravenscraig steelworks in Scotland. Speculation as to the future of the works grew in the autumn of 1982, against a background of debate about whether BSC could continue to operate its five major integrated production complexes. A broadly based campaign to oppose the threat 298 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER of closure rapidly developed, embracing not only steelworkers but also groups of workers from other industries in other parts of Scotland. Moreover, drawing on a history of nationalist sentiment in Scotland and an attachment to Scotland as a place with shared, socially endowed meanings that cut across class and other social divi- sions (for example, Smith and Brown, 1983), the campaign developed to involve a much broader spectrum of class interests and to encompass a wide social basis within Scotland. One important element in it was a powerful cross-party Scottish parliamentary lobby, presented with ammunition by a report of the Parliamentary Committee for Scottish Affairs on the significance of the Ravenscraig plant to the Scottish economy. Such was the breadth and strength of the campaign to preserve Ravenscraig that, despite the fact that it was costing BSC £100 million per annum to keep Ravenscraig open, its future was guaranteed as a steel-making plant until 1985. Even if this turns out to be only temporary, what the success of the 1982–3 campaign demonstrates is that, in certain conditions, territorially based alliances can force a recognition of the fact that, ultimately, closure decisions are political rather than merely narrowly economic (see Sadler, 1984). The third example is more complicated, also involving individual plant, region- alist, and nationalist dimensions. It relates to Hoesch’s decision to end steel-making at Dortmund, in the eastern part of the Ruhr in West Germany. The course of this (unsuccessful) campaign was strongly conditioned by the merger in the 1960s of Hoesch with the Dutch steel company, Hooghoven, and the subsequent breakup of the union of the two companies in the early 1980s. Fears about the ending of steel- making in Dortmund in 1980 led to the formation of a broad cross-class alliance, the Burgerinitiative Stahlwerk, in an attempt to guarantee the continuation of steel production in Dortmund rather than its further concentration at Hooghoven’s coastal Ijmuidenworks, with Dortmund reduced simply to a steel rolling plant. The broad social base of the protest movement soon dissipated in 1981, however, partly because it had led to the focus of attention being switched to the provision of alter- native employment rather than the preservation of steel-making, with the movement to contest the closure proposals becoming much more centered on the Dortmund works and steelworkers. The separation of Hoesch and Hooghoven led to both a revival and a redirection of protest, amid an atmosphere of considerable uncertainty about the proposed restructuring of steel production in West Germany involving the major steel groups (Krupp and Thyssen). Having got rid of the Dutch connection, the way was open to the Dortmund branch of the IG Metall Union to propose, in December 1982, a complete nationalization of West Germany’s steel industry as a means of securing Dortmund’s future. (Even though the union at national level was opposed to nationalization, a compromise between local and national levels was agreed whereby proposed government financial aid would take the form of it acquir- ing share capital in the steel companies.) Thus the definition of place altered as the campaign evolved, changing from one that began as a regionally based cross-class protest movement to one with a narrower basis centered on steelworkers in Dortmund itself, and eventually ending up by proposing a national solution as the route to preserving steel-making at Dortmund and, by implication, unity of inter- ests between steelworkers in different plants in West Germany. There is, then, considerable evidence simply from this review of campaigns against steel closures in the EC of groups within the (structurally defined) working CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 299 class becoming involved in territorially based cross-class alliances in attempts to pursue what they perceive to be their interests. In fact, there is much more evidence which suggests that historically this process of the formation of such territorially based groupings trying to further the interests of their place has become a persist- ent one within capitalist societies, a central feature of the reproduction of spatial uneven development within and between them that is deeply embedded in the social practices that are central to their reproduction. Thus groups within the working class become actively involved in the forging of territorially defined alliances, at a variety of spatial scales, unified by their organization around or mediated in a variety of ways through capitalist states. Three examples, at differing spatial scales, will suffice to illustrate the point. At national scale, the formation of cross-class agree- ments around proposals to nationalize particular branches of industry hinges on a perception of shared interests by some capitals, some elements of labor and the state: for example, in the UK case, the nationalizations of coal, railways, and steel were all seen as satisfying these varying (and ultimately contradicting) interests (Hudson, 1986). It is significant that subsequent decisions to close plants in such nationalized industries have been among the most strongly contested. At a regional scale, the formation of cross-class alliances around a shared perception of the need to modernize old industrial regions by public sector investment programs to build new industrial estates, factories, roads, commercial centers, houses, and so on, provid- ing both fresh opportunities for capitals to reap profits and new employment and better living conditions for some members of the working class, became a recurrent feature of contemporary capitalism, especially in the 1960s. It was a crucial reason why works closures then were generally not contested in the way that they were in the late 1970s and early 1980s. For example, such agreements are discernible in Scotland, Wales, and the peripheral regions of England from the late 1950s (for example, Hudson, 1986) and more generally in Western Europe (Hudson and Lewis, 1982) and the USA (Clavel, 1982), though their roots are often traceable to the interwar years (Carney and Hudson, 1978). At the same time, in so far as such policies are tied to intraregional settlement policies, as is commonly the case, concentrating new public sector investment in terms of general conditions of production and collective consumption within regions (into selected “growth points,” “growth zones,” etc.), then their effect is to en- courage intraregional divisions on a territorial basis. This arises both because of competition to achieve growth-center designation and because of the divisions engendered between those localities which achieve this and those which do not. Thus the promulgation and implementation of state policies, the formally pro- claimed aims of which are to reduce interregional inequalities in employment oppor- tunities and living conditions, presuppose increasing intraregional fragmentation as alliances of interests tied to particular localities form to promote the interests of their particular place. Perhaps the most extreme example of such intraregional growth point policies is that of the UK New Towns. New Town developments in the UK involve the establishment of non-elected development corporations, with a considerable degree of autonomy, cutting across the networks of local political power and control exercised via democratically elected local authorities. In some circumstances, this itself can become a focus for uniting opposition to them within areas (for example, see Robinson, 1983); in others it has served more or less to unite 300 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER local authorities and local political opinion around coalitions to strive for a New Town in or near their area so as to secure new jobs, better living conditions, and so on. The final example, to a degree already presaged in the inter and intraregional competition outlined above, refers to the UK in the 1970s. Central government’s macroeconomic policies have increasingly been to rely on the market as a steering mechanism, and cut back the scope of regional and urban policy initiatives as part of a more general drive to cut public expenditure and roll back the boundaries of the state itself. As this occurs, cross-class alliances have increasingly formed around the structures of local government (metropolitan, county, and district councils) in defense of the local economy (see Cochrane, 1983). One particularly revealing symptom of competition for jobs between local areas has been the intense lobbying to achieve Enterprise Zone status and so, supposedly, a competitive edge over one’s rival areas. Furthermore, as ad hoc employment creation agencies such as British Steel (Industry) have proliferated as part of a cosmetic response by national states to place-specific industrial decline, a similar pattern of competition has been set in motion as places strive for the attention of these new organizations. In summary, then, the “normal” pattern of social organization within capitalist societies is one that chronically involves competition between territorially defined groups attempting to promote the interests of “their place.” It is not the case that territory replaces class as a basis of social organization and practice but rather that identification with and attachment to place itself becomes integrally involved in the process of class formation. Place and class become contingently related in a complex manner as bases for social organization and thus pivotally involved in the repro- duction of spatial uneven development within capitalist societies. Thus the defense of place becomes central to the reproduction of those societies as capitalist as an unintended consequence of campaigns to defend or promote the interests of specific places (whether village, town, region, or national state) in competition with other places.

Routinization, Deroutinization, and the Reproduction of Capitalist Societies A central element in Giddens’ theory of structuration is that of the routine, taken- for-granted character of much social interaction within capitalist societies. In this sense, they are routinely, though contingently, reproduced (Giddens, 1981). What is central to the reproduction of capitalist societies as capitalist, then, is the normal routine of “going to work,” presupposing as it usually (though by no means always) does the separation of home and workplace in time-space. Put slightly differently, what is central is the normative acceptance by people working for a wage within them of their class position as wage labor (of whatever level of qualification), thereby simultaneously accepting, affirming, and reproducing the decisive central axis of the contradictory structural relationship between capital and labor. A corollary of this, however, is that when such people become unemployed – when what has been accepted as the normal routine becomes “deroutinized” – then this might lead them to question the legitimacy of their class position, particularly CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 301 given the close links within capitalist societies between being able to earn a wage, and lifestyle and living conditions. The effects of such deroutinization are obviously severe at the individual level, but when they affect comparatively few individuals in a period of full employment it is usually possible for bourgeois accounts to prevail, generally pointing the finger at individual failings or weakness as the cause of unem- ployment. Where such deroutinization creates mass unemployment in whole local- ities, with thousands of people losing their jobs as a result of a single and necessarily place-specific devalorization decision by a capital or a national state, then one might reasonably anticipate a challenge to such accounts and a rather different reaction from those adversely affected. Such collectively experienced and simultaneously imposed deroutinization might lead those made redundant to raise questions about the legitimacy of their class position which left them vulnerable, exposed to bearing the costs of decisions over which they could exercise no effective control; or if not to raise this question, then at least to fight for the right to work, albeit as wage labor. Furthermore, one might expect the strength of protests against such imposed deroutinization to be strongest in those communities that substantially depend upon one industry (such as coal or steel) as their source of employment for wage labor, a fortiori when the relevant industries are nationalized, formally subject to a logic of politics rather than of the market, so that the normal separation of the economic and political spheres in capitalist societies is broken and these are seen to be reconnected. Giddens (1981) has pointed out that we can learn a good deal about day-to-day life in routine settings from analyzing circumstances in which it is radically dis- turbed. His point is neatly illustrated by the various examples referred to above of how threats to the everyday lives of members of the working class have frequently been contested, though not necessarily in ways that have raised questions as to the legitimacy of their class position. Rather than question the legitimacy of the class structural relation between capital and labor, and in particular the class position of working people as wage laborers, the struggles by territorially defined groups of workers to fight for their jobs transform the contest into one between such groups for a share of those jobs that are offered on the labor market. So, for example, there is conflict between different groups of workers within a factory or mine over dif- ferential levels of redundancy payments and therefore over whether to accept or contest proposals for closure. Or there is conflict between plants in different places (regions within a nation-state or different nation-states) for such wage labor employ- ment as capital offers on the market. Furthermore, in particular circumstances this competition for jobs can develop on a broader social basis, from simply the groups of workers directly affected into one based on cross-class alliances. While in general we would accept Giddens’ critique of functionalist social theories which presuppose a normative consensus among social agents, in so far as members of the working class fight in various ways to preserve their status as wage labor there is little evi- dence to support his claim that “those in subordinate positions in a society, par- ticularly those in large-scale societies, may frequently be much less closely caught within the embrace of consensual ideologies than many writers . . . assume” (1981, p. 67). Whether their position as wage labor is willingly accepted is another matter, but in so far as it is accepted, it is central to the reproduction of capitalist societies as capitalist. 302 RAY HUDSON AND DAVID SADLER

Moreover, this territorially defined struggle for employment between groups of workers (and maybe their allies) in particular localities often takes on an additional dimension. Characteristically it can encompass competition for a greater share of state resources for the acquisition of new jobs as well as the defense of “old” ones. Indeed, this has become a persistent feature of contemporary capitalist societies and integrally involves capitalist states in a variety of ways: one diagnostic symptom is the identification of a variety of spatially defined problems (for example, inner city or regional problems, or problems of national economic or industrial development) as various groups press their case for special treatment for their areas. Thus the variety of state spatial policies is to be interpreted not simply in terms of some mech- anistic response to the need(s) of capital(s), or as symptomatic of a bad case of false consciousness on the part of members of the (structurally defined) working class, but rather as something fought for by the labor movement, by groups within the working class in such areas, as they rationally engage in forms of social practice intended to further their own interests. Moreover, this is not simply a struggle con- ducted by such groups within the state as an immutable object, but rather an attempt by them to redefine what are seen as the justified boundaries to the activities of the state in such a way as to protect or further their (territorially specified) interests. It is correct, however, to point out that these spatial policies tend to take their most potent form within capitalist societies when the perception of working-class groups of their interests is coincident with the perception of some capitals or the relevant national state of their interests. The regional modernization programs in the 1960s in parts of the UK (the northeast of England, Scotland, and Wales, for example), together with what is generally regarded as the strengthening of regional policy by the Labour central government in the UK in the same period and its subsequent dis- mantling after 1979 by the Conservative government, exemplify this point well. Nevertheless, the actual outcome of these heightened processes of state involve- ment has been to reinforce tendencies toward competition for “new” jobs between territorially defined groups within the working class and their party political repre- sentatives, sometimes in the context of cross-class alliances. More and more, this competition has been intensified and conducted within the corporate structures of transnational capitals on an increasingly global market for labor power and pro- duction sites as part of a new and evolving international division of labor. Increas- ingly, localities must engage in a bitter and divisive struggle to sell themselves to capitals as the most desirable location for their activities in an attempt to defend the right to live, learn, and work in their place.

Some Concluding Comments Deep attachments to place in Western Europe’s “old” industrial regions (and else- where) are grounded in the routine of everyday life there. The emergence from the late 1970s onward of campaigns to defend the right to live, learn, and work in them reflects their heavy reliance on a single industry as a source of jobs and wages, coupled with a perception of the minimal opportunities for the introduction of new sources of employment should the “traditional” industries disappear. Characteris- tically, these campaigns have conjoined attachment to place and class in complex and shifting ways, and have been conducted on the basis of attempts to promote CONTESTING WORKS CLOSURES 303 the interests of one (“our”) place at the expense of other (“their”) places. Never- theless, it is important to remember that these sorts of contingent class–place rela- tions as a basis for the defense of the place-defined interests of particular social groups are clearly ones that are associated with the legacy of a territorial division of labor associated with much earlier rounds of capitalist accumulation. It is pre- cisely this material basis for the cultural tradition associated with successive gener- ations living, learning, and working in the one-industry places, thrown up by the historical geography of capitalist development in old industrial regions, that has been and is being removed by the changing intranational and international divisions of labor and the hyper-mobile switching of investment between locations which to their inhabitants are deeply meaningful places but to capitals are merely another piece of space offering possibilities for profitable production. The net unintended result to date of these various forms of competition to defend particular places between territorially defined groups is doubly to reinforce the hege- monic position of capital as the dominant and decisive social relation. Not only is wage labor legitimated by working-class people competing for the chance to be able to sell their labor power, but to be without the possibility to sell one’s labor power (with all that this entails in capitalist societies) is equally recognized as legitimate. To this extent, spatial uneven development is not only an integral part of the devel- opment of capitalism, but one that involves working-class people as rational agents, rather than passive cultural dupes, even if the unintended effects of how they engage in social practice in pursuit of their own interests are to reproduce their class posi- tion as labor power. Chapter 19 Class and Gender Relations in the Local Labor Market and the Local State

Ruth Fincher

The local labor market and the local state contribute significantly to the way in which class and gender are experienced by residents and workers in urban com- munities. They are not independent of one another. The provisions of governments in local areas (part of the local state), in public transport and child day-care, for example, permit people to undertake paid work outside the home. In this sense the spatial scope of local labor markets is defined by virtue of their accessibility to people who must be sustained in paid work by community-based services. More- over, the hours of operation of paid workplaces and their requirements of workers influence the extent to which existing public services are useful for those workers. It is important to emphasize the obvious point that in people’s daily lives the paid work available and the community services that can be used are utterly interrelated. The many analyses that separate production in local labor markets and social repro- duction in the use of community services cannot do this. This chapter aims to indicate some of the characteristics emerging in the local labor markets and local states of Melbourne, and their implications for the forma- tion of class and gender relations. It has the following structure. First, it discusses how the practices of the local state and the nature of the local labor market may structure people’s experience of class and gender. In the second section, some of the characteristics of Melbourne’s local labor markets are presented, with suggestions for the different and similar class and gender experiences associated with them in different parts of the metropolitan area. Section three documents some of the pri- orities of local states in Melbourne, and how these priorities are being influenced by changes in federal social policy.

Class and Gender Relations Theoretical statements usually differentiate class formation – a conscious process of grouping into class collectivities, from class structure – a formal map of class posi- tions in a society, and how many people could be said to hold positions in the capitalist class, the working class, and the middle class (see Wright, 1985). Class CLASS AND GENDER RELATIONS 305 formation is based in varying degrees on class structure, but is never entirely inde- pendent of it. Embodied in both the process of class formation and the map of class structure are class relations; these are the social relationships between people in the paid workplace, the community, and the home, through which they experience class (the unequal relationship between capital and labor in a capitalist society), even if they do not consciously give their experiences that label. Many of the circumstances affecting the experience of class are institutional fea- tures particular to a time and place that differentiate the population along lines not directly identifiable as class-based. Harvey (1975a) long ago termed these features of class structuration, and listed them as the division of labor, the consumption habits and authority relations of a time and place, and the institutional and ideo- logical barriers to mobility there (Harvey, 1975a, p. 362). This chapter seeks to identify emerging gendered divisions or groupings within Melbourne’s working class that are being produced through class structuration (via the local labor market, and the local state with its authority over forms of community social reproduction), and the sorts of class relations they seem to embody. The changing class relations of the paid workforce in contemporary capitalist cities have been noted by many authors (Massey, 1984; Massey and Meegan, 1982). They include the casualization, marginalization, and peripheralization of large groups within the traditional working class, e.g., male manufacturing workers. New class relations are appearing as well within groups like part-time women workers, and between them and other segments of the paid labor force. It is now quite widely accepted that the reproduction of labor power that occurs in the home and the com- munity, and the fact that household members are often workers in the paid labor force as well as workers in the household and community, draw class relations into the household and community as well. Class relations exist in a wide range of daily activities, then, and through a number of strands of class structuration. Class rela- tions, class formation, and the means of class structuration that affect them both, are profoundly spatial phenomena; they are restricted or facilitated through use and reproduction of spatial structures. Now, gender relations are the socially constructed relationships between men and women. I suppose analysts committed to the theoretical primacy of class categories over gender categories would term gender relations one form of class structuration; others would champion the primacy of socially constructed gender roles over class as the basis of many everyday experiences. The point is not just to “add on” gender to class, to adhere feminist concerns to historical materialist ones, but rather to accept the need for an expanded and reworked concept of a mode of production, wherein the production of labor power stands on an equally basic footing with the production of the means of production and subsistence (Livingstone et al., 1982, p. 9). This conceptual intermeshing, as well, emphasizes that men’s and women’s activities in the paid workforce, in the household or family, and in the community are not separate spheres but are mutually interrelated. At the simplest level, the time–space requirements of getting to and being at work restrict people’s opportu- nities to act elsewhere. But less tangible aspects of the social relations of one “sphere” affect the social relations of another “sphere”: for example, a rigid hier- archy in the paid workplace, and strict sex segregation in occupations there, may 306 RUTH FINCHER have implications for the assumption or allocation of tasks and responsibilities in the household of a worker undertaking paid work in that workplace.

The Local Labor Market How is the structuring of class and gender relations affected by the (changing) char- acteristics of local labor markets? First, consider how local labor markets have dif- ferent characteristics; second, how these may encourage the formation of particular class and gender relations in certain contexts; and third, how changes in economic and other relations may alter all this, and what form some such recently noted changes have taken. Local labor markets will often have different characteristics, related to the par- ticular industrial and occupational sectors represented in them. Associated with a predominantly manufacturing local economy may be a sexual division of labor and a set of labor processes unlike those of a local economy dominated by personal service provision or tourism. The particular economic base of a local labor market will be important in determining its fate in a time of economic restructuring: tradi- tional manufacturing centers have been hard hit since the 1970s in a number of capitalist countries, as the literature on the deindustrialization of the American northeast and the English north demonstrates. At the same time as traditional manu- facturing areas and their predominantly male full-time workforces are experiencing dislocation in the present economic circumstances, other forms of production are emerging and other social groups are finding work, albeit work of different char- acteristics. Particularly, female participation in the paid labor force is increasing, and is often associated with increasing numbers of part-time jobs. The dominance of certain employment sectors and forms of work does not deter- mine the class and gender relations of communities, regions, or nations. If this were the case, we would find identical social relations in places with similar economic bases. Rather, continuing economic changes combine with traditions forged out of histories of economic, political, and social interaction in a place, on the part of its long-term residents and indeed on the part of immigrants too. Massey (1984) con- ceived of layers of past economic and social relationships underlying and influenc- ing the present circumstances of a region. Of importance, too, is the degree to which collective action by local residents and workers can transform local circumstances, despite or in sympathy with exogenous changes. The challenges to existing class and gender relations in manufacturing commu- nities caused by recent economic upheavals have included: (a) fewer jobs exist in traditional manufacturing. Youth unemployment in places dependent on such jobs is now accompanied increasingly by the unemployment of middle-aged men who had been full-time factory workers. Though the decline of manufacturing in a community does not imply the appearance of a service sector employment base (Murgatroyd et al., 1985, ch. 1), the part-time employment of women, especially in jobs classified as “services,” has increased over this period. In some areas, then, one may expect to find a change in the gender characteristics of the workforce in paid employment. (b) This has implications for the characteristics of the unionized labor force, which has traditionally been male-dominated (and often male-centered), and unfavorably disposed towards part-time work. A change in the gender and nature CLASS AND GENDER RELATIONS 307 of the workforce and paid work done, then, will see changes in the proportion of the paid labor force that is organized in the traditional manner. (c) Outwork, or homework, is on the increase. A large number of jobs are being performed from the home and there is every indication that this will increase. Across metropolises, where communities traditionally dependent on manufac- turing are juxtaposed with residential suburbs that are also the sites of retail and office development, it appears that women in part-time work in those businesses are also becoming more numerous. And as flexible accumulation grows, a mode of profit-making in which production is disaggregated and spatially decentralized to different communities and households, so suburban residential sites that previously were locations of consumption are the new production sites as well (Nelson, 1986; Harvey, 1987). New social relations will emerge from the placement of these new groups of workers and new forms of employment into any local circumstances, but changes will be especially dramatic where they accompany decline in traditional ways of making a living. Women and men are doing different forms of paid work: their relationships with each other in the workplace and in the home and commu- nity will change because of this. New alliances within the working class will emerge from this, and old ones perhaps disappear.

The Local State The local state is interpreted here as the sphere of political relations associated with the local practice of government (see Fincher, 1987). Studies of the local state there- fore include studies of those community conflicts that are associated with the state apparatus and its policies as well as studies of the state apparatus that acts with respect to localities. Clearly, the local state is a sphere of relationships that contains class and gender relations, and can influence their formation or change elsewhere. Consider the following ways the local state (the apparatus and associated political conflicts) influences class and gender relations in paid work and its community support. First, the local state, through its direct provision (or contract provision, to for- profit firms or charities) of public services to people in paid work who have depend- ents (children, the elderly), affects the degree to which some people can participate in the paid labor force, quite apart from whether or not employment opportunities are available locally. If suitable child day-care and after-school programs, or domi- ciliary care for elderly dependents of potential labor force participants, are not avail- able, then those individuals involved in caring will be unable to take up waged work. Second, the local state may, through its direct involvement in employment creation schemes, cause scheme participants to experience work in new ways, and may decrease the incidence of unemployment amongst certain local groups (e.g., women, youth). Third, through its facilitation of different forms of built environment change, the local state can change the nature of work in communities and the demand for public services there, through a change in the nature of the local resi- dent and workforce population. The classic case of this is gentrification, for example the situation in which an alliance of the local state and a major developer locates a luxury waterfront development of offices and expensive, high-density housing in an inner city working-class neighborhood. 308 RUTH FINCHER

A large international literature on the restructuring of the welfare state in advanced capitalist countries since the mid-1970s indicates a ubiquitous reduction in central government financing of, and responsibility for, human services (see Mishrah, 1984; Dear and Wolch, 1987). To the extent that these reductions have locational effects, and are influential in causing local service providers to reduce or change human service provisions, then the local state is involved. Generous provi- sion of child day-care and domiciliary care for elderly dependents would allow more women (especially, as they are the traditional “minders”) to participate in paid work, or at least to have more flexibility in doing so. Reductions in human service provisions supporting people in paid work, and the increasing cost of services like child day-care, are most likely to return women to the home by reducing their options to work outside it. Though the local state is often seen largely as a service provider, as a set of insti- tutions involved in the reproduction of labor power and the provision of collective consumption goods (see Fincher, 1987), local state institutions are becoming involved in employment creation schemes, usually on a fairly small scale. The social- ist municipalities of Britain have made their mark here (Boddy and Fudge, 1984). As these and other initiatives show, the activities of the local state have implications for the nature of class and gender relations, as do the activities of employers in the local labor market. Furthermore, the local state influences accessibility to the labor market, and the local labor market creates needs for certain types of public service provision. The local state can be a player in the local labor market through its devel- opment of local employment schemes; local businesses can provide community services to support people in paid work, either through employee benefits like work-based day-care, or through being in the business of for-profit human service provision.

Melbourne’s Local Labor Markets This section describes Australian, and then Melbourne’s, contemporary labor market characteristics. It goes on to hypothesize the labor market sources of local class and gender relations found in the eastern and western suburbs of Melbourne. Melbourne’s local labor markets embody many national trends. These national trends show Australia to be quite like other advanced capitalist countries: its labor market characteristics indicate increasing marginalization in paid work for some employees. The following are Australia’s recent labor market features.

(1) Unemployment has risen drastically in Australia since the mid-1970s. This increase has not been shared equally across different social and economic groups, according to their share of labor force participation. Youth, non- English speaking migrants and women have suffered high relative unemploy- ment, this of course relating to their concentration in particular industries whose labor requirements have decreased. (2) There have been different trends since 1966 in full-time and part-time paid labor force participation. Male full-time participation rates have decreased sharply since 1976 and male part-time rates have risen but not offset the full- time rate decreases; female paid labor force participation has increased since CLASS AND GENDER RELATIONS 309

1966, 90 percent of it in part-time work. Married females accounted for all this increase. (3) Over half the new jobs created since 1973 have been part-time, many of them in community services and retailing. That many of these jobs have gone to women reflects the significant sex segregation of the Australian labor force. (4) The labor market is further segmented, particularly in Melbourne and Sydney, along another axis relating to the recency of migration of workers, and whether they have non-English speaking backgrounds. (5) The number of people working at home now forms a significant portion of Australia’s paid labor force.

Different parts of Melbourne exhibit these national trends in different degrees: jobs have been growing and declining in number, and changing in type, in different locations within the metropolis. The early 1960s saw “suburbanization” of the considerable job growth in Melbourne. Manufacturing employment was expanding in the east, away from the traditional manufacturing base of the western suburbs. This eastern suburban movement was compounded by commercial job growth between 1966 and 1971, though the inner city also regained some jobs in the early 1980s. The eastern sector’s job growth rates were the highest in the period for each industry category. There was some disparity, too, between the location of jobs and the location of workers’ residences. Workers have been moving to the outer suburbs faster than jobs, which are still tending to concentrate in the middle ring suburbs. New offices are locating in the middle eastern suburbs, and more recently in the outer east of the metropolitan area. The disproportionate growth of suburban jobs in the east, compared to the west, is a major difficulty in a large urban area in which regional laborsheds are relatively independent. It is certainly a problem for those without access to a car, and for those whose preferences have been to work locally (traditionally women and blue-collar workers). What changes in class and gender relations are revealed in the local geographies of the labor market in Melbourne? First, manufacturing workers have in the past been concentrated in western Melbourne. Therefore the decline in manufacturing jobs in the traditional industries and the reappearance of new manufacturing jobs elsewhere (beyond the labor market accessible to western suburbs workers) will be influencing the traditional, male-dominated working class of this region dispropor- tionately. Perhaps marginalization from class practices is increasing with the removal of men from the collective labor processes of the factory floor and the con- centration of women in isolating, long homework. Certainly, within households and communities in which males have traditionally held paid positions and women have not, there will be confrontations of class places and gender roles if men are now the unpaid workers. Second, in the outer eastern region of Melbourne there is a substantial but declin- ing proportion of the labor force in manufacturing jobs, and growth in the pro- portion of the workforce employed in services, clerical, and professional categories. In the inner east there is a lower and comparatively stable proportion of the popu- lation in manufacturing jobs, higher and relatively stable proportions of the work- force in sales, clerical, and services categories, and much larger workforce segments 310 RUTH FINCHER in professional and administrative jobs. Women dominate services and clerical occu- pations, as elsewhere. There are higher labor-force participation rates and lower unemployment rates for both men and women in the east than in the west. A higher percentage of women in the workforce works part-time there. And participation rates for women are increasing – probably because of the growing need for households to have two incomes to afford house mortgages. But it is likely that few new part- time service sector or clerical positions are in unionized occupational sectors, and that many jobs are casual or contract-based rather than salaried, permanent, and superannuated. In sum, we find national paid labor force trends exhibited in eastern and western Melbourne in different fashion. Some variations in the class and gender relations associated with these labor force trends have been hypothe- sized. These, of course, are general expectations. The precise experiences of class and gender in the different locations and workplaces of Melbourne are not indi- cated adequately by listing trends in occupational and industrial sector data. A range of other factors is relevant, their particular combination to be determined in field- work. But one institutional feature that, along with the changing local labor market, differentiates class and gender relations across the city is the local state, and to it we now turn.

Class and Gender Relations in the Local State A major contributor to the modes of social and economic reproduction in local areas is the local state. Though it does not have complete control over the range of public services available or affordable in an area or investment in jobs there, the appara- tus of the local state can influence aspects of economic and social opportunities. For example, local governments may take up or decline federal funds available to set up child day-care centers; they may start local employment creation initiatives or ignore this possibility. As one recent description of local government revenue and expenditure patterns explained: “some councils may decide it is not their role to house needy groups,” and “not all municipalities take full advantage of their local entitlements” (City of Camberwell, 1987, pp. 2, 5). The local state is also an arena of local social and political practices that may be channels for changing local class and gender relations – community support networks that help sustain people in paid work are often formed using the resources of local government and local state. Even participation in local community organizing against the local state might weld par- ticipants into new groups with new class insights. There is considerable variation across Melbourne in local government spending on matters that could form better community networks and better prospects for employment. But spatial differentiation in spending is more easily noted between outer and inner municipalities than between east and west. The size and adequacy of amounts spent on education, health, and social welfare depend in part on factors like the age structure of the local population (numbers of elderly, children, needy), income and employment levels. Since 1983 the federal Labor Government accepted major responsibility for increasing the supply of child day-care places, in contrast to administrations of the previous decade which emphasized that childcare was a family responsi- CLASS AND GENDER RELATIONS 311 bility and which directed most children’s services expenditure to pre-schools. A range of strategies enabled the increase in the supply of child day-care places during the mid-1980s. The major federal focus was on expansion of places in local government controlled child-care centers. Family day-care services (where individuals look after others’ children in their own homes) were continued, but not emphasized. Government funding of private sector, for-profit centers was avoided altogether, although funding of non-profit, non-government centers was introduced. In the mid-1980s, the focus of the federal government’s role in childcare shifted away from the maintenance of quality standards and the expansion of provision and towards a narrow concern with cost control. Previously, federal subsidies were based on institutionally bargained wages of qualified staff, thus setting staff stan- dards, and center fees were limited by a maximum recommended fee (White, 1986). Together with cuts in funding levels came a new system which established a ceiling of a certain weekly rate above which no federal subsidy will be paid. Service quality, usually regarded as a function of staff experience and training, must now be main- tained at the discretion of the centers and the state governments. If centers are to cover their costs, they must either use cheaper (less qualified) staff, or charge higher income parents higher fees than are necessary to cover the cost of the service those parents receive. Subsequently, the federal government indicated that family day-care services (cheaper, but long criticized for their exploitation of care-givers and lack of quality control) would be relied upon for further increase in the supply of child day-care places. The implication of these changes in federal policy is that the quality of centers will vary according to users’ ability to pay for them. Centers will perhaps become the day-care services of higher income users; family day-care providers and infor- mally organized care will perhaps cater to lower income users. Responsibility for enforcing standards will rest more with local and state governments, and will no doubt have to be prompted by continual lobbying: day-care services, their mainte- nance and extension, have been thrown back into the arena of political competi- tion. It is also, of course, most important to combine this insight with analysis of the workplaces where day-care of children is being done, and their class and gender relations. As family day-care is favored by government funding strategy, with its exploitative, outwork characteristics for women carers, a scenario can be depicted of women working outside the home exploiting women working as child carers within it. Withdrawals of the federal government from its previously high level of com- mitment to child day-care are not likely to prompt renewed investment in that service on the part of local government. Should “community management” models of child day-care provision emerge as a way of coping with federal withdrawal, then Mowbray’s (1984) comments must be kept in mind. He has argued that community-based and self-help strategies, that place the burden of social service provision on the “community,” usually in fact set that burden squarely on the shoul- ders of women and “the family”: they are often very conservative strategies. They do nothing to complement or support increased female participation in the labor force. Government provisions for adults who care for elderly dependents also illus- trate this point. 312 RUTH FINCHER

For the last two decades federal government policy in Australia has been to encourage community care of the dependent elderly. Concerns to deinstitutionalize the elderly, however, have been underlain by economic as well as humanitarian motives: some analysts have interpreted the federal government’s 1956 Home Nursing Subsidy Act and 1973 Domiciliary Nursing Care Benefit as less an indica- tion of the government’s willingness to pay for home-based care than of its desire to encourage more care within the community and the family (Kinnear and Graycar, 1982). The family, they say, is increasingly performing as a “hidden welfare service,” especially as community care becomes more favorably viewed in the public eye than institutional care (Kinnear and Graycar, 1983). Its costs to care-givers are hidden, as they are in family day-care provision. The general implication of a continuing government focus on community care as the most appropriate form of care for elderly dependents, and yet the lack of expanding financial support for this care, is no doubt clear. “The community” will assume the costs and burden of caring for its elderly residents; in practice, this means “the family” will have this responsibility, and in turn this means that women in the family will be care providers. A recent Australian survey of families caring in their homes for elderly relatives echoed the findings of overseas research that family care is usually synonymous with care by women, with little support from spouses, chil- dren, and the extended family (Kinnear and Graycar, 1982). A range of changes in carers’ lifestyles were observed, with most problems for carers associated with declining leisure activities, and deteriorated work performance, relationships with spouse and siblings, and sleeping patterns. Astoundingly, the survey showed that over 50 percent of the carers interviewed, all women, had given up jobs in the paid labor force in order to provide this care. Clearly “current concepts of community care build on traditional sex roles, and the practice continues a sexual division of labor which makes it a viable and cheap care alternative for the state” (Graycar and Harrison, 1984, p. 6). Now, there are considerable local spatial variations in access to care for elderly people, and also in access to services for family members caring for dependent relatives. These local variations occur despite the considerable financial involvement of the federal government in service provision which affects the whole of Australia. Howe (1986) shows how the presence of different sorts of providers (public, private, or voluntary sector) in localities dictates the availability of care there, as do the deci- sions of provider agencies to participate in particular programs. Non-institutional services, that is, community care, are overwhelmingly delivered by local govern- ment, and so are potentially universal in their provision. The range and quality of services in a municipality depends on local government’s financial capacity and its political will to match funds available from higher levels of government. This is especially true of services giving care to residents outside institutions, which are delivered by local governments. As with the trend in provision of child day-care services, it appears that the trend in community care for the dependent elderly is one where higher socioeconomic groups will obtain better service levels and where federal government policy will exacerbate this situation. The class and gender implications of this situation, for people working in the paid labor force who have dependent children or elderly rel- atives, are not entirely clear. For higher incomes and secure jobs do not guarantee CLASS AND GENDER RELATIONS 313 that accessible services for dependents will be available to their holders in a local- ity; this is up to decision-makers in service-providing agencies and organizations. Some local councils accord high priority to provision of these services for their residents, even if those residents are not articulate lobbyists; other councils need to be prodded continually and remain convinced that care of dependents needs council support. However, it does seem very clear that, across all regions of the city and income groups, women bear the major responsibility for dependents. Brennan and O’Donnell (1986) note in the case of child day-care, and Kinnear and Graycar (1982) in the case of care of elderly dependents, that women are the members of the household who most often take on less secure, less well paid and therefore more flexible work in order to meet the need for care of dependents. Federal expenditure on services for adults in the paid labor force, and policy to encourage the “com- munity” basis of care, seems to be reinforcing this reality. There are groups within the labor force that have particularly low access even to those few services available, however. Non-English speaking immigrants, for example, have been found to make less use of government-sponsored children’s services than have families in Australia as a whole (Pankhurst, 1984). This is attributed primarily to the limited information available about centers, to their hours of opening and locations being inappropriate – especially for shiftworkers. Surveys have dispelled the myth that recently immigrated families prefer informal care, and have exposed the anxiety felt by workers whose children have been left alone at home or who have had to make complex child-care arrangements that are constantly breaking down (Pankhurst, 1984). It seems to be the case, even in areas where formal day-care places are relatively numerous, that they are primarily patronized by middle-income, English-speaking Australians. Immigrant women have been less able to use one of the alternatives open to English-speaking women – community-controlled child-care cooperatives. These sorts of centers are only sus- tained by successful written submissions and frequent meetings, work that requires English language and writing skills (Loh, 1987). The class and gender relations of child day-care provision in the traditionally industrial western suburbs of Melbourne, whose workforce is ethnically very diverse, would reflect this special situation. Local government provision of services like child day-care and domiciliary care for the dependent elderly, which support adults participating in the paid labor force, is not even in their spatial distribution. The question of how to explain this uneven- ness is interesting: Why is it that some municipalities have better local government provision than others, some relying more on private or informal provision? Rather than just assuming service levels are set to meet “needs” or depend on the whim of individual bureaucrats, one promising alternative has been suggested by Mark- Lawson et al. (1985) in Britain. They have examined the history of women’s involve- ment in the political arena of the local state, drawing links between this and the provision of community support services. Though local differences may be revealed and explained in Melbourne, federal government changes in social policy threaten everywhere to reduce the accessibility of care for young and old dependents of workers. As these collective consumption goods take on “user pays” characteris- tics, they will be less affordable. The implications for women, the traditional “carers,” may be that they are less able to hold down secure employment: their 314 RUTH FINCHER home, community, and workplace circumstances will combine to alter their experi- ences of class and gender.

Conclusion This chapter has suggested ways in which the emerging characteristics of Melbourne’s local labor markets and the reactions of local states to the changing priorities of federal social policy may be affecting the class and gender relations experienced in different parts of the metropolitan area. In concentrating on the local labor market and the local state as two institutional features structur- ing locally experienced class and gender relations, it is easy to think of the labor market as the realm of profit-making firms and the large bureaucracies of the public and private sectors. Equally, it is tempting to regard the local state, especially that part of its apparatus that is local government, as the provider of collective con- sumption goods for social reproduction. There are two ways in which matters are more complex than this, and I want to raise them as important foci for further research. First, the local state, far from being only the site of the social reproduction of labor power, has direct effects on the class and gender relations of employment in some localities. British discussions, particularly, illustrate the activity of the state in the formation of urban enterprise zones and freeports, encouraging the relocation of employment opportunities. The involvement of the local state in local employ- ment initiatives, like those of London’s Greater London Council, can improve the experience of employment and its availability for people in some localities. To date, these are on such a small scale that they will have little impact on the overall nature of employment-based social relations. But local employment schemes, especially those based around notions of socially useful production, have very interesting implications for the way in which different workplace experiences can facilitate dif- ferent class and gender relations. There are hints in the Australian initiatives that special efforts may be made by branches of the state apparatus involved to improve the work opportunities and work experiences of women workers there. The involve- ment of the state in the local labor market, and the degree to which some work- places can be made the sites of better class and gender relations, is something which should not be overlooked in studies of the local state. The second point is related to the first. Provision of community services to adults who have dependents and who need those services in order to participate in the paid labor force, is a workplace issue as well as a service delivery use. Services are produced as well as consumed. So the other side of the coin that is marked with declining accessibility of childcare is the side that is marked with the exploitation of women outworkers who are picking up the task of caring for workers’ children on an informal basis. That there seems to be a gender bias in both aspects of the situation, that women are often the ones needing the care for their dependents and that women workers are the ones doing the caring under increasingly difficult con- ditions, has often been remarked and needs to be explained. Class and gender rela- tions are everywhere intertwined, within institutions like the local state as well as in their outcomes. Chapter 20 Thinking through Work: Gender, Power, and Space

Linda McDowell

Introduction: Organization, Space, and Culture This chapter counterposes a number of sets of literatures to draw out some ques- tions about the changing organization and distribution of waged work, especially its feminization. As many analyses have made clear, there is an evident, empirically demonstrable, trend towards the “feminization” of work in contemporary Britain. In using this term, I intend to indicate a great deal more than the numerical increase in the numbers of women entering waged employment. I also want to encompass the shift to service sector employment, where the attributes of growing numbers of jobs and occupations are based, in the main, on those purportedly feminine attri- butes of serving and caring, as well as what organizational theorists and manage- ment consultants see as a trend towards the feminization of management structures and practices, with a growing emphasis on less hierarchical, more empathetic and cooperative styles of management. The popular as well as the academic literature in these areas includes praise for nonhierarchical structures, for empathy and caring in the workplace and a range of other essentialized feminine attributes. Indeed, so lyrical has a stream of this literature become about feminized attributes that women have been dubbed “the new Japanese” of organizational theory by one over- enthusiastic advocate (Helgasen, 1990). If these literatures are to be believed, if sheer numbers of women in the labor market are emphasized and the terms and condi- tions of many women’s employment are ignored, it might seem that women are entering a new period of success and empowerment in the late twentieth-century world of work. The empirical evidence about the purported feminization of organizations has been paralleled by a remarkable expansion in theoretically grounded studies of service-based economies. A particularly noticeable trend in this work has been what we might term a “cultural turn,” in which the perception of work and workplaces as active forces in the social construction of workers as embodied beings has become a prominent emphasis. Rather than seeing the workplace as a site which men and women as fixed and finished products enter to become labor power, the ways in 316 LINDA MCDOWELL which the workplace or the organization plays a key role in the constitution of sub- jects is becoming clear. It is this work that has been a major influence here, espe- cially studies that have examined the gendering of organizations, the construction of work as emotional labor and the management of feeling, and the significance of embodiment – of men and women as physical beings of different sizes, shapes, skin colors, and sexual proclivities and preferences as well as gendered attributes – in workplace interactions. To this incisive and significant literature, I want to bring a specifically geo- graphical imagination and suggest that the location and the physical construction of the workplace – its site and layout, the external appearance and the internal layout of its buildings and surrounding environment – also affects, as well as reflects, the social construction of work and workers and the relations of power, control, and dominance that structure relations between them. Here a set of literatures from geography, architecture, and urban sociology are useful. The link between these dif- ferent literatures, between sociological and geographical imaginations, is the notion of performance, especially the new theoretical work on the body as a site of inscrip- tion and cultural analyses of the body. The social constructionist literature has, for several decades from Goffman (1963) onwards, fruitfully used the notion of the stage and performance as a way of understanding everyday behaviors and interac- tions, and this is mirrored in some of the earliest feminist writing about gender roles. More recently, feminist scholars have developed a psychoanalytically based notion of gender itself as a performance (Butler, 1990). In the work on the built environ- ment, the physical structures of the workplace and the street, Sennett’s (1977) classic examination of the decline of the public arena uses the concept of performance as a key to unlock changing attitudes to public and private spaces. A focus on the body as culturally inscribed but also as occupying a range of different spaces in the city, both inside and outside, public and private, is one way of bringing together differ- ent theoretical, disciplinary, and methodological approaches.

Men’s Jobs, Women’s Jobs: Employment Change in the 1980s and 1990s Like other advanced industrial nations, the last decades of the twentieth century in Britain have been marked by a series of remarkable changes in the nature and loca- tion of waged work. So great has been the impact of these changes that Pahl (1988) has suggested that waged work is the dominant but unresolved question at the end of the twentieth century. The postwar certainty about the nature of work, when it was assumed that full-time, waged employment for men was the norm, is now revealed as an exception, dominant only for three brief decades between 1945 and 1975. As in earlier centuries, it seems clear that waged work for growing numbers of people, perhaps even for a majority, was and will be discontinuous, interrupted, and uncertain – in short, a world of employment that has always been familiar to most women. The remarkable series of changes that was set in motion in Great Britain, and indeed in other advanced industrial economies, from the mid-1960s onwards to their apotheosis in the late 1980s, seems to have finally buried the belief in the perma- nency of work. In the 1980s, the nature and structure of waged work in these THINKING THROUGH WORK 317 societies, its organization and rewards, the types of tasks undertaken and the people who did them, as well as the places in which they labored, changed irrevocably. The relative certainty of lifetime employment, often for a single employer and frequently in the same place, that had faced men in the postwar decades was swept away in a rhetoric and reality of flexibility, restructuring, casualization, polarization, and feminization. The decline of manufacturing employment in western industrial economies that had been evident for two decades accelerated in the 1980s, and increasing numbers of people found themselves employed in the service economy in a range of occupations from selling haircuts to selling financial advice. These new jobs in the service sector – new only in the sense that they came to dominate these economies – were unevenly distributed across space and between the population. Old manufacturing heartlands suffered serious employment decline, whereas the sunbelt in the south and southwest of the United States, and the golden arc or triangle joined by Bristol, London, and Cambridge in Britain, increased their share of national employment and associated prosperity. For a time Pahl’s thesis about the changing nature of work seemed overly gloomy and, as the 1980s progressed, the huge expansion of employment in the service sector seemed to counter his pessimism. In the southeast of England in particular, economic growth accelerated in the mid-1980s after a period of recession in the early years of that decade, and there was a widespread belief in the buoyant middle years of the decade that the expanding financial services sector heralded a new secure economic future for Britain. New forms of work based on the ownership, control, movement of, and access to money led to the rise of new types of well-paid, middle- class occupations which in combination were dubbed a “new service class” or a new cultural class (Savage et al., 1992; Thrift, 1989). This was the group designated “yuppies” in popular culture. While the term “yuppy” was used, without doubt, to include professional workers in the financial services sector, the label “new service class” tended to be used more restrictively to distinguish a group of workers in what might be referred to as the cultural industries in marketing, advertising, and public relations as well as TV and radio producers and presenters, magazine journalists, fashion writers, and arts administrators and performers. The helping professions – social workers, therapists, etc. – are also often included in this new class fraction. This group of middle-class workers were identified as being of key significance in the socioeconomic changes that seemed to be sweeping 1980s Britain. Their atti- tudes to work, it was argued, were different from both the old bourgeoisie and the old manufacturing-based working class. For this new middle class or cultural class, work was fun: indeed, the boundaries between work and leisure were increasingly difficult to define as the social relations of production and consumption merged into each other (Du Gay, 1996). Questions of style and performance, of the ownership and possession of a range of “positional” goods – the Filofax, a Peugeot car, Gucci shoes, a gentrified flat or house in an inner area that was, in estate agents’ parlance, “rapidly improving” – all marked out these workers as a distinct class fraction (Thrift, 1989). It is also significant that a spatial referrent was attached to the group. Paralleling geographers’ arguments about deterritorialization, Featherstone (1991, p. 44) suggested that the new cultural class had a “frequent lack of anchoring in terms of a specific locale or community,” although other theorists identified a specifi- cally local impact of the group who were among the key actors in the gentrification 318 LINDA MCDOWELL of inner area housing markets in the global cities in which they worked (King, 1993; Sassen, 1990). The remarkably uncritical tone in which the new cultural class is analyzed by some, however, was challenged by the reassertion of the cold world of economics in the celebration of consumption. As Harvey (1989) never ceased to argue, the “postmodern” turn to consumption was little more than “the cultural froth of late capitalism.” The mechanisms of class division and exploitation ground on slowly and surely below the surface, and the emphasis on estheticization and lifestyle merely disguised the insecurity of many of those employed in the new service indus- tries. The bubble of service sector expansion burst at the end of the decade. In Britain and the US, between 1990 and 1992, there was recession and a “shakeout” of service sector employment, and Pahl’s next examination of work had a pessimistic tide: After Success (Pahl, 1995). Financiers, dealers, lawyers, and cultural workers alike were reminded of the harsh world of economic reality as unemployment rose and the housing market suffered an almost unparalleled crisis as real prices fell. Many of those who had bought into the gentrified lifestyle in inner areas or dock- land conversions were stranded in negative equity as the value of their property fell below the loan secured to purchase it. A new literature about downsizing and shake- outs and the advantages of a less pressurized lifestyle – an individual’s choice to downshift matching enforced corporate downsizing – began to replace the more out- rageous of the 1980s texts that had celebrated the “greed is good” ethos. But even in the boom years, the expansion in service sector employment had not brought prosperity for all. While many of the new jobs were highly paid, demand- ing increasingly well-qualified employees who were rewarded commensurately, the greatest expansion of employment had been in poorly paid, often casual and tem- porary work at the bottom end of the service sector – perhaps more accurately called “servicing” rather than service occupations. In the 1980s, the fastest growing jobs in the US economy, for example, included retail assistants, nursing auxiliaries, care attendants in old people’s homes, janitors, truck drivers, waitresses and waiters. The list in Great Britain was similar. The net result was a widening pay differential between the well paid and the poorest paid. For those in the bottom decile of the income distribution, for example, the decade brought an absolute as well as a relative decline in their share of the total earnings from employment. As well as growing income polarization, the 1980s saw the continuation of a shift of employment from men to women which had begun with manufacturing decline in the 1960s. In the ten years after 1966, the net decline in manufacturing output led to significant job losses, of which 73 percent were jobs previously held by men, but only 27 percent by women. Over the same decade, the net increase in private sector services resulted in a 125 percent increase in jobs for women, but a 44 percent decrease in men’s service employment (Dex, 1987). In the next 15 years, the loss from the manufacturing sector slowed down but the attrition of men’s employment continued. Consequently, by the beginning of the 1990s, there were 3.5 million fewer men in waged employment than at the beginning of the 1960s and almost 3 million more women, although as women were more likely to work part-time, the total number of hours worked had fallen (McDowell, 1991; Walby, 1990). These figures reflect a transformation in the labor market behavior of women in Great Britain in the postwar era. In response to employment restructuring and THINKING THROUGH WORK 319 to social changes from reliable contraception to new patterns of consumption, more and more women entered the workforce. At the beginning of the 1990s, more than half of all women and almost 60 percent of married women were economically active, compared to just over a third of all women and a fifth of married women in 1951. The feminization of the labor market is not, however, an undifferentiated process. Just as work is becoming increasingly differentiated as a whole in its conditions and rewards, women as waged workers are also becoming increasingly differentiated (McDowell, 1991; Phillips, 1989). Whereas a minority of well-educated women are able to enter and hold on to full-time work in professional occupations, the major- ity of women in waged work are in part-time jobs at the bottom end of the labor market. Thus, the proportion of women able to return to work after giving birth, for example, differs according to the type of work they do or are willing to accept. In comparison with other occupational groups, women professionals and associate professionals (the latter group includes teachers, health and social workers, and librarians) are more likely to return and most likely to return full-time. Many of these women are in public sector employment where provision for working mothers in the form of flexible working and part-time work is more usual. Women man- agers and administrators in the private sector, on the other hand, have a lower rate of return, partly reflecting restricted opportunities for part-time employment at this level. Women professionals, as a group, are less likely than either managers and administrators or secretarial and clerical workers to experience downward occupa- tional mobility (Dex, 1987). These trends reinforce arguments based on the analysis of pay differentials which suggest that women are becoming increasingly differentiated as a workforce. Throughout the 1980s, a growing proportion of women gained educational qualifications and they are beginning to constitute a substantial proportion of those entering professional occupations. Young women improved their performance in school-leaving examinations throughout the 1980s, and as the 1990s began, there was almost no difference between the proportions of men and women aged 20–24 gaining degrees (11 and 10 percent respectively), although considerable differences still exist in the subjects they study. Such is the evident success of women in school, university, and professional examinations, that a crisis of male under-achievement has been recognized as the popular and academic press begins to investigate “boys who fail” and young men with little hope of steady employment (Campbell, 1993). These trends in the education sector and in the labor market have resulted in a rising number of women gaining access to professional occupations – once the bas- tions of masculine privilege. In some cases women’s representation in the profes- sions has increased dramatically. Examples include law, banking, accountancy, pharmacy, and medicine. In 1991, for example, almost half the new entrants to the legal profession in Great Britain were women, up from 19 percent in 1975. In banking, women accounted for just 2 percent of successful finalists in the Institute of Banking examinations in 1970, but by the early 1990s almost a third of the finalists were women. In 1975 only 7 percent of new chartered accountants and 6 percent of the Chartered Institute of Public Finance Accountants members were women, but a decade later these proportions had risen to 25 percent and 36 percent respectively (Crompton, 1992). Despite their growing presence in higher-level jobs, 320 LINDA MCDOWELL however, few women make it to the top of the occupational hierarchies in the public or private sector. Although one in four junior managers in Britain was female at the start of the 1990s, at senior management levels the number of women remaining was down to one or two percent.

Explaining Organizational and Workplace Change Now, I want to shift from an empirical to a theoretical focus and examine the sets of theoretical literatures about work, organizational change and culture, and gender divisions of labor that influenced this study of gendered patterns of recruitment, promotion, and social interaction in the world of investment or merchant banking. I want to outline briefly the ways of thinking that have influenced me in the years in which I have been preoccupied with questions about gender and power. I hope to show that, rather than taking a singular or disciplinary-specific approach, a more complete understanding of why certain types of people are successful merchant bankers can be gained by bringing together a range of different theoretical approaches to occupational segregation and labor market segmentation, the culture of workplaces literatures about the body, about clothes and personal presentation, about success, organizational structures, and the meaning of work, and about the impact that the built environment has on how men and women situate themselves in spaces and places. In a study of gendered management and employment practices in the insurance industry, Kerfoot and Knights (1994, p. 124) argued that, for them, “financial services are merely a site for empirical research rather than the intrinsic object of investigation.” I began this study of merchant banks in the City of London with a somewhat similar belief – my concern was not with the economic niceties of fluc- tuating interest rates, nor with instruments of deregulation and re-regulation, not even with the successive scandals that affected so many City banks in the 1980s and 1990s, but rather with the everyday practices of the men and women who worked in City banks. But, of course, the two cannot be separated. The specificities of finan- cial services as an industry, the particularities of the City in the early 1990s, and the environment, attitudes, and culture of each merchant bank affected the ways in which gender differences in recruitment policies and career opportunities worked out. What economic sociologists term “embeddedness” and geographers “location” cannot be ignored in the investigation of gender segregation at work. The embeddedness of social and cultural institutions, firms, and individual workplaces is now a key area of study in the new economic sociology (Zukin and DiMaggio, 1990), whereas Bourdieu (1984) used the term “embodiment” to refer to similar processes at the scale of an organization. In the main, however, in analy- ses of the ways in which national and local factors have influenced economic changes, geographers have turned to the revitalized area of economic sociology, rather than to studies of organizational culture, not only to shed light on the loca- tion of industries and their position within national and local systems of political and financial regulation, but also to open up new questions about the cultural meaning of new products, new forms of workplace organization and labor recruit- ment (Schoenberger, 1997; Storper, 1997; Thrift, 1994). Economic sociology focuses on issues of power, the social aspects of markets and business–government links, on THINKING THROUGH WORK 321 social networks and the culture of organizations. It challenges conventional notions of rational economic actors, suggesting rather that economic action is embedded in the social context and the specific institutions within which it takes place. Like all social interactions, economic decisions are as much affected by tradition, historical precedent, class and gender interests, and other social factors as by considerations of efficiency or profit. This is particularly evident in the world of merchant banking, in which networks of familial interests as well as the networks of social elites link directors of banks together and to directors of other British firms and the Conservative Party. Sets of common social assumptions and cultural understandings shape economic strategies and goals. As Zukin and DiMaggio (1990, p. 17) have argued:

culture sets limits to economic rationality: it proscribes or limits exchange in sacred objects and relations (e.g. human beings, body organisms or physical intimacy) or between ritually classified groups . . . culture, in the form of beliefs and ideologies, taken for granted assumptions, or formal rule systems also prescribes strategies of self-interested action . . . and defines the actors who may legitimately engage in them (e.g. self-interested individuals, families, classes, formal organizations, ethnic groups). Culture provides scripts for applying different strategies to different classes of exchange. Finally, norms and constitutive understandings regulate market exchange, causing persons to behave with institutionalized and culturally specific definitions of integrity even when they could get away with cheating. On the one hand, it constitutes the structures in which economic self-interest is played out; on the other, it constrains the free play of market forces.

In the 1980s, one of the Conservative government’s achievements was to reverse long-standing constraints, creating the circumstances for the spread of a new set of cultural assumptions in the City and in wider society. An ideology of individualism – that people are solely motivated by pecuniary gain – and the associated claims for the efficacy of deregulation in freeing the market from the stranglehold of the state and assuring economic efficiency and success gained the high ground. How these notions progressively infiltrated discourse and practice in a range of economic insti- tutions is a major research challenge for economic sociologists and anthropologists. Merchant banking in particular, within the City as an institution, was one of the prime locations for the successful promulgation and diffusion of these new cultural assumptions. Of all the middle-class occupations in that new service or new cul- tural class that expanded in the 1980s, it was bankers who were characterized as the personification of the era: the apotheosis of individualistic, profit-oriented “yuppies.”

Gender Segregation at Work Whether in times of economic stability or of marked change, such as those of the 1980s, it seems that women’s concentration into a few sectors of the economy and certain types of occupations within them has remained a constant feature of the social division of labor (A. M. Scott, 1994). In the face of this persistence, the unsexed worker, labor power unencumbered by a body or any other social 322 LINDA MCDOWELL attributes, has almost disappeared from all but the most blinkered of studies, as the lived experience of workers distinguished by, among other characteristics, their gender, ethnicity, age, and family circumstances has become an important focus of research on work and organizations. In the 1970s and 1980s the dominant perspective was a version of what might be termed the “division of labor” approach (Fröbel et al., 1980; Massey, 1984) in which workers entered the labor market with their gender attributes firmly estab- lished. In both the advanced and newly industrializing countries, women were theorized as a reserve of cheap labor, attractive to newly mobile capital in search of higher rates of profit. While the “division of labor” approach implicitly drew on feminist analyses of how women’s domestic responsibilities were part of the expla- nation for their construction as a reserve army, less attention was paid to the reasons for women being drawn into a narrow range of occupations even as the labor market became increasingly feminized. Women’s occupational segregation was noted rather than explained. Feminist scholars working within a broad Marxist church, however, explained these patterns through theories of patriarchy, whether conceptualized as a separate system that parallels capitalism, drawing on Marxist notions of exploita- tion, or as an inseparable part of the capitalist mode of production (Beechey, 1987; Walby, 1990). This stream of explicitly feminist work has the closest links with the divisions of labor school in geography. More recently, Hanson and Pratt’s (1995) work has been particularly influential in drawing attention to geographical issues, extending the understanding of the role of residential location and gender differ- ences in job search behavior in the maintenance of occupational sex segregation. They developed a concept of spatial containment, consequent upon women’s domes- tic responsibilities, to explain gender differences. A second step in the explanation of gender segregation in the labor market came with the recognition that occupations and workers themselves are socially constructed through a variety of practices to conform to a particular set of gender attributes. Occupations are not empty slots to be filled, nor do workers enter the labor market and the workplace with fixed and immoveable gender attributes. Instead these features are negotiated and contested at work. As J. Scott (1988a, p. 47) recognized:

if we write the history of women’s work by gathering data that describe the activities, needs, interests, and culture of “women workers,” we leave in place the naturalized contrast and reify a fixed categorical difference between women and men. We start the story, in other words, too late, by uncritically accepting a gendered category (the “woman worker”) that itself needs investigation because its meaning is relative to its history.

Jobs are not gender neutral – rather they are created as appropriate for either men or women, and the set of social practices that constitute and maintain them is constructed so as to embody socially sanctioned but variable characteristics of masculinity and femininity. This association seems self-evident in the analysis of classically “masculine” occupations; consider, for example, the heroic struggle and camaraderie involved in heavy male manual labor (McDowell and Massey, 1984). The same belief now holds with respect to self-evidently female occupations such THINKING THROUGH WORK 323 as secretarial work, but it is salutary to remember that the latter have changed their gender associations over the century (Bradley, 1989). Less obviously “sexed” jobs and new occupations are struggled over and negotiated to establish their gender coding.

Gendered Organizations: Sexing and Resexing Jobs An important stimulus to my thinking about the construction and maintenance of gendered occupations in the financial services came from organization theory, espe- cially from recent studies that have drawn attention to the ubiquity of sexuality in organizational processes and the ways in which it is related to the structures of power (Acker, 1990; Hearn and Parkin, 1987; Pringle, 1989). Within this literature, there has been a shift from what might be termed the “gender-in-organization model” – where organizations are seen as settings in which gendered actors behave, as gender-neutral places which affect men and women differently because of their different attributes – to theorizing organizations themselves as embedded with gen- dered meanings and structured by the social relations of sexuality. In these studies, sexuality is defined as a socially constructed set of processes which includes patterns of desire, fantasy, pleasure, and self-image. Hence, it is not restricted solely, nor indeed mainly, to sexual relations and the associated policy implications around the issue of sexual harassment. Rather the focus is on power and domination and the way in which assumptions about gender-appropriate behavior and sexuality, broadly defined, influence management practices, the organizational logic of job evaluations, promotion procedures and job specifications (Acker, 1990), and the everyday social relations between workers. The growing recognition of the ways in which male sexuality structures organizational practices counters commonly held views that sexuality at work is a defining characteristic of women workers. As Acker (1990, p. 139) has argued:

their [organization’s] gendered nature is partly masked through obscuring the embodied nature of work. Abstract jobs and hierarchies assume a disembodied and universal worker. This worker is actually a man: men’s bodies, sexuality and relation- ships to procreation and waged work are subsumed in the image of the worker. Images of men’s bodies and masculinity pervade organizational processes, marginalizing women and contributing to the maintenance of gender segregation in organizations.

The earliest explorations of how organizations are saturated with male power and masculinist values, however, tended to take the social construction of masculinity for granted, instead uncovering in careful detailed work alternative versions of fem- ininity (Kanter, 1977; Marshall, 1984). Although the centrality of a masculine model of employment, based on lifetime, full-time, and continuous employment, and the importance of waged work as a key element in the construction of a masculine iden- tity were clear, the focus was on the ways in which these structures and assump- tions exclude women rather than on the different ways in which alternative masculinities are constructed in the workplace. Pringle (1989), for example, in her study of the relationships between secretaries and bosses, noted that the association between masculinity and rationality allowed male sexuality to remain invisible yet 324 LINDA MCDOWELL dominant, positioning women as the inferior “Other” at work, and yet she inter- viewed only women. The realization that male embodiment and masculine sexuality must also be ren- dered visible and interrogated resulted in a significant shift in feminist analyses of the gendering of occupations. Men began to enter the analyses of feminist work and slowly more organizational sociology where the significance of gender previously had been ignored. Not only the formal structures of institutions, their recruitment, promotion and appraisal mechanisms, and their working hours, but also informal structures of everyday life reinforce women’s inferiority. Male power is implicitly reinforced in many of the micro-scale interactions in organizations: in workplace talk and jokes, for example, “men see humour, teasing, camaraderie and strength . . . women often perceive crude, specifically masculine aggression, competition, harassment, intimidation and misogyny” (Collinson and Hearn, 1994, p. 3). The expansion of work about masculinity and organizations, about male power, masculine discourse, and gendered social practices, is part of a wider move in feminist-influenced scholarship to understand the complexity of gendered subjec- tivities and the ways in which they are constructed in and vary between different sites: the home, the street, and the workplace, for example. It coincided with attempts by feminists, particularly feminists of color, to reveal the assumptions about “woman” that lie behind the early feminist scholarship. Criticized for its implicit focus on a version of white, anglocentric, and middle-class femininity, fem- inist scholars are increasingly working on the ways in which race, class, and gender are mutually constituted. There has been a parallel rise of queer scholarship. Lesbian feminists, such as Butler (1990), have shown how the “regulatory fiction” of het- erosexuality reinforces a naturalized binary distinction between men and women. Similarly, in a remarkable growth of male gay scholarship from the mid-1980s, the construction and dominance of a hegemonic heterosexual masculinity which excludes other forms of masculinity has been revealed (see Kimmel, 1988). In recent work on gender, therefore, in general as well as in the “sociology of organizations” school, the notion of multiple masculinities has been developed to refer to the variety of forms of masculinity across space and time.

Normalizing the Self The focus on constructing the self at work led to a growing interest in the concept of “normalization” in Foucault’s work. The narrow range of socially sanctioned gendered identities and ways of behaving are reinforced and policed through a set of structures that keep in place dominant and subordinate social relations. These structures or mechanisms include not only institutional force and sanctions from above but also self-surveillance and what Foucault termed “capillary power.” This interest opened up a way to link analyses of institutional interests and power rela- tions to micro-scale social practices (Foucault, 1979). Here the enormous expan- sion of interest in subjectivity and in the body by labor analysts and other social scientists is crucial. New ways of thinking about theory, politics, and the subject have developed in an interesting confrontation between feminism, postmodernism, and poststruc- turalism. Challenges to the supposed universalism of the rational subject of liberal THINKING THROUGH WORK 325 theory have resulted in a new emphasis in a wide range of different disciplines on the positionality and situatedness of action and knowledge concepts that are not unrelated to the notion of embeddedness in economic sociology. One of the central elements of these arguments is a challenge to the modernist confidence that indi- viduality is grounded in a singular and unique subjectivity that is invariant. In con- trast, it is now argued that the self is in a fragile process of construction throughout the life cycle and that a multiplicity of identities are constructed through the symbolic repertoires of everyday actions in institutional contexts (Giddens, 1991). In this sense, the significance of position or location has taken a new precedence in social theory. Here then is a productive coincidence of the notions of embeddedness and embodiment. The theoretical focus on the body, sexualized performances, and strategies of sur- veillance parallels material changes in the nature of work in service sector occupa- tions. One of the key features of service sector work, compared with manufacturing jobs, is that the labor power and embodied performance of workers is part of the product in a way that was not the case in the production of manufactured goods. Services that are exchanged, sold, purchased, used up, be they producer or con- sumer service products – a pedicure, a lecture, or a piece of legal advice – cannot be separated from the workers who are producing and exchanging them. Service occupations revolve around personal relationships or interactions between service providers and consumers, in the main unmediated by a set of exchange profession- als as is more usual in the exchange of manufactured goods. In service interactions, the body of the worker be it the “managed heart” of care professionals or flight attendants (Hochschild, 1983), the uniform service of the fast food joint or per- sonalized but scripted service of more upmarket restaurants (Leidner, 1993), the smiling charm of a bank teller or the professional advice of a besuited male manager (Kerfoot and Knights, 1994) – all demand an embodied and visible performance. Special clothing or uniforms may be required for the performance of particular tasks, and prohibitions, for example of facial hair or jewelry, are common in order to produce a specific, usually explicitly heterosexual self-image, both for men and for women. Leidner (1993) has termed these types of service occupations “inter- active work,” where workers’ looks, personalities and emotions, as well as their physical and intellectual capacities, are involved, sometimes forcing them to mani- pulate their identities more self-consciously than workers in other kinds of jobs.

Bodies at Work The re-theorizing of work as an embodied performance accords well with the realities of the restructured world of work with which this chapter began. One of the most significant aspects of the 1990s is the ways in which individuals’ attach- ment to the labor force and to a particular job within it has changed. For increas- ing numbers of workers, there is an expectation of a career that is discontinuous and interrupted, marked by successive contracts rather than the lifetime tenure of a single occupation. Work, once regarded as a (relative) certainty and a central aspect of personal identity, especially for men, has itself become a fluid, multiple, and uncertain performance. Despite these uncertainties, however, and women’s greater visibility in the workplace, the most dominant image that continues to struc- 326 LINDA MCDOWELL ture the world of work in contemporary Britain is that it is a public arena, associ- ated with men and masculinity. As feminist scholars have argued, in western enlight- enment societies, embodied social structures, and the physical locations in which they take place, construct acceptable ways of being and “reasonable” behavior on the basis of a set of binaries. As Bourdieu (1984, p. 468) noted:

The network of oppositions between high (sublime, elevated, pure) and low (vulgar, low, modest), spiritual and material, fine (refined, elegant) and coarse (heavy, fat, crude, brutal), light (subtle, lively, sharp, adroit) and heavy (slow, thick, blunt, laborious, clumsy), free and forced, broad and narrow, or in another dimension, between unique (rare, different, distinguished, exceptional, singular, novel) and common (ordinary, banal, common place, trivial, routine), brilliant (intelligent) and dull (obscure, grey, mediocre) is the matrix of all the commonplaces which find such ready acceptance because behind them lies the whole social order.

And, he continued, they “derive their ideological strength from the fact that they refer back to the most fundamental oppositions between the dominant and the dom- inated, which is inscribed in the division of labour” (1984, p. 469, emphasis added). In contemporary western societies, therefore, these binaries structure the em- bodiment of waged labor. They act to define woman as inferior, separating her purportedly natural and private world from the public world of men which, as a public arena, is portrayed as being as distant from the natural world as it is possi- ble to be. Abstract symbols of power, particularly money, are the markers of status and culture. Whereas the natural world is associated with animality, the cultural and cultured world of work is distinguished by its humanity. It is constructed as a rational, objective world in which behavior and decisions are ruled by accepted and conventional norms. In modern industrial societies, the workplace is distinguished by its rational and bureaucratic social order, an arena supposedly unmarked by emotion or by personal characteristics or attributes, one that above all is associated with all that is culturally valued as masculine. Thus, women are literally out of place at work for, as many commentators have pointed out – some approvingly, others critically – woman is to nature as man is to culture. Women, like nature, are viewed as fecund and unreliable, part of the natural order of things, the body rather than the mind, and so unfit for the cool rationality of the public arena. Women are out of place in the embodied social structures of the workplace precisely because they are unable to acquire the cultural markers associated with the attributes valued in the workplace, or perhaps to qualify this, those associated with the rational and bureaucratic workplace. As Young (1990, p. 176) has pointed out, the idealization of a particular notion of (dis)embodiment in the workplace means that “women suffer workplace disadvantage . . . because many men regard women in inappropri- ate sexual terms and because women’s clothes, comportment, voices and so on disrupt the disembodied ideal of masculinist bureaucracy.”

The Places and Spaces of Work Despite the incisiveness of these various sets of literatures about gender, work, power, and organizations, they all seem to have a remarkable blindness to the THINKING THROUGH WORK 327 significance of location. What is happening in the new forms of organizational struc- tures and workplaces has been emphasized to the neglect of where new forms of behavior occur. Yet workplace behavior is both shaped by and shapes the design of the workplace environment at the scale of the city itself, of spaces and localities within it and of individual buildings. The meanings given to different social behav- iors, to the characteristics that distinguish femininity and masculinity, are grounded in and accordingly judged more or less appropriate to particular physical spaces. Lash and Urry (1994) have argued that radical economic changes are paralleled by shifts in the location and structure of industrial spaces. The production and exchange of manufactured products in industrial economies resulted in the pro- duction of specialized industrial spaces, the manufacturing heartlands of the indus- trial nations. Similarly, the production and exchange of commodified signs – the cultural industries and advertising are their example, but financial products such as futures and derivatives are even clearer examples – result in the emergence of post- industrial spaces, even though the goods and services of the late twentieth-century economy are less place-bound in the sense of being reliant on a spatially bound set of raw materials or a local market. As the delivery of services becomes more impor- tant and the quality of the interaction between producers and consumers becomes part of the product, the availability both of the right type of labor (often young and personable as well as highly educated for high-status services) and of the location of the interaction in an appropriate environment that reinforces the meaning of the commodified signs increases in importance. Indeed, in post-industrial economies, architecture and urban design themselves are a key part of cultural production, both of the products and of performing selves. Cultural industries are increasingly dominating the economies of large cities (Sassen, 1990; Zukin, 1995). As well as the expansion of financial services in the 1980s and 1990s, global cities became important locations for cultural ventures, from museums and universities to the advertising industry. These industries are part of that “estheticization” of urban life. Zukin (1995) has shown how, in New York at least, the physical reconstruction of urban spaces for workplace and leisure activities for the new middle class is part of the redefinition and reclaiming of inner- city areas. Through the form of the buildings themselves and the nature of intersti- tial spaces, as well as through mechanisms of physical surveillance and electronic control, undesirable or “dangerous classes” are excluded. Despite the apparent shift to emphasize representations, the best new work on urban landscapes is distinguished by its determination to link together the material production of the built environment, symbolic meanings and forms of representa- tion, and the sets of material and social practices facilitated or constrained by both physical and symbolic forms. Landscapes are, after all, but the concrete expression of a society, especially its institutions of class and power. Buildings “represent, trans- mit and transform institutionally embedded power relations” (Zukin, 1991, p. 21). They are not only symbolic representations of discourse, ideologies, and relations of power but also constitute and affect these same attitudes, beliefs, social relations and structures, and so the very distinction between representations and reality falls to the ground. While the relations of power and class have been emphasized in this new “school” of urban scholarship, the way in which the built environment reflects and affects gender relations has been given relatively less attention (Colomina, 328 LINDA MCDOWELL

1992). Sassen (1996, p. 91) observed that corporate culture is dominated by notions of precision and expertise, imposing its authority on the central area though high- rise, corporate towers: “The vertical grid of the corporate tower is imbued with the same neutrality and rationality attributed to the horizontal grid of American cities.” The neutrality and rationality she identified are the same characteristics that con- struct the female body as out of place in the workplace.

Conclusions I have argued that the sociology and culture of work literatures, especially those that focus on the gendering of organizational structures and practices, may profitably be brought into juxtaposition with the literatures from urban studies, architecture, geography, cultural studies, and urban sociology, which focus on the built environment not only as a container for the social practices and everyday inter- actions in workplaces that sociologists and anthropologists have documented in increasing and fascinating detail, but also as an active influence on these behaviors. As geographers have claimed for so long and with increasing success, social and spatial processes are mutually constitutive. Where an event or activity takes place shapes its form, and vice versa. The built environment of the City, whether the spatial divisions of the Square Mile and its environs or individual buildings and the layout of workplaces – from the oak-paneled boardrooms and the old open spaces of the trading floors and exchanges to the newer electronic dealing rooms – conveys powerful messages about embodied class and gender attributes. Part V Spaces of Circulation

Editors’ Introduction: From Distance to Connectivity

Eric Sheppard, Adam Tickell, Trevor J. Barnes, and Jamie Peck

Debates about the importance of space and distance to economic geography are as old as the sub-discipline itself. Their persistence reflects the old geographical idea that what happens in a place depends both on local conditions in that place and on how it is connected to the rest of the world; i.e., on site and situation. In the early “commercial” geographies, such as J. Russell Smith’s 1913 foundational text Indus- trial and Commercial Geography, much attention was devoted to trade patterns and the transportation infrastructures that shaped them. They sought to describe how places are connected and how connectivity depends upon ease of travel between them (itself related to distance). The shift to location theory and the search for “sci- entific laws” in quantitative economic geography in the 1960s made distance into the prime factor in explanations of the geography of economic activities. Location theories generally assumed an isotropic plain, meaning that the only thing varying across the map was distance, whereas uneven distributions of resources or people simply were not considered. Spatial interaction theories sought to predict how the flows of people and goods between places are related to the distance separating them. While spatial analysts devoted much empirical attention to what distance means, distinguishing between economic, social, and Euclidean distance, their the- ories typically used Euclidean distance as a proxy for relative location.1 This meant that Euclidean distance became the determinant of location patterns and spatial flows. This causal relationship remains central to the “new economic geography” in economics. One of the first critiques articulated by Marxian economic geographers against spatial analysts was that this veneration of Euclidean distance is wrong. Marxists argued that economic and social distance are not well approximated by Euclidean distance, because distance is itself a social product. Neil Smith (1984) called this “the production of space.” As Marx recognized, in order for capitalists to receive a return on their investment, they must ship their product to distant customers and wait for returning cash payments to be returned to them. The speed and efficiency with which commodities are shipped across space, and money returned, depend on the relative location of linked economic activities and the efficiency of 332 ERIC SHEPPARD, ADAM TICKELL, TREVOR J. BARNES, AND JAMIE PECK communications technologies. Capitalists and the state thus invest in the built envi- ronment and communications infrastructures, in order to accelerate the spatial cir- culation of commodities and money and thereby enhance profitability. From this perspective, one in which economic distance is produced within the economy, the proposition that Euclidean distance is an externally given determinant of location and spatial interaction amounts to “spatial fetishism” – that is, elevating a social construct (relative location) to the status of a natural feature of the world. As in discussions about the naturalness of natural resources (cf. Part III Intro- duction), the conclusion that space is produced by society led Marxist and post- Marxist economic geographers to debate how distance matters in economic geography. If distance is a social product, how can it be isolated as a distinct explanatory factor? After all, if economic activities in a place depend on its con- nectivity with other places, then connectivity is as much a consequence as it is a cause of socioeconomic processes. Skepticism about the importance of distance has also become more widespread in recent years, as many began to argue that global- ization and telecommunications technologies are making Euclidean distance irrele- vant anyway – i.e., that we now live in a global village. Frances Cairncross (1997) called this The Death of Distance. Reflecting these debates, Graham examines the role of telecommunications in shaping distance and connectivity, and thereby place and space. He engages in a conceptual comparison of three paradigms: a technological determinist claim that telecommunication is making space and place irrelevant; a co-evolutionary argu- ment that electronic and geographic space are mutually constitutive; and a “recom- binant” account, drawing on actor-network theory, that stresses the relational connections between technology, space and place, and social life. Favoring the last approach, and drawing on his own research, he argues that even though space and place are continually reshaped they are not disappearing as material or discursive concepts. Cities remain coherent geographic entities, with communications infra- structures whose geographies are far more coterminous with earlier transportation technologies than technological visionaries suggest. Distance, space, and place thus still matter, despite the space-busting potential of telecommunications. The next three essays testify to how economic geography over the past two decades has paid more attention to the fortunes of places, and to territoriality, than to the interdependencies connecting places. Yet while their focus is on place, they stress how places are shaped by connectivities with the wider world. Both Gertler and Hsing examine the impact of international flows of foreign direct investment (FDI) on the dynamics of local industrial clusters. FDI connects distant places through intrafirm investments in branch plants as a part of global production or assembly lines (Dicken, this volume). They entail flows of capital, control (over branch plants), influence (over national host governments), and ideas (technologies, labor practices and ideologies). Gertler seeks to extend the research program on industrial districts (Scott, Storper, this volume), arguing that the success of such regions depends on their connectivity to other places, and not just on local condi- tions. He notes that industrial districts often include branches of multinational firms, whose ability to function effectively in any given industrial district depends on where they originate. He argues that branch plant practices reflect the institutional envi- ronment of the home nation, where the parent company is located, and that this INTRODUCTION TO PART V 333 environment may differ greatly from that of the host country, where the industrial district is located. His conclusions are grounded in his own research on German- owned branch plants in Ontario, Canada, but his arguments are directed more broadly at the prevailing literature. He is critical of the idea that the prosperity of a region depends on its ability to develop a local culture of learning. Firms gather- ing there bring cultural norms and practices developed within the institutional context of the nation they come from. The difference (i.e., cultural “distance”) between this national context and that of the industrial district may be as impor- tant to the success of the cluster as any local learning-based regional development strategies. Hsing studies industrial cities in southern China. Paying attention to the distinc- tive geographic and political context of The People’s Republic of China, she also concludes that site and situation are important, but in other ways. The willingness of the Chinese central state to devolve responsibility for development to local gov- ernments, as it seeks a path to development along the tightrope connecting com- munism and capitalism in the global periphery, means that local conditions do matter even in this highly centralized society. Yet just as important to her argument is how cultural affinities between Taiwanese owners of local branch plants and local Chinese officials lubricate further investment and growth through traditions of gift exchange. Although she adopts an anthropological account of gift exchange that runs a danger of reducing Chinese culture to a particular trait, she shows, on the basis of extensive interviews, how new investments depend on close connections that have been retained with the overseas Chinese despite mainland China’s long- term isolation. In this case, cultural proximity is not shaped by national institutions but by persistent ethnic, familial, and cultural networks spanning space. Pratt’s study of Filipina nannies in Vancouver examines migration, a different but equally important kind of interdependence between places, and takes a different approach to unraveling the cultural dimensions of connectivity. Adopting post- structural discourse analysis, and a feminist methodological strategy of close, situ- ated, and reflexive readings of her interview materials, she seeks both to portray and to disrupt discourses shaping the position that these women occupy as immi- grants within Vancouver’s labor market. She traces the various geographies of these discourses – situating Filipina domestic workers as somewhere between family members and employees in the households where they work; as housekeepers rather than nannies; and as between visitors and landed immigrants in Canada and Canada’s Philippine community. She argues that these discursive geographies stigmatize the nannies’ status, but also create a resource for Filipinas and their immigrant organizations to challenge this stigmatization. These three studies ask how connections across space shape the economic geo- graphy of places, but do not seek to conceptualize the processes generating con- nectivity. Indeed, this question has received limited attention as economic geographers focused on the territoriality of economic activity. Transportation geo- graphy has only slowly begun to move beyond traditional location theory, and communications geography was similarly moribund until the recent popularity of telecommunications and the new economy. A number of economic geographers have turned to actor-networks, however, as a way of conceptualizing connectivity. Actor- networks are capable of capturing the complexity and fluidity of the “spaces of 334 ERIC SHEPPARD, ADAM TICKELL, TREVOR J. BARNES, AND JAMIE PECK

flows” and the contingent and negotiable nature of any spatial structures of con- nectivity (Graham, this volume; Whatmore and Thornes, this volume). Others argue that this focus on fluidity understates the persistence of communications structures. At the opposite extreme, social network analysis conceptualizes networks as rela- tively fixed relational structures that subdivide the world into self-reproducing cores and peripheries. In this view, sociospatial connectivities are unchanging and deter- minant of the conditions of possibility of network participants (and of the places they reside in). Reality almost certainly falls somewhere between these extremes, and economic geographers still face the challenge, articulated by Graham, of under- standing connectivity in ways that recognize both its fluidity as a social construct and its persistence (Sheppard, 2002). Beyond theorizing connectivity, a further question is whether attention to con- nectivity also affects how we can think about and use economic concepts, like com- petition. Schoenberger seeks to effect such a change; to challenge the now common understanding of competition as an overarching economic logic that determines how firms, regions, and nations should behave, by creating discursive space to consider its social dimension. Her analysis of competition shows well how this seemingly spaceless economic logic can be unpacked to reveal a geographical sensibility that then calls into question the coherence of the original concept. Both of her examples can be interpreted as demonstrating how competitiveness also depends on the inter- dependencies linking places (Sheppard, 2000). First, drawing on corporate reports, she shows how the profitability (i.e., competitiveness) of Nike reflects the super- profits it makes from underpaying Third World assembly workers. She argues that these wages are not dictated by Nike’s struggle to stay competitive, but are a con- sequence of the ability of Nike to stretch its production chain across space to incor- porate national polities with few regulatory structures and low-wage national accumulation strategies. Thus Nike’s strategy is one of accumulation, not of achiev- ing competitiveness. Second, drawing from activist research on the living wage campaign in Baltimore MD, she questions the common claim that living wages (successfully negotiated for Baltimore workers in companies with city contracts) undermine local competitiveness.2 Across the US, firms and the local state have fought against living wage campaigns on the grounds that they make a city unat- tractive to investors by increasing labor costs. In this view, inter-urban investment flows undermine the economic viability of living wages. By contrast, Schoenberger argues that living wage initiatives may actually attract new money to the city, reduc- ing poverty and thus making the city a more secure place to invest in. Her argument can be taken one step further. During the 1990s, the US living wage campaign jumped scale, from a few isolated local campaigns to a nationwide grassroots network. The same has happened with the sweatshop campaign that has now put pressure on clothing and shoe corporations, like Nike, to allow inspection of their foreign affiliates and subcontractors. The connectivities created by these activist networks are thus contributing to a shift in how we think about competi- tiveness, away from bottom-line logic to embrace social considerations. As more localities introduce living wages, it becomes less plausible to argue that when a place introduces living wages it drives investors away. As global clothing manufacturers concede to consumer-led campaigns, allowing inspection of wages and working conditions in assembly plants, social considerations gain more attention. Economic INTRODUCTION TO PART V 335 geographers, she argues, must be continually reflexive and self-critical of the concepts and discourses we use. New connectivities on the ground can have the same effect. In reading these essays, consider the following questions. How does the author conceptualize connectivity and situation? Is connectivity treated as a social construct, a determinant of social processes, or both? What relationships between place and connectivity are highlighted? What theoretical approach does the author adopt (cf. Part I), and how does this affect the questions asked? What kinds of methodologies are used, how are these related to the theoretical approach, and how do they shape the conclusions drawn? How would the adoption of a different theory and/or methodology change the study?

NOTES

1. Euclidean distance is the straight-line distance between two points, measured in miles or kilometers. 2. A living wage is the income necessary to support a family of four at the Federal poverty line, and substantially exceeds the nationally mandated US minimum wage. Chapter 21 The End of Geography or the Explosion of Place? Conceptualizing Space, Place, and Information Technology

Stephen Graham

It is now widely argued that the “convergence” of computers with digital telecom- munications and media technologies is creating “cyberspace” – a multimedia skein of digital networks which is infusing rapidly into social, cultural, and economic life. Cyberspace is variously defined as a “consensual hallucination, a graphic represen- tation of data abstracted from the banks of every computer in the human system” (Gibson, 1984, p. 51); a “parallel universe” (Benedikt, 1991, p. 15); or a “new kind of space, invisible to our direct senses, a space which might become more impor- tant than physical space itself [and which is] layered on top of, within and between the fabric of traditional geographical space” (Batty, 1993, pp. 615–16). Interestingly from the view point of geographers, the recent growth of discourses on “cyberspace” and new communications technologies, even the very word “cyberspace” itself, has been dominated by spatial and territorial metaphors (Stefik, 1996). “Cyberspace,” suggests Steve Pile (1994, p. 1817), “is a plurality of clashing, resonating and shocking metaphors.” The expanding lexicon of the Internet – the most well-known vehicle of cyberspace – is not only replete with, but actually constituted by, the use of geographical metaphors. Debates about the Inter- net use spatial metaphors to help visualize what are, effectively, no more than abstract flows of electronic signals, coded as information, representation, and exchange. Thus, an Internet point-of-presence becomes a web site. The ultimate convergent, broadband descendent of the Internet is labeled the information superhighway. A satellite node becomes a teleport. A bulletin board system becomes a virtual community or an electronic neighborhood. Web sites run by municipalities become virtual cities (see Graham and Aurigi, 1997). The whole society-wide process of technological innovation becomes a Wild-West-like elec- tronic frontier awaiting colonization. Those “exploring” this frontier become Web surfers, virtual travelers, or, to Bill Mitchell (1995, p. 7), electronic flaneurs who “hang out on the network.” The Internet as a whole is variously considered to be an electronic library, a medium for electronic mail, or a digital marketplace (Stefik, 1996). And Microsoft seductively ask “Where do you want to go today?” And so the list goes on and on. THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 337

Such spatial metaphors help make tangible the enormously complex and arcane technological systems which underpin the Internet, and other networks, and the growing range of transactions, social and cultural interactions, and exchanges of labor power, data, services, money, and finance that flow over them. While many allege that networks like the Internet tend to “negate geometry,” to be “anti-spatial” or to be “incorporeal” (Mitchell, 1995, pp. 8–10), the cumulative effect of spatial metaphors means that they become visualizable and imageably reconstructed as giant, apparently territorial systems. These can, by implication, somehow be imag- ined similarly to the material and social spaces and places of daily life. In fact, such spatial metaphors are commonly related, usually through simple binary oppositions, to the “real,” material spaces and places within which daily life is confined, lived, and constructed. Some argue that the strategy of developing spatial metaphors is “perhaps the only conceptual tool we have for understanding the development of a new technology” (Sawhney, 1996, p. 293). Metaphor-making “points to the process of learning and discovery – to those analogical leaps from the familiar to the unfamiliar which rally the imagination and emotion as well as the intellect” (Buttimer, 1982, p. 90, quoted in Kirsch, 1995, p. 543). As with the glamorous, futuristic technological visions, or dark, dystopian portraits within which they are so often wrapped, these techno- logical metaphors “always reflect the experience of the moment as well as memo- ries of the past. They are imaginative constructs that have more to say about the times in which they were made than about the real future” (Corn, 1986, p. 219). Too often, the pervasive reliance on spatial and technological metaphors actually serves to obfuscate the complex relations between new communications and infor- mation technologies and space, place, and society. In the simple, binary allegations that new technologies help us to access a new “electronic space” or “place,” which somehow parallels the lived material spaces of human territoriality, little conscious thought is put to thinking conceptually about how new information technologies actually relate to the spaces and places bound up with human territorial life. Without a thorough and critical consideration of space and place, and how new information technologies relate to, and are embedded in them, reflections on cyber- space, and the economic, social, and cultural dynamics of the shift to growing “tele- mediation,” seem likely to be reductionist, deterministic, oversimplistic, and stale. In this article I aim to explore some of the emerging conceptual treatments of the relationships between information technology systems and space and place. Build- ing on my recent work with Simon Marvin on the relationships between tele- communications and contemporary cities (Graham and Marvin, 1996), and on conceptualizing telecommunications-based urban change (Graham, 1996), I iden- tify three broad, dominating perspectives and explore them in turn. First, there is the perspective of substitution and transcendence – the idea that human territorial- ity, and the space and place-based dynamics of human life, can somehow be replaced using new technologies. Secondly, there is the co-evolution perspective which argues that both the electronic “spaces” and territorial spaces are necessarily produced together, as part of the ongoing restructuring of the capitalist political-economic system. Finally, there is the recombination perspective, which draws on recent work in actor-network theory. Here the argument is that a fully relational view of the links between technology, time, space, and social life is necessary. Such a 338 STEPHEN GRAHAM perspective reveals how new technologies become enrolled into complex, contin- gent, and subtle blendings of human actors and technical artifacts, to form actor- networks (which are sociotechnical “hybrids”). Through these, social and spatial life become subtly and continuously recombined in complex combinations of new sets of spaces and times, which are always contingent and impossible to generalize.

Substitution and Transcendence: Technological Determinism, Generalized Interactivity, and the End of Geography Both the dominant popular and academic debates about space, place, and infor- mation technologies adopt the central metaphor of “impact.” In this “mainstream” of social research on technology (Mansell, 1994), and in the bulk of popular and media debates about the Internet and “information superhighway,” new telecom- munications technologies are assumed directly to cause social and spatial change, in some simple, linear, and deterministic way. Such technological determinism accords with the dominant cultural assumptions of the West, where the pervasive experience of “technology is one of apparent inevitability” (Hill, 1988, p. 23). Here technology is cast as an essential and independent agent of change that is separated from the social world and “impacts” it, through some predictable, universal, revolutionary wave of change. In terms of the “spatial impacts” of current advances in communications tech- nologies, two broad and related discourses have emerged from the loosely linked group of technological forecasters, cyberspace commentators, and critics who found their commentaries on simple technological determinism (that is, extrapolating the “logic” of the spatial impacts of telecommunications from the intrinsic qualities of the technologies themselves). First, there are widespread predictions that concen- trated urban areas will lose their spatial “glue” in some wholesale shift towards reliance on broadband, multimedia communications grids. Advanced capitalist soci- eties are thus liberated from spatial and temporal constraints and are seen to decen- tralize towards spatial and areal uniformity. Secondly, there are debates about the development of essentially immersive virtual environments, which, effectively, allow the immersive qualities of geographical place to be transmitted remotely.

Areal uniformity, urban dissolution, and generalized interactivity The geographical effects on space and place of the supposedly wholesale “techno- logical revolution” based on new information and communications technologies become fairly easy to establish, if one follows an essentialist, cause-and-effect, and deterministic logic through. As technologies of media, computing, and telecommu- nications converge and integrate; as equipment and transmission costs plummet to become virtually distance independent; and as broadband integrated networks start to mediate all forms of entertainment, social interaction, cultural experience, eco- nomic transaction, and the labor process, distance effectively dies as a constraint on social, economic, and cultural life. Human life becomes “liberated” from the constraints of space and frictional effects of distance. Anything becomes possible anywhere and at any time (see Graham and Marvin, 1996). All information becomes accessible everywhere and anywhere. The “logic” of telecommunications and THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 339 electronic mediation is therefore interpreted as inevitably supporting geographical dispersal from large metropolitan regions, or even the effective dissolution of the city itself (Gillespie, 1992; Graham, 1997). Most common here is the assumption that networks of large metropolitan cities will gradually emerge to be some technological anachronism, as propinquity, con- centration, place-based relations, and transportation flows are gradually substituted by some universalized, interactive, broadband communications medium (the ultimate “Information Superhighway”). To Baldwin and colleagues (1996), for example, this all-mediating network, this technological Holy Grail of fully con- verged telephony, TV, media, and data flow, embellished with virtual shopping and interactive video communications, is already in sight, with the trials of so-called full-service networks (FSNs) in cities like Orlando, Florida. “We now have,” they write (1996, p. 1),

a vision of an ideal broadband communication system that would integrate voice, video and data with storage of huge libraries of material available on demand, with the option of interaction as appropriate. The telephone, cable, broadcast, and computer indus- tries, relatively independent in the past, are converging to create these integrated broad- band systems.

Such substitutionist arguments, in fact, have a long lineage. Assumptions that advances in telecommunication will “dissolve” the city have a history as long as electronic communication itself. Caroline Marvin (1988), in her book When old technologies were new, recounts the many assumptions in the late nineteenth century that the seemingly fantastical technologies of the telegraph, wireless, and telephone would annihilate space constraints through minimizing time constraints. Social, cultural, and geographical differences were to be obliterated in the world- wide shift to ubiquitous, universally accessible telecommunication. According to Edward Bellamy, writing in 1897 (pp. 347–48), “wherever the electric connection is carried . . . it is possible in slippers and dressing gown for the dweller to take his choice of the public entertainment given that day in every city of the earth.” Such technologically determinist predictions also resonate surprisingly strongly with some of the more critical recent perspectives of the relationships between space, place, and technological change. For example, Paul Virilio (1993) recently suggested that a culture of “generalized interactivity” is emerging, based on pervasive, ubiquitous, and multipurpose telematics grids, through which “everything arrives so quickly that departure becomes unnecessary” (Virilio, 1993, p. 8). “The archaic ‘tyranny of distances’ between people who have been geographically scattered,” he writes, increasingly gives way to the “tyranny of real time . . . The city of the past slowly becomes a paradoxical agglomeration in which relations of immediate proximity give way to interrelationships over distance” (Virilio, 1993, p. 10).

”Mirror worlds,” the transmission of place and world transcendence Virilio’s predictions of the evaporation of the material, physical dynamics of space and place find support in the more optimistic perspectives of “cyber-gurus” like Nicholas Negroponte (1995) and Bill Gates (1995). Again, the substitution ethos 340 STEPHEN GRAHAM dominates here, with the assumption that sophisticated VR technologies, switched over broadband global grids, will allow immersive, 3D environments to become so life-like that “real” places will easily become substitutable. David Gelerntner (1991) imagined that such technological trends will lead to the construction of “mirror worlds,” immersive electronic simulations tied into real-time monitoring apparatus which would allow us to “look into a computer screen and see reality. Some part of your world – the town you live in, the company you work for, your school system, the city hospital – will hang there in a sharp color image” (Gelerntner, 1991, p. 1; see also Graham, 1998). Such technologically evangelistic debates about “digital living” therefore suggest that we are on the verge of accessing a technological infrastructure which will do little less than provide some single, immersive system to mediate all aspects of human life. The implication is that the very concepts of material space, place and time, and the body, will be rendered problematic, even obsolete. We will shed, as Benedikt (1991) put it, the “ballast of our materiality,” escaping the physical, cor- poreal domains of the body, the territorial earth, and space and time in the process (Slouka, 1995, p. 25). Human societies, cultures, and economies are seen simply to migrate into the electronic ether, where identities will be flexibly constructed, any services might be accessed, endless fantasy worlds experienced and any task performed, from any location and at any time, by human agents acting inside the limitless domains of constructed electronic environments. Presumably, as human life becomes more and more dominated by what Thu Nguyen and Alexander (1996, p. 117) call “participation in the illusion of an eternal and immaterial electronic world,” the material world of space and place would become gradually eviscerated. Many cyberspace enthusiasts do, indeed, proclaim the need for what Schroeder (1994) has termed “world rejection.” Here cyberspace is seen to offer an alternative territoriality, an infinitely replenishable and extendible realm of spatial opportunity that counters the finitudes and problems of the increas- ingly crowded and problematic material spaces on earth. Of course, the foundations for such technological Utopianism, and determinism, are woven deeply into the very cultural roots of modern capitalist society (Marvin, 1988; Smith and Marx, 1995). Discourses of modernity and “progress” have been widely constituted through technological promises of brave new worlds with uni- versal, beneficent, totalizing shifts and secular technological Utopias variously prom- ulgated by pulp science fiction, comic books, futurists, architects and “city of the future” visionaries, advertisers, and technology firms (Corn and Horrigan, 1984).

Co-evolution: The Parallel Social Production of Geographical Space and Electronic Space The strong leaning of contemporary technological discourse towards substitution and transcendence perspectives, I would argue, tends to perpetuate little but dan- gerous myth and fallacy. In proffering new technologies as some complete and simple substitutes for the material body, the social world, and for space and place, its proponents do little to advance understanding of the complex co-evolutionary processes linking new information technologies and space, place, and human terri- toriality. Kevin Robins (1995, p. 139) has argued that they say more about their THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 341 own (usually masculine) “omnipotence fantasies” than about how complex combi- nations of place-based and telemediated interactions co-evolve. As he suggests, such perspectives rest on a

common vision of a future that will be different from the present, of a space or a reality that is more desirable than the mundane one that presently surrounds and contains us . . . All this is driven by a feverish belief in transcendence; a faith that, this time around, a new technology will finally and truly deliver us from the limitations and frustrations of this imperfect world (Robins, 1995, p. 135).

Fortunately, however, a much more sophisticated understanding has been developed recently through our second broad perspective which explores how the social pro- duction of electronic networks and “spaces” co-evolves with the production of material spaces and places, within the same broad societal trends and social processes (see Mosco, 1996, pp. 173–211). Three strands of work have emerged.

Articulations between place-based and telemediated relationships Rather than assuming some simple substitutional relationship, our second perspec- tive suggests that complex articulations are emerging between interactions in geographical space and place, and the electronic realms accessible through new technologies. The argument here is that, because cyber-evangelists are naively obsessed with the abstract transmissional capabilities of information technologies, technologically determinist debates usually neglect the richness and embeddedness of human life within space and place. Sawhney (1996, p. 309) criticizes the “very transmission-oriented view of human communication [in cyberspace debates]. The purpose of human communication is reduced to transfer of information and the coordination of human activity. The ritual or the communal aspect of human communication is almost totally neglected.” Technologically determinist commentators are accused of failing to appreciate the social, cultural, and economic dynamics of place and space that cannot be simply telemediated no matter how broadband, 3D, or immersive the substitutes. Quite the reverse, in fact, because the human construction of space and place is seen actually to ground and contextualize applications and uses of new technologies. Kevin Robins (1995, p. 153) believes that “through the development of new technologies, we are, indeed, more and more open to experiences of de-realization and de- localization. But we continue to have physical and localized existences. We must consider our state of suspension between these two conditions.”

Telecommunications and the city This “state of suspension” is especially evident in the contemporary metropolis, which, despite some trends towards the decentralization of routine service functions, shows no sign of simple, wholesale evisceration. Globally, urbanization trends are unmatched in history in their intensity; the global urban system continues to domi- nate the planet economically, politically, socially, and culturally; transportation flows and demands are spiraling at every scale; and even the large industrial cities 342 STEPHEN GRAHAM in the UK and USA that recently were shedding population are showing some signs of an (albeit patchy) economic and cultural renaissance, and demographic turn round. In short, new communications technologies are not simply substituting for the experience of, or reliance on, metropolitan places. Rather, a complex co- evolution, articulation, and synergy between place-based and telemediated exchange seem to be emerging. Castells (1996, p. 373) similarly posits that the new, integrated media systems will bring with them what he calls a “culture of real virtuality” drawing diverse participants and fragmented communities into new symbolic environments in which “reality itself (that is, people’s material/symbolic existence) is entirely captured, fully immersed in a virtual image setting, in the world of make believe, in which appear- ances are not just seen on the screen through which experience is communicated, but they become the experience.” Cyberspace is, in fact, a predominantly metropolitan phenomenon which is devel- oping out of the old cities. In terms of hard infrastructural investment, demand for services, and rates of innovation, the largest, globally orientated metropolitan areas are clearly maintaining their dominance. Thus, while New York has around 7% of the USA population, 35% of all outgoing USA international calls start there. While London has 17% of the UK population, 30% of all UK mobile phone calls are made there. And while Paris has 16% of the French population, it commands 80% of all investment in telecommunications infrastructure in France (Graham and Marvin, 1996, p. 133). The work of Jean Gottmann (1982) has clearly demonstrated that the incorpo- ration of computer networks into the economic, administrative, and sociocultural dynamics of the city merely intensifies and adds further capability to the older func- tions of the post, the telegraph, and the telephone. The maintenance of control over ever-more complex urban and regional systems, straddling ever-larger distances, and spread over larger and larger metropolitan corridors and regions, becomes possible. Rather than simply substituting or revolutionizing the city, and flows of people and material goods, the evidence suggests that new technologies actually diffuse into the older urban fabric offering potential for doing old things in new ways. Urban trans- portation and infrastructure systems can be managed and controlled more precisely, improving capacity. Telecommunications co-evolve with transportation and physi- cal flows, sometimes replacing (telebanking for branch networks, email for post), sometimes generating (travel TV programs and conference and retail adverts), and sometimes enhancing transport capability (automatic route guidance) (see Graham and Marvin, 1996). New information technologies, in short, actually resonate with, and are bound up in, the active construction of space and place, rather than making it somehow redundant. William Mitchell’s notion of “recombinant architecture” is especially relevant here, because it demonstrates how constructed and produced material spaces are now being infused with cyberspace “entry points” of all kinds (Mitchell, 1995). Material space and electronic space are increasingly being produced together. The power to function economically and link socially increasingly relies on con- structed, place-based, material spaces intimately woven into complex telematics infrastructures linking them to other places and spaces. “Today’s institutions,” argues Mitchell (1995, p. 126), “are supported not only by buildings but by telecom- THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 343 munications and computer software.” Thus the articulation between widely stretched telematics systems, and produced material spaces and places, becomes the norm and is a defining feature of contemporary urbanism. Bookstores, libraries, universities, schools, banks, theaters, museums and gal- leries, hospitals, manufacturing firms, trading floors, and service providers increas- ingly become embodied through their presence in both material spaces and electronic spaces. While some substitution is evident – for example, with the closure of banking branches paralleling the growth of telebanking – much of the traditional, nonroutine face-to-face activity within constructed spaces, and the transportation that supports it, seems extremely resilient to simple substitution. In other words, the contemporary city, while housing vast arrays of telematic “entry points” into the burgeoning worlds of electronic spaces, is a cauldron of emotional and personal worlds and attachments, an engine of reflexivity, trust, and reciprocity (Amin and Graham, 1998). The complex articulations between the local and global dynamics of both mate- rial places and electronic spaces have recently been explored by Staple (1993). He believes that the Internet and other communications technologies, far from simply collapsing spatial barriers, actually have a dialectic effect, helping to compress time and space barriers while, concurrently, supporting a localizing, fragmenting logic of “tribalization.” Far from unifying all within a single cyberspace, the Internet, he argues, may actually enhance the commitment of different social and cultural inter- est groups to particular material places and electronic spaces, thus constituting a “geographical explosion of place” (Staple, 1993, p. 52). This “new tribalism,” exemplified by the use of the Internet to support complex diasporas across the globe, and to draw together multiple, fragmentary special interest groups on a planetary basis, “folds” localities, cities, and regions into “the new electronic terrain” (Staple, 1993, p. 52). But it is important to stress that the ways in which places become enmeshed into globally stretched networks like the Internet will be a diverse, contingent process. A wide diversity of relations seems likely to exist between the urban structures and systems, and indeed the particularities of culture, of different spaces and the growth of telemediated interaction.

Telecommunications, “spatial fixes,” and the production of space Theoretical perspectives drawing on critical political economy serve to exemplify further the ways in which new telecommunications systems are materially bound up with the production of complex new social and economic geographies. Reacting against the all-encompassing and overgeneralized concepts of the “global village” and “time–space compression,” Scott Kirsch (1995, p. 544, emphasis in original) argues that “by resorting to the rather cartoonish shrinking world metaphor, we lose sight of the complex relations . . . between capital, technology, and space, through which space is not ‘shrinking’ but rather must be perpetually recast.” Perhaps the clearest exploration of how telecommunications become woven in to the production of new geographical landscapes of production, consumption, and distribution at all spatial scales comes from Eric Swyngedouw (1993, p. 305). 344 STEPHEN GRAHAM

Building on the work of Harvey (1985a), he argues that every social and economic activity is necessarily geographical. It is “inscribed in space and takes place” (empha- sis in original). Human societies “cannot escape place in the structuring of the prac- tices of everyday life” (p. 305). Within an internationalizing economy, capitalist firms and governments must continually struggle to develop new solutions to the tensions and crisis tendencies inherent within capitalism, between what David Harvey calls “fixity” and the need for “motion,” mobility and the global circula- tion of information, money, capital, services, labor, and commodities (Harvey, 1985a). Currently, such tensions and crises arise because increasingly widely dis- persed areas of production, consumption, and exchange, befitting of the interna- tionalizing economy, need to be integrated and coordinated into coherent economic systems. Space thus needs to be “commanded” and controlled, on an increasingly international scale. To do this, relatively immobile and embedded fixed transport and telecommuni- cations infrastructures must be produced, linking production sites, distribution facil- ities, and consumption spaces that are tied together across space with the transport and communications infrastructure necessary to ensure that a spatial “fix” exists that will maintain and support profitability. Without the elaboration of ever more sophisticated and globally stretched transport and communications infrastructures, Harvey (1993a, p. 7) argues that “the tension between fixity and mobility erupts into generalized crises, when the landscape shaped in relation to a certain phase of development . . . becomes a barrier to further [capital] accumulation.” Thus, new telecommunications networks “have to be immobilised in space, in order to facili- tate greater movement for the remainder” (Harvey, 1985a, p. 149). Crucially, then, the political economic perspective underlines that the develop- ment of new telecommunications infrastructures is not some value-neutral, techno- logically pure process, but an asymmetric social struggle to gain and maintain social power, the power to control space and social processes over distance. As any inves- tigation of, say, the growth of global financial centers, or the extending global coverage of corporate telematics networks will soon discover, power over space and power over telecommunications networks go hand in hand. For example, Graham Murdock draws the striking parallel between the “fortress effect” generated by many postmodern office buildings, and the development of vast, private “data- spaces” on corporately controlled networks. He argues (1993, p. 534) that “here, as in territorial space, continuous battle is being waged between claims for public access and use, and corporate efforts to extend property rights to wider and wider areas of information and symbolization.” By demystifying, and unpacking, the social and power relations surrounding telecommunications and the production of space, the political economic perspective does much to debunk the substitutionist myths of technological determinism dis- cussed above. It allows us to reveal the socially contingent effects of new technolo- gies, the way they are enrolled into complex social and spatial power relations and struggles, and the ways in which some groups, areas, and interests may benefit from the effects of new technologies, while others actually lose out. Thus, “the increased liberation and freedom from place as a result of new mobility modes for some may lead to the disempowerment and relative exclusion for others” (Swyngedouw, 1993, p. 322). THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 345

Thus, within cities, forms of telematics super-inclusion (Thrift, 1996a) emerge for elite groups, who may help shape cocooned, fortified, urban (often now walled) enclosures, from which their intense access to personal and corporate transport and telematics networks allows them global extensability. Meanwhile, however, a short distance away, in the interstitial urban zones, there are “off-line” spaces (Graham and Aurigi, 1997), or “lag-time places” (Boyer, 1996, p. 20). In these, often- forgotten places, time and space remain profoundly real, perhaps increasing, constraints on social life, because of welfare and labor market restructuring and the withdrawal of banking and public transport services. It is easy, in short, to overem- phasize the mobility of people and things in simple, all-encompassing assumptions about place-transcendence (Thrift, 1996b, p. 304), which conveniently ignore the splintering and fragmenting reality of urban space. To Christine Boyer (1996, p. 20), the highly uneven geography of contemporary cities, and the growing severing of the “well designed nodes” of the city from the “blank, in-between places of nobody’s concern,” allows fortunate groups to “deny their complicity” in the production of these new, highly uneven, material urban landscapes. But perhaps the most extreme example of the complex interweaving of new technologies, power relations, and the production of space and place comes with the small, elite group who run the global financial exchanges in world cities. Here, we find that “the extensible relations of a tiny minority in New York, London, and Tokyo, serve to control vast domains of the world through international net- works of information retrieval and command” (Adams, 1995, p. 277).

Recombination: Actor-Network Theory and Relational Time-Spaces Our third and final perspective takes such relational views of the social construc- tion of technology further. Anchored around the actor-network theories of Michel Callon (1986, 1991) and Bruno Latour (1993), and drawing on recent theorizations of Donna Haraway on the emergence of blended human–technological “cyborgs” (or “cybernetic organisms” – see Haraway, 1991), a range of researchers from the sociology of science, science, technology and society, cultural anthropology, and, increasingly, geography have recently been arguing for a highly contingent, rela- tional perspective of the linkage between technology and social worlds. Actor- network theory emphasizes how particular social situations and human actors “enrol” pieces of technology, machines, as well as documents, texts, and money, into “actor-networks.” The perspective is fully relational in that it is “concerned with how all sorts of bits and pieces; bodies, machines, and buildings, as well as texts, are associated together in attempts to build order” (Bingham, 1996, p. 32). Nigel Thrift (1996a, p. 1468) summarizes the approach:

no technology is ever found working in splendid isolation as though it is the central node in the social universe. It is linked – by the social purposes to which it is put – to humans and other technologies of different kinds. It is linked to a chain of different activities involving other technologies. And it is heavily contextualised. Thus the telephone, say, at someone’s place of work had (and has) different meanings from the telephone in, say, their bedroom, and is often used in quite different ways. 346 STEPHEN GRAHAM

This linkage of heterogeneous technological elements and actors, strung across dis- tance, is thus seen as a difficult process requiring continuing efforts to sustain rela- tions which are “necessarily both social and technical” (Akrich, 1992, p. 206). The growing capabilities of telecommunications, for supporting action at a distance and remote control, do not therefore negate the need for the human actors which use them to struggle to enroll passive technological agents into their efforts to attain real, meaningful remote control. “Stories of remote control tend to tell of the sheer amount of work that needs to be performed before any sort of ordering through space becomes possible” (Bingham, 1996, p. 27). Such “heterogeneous work involv- ing programmers, silicon chips, international transmission protocols, users, tele- phones, institutions, computer languages, modems, lawyers, fibre-optic cables, and governments to name but a few, has had to be done to create envelopes stable enough to carry [electronic information]” (Bingham, 1996, p. 31). “Cyberspace” therefore needs to be considered as a fragmented, divided, and contested multiplicity of heterogeneous infrastructures and actor-networks. For example, there are tens of thousands of specialized corporate networks and intranets. The Internet provides the basis for countless Usenet groups, Listservers, corporate advertising sites, specialized Web sites, multi-user dungeons (MUDs), cor- porate intranets, virtual communities, and increasingly sophisticated flows of media and video. Public switched telephone networks (PSTNs) and the many competing telecoms infrastructures support global systems of private automatic teller machine (ATM) networks, credit card and electronic clearing systems, as well as blossoming applications for CCTV, tele-health, teleshopping and telebanking, global logistics, remote monitoring, back office and telesales flows, electronic data interchange (EDI), electronic financial transactions and stock market flows, as well as data and telephony flows. And specialized systems of satellite, broadband, cable, and broad- casting networks support burgeoning arrays of television flow. Each application has associated with it whole multiplicities of human actors and institutions, who must continually struggle to enroll and maintain the communications technologies, along with other technologies, money, and texts, into producing some form of function- ing social order. These, and the hundreds of other actor-networks, are always con- tingent, always constructed, never spatially universal, and always embedded in the microsocial worlds of individuals, groups, and institutions. Such sociotechnical net- works “always represent geographies of enablement and constraint” (Law and Bijker, 1992, p. 301); they always link the local and nonlocal in intimate relational, and reciprocal, connections. Such a fully relational perspective has important implications for the ways in which we conceptualize place, space, and time. For actor-network theory suggests that, rather than simply being space and time transcending technologies, telecom- munications systems actually act as technological networks within which new spaces and times, and new forms of human interaction, control, and organization are continually constructed (Latour, 1987). The merit of the actor-network perspective is the way it articulates human– technological recombinations and relationships through a rich, contextual, mapping which avoids essentializing sociotechnical relations. As an analytic perspective it helps to capture the complex and multiple relational worlds supported by infor- mation technologies. Its emphasis on sociotechnical “hybrids” further underlines THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 347 the growing difficulties of easily separating something called the “social” (or, for that matter, the “spatial”) from the “technological.” Rather than hypothesizing macrolevel technological “revolutions” it stresses multiple, contingent worlds of social action, underlining the difficulties involved in achieving social ordering “at a distance” through enrolling complex arrays of technological artifacts. In it humans emerge as more than just subjects whose lives are to be “impacted”; as more than bit-players within macrolevel processes of global structural change. Actor-network theory underlines forcefully that “living, breathing, corporeal human beings arrayed in various creatively improvised networks of relation still exist as something more than machine fodder” (Thrift, 1996a, p. 1466). Work by Thrift (1996a, 1996b) has used actor-network theory to show how highly concentrated urban spaces like the City of London, far from suffering some simple dissolution, have, over the past century, actually been continually recom- bined with new technological networks: the telegraph, telephone, and, most recently, the telematics trading system. Such new technologies, he writes, do not produce some “abstract and inhuman world, strung out on the wire” (Thrift, 1996a, p. 1480); they are subtly recombined with the spatial and social practices of workers and managers, operating within the complex, material, and social spaces of the City. Often, the use of faster and faster telematics systems actually increases the demands for face-to-face contact so that the interpretive loads surrounding infor- mation glut can be dealt with rapidly and competitively. “The major task in the information spaces of telematic cities like the City of London,” writes Thrift (1996a, p. 1481), “become interpretation and, moreover, interpretation in action under the pressure of real-time events.” Thus the production of new material spaces, and the social practices that occur in them, is neither some technological cause-and-effect, nor some simple political-economic machination. Rather, it is

the hybrid outcome of multiple processes of social configuration processes which are specific to particular differentially-extensive actor-networks (made up of people and things holding each other together) and generate their own space and own times, which will sometimes, and sometimes not, be coincident. There is, in other words, no big picture of the modern City to be had but only a set of constantly evolving sketches (Thrift, 1996a, p. 1485).

Conclusions: Space, Place, and Technologies as Relational Assemblies Two clear conclusions for how we might address the linkages between space, place, and information technology emerge from our discussion of the three broad substi- tution, co-evolution, and recombination perspectives. First, we need to be extremely wary of the dangers of adopting, even implicitly, deterministic technological models and metaphors of technological change. The choice of words here is important. For example, the very notion of a technological “impact,” so long a central feature of mainstream technological debates in urban and regional studies (e.g., Brotchie et al., 1987), is problematic, because of its atten- dant implications of simple, linear, technological cause and societal effect. In their extreme form, deterministic approaches deliver little but the “logic” of apparent 348 STEPHEN GRAHAM technological inevitability, naive assumptions about simple, cause-and-effect, social and spatial “impacts,” and even messianic and evangelistic predictions of pure, technological salvation. The co-evolution perspective teaches us that such perspectives fail to capture the ways in which new technologies are inevitably enrolled into complex social power struggles, within which both new technological systems and new material geo- graphical landscapes are produced. The recombination perspective, on the other hand, teaches us that such broad-brush transition and “impact” models ignore the full, contingent, and relational complexity surrounding the social construction of new technologies, within and between specific places. It argues powerfully that, outside such contingencies, the meaning and effects of new information technolo- gies can never be fully understood or simply generalized. Secondly, however, we need to be equally wary of the dangers of adopting simplis- tic concepts of space and place. Following the arguments of such authors as Giddens (1979), Massey (1993), and Harvey (1993a, 1996) we need to reject the extremely resilient “Euclidean” notions, still implicitly underlying many treatments of the geographies of information technology, that treat spaces and places simply as bounded areas, as definable, Cartesian spatial objects, embedded within some wider, objective framework of time-space. As Doreen Massey (1993, p. 66) suggests, places need to be defined in relational terms, too, as “articulated moments in networks of social relations and understandings” rather than as “areas with boundaries around.” The message, then, is clear. Only by maintaining linked, relational conceptions of both new information and communications technologies and space and place will we ever approach a full understanding of the interrelationships between them. For Latour’s “skein of networks” (1993, p. 120) involves relational assemblies linking technological networks, space and place, and the space and place-based users (and nonusers) of such networks. Such linkages are so intimate and recombinatory that defining space and place separately from technological networks soon becomes as impossible as defining technological networks separately from space and place. The example of the contemporary city helps illustrate the point. Here, pro- pinquity in material space has no necessary correlation with relational meaning. Complex place and transport-based relational meanings – such as access to physi- cal infrastructure, property, labor markets, an “innovative milieu,” social inter- action, and the use of cultural facilities – are constantly being recombined with local and nonlocal relational connections, accessed via technological networks (telecom- munications, long-distance transport networks, and, increasingly, long-distance energy supplies too). The “urban” thus can now be seen as a locus for many sociocultural, economic, and institutional networks and practices, spread out over diffuse and extended regions, and mediated by complex combinations of physical “copresence” and tech- nological mediation (see Healey et al., 1995). In some, the interlinkage and super- imposition within physical urban space form meaningful nodes and connections – economic, social, cultural, physical. In others, the place-based relations are out- weighed by the technologically mediated links to far-off places. Thus, neighbors may or may not know each other’s names and have meaningful social relations. Adja- cent firms may or may not create meaningful linkages (adjacent back offices are likely to be tied intimately into their own distant corporate telematics networks but THE END OF GEOGRAPHY OR THE EXPLOSION OF PLACE? 349 poorly linked to each other). Urban public spaces may or may not emerge as common cultural arenas in their articulations with global media flows and exchanges. Complex, subtle, and contingent, combinations of electronic propinquity in the “nonplace urban realm” (Webber, 1964) and place-based relational meanings based on physical propinquity and transport therefore need to be considered in parallel. Such recombinations of “technology” and “place” represent merely the latest processes of urbanism and not some simple post-urban shift (Graham and Marvin, 1996). While cities are often spreading out to be vast, multicentered urban regions linked into global networks, place-based relational webs that rely on adjacency, propin- quity, and physical flows remain central to the experience of human social, eco- nomic, and cultural life. The two rely on each other; they recursively interact. For, as Storper (1996) suggests, shifts towards growing reliance on telemediated infor- mation, image, electronic transactions, and financial flow, as well as the continuing importance of fashion, art, the media, dance, consumption, leisure, research, play, collective consumption, travel, tourism, education, and governance (Thrift, 1996b), place a premium on reflexivity, interpretation, and innovation – the key assets of urban areas. As he argues, “the worlds of action which make up the [reflexive] city economy and society are hybrids, constrained by the machine-like forces of late modern capitalism, but themselves enabled by the ways that system not only permits, but in certain ways, thrives on social reflexivity” (Storper, 1996, p. 32). Chapter 22 Best Practice? Geography, Learning, and the Institutional Limits to Strong Convergence

Meric S. Gertler

According to an increasingly accepted view, the sovereignty of national economies has been eroded to the point where nation-states “have become little more than bit actors” (Ohmae, 1995, p. 12). With the development of globalized financial markets, the rising power of multinational corporations (MNCs), and the emer- gence of a new set of supranational institutions to govern economic processes on a continental or world scale, nation-states are said to have lost the ability to manage their own domestic economic affairs, having ceded control over exchange rates, investment, and even fiscal policy to extranational forces (Strange, 1997). More- over, with the increasing leverage and reach of MNCs further contributing to the erosion of national economic sovereignty, the once distinctive character of particu- lar national industrial “models” is said to be under imminent threat. While it may still be possible to identify at least three clearly distinctive national models – an Anglo-American model, a Rhineland (German) model, and a Japanese model – the decline of national institutions, the intensification of competitive forces on a global scale, and the cross-penetration of national markets by MNCs are said to have propelled a process of convergence between these different national models. In most representations of this globalization dynamic, convergence is regarded as inexorable and unstoppable. One of the most important processes underpinning this dynamic is learning. At the global level, large corporate actors are allegedly learning from each other, so that the most successful corporate practices are emulated and diffused crossnationally at an increasingly rapid pace. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, considerable attention was devoted to the diffusion of methods of production and workplace organization perfected by Japanese producers of cars and consumer elec- tronics, in which American, Canadian, and European manufacturers were shown to be learning methods such as just-in-time, kaizen/continuous improvement, and other aspects of lean production techniques from their Japanese competitors (Womack et al., 1990). Since the resurgence of the United States economy begin- ning in the second half of the 1990s, American practices have apparently become the object of global firms’ affections, with large corporations in Europe and Asia BEST PRACTICE? 351 adopting the core characteristics of US-style “shareholder capitalism”; especially flexible labor market practices, “reengineering,” and the empowerment of share- holders (The Economist, 1996a, 1996b). Closely bound up with this narrative on convergence and learning is the key concept of “best practice,” a term which has diffused into the lexicon of business school theory, corporate rhetoric, management consulting, and the popular business press with startling speed. It reflects the idea that there is one universal standard against which firms (anywhere) can and should measure their operational perform- ance. Moreover, best practice is applied to both outcomes (e.g., defect rates per thou- sand; labor hours per vehicle assembled) and processes (e.g., ISO 9000 and ISO 14000 standards for quality management and environmental practices; as well as specific techniques and modes of production organization). Not surprisingly, an entire industry dedicated to the benchmarking of firms’ practices, processes, and achievements has arisen, led by international management consultancies such as McKinsey, Boston Consulting Group, KPMG, PricewaterhouseCoopers, and others. Despite the compelling nature of this narrative about learning-driven convergence and best practice, at least two major questions remain contentious and unresolved. First, what are the principal mechanisms and channels through which learning-drive convergence is alleged to take place? The absence of detailed analysis of this issue in both the scholarly literature and the business press is troubling. Concepts such as learning and best practice have become, implicitly, both self-evident and unas- sailable. As a result they have also become deproblematized, in the sense that not only the definition but also their implementation and attainment are accepted as straightforward. The arguments presented in this paper aim to demonstrate the utter folly of this position, while analyzing the principal mechanisms and processes through which learning-driven convergence could conceivably be achieved. Second, while the evolutionary paradigm in economics (Hodgson, 1988, 1993; Nelson, 1995), as well as the closely associated multidisciplinary field of socioeco- nomics (Granovetter and Swedberg, 1993), emphasize the central role played by institutions in the structuring of practices inside the firm and in interfirm relations, there remains considerable debate and uncertainty about which institutions matter, how they exert their influence to shape, constrain, limit, or govern firms’ practices and ability to learn, and whether or not this is changing at present. In particular, our understanding of the role of these institutions in mediating social learning processes by firms remains rather underdeveloped. These questions also raise the important issue of scale: what is the relative importance of different scales of insti- tutional governance in the regulation of these economic processes? In this paper, the well-known arguments about the declining purchase of the nation-state and the rise of new institutional forms at the regional level to fill the regulatory void will be reconsidered, along with a set of more recent claims about the growing importance of a third source of governance of the firm whose influence allegedly transcends institutional boundaries at both the regional and the national scale.

Mechanisms and Channels of Learning-Driven Convergence Since “convergence” appears to mean many things to many people, it is best to begin by clarifying the sense in which it is being used in the present context. Simply 352 MERIC S. GERTLER put, convergence may be said to occur when firms originating in different national institutional spaces implement the same production methods or practices. Here, “methods or practices” must be broadly defined to embrace two different scales. They include practices internal to the individual firm, such as the use of particular machinery and process technologies, production systems, and the organization of work flow, the division of labor within individual plants or offices, quality man- agement approaches, inventory management systems, employment relations, and inter-divisional relationships (between, for example, research and development, pro- duction, and marketing). They also include practices external to the firm, that is interfirm relationships and transactions of both a vertical and horizontal nature. The former encompass relations with customers and suppliers, the types of relationships established (e.g., contractual/arm’s length, collaborative), including what Lundvall (1988) and others refer to as user–producer interaction, as well as the technologies used to support transactions (logistics, information systems). The latter refer to relations between firms in the same or closely related industries (e.g., direct collaboration, other forms of associative action) and firms’ relations with institutions (e.g., education and train- ing, research, producers’ associations, chambers of commerce). Two further comments on this definition are warranted. First, this broad defini- tion of “practices” is adopted explicitly to foreground the social context in which they are developed, diffused, and implemented. It also corresponds to broader conceptions of “technology,” not dissimilar to classical Marxian definitions which emphasize both forces of production and the social relations in which those forces are applied (Harvey, 1982). Second, notice as well that “convergence” as employed here does not refer to the narrow economic definition of diminishing differences in incomes, wages, productivity, or industrial structure between regions over time (for a critical review of this literature, see Martin and Sunley, 1998). While the processes outlined above may ultimately lead to such outcomes, this is by no means a fore- gone conclusion. Before considering the actual mechanisms or channels of convergence, it is impor- tant to make one further distinction which is frequently overlooked in less-than- systematic accounts of convergence dynamics – that is, the key distinction between weak and strong convergence. When a firm originating in country A establishes (or acquires) a branch in a new host country B, and adopts the distinctive practices characteristic of the host country (B) at its foreign site, this constitutes convergence of a sort. However, when the same firm adopts “country B” practices for imple- mentation in its home country (A) operations (with or without having first estab- lished a foreign branch), arguably a much more profound form of convergence has occurred. One must therefore distinguish between the former (an example of weak convergence) and the latter (strong convergence). This is more than a semantic dis- tinction. While the former case provides evidence of the growing internationaliza- tion of production systems, it stops well short of dismantling the characteristic practices that constitute the industrial “model” of either country A or country B. While some might be tempted to argue that one ultimately leads to the other, that learning and adoption of new practices abroad represent a first step toward their implementation at home, there is no a priori reason why this would be either desir- able or easily attainable. We return to these issues below. First, however, we shall BEST PRACTICE? 353 consider the precise mechanisms through which such convergence processes might unfold.

Channels of convergence The issue of how convergence in industrial practices might actually occur has been considered so obvious or self-evident as to require no systematic consideration. Implicitly, the logic runs something like the following. Firms somehow become aware of a best practice (which differs from their own status quo) and, once enlight- ened, simply implement the new practice in straightforward fashion. Notice the number of hidden assumptions and processes embedded in this simple approach. First, the notion of “the firm”: presumably, what is usually meant by this is indi- vidual managers within these firms, although the dynamic of competition between individuals or divisions within large firms is not acknowledged (Schoenberger, 1997). The next step, somehow become aware of a best practice, is equally problematic on two grounds. First, the process by which firms become aware is rarely if ever spelled out; second, the status of best practice is itself assumed to be self-evident. The characteristic of universal superiority is presumed to have been established, as have the criterion/criteria by which this superiority is to be judged. Moreover, there is an implicit presumption above that, once firms have become aware of a new prac- tice which they believe to be superior to their own status quo, they will strive to adopt the new alternative. Clearly, this is somewhat unrealistic since the cost of change may be high and the anticipated benefits must be large enough to justify these costs. It is probably more reasonable to assume that firms depart from the status quo only when they perceive some kind of crisis or major threat to their com- petitive position. As for the final step, in which firms “simply implement the new practice in straightforward fashion,” even a moment’s reflection should be sufficient to convince one that this process is nowhere near as simple as it might seem. The annals of technology implementation analysis are replete with case studies in which new process technologies or modes of work organization have encountered serious – sometimes fatal – difficulties (Gertler, 1995). While the origins of these difficul- ties are often alleged to include insufficient investment in training of managers and workers, poor initial design, and overly enthusiastic sales people who make unsus- tainable promises concerning the capabilities of new technologies, the real founda- tions for such problems are usually found at a much deeper, institutional level, as we shall see below. Although each of the steps outlined above is seriously problematic, the one which has received the least attention in prior research is step two: how firms “become aware of a best practice,” and all of the issues implicitly associated with this process. One helpful approach to this question invokes actor-network theory from the soci- ology of scientific knowledge (Callon, 1991; Blauhof, 1994). This tradition views the diffusion of process innovations as the circulation of conventions which are pro- moted through three types of channel or media: texts (industry conferences, indus- try and trade journals); people (actors such as consultants, seconded employees, new hires, other personal contacts, social networks); and artifacts (“hard” technologies, including advanced machinery, information and communication technologies, 354 MERIC S. GERTLER

Passive/shallow • Media/education • Travel • Management consultants • Market trade (simple) • Market trade (organized) • Alliances • Mergers, acquisitions Active/deep • Foreign direct investment

Figure 22.1 Channels of convergence: a continuum of opportunities for learning- through-interaction database systems). Furthermore, it argues that such innovations are more likely to be adopted when they are perceived by firms to be capable of responding to spe- cific operational problems. This approach has the virtue of emphasizing the active and social nature of the process by which practices (best and otherwise) migrate between firms, industries, regions, and countries. While it is a helpful beginning, it can be improved upon. Among other things, despite signaling the social nature of the practice-diffusion process, the role accorded to actors (agents) in shaping firms’ practices is far too large since it fails to acknowledge a significant enough role for institutions (struc- tures) at a variety of spatial scales. Moreover, the three-way typology of texts, people, and artifacts is not sufficiently specific. By focusing on the medium through which interaction occurs rather than the nature of the interaction process itself, this scheme is of limited use: a more systematic typology would differentiate between different channels of transmission according to their degree of activeness since some forms of interaction are clearly more important while others are more superficial. [To address the issue of greater differentiation between various channels, Gertler proposes and discusses an eightfold classification of channels, ranging from passive/shallow to active deep (Figure 22.1): Media (print, video, electronic); travel (attending conferences or conducting site visits and tours to witness new practices); hiring management consultants; simple market trade (purchasing commodities “off the shelf”); organized market transactions (significant departures from existing prac- tice requires extended interaction and information sharing between producers and users who ideally are geographically, organizationally, and culturally proximate); alliances (extra-market collaboration for the purpose of sharing and/or jointly devel- oping technology); mergers/acquisitions (where learning occurs through explicit ownership stakes in new practices); and foreign direct investment (acquiring exist- ing assets or establishing new production facilities abroad, a long-term commitment often accompanied by exchange of personnel among branches and the head office).]

Scale and the institutional governance of industrial practices In this section, I critically assess three sets of arguments concerning institution influ- ences on firm practices which are differentiated primarily on the basis of scale: regional, national, and firm-level. BEST PRACTICE? 355

Regional institutions: “embeddedness” and the learning region thesis Perhaps no idea has gained currency with more speed and enthusiasm within eco- nomic geography than the notion that place plays a key role in determining the innovative capabilities and performance of individual firms (A. J. Scott, 1988b, 1996; Porter, 1990; Putnam, 1993; Saxenian, 1994; Storper, 1997; Cooke and Morgan, 1998). The central argument [is] that the geography of economic advantage and innovative capability is highly uneven, owing primarily to spatial variation in the social-institutional character of places. In these lucky places, firms become “embedded” in close vertical and horizontal relationships with other nearby firms, and within a rich, thick local-institutional matrix that supports and facilitates the production (private and socially organized), transmission, and propagation of new technologies (product and process). The ability of firms in such regions to do so is based on shared language, culture, norms and conventions, attitudes, values, and expectations which generate trust and facilitate the all- important flow of tacit and proprietary knowledge between firms (Grabher, 1993; Amin and Thrift, 1994). In other words, a set of characteristic practices emerges and rapidly spreads to many firms within the region, becoming in turn a part of the shared conventions characteristic of the local production cluster (Storper, 1997). Closely related is the idea that such regions can be characterized as learning regions: that is, places which foster social learning processes amongst firms, between firms and other local organizations, and reflexive learning by local and regional economic development agencies in the public and quasi-public sector (Florida, 1995; Morgan, 1997). Under such conditions, the “region-state” emerges as the scale best suited to the management of economic development and innovation. Especially important institutional entities include research centers and universities, other educational and training institutions, local producers’ associations, chambers of commerce, and technology-transfer agencies. Taken together, these elements have been characterized as constituting a regional innovation system (Braczyk et al., 1998). It is these institutional forces which are seen as being primarily responsible for producing and reproducing the characteristic firm practices (both internal and interfirm) which are so important to the economic success of such regions. Underlying these arguments about the rising prominence of the region-state as a source of successful economic governance is the parallel idea that the spread of the global economy has undermined and hollowed out the nation-state. National gov- ernments are viewed as no longer capable of governing the practices of firms within their borders to ensure economic prosperity, having ceded this role to institutions at the subnational (regional) and, to some extent, supranational levels (Ohmae, 1995). Indeed, this view has become so widely accepted as “received wisdom” that it has provided the rationale and guiding framework for economic development policy initiatives at the subnational level in many countries. However, as we shall see below, there may be good reasons to approach the learn- ing region and region-state hypotheses with a healthy degree of skepticism and caution. 356 MERIC S. GERTLER

National institutions: innovation systems, business systems, and the nation-state A growing body of research asserts the following thesis. Notwithstanding the unde- niably increasing influence of supranational institutions such as the European Union, the North American Free Trade Agreement, and the World Trade Organi- zation, and while acknowledging the growing importance of the region-state and other non-state regional initiatives, the nation-state and its institutional legacy still continue to exert a crucial influence over the practices of firms. However, precisely how this influence is exerted remains the subject of some debate, with at least two diverging views evident. Pauly and Reich (1997) find that multinational corporations forever bear the markings or imprint of their national origins. The path or strategy they choose is most strongly shaped by the national institutional legacy of their home country. These findings are consistent with the body of work which has been framed within national systems of innovation perspective. The contributors to Lundvall (1992), Nelson (1993), and Edquist (1997), as well as Pavitt and Patel (1995), assert that distinctive nationally organized constellations of institutions shape firms’ innova- tion practices and longer-term trajectories. There is no compelling evidence of con- vergence in national activities for technological accumulation since the 1970s and even some evidence of divergence, implying that national innovation systems have become more (not less) distinctive over time. Another related literature – on national business systems – offers a complemen- tary perspective which goes well beyond the study of innovation-generating activi- ties alone to argue that virtually all firm practices (day-to-day practices as well as long-term strategies) are strongly influenced or governed (though not wholly determined) by national macro-regulatory institutions and “market rules” (Maurice et al., 1986; Christopherson, 1993, 1999; Streeck, 1996; Lane, 1997; Whitley, 1998, 1999; O’Sullivan, 2000). Moreover, firms are quite often not conscious of the influence that this larger institutional matrix exerts on their choice of practices. The argument implicit in this literature is that the contours of the national macro-regulatory framework make certain choices easier or more likely, and others less so. Other recent work suggests that the framework national institutions of the economies are most influential in shaping the practices and strategies of multi- national firms abroad. Wever (1995) examines the experiences of American firms operating branches in Germany as well as German firms with branches in the United States. In a detailed assessment of these cases, she reports that both sets of firms were frustrated in their attempts to institute the “home” way of doing things in their foreign branch operations. Hence, according to Wever, when MNCs go abroad, the rules of the host country hold sway. In another study of the transfer of German practices and technology abroad, I conducted interviews with German advanced machinery manufacturers serving the Canadian and American markets (Gertler, 1996), having also interviewed their customers in Canada. The overwhelming conclusion of this work was that the most fundamental sources of difficulty for the North American users (including German-owned user plants) stemmed from the starkly different macro-regulatory BEST PRACTICE? 357 environment and institutions regulating labor markets, industrial relations, corpo- rate governance, and capital markets in these two “models” (Gertler, 1999). In other words, the “host rules” prevailed here too, even though they did not provide a very effective framework for the implementation of German manufacturing practices in North America. Finally, Schoenberger’s (1999) recent analysis of US multinationals with Japanese branches lends further support to the argument that rules in the national “host” setting prevail. Her case study of Xerox corporation reveals that the American parent had ample opportunity to learn from the obviously successful prac- tices of its Japanese subsidiary (a joint venture with Fuji), but failed to do so. While Schoenberger attributes this failure to the “cultural crisis of the firm,” her analysis raises some important questions about the difficulties or barriers to intrafirm learn- ing across major boundaries between distinct national systems (a theme to which I shall return below). The work reviewed above offers many important insights in support of the general proposition that the nation-state (whether “home” or “host”) is still a primary source of influence over industrial practices. Moreover, this work argues implicitly that all firms are embedded within an institutional matrix whether they realize it or not. This is not a process that happens just in those places lucky enough to have abundant trust and local institutional thickness. As a result, according to this view, the success with which firms can transpose a distinctive set of practices from one national space to another (i.e., learn) where the institutional environment is not as conducive or supportive of such practices will be limited at best. Moreover, although there is very little analysis of this issue in the literature, the same limitations ought to apply to interfirm as well as intrafirm practices. Hence, for example, to what degree and how successfully can German or Japanese firms setting up production operations in North America also re-create the unique set of “network” user–producer (or buyer–supplier) relations that have been so important to the earlier competitive success of their home operations? Moreover, given that the key macro-regulatory features of the German “stakeholder capitalism” model and the Japanese variant are so different from those in North America (Christopherson, 1993, 1999; Wever, 1995; Pauly and Reich, 1997; Lane, 1997; Whitley, 1999; O’Sullivan, 2000), what impact might this have on (i) the ability of these foreign firms to transpose their internal and interfirm practices to North America, or (ii) their ability to transpose lessons learned in their North American operations back to their home plants? After all, in order for us to be able to docu- ment strong convergence between national industrial models, we would need to find evidence that North American (or Anglo-American) practices learned abroad were in fact being imported back to Germany or Japan to transform practices there. In order to answer these questions, it is necessary to develop a detailed understanding of the processes by which interfirm learning occurs. Appealing as this line of argument is, it suffers from limitations. The region remains somewhat underdeveloped in these accounts. Moreover, we should be con- cerned to avoid the pitfalls of an excessive reliance on “methodological national- ism.” Clearly, our explanatory framework must accommodate qualitative variation between firms and the role of management in shaping outcomes. 358 MERIC S. GERTLER

The firm: capability, absorptive capacity, learning and communities of practice The large and well-established literature on corporate strategy suggests that there will be important variations from firm to firm in their willingness or ability to imple- ment particular workplace practices or to engage successfully in interfirm and inter- national learning processes (Porter, 1980; Mueller and Loveridge, 1995). Recently, this level of analysis has begun to attract much more attention within economic geography (see, for example, Schoenberger, 1997; Dicken, 1998). Firm-centered approaches privilege the firm as the decisive institution shaping its own practices. Ever since the publication of Michael Porter’s classic Competitive Strategy (1980) two decades ago, the fundamental notion – perhaps best thought of as the original conceit of modern management theory – is that firms have the potential to be “masters of their own destiny.” In its full-blown form, this idea has even been extended beyond the boundaries of the single firm, suggesting that firms can deter- mine not only their own internal practices and performance, but also actively shape or control the competitive environment around them. More recent approaches have shown considerably more humility on this matter, in particular the resource-based or capability-based view of the firm. According to this approach, the firm can be thought of as a collection of capabilities. The firm’s competitive success is seen to depend especially on its ability to develop and exploit its own distinctive capabilities – that is, those which cannot be easily replicated by competitors (Kay, 1996; Maskell and Malmberg, 1999). In the capability-based approach, most of the assets which constitute a firm’s distinctive capabilities must accumulate over time and may include things such as brand identity and reputa- tion, but also knowledge and routines embedded within teams, and relationships between the firm and its customers and suppliers. Moreover, it is the tacit knowledge produced and reproduced in these teams and relationships, based on shared norms and conventions, which is seen to be key. Here, capability and absorptive capacity merge with the closely related competence-based view of the firm, which conceives of the firm as a processor of knowledge (Fransman, 1994). Since the firm’s innovative capability is seen to be dependent on its ability to process (generate, maintain, replicate, modify, and, when necessary, forget) knowledge, this approach places key emphasis on cognitive or learning mech- anisms and the routines that support them. As in our earlier discussion of learning dynamics at the regional scale, this approach also views learning as fundamentally social in nature. However, the most important scale at which these social learning dynamics unfold is the community of practice (Brown and Duguid, 1996; Wenger, 1998). Communities of practice are groups of individuals informally bound together by shared expertise and a common problem. Typically a single large organization will contain multiple communities of practice – leading to a process of “distributed learning” – and the communities may also span the boundary of a single organiza- tion to include those in other organizations working on similar issues. These com- munities serve as the principal ensemble in which “learning-in-working” occurs through a collective, shared process of problem-solving, trial and error, and exper- imentation which leads to the development of new routines, conventions, and norms. In essence, communities of practice are seen as the principal mechanism through which tacit knowledge relating to new practices is produced and spread. BEST PRACTICE? 359

They are also presented as vehicles through which “best practices” may be spread throughout large (including multilocational) organizations (Ichigo et al., 1998; Brown and Duguid, 2000; Wenger and Snyder, 2000). Amin (2000) takes this idea one step further by offering a provocative sugges- tion that the received wisdom within economic geography and related disciplines concerning the centrality of the region as a source of innovation, learning, and tacit knowledge production is perhaps misguided. Instead, he offers up the possibility that relational organizational proximity (i.e., that which is achieved through communities of practice) might be more important than geographical proximity in constituting “the ‘soft’ architecture of learning.” While relational proximity may depend to some extent on face-to-face interaction, “it can also be achieved at a dis- tance,” thanks to modern communications technology and global business travel. Amin’s critique of the learning region hypothesis is salutary, for it reminds us of the importance of nonlocal organizational ties in the production of innovations and the transmission of new practices. It is especially welcome too for emphasizing the existence and importance of diversity and variation within large organizations – a view which dispenses once and for all with the myth of the unitary organization. Welcome as these insights are, one cannot help but wonder about the accuracy of the assumptions underlying them. The idea that organizational or relational proximity is sufficient to transcend the effects of distance (even when assisted by telecommunications and frequent travel) seems improbable. The contention that communities of practice can serve as the vector through which best practices are disseminated between different locales within the global corporation seems prob- lematic in light of our earlier discussion concerning the limits imposed on the trans- fer of firm practices by regulatory frameworks at the national level. There is little acknowledgement that systemic institutional influences might play an important role in helping determine which practices will flow between locations most easily and which will not. This is not to deny the possibility or feasibility of transferring best practices from one national setting to another. Under certain circumstances – that is, when the insti- tutional and regulatory framework in the “sending” and “receiving” country are similar – this kind of “convergence” will be relatively easy to achieve. When they differ, as in the work of Wever (1995) and others discussed above, this will be con- siderably more difficult even for global firms with deep resources.

Conclusion: Requirements of a New Theory of Firm Practices Returning to the central question of this paper – how are firm practices determined, and what does this tell us about the likelihood of convergence being achieved – we are now in a better position to evaluate the competing arguments and theoretical perspectives. It seems clear from the foregoing analysis that each of the major con- tenders does not, on its own, provide an adequate explanatory framework. If one accepts the central insight of Polanyi (1944) that the market is socially constructed and governed – and not a “natural,” given, inevitable form – then it makes perfect sense that firms in market economies should also be constructed to some extent by their social-institutional environment. The analysis presented above suggests strongly that firms’ choice of practices is constrained by more than the 360 MERIC S. GERTLER limits of their internal resources (financial, organizational, technological, creative) and strategic vision. However, this view is still not sophisticated enough to help us understand how firm practices arise and change over time. Among other things, a revised approach must give greater credence to the path- dependent nature of geo-corporate change. For example, when a firm “arrives” in a location inside a new national-institutional space (via FDI), it is not a blank slate – that is, it continues to bear many strong markings and influences from its origins (Doremus et al., 1998). These characteristics are bound to interact with local insti- tutional signals, influences, and characteristics in dialectical ways to produce a new set of practices which conform to neither “original” model – Abo’s (1996) “hybrid factories” and the German variant of “lean production” (Streeck, 1996) come to mind here. Second, it is important to reemphasize the undeniable reality that not all firms or managers are created equal: the agency of these actors does matter. They respond in different ways to the same challenges, based on their own histories, education, experience, temperament, corporate cultures, distinctive capabilities, intangible assets, and so on. Any revised theory of firm practices must make adequate room for individual, collective, and corporate agency within the firm. But at the same time, it is clearly misguided to argue that firms shape their own practices inde- pendently of wider, systemic influences. Third, a revised theory of firm practices should also be supple enough to accom- modate a role for regional institutions. For example, in the case of German firms bringing industrial practices to their newly established production operations in the United States, we might expect such influences to be exerted at both ends of the process, especially for small and medium-sized (Mittelstand) firms, which typically take on a characteristic set of practices that are strongly shaped by the distinctive institutional contours of many of Germany’s Länder (states) and substate regions (Sabel, 1989; Herrigel, 1994; Cooke and Morgan, 1998; Braczyk et al., 1998). These analysts stress the dense concentration of institutions at the Länd level which shape labor markets, industrial relations, training, investment, and industrial organ- ization, forging important horizontal linkages across firms in the same industry. These institutions include not only government agencies and educational institu- tions, but also private producers’ associations and chambers of commerce. There is also a need to consider the influence of key institutions and characteristics at the regional scale on the “receiving end,” as an important intervening force helping to shape the process by which firms transpose industrial practices and strategies from one national space (and continent) to another. How important are regional features such as state- or provincially-regulated industrial relations regimes, education and training systems, research, development, and (more broadly defined) innovation policies? What role does local history play in this process? These questions have received surprisingly little attention thus far. Coming back to our original question – about the true prevalence of convergence and prospects for future industrial and institutional evolution – it is important to keep in mind that true “strong” convergence requires best practices learned abroad to be transposed (with minimal modification) back home. The arguments presented in this paper suggest that the prospects for strong convergence are limited at best, and will remain so as long as national institutional frameworks retain their BEST PRACTICE? 361 distinctive character. They also suggest that the idea of a single, universal, bound- ary-transcending “best practice” is utterly unattainable, even though it may well be in management’s interest to perpetuate the myth of a single standard against which all local practices must be measured. This analysis also reminds us that while firms’ practices may converge, this does not necessarily translate into convergence of national systems, especially when the firms in question are multinational ones. For example, it will be considerably easier for a German firm to adopt Anglo-American practices by implementing these at pro- duction sites in the US or the UK than in its domestic operations. While there are undeniable pressures for change at home – supported, as Clark et al. (2001, 2002) point out, by the adoption of Anglo-American accounting practices amongst large German firms whose shares are publicly traded – fundamental questions remain. Are these sufficient conditions to bring about system-wide change (i.e., strong con- vergence) in a country such as Germany? How do the interests of internationally mobile managers within these large firms interact with those of other stakeholders (labor, consumers, small business, governments) to determine the path of change? Given that the large majority of Mittelstand firms remain privately held and con- trolled, how pervasive might such influences actually be? In addition to advancing the state of our theoretical understanding of how prac- tices are shaped, the accompanying empirical study of how convergence actually works (or doesn’t) is also sorely underdeveloped. The multi-channel approach presented in this paper may offer one promising avenue to explore in this regard. It is only through detailed, systematic, historically grounded case studies that we will once and for all be able to distinguish between the rhetoric and the reality of convergence. Chapter 23 Blood, Thicker than Water: Interpersonal Relations and Taiwanese Investment in Southern China

Y. Hsing

In this paper I explore the question of cultural and institutional conditions that shape the processes of transnational capital flows, by looking at Taiwanese manu- facturing investment in southern China. Since the late 1970s, Taiwan, like other Asian newly industrialized economies, has been caught in a squeeze between lower wage Third World competitors and the growing protectionism in the markets of the OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). Taiwan’s export-oriented manufacturing factories then began to move to Malaysia, Thailand, Indonesia, and the Philippines, where cheap labor was plentiful. However, in the 1980s, the rise in labor costs and the unstable political environment in many of these countries forced Taiwanese manufacturers to look elsewhere. In the meantime, China’s Open Door policy caught the attention of Taiwanese manufacturers, who responded quickly to the new opportunity (Hsing, 1997). By 1991 Taiwan had sur- passed the USA and Japan to become the second largest investor in China after Hong Kong. Realized direct investment from Taiwan to China totaled US $8–10 billion in 1994, which accounted for 20% of China’s total foreign direct investment; and provided more than 5 million jobs, of which 70% were concentrated in the Provinces of Guangdong and Fujian. Taiwanese manufacturing investment in southern China represents a new pattern of the foreign direct investment found in the rapidly industrializing regions. The new pattern of foreign direct investment is characterized by investors who are not vertically integrated giant transnational corporations. Instead, they are mostly small- and medium-sized, independent manufacturing firms. In addition, in contrast to the common pattern of foreign direct investment, which is based on the interaction between transnational corporations and the national government, the new pattern of investment is shaped by small investors negotiating with low-level local govern- ments in the host country. The investment is made more effective because of two major favorable conditions, namely, the newly gained economic autonomy of local governments in southern China; and the cultural affinity between the Taiwanese investors and their local agents in China. BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 363

Beginning from revising the model of a new international division of labor, in which cheap labor is seen as the main driving force of transnational capital flows (Fröbel et al., 1980), in this study of Taiwanese direct investment in southern China I show that although, since the 1980s, capital might have moved freely across national boundaries (see for example Carnoy, 1993; Castells, 1993; Johnston, 1986), it is still confined by institutional and cultural boundaries. Transnational capital has by no means flooded in all directions, as the terms “footloose” or “bor- derless world” (Ohmae, 1990) might imply. Nor has transnational capital followed a universally applicable set of strategies of accumulation and expansion in different places. Globalization does not produce homogeneity. Such an “unevenness” is generated, on the one hand, from the specificity and diversity of the locality itself. Globalization is conditioned by, and interacts with, local interpretations (Giddens, 1994, p. 5). In their studies of localities in the face of globalization, Bagguley et al. (1990), Ong (1991), and Hall (1991) show that elements such as production organ- ization, power structure, ethnic–racial constitutions, gender and labor relations, the cultural system, historical construction, and the intersections of these elements define the problematic of a locality. On the other hand, transnational capital is not homogeneous either. Although US, Western European, and Japan-based giant multinationals continue to play a crit- ical role in the global economy, international investments by the newly industrial- ized countries (NICs), especially investments from Brazil, South Korea, Hong Kong, and Taiwan, have received increased recognition (Agrawal, 1981; Allen and Hamnett, 1995, pp. 88–9; Chang and Thomson, 1994; Jo, 1981; Lall, 1985; Sercovich, 1984; Wells, 1983; White, 1981). In literature on the NIC-based multi- nationals the focus has been on how they behave differently from the “traditional” multinationals in terms of investment scales, levels of technological input, labor intensity, and the establishment of local production linkages. Though some writers believe that “Third World MNCs” (multinational corporations) have a greater potential to transfer more appropriate technologies to the host country, and are under greater pressure to purchase inputs locally because of their smaller scale (Lall, 1984; Wells, 1983), others argue that, although smaller in scale, the new MNCs are not qualitatively different from the traditional ones (Jenkins, 1987, pp. 159–62). However, given the increasingly diverse organizational characteristics of trans- national capitals and their investment strategies (for example, strategic alliance, international subcontracting, etc.), the dichotomy of “traditional” versus “new” multinationals is now less of an aid to understanding the interaction between local societies and transnational capitals. As the production, marketing, and financing arrangements between transnational capitals and local economic systems become increasingly complex, the differences between transnational capitals lie not only between traditional and new multinationals, but also between those of different organizational characteristics (Lim and Fong, 1982). Our inquiry, therefore, should be about the process and impact of specific investment patterns undertaken by spe- cific types of capital in specific places. Furthermore, corporate strategies and behaviors are not just the results of straightforward economic calculations in a vacuum. Instead, they are shaped by a set of socially and territorially grounded relationships. Economic processes are socially structured by ethnicity, gender, and other social and institutional elements. 364 Y. HSING

In terms of regional production networks, the social and institutional basis for the economic organization is mainly composed of the competitive and cooperative mechanisms among firms, the function of trade associations, the structure of labor markets, the dynamism of the local government, and so on. Some of the institu- tional elements are less formalized and therefore, more personalized than others. Long term and face-to-face interactions amongst agents also contribute to the estab- lishment and consolidation of interpersonal networks, which in turn generate intel- lectual ambience, trusting relationships, and information exchanges. The synergy created by interpersonal networks further enhances the flexibility, adaptivity, and competitiveness of firms and regional economies. Interpersonal network building is also a process of culture formation, represented by specific patterns of business prac- tices and social interaction in specific institutional contexts. If the interpersonal networks are socially embedded and territorially specified, what would happen to the networks when the capitals expand from one territory to another? Under which conditions will investors from outside the region be able to establish effective social networks in the new territory? And again, along which dimensions does the specificity of the capital affect the processes and consequences of such cross-territorial investments? These questions have to be explored in a more specific historical conjuncture. In the case of Taiwanese investment in southern China since the 1980s, one of the most intriguing characteristics of the investment is the historical connection and the cultural affinity between the investors and their local partners. Since the late 1980s Taiwanese investment in China has been a part of the fast growing “Greater China” economic circle (including China, Taiwan, and Hong Kong). In the meantime the formation of the Southeast Asian “growth tri- angle,” composed of Singapore, Malaysia, and Indonesia, has also been conducted mainly by overseas Chinese firms in these regions. These trade and investment alliances seem to suggest that there is some correlation between culture, history, and the direction of transnational capital flows. However, it is still not very clear how such cultural and historical connections affect the establishment of the interpersonal networks in the process of capital expansion, or, what the cultural principles that facilitate the establishment of the interpersonal networks are. If culture is defined as a given set of values and behavior codes of a specific people, and it is assumed that there is such a thing as “Chinese culture,” then what are the principles unique to Chinese culture (or, the principles that make Chinese culture different from other cultures) that are shared by Taiwanese investors and their Chinese partners, and have facilitated the interpersonal network building between them? If culture is defined not only as a set of values but also a historically and institutionally situated dynamism (Ong, 1987), how do we understand the interaction between the general cultural principles in Chinese traditions and specific institutional conditions in southern China, which have provided the basis for interpersonal network building between Taiwanese investors and their local Chinese partners? Most writers agree that the foundation of the Chinese style of business organi- zation is familism (which usually includes nepotism, paternalism, and family own- ership in firm organization) and “long-term personalistic ties,” or guanxi in Chinese, on which a trusting and reciprocal obligatory relationship is built between business partners. The question of interpersonal ties in economic processes has had a long tradition in anthropological studies, especially within the framework of “gift BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 365 exchange” (Curtin, 1984; Malinowski, 1961; Mauss, 1967; Sahlins, 1972; Yang, 1988, 1989, 1994). Gift exchange is understood as a process of building trusting interpersonal relationships in economic activities. What needs to be explored further is how, if at all, is the gift exchange practiced in the Chinese societies, or in the process of Taiwanese investment in southern China, different from the gift exchange in other societies and cultures. The historical and institutional contexts in southern China since the economic reform began, especially the increasing fiscal autonomy of local authorities, have shaped the forms and contents of gift exchange and the way Taiwanese investors establish interpersonal relations with local Chinese officials. Decentralized economic policymaking in China provides the basis for local authorities to bypass the central government and to link up with transnational capital directly. The greatly enhanced bureaucratic flexibility at the local level has been particularly crucial for the Taiwanese capital which is characterized by small scales, network form of organization, export orientation, and time sensitivity. My analysis in this paper is based on my interviews conducted in Taiwan, Hong Kong, Guangdong (the Pearl River Delta), Fujian (Xiaman Special Economic Zone), and Shanghai in 1991, 1992, 1993, and 1994. I conducted interviews with 54 local Chinese officials and 134 Taiwanese and Hong Kong investors, factory managers, and Chinese managers, staff, and workers in the factories. I focused my factory interviews on the export fashion shoe industry, and stayed in two Taiwanese- invested fashion shoe factories in the Pearl River Delta for one month.

Economic Autonomy of China’s Local Governments The decentralization of economic resources from the central government to local governments at the county and municipality levels, and the increasing economic autonomy of local authorities and the active role played by local officials, have been two of the major characteristics of China’s recent economic reforms. The economic autonomy of China’s local government is characterized by fiscal sovereignty and responsibility. There have been various revenue-sharing schemes which provide incentives to local governments to collect taxes and to engage directly in profit-making activities. At the same time, the central government permitted provinces to engage in foreign trade through local branches of the national foreign trade corporation (Ho and Huenemann, 1984; Solinger, 1987; Zhang and Zou, 1994). The county and municipal governments have also enjoyed the authority of approving foreign investment projects. The county government has the full author- ity to grant the permission for those projects under US $3 million; higher rank municipal authorities have as high as US $10 million leeway. The municipal and county governments can also issue import–export licenses, set up independent customs, grant industrial and residential land under a certain size, offer favorable investment conditions for foreign firms, and so on. Many state-owned enterprises have been transformed into collective enterprises which are owned and run by local governments at different levels. Compared with other regions in China, the provinces of Guangdong and Fujian have enjoyed the greatest economic autonomy. This is because of their 366 Y. HSING geographical position in the periphery and their strong social ties with overseas Chinese funding sources. Guangdong and Fujian could also retain a large portion of the foreign exchange which they earned from exports and tourism as well as a share of the remittances the residents of the two provinces received from abroad. The increasing fiscal autonomy was accompanied by the gain of financial responsibility by local authorities. Indeed many of the local bureaucrats are highly motivated in exploiting the new opportunities provided by the fiscal reform for their own personal gains. Yet, motivation also came from another source: the greater financial responsibility that the central authority transferred to the local governments. Local governments were required to be self-sufficient financially, and had to search for additional revenues to fund the increasing local shares in the expenditures on infrastructure construction, education, public health, and other items. The highly motivated local officials with their newly gained economic authority, who were also the only qualified partners for foreign capitals to establish joint ven- tures in China, have been the most important agents for Taiwanese investment in southern China. Local officials tend to be more flexible than central government officials in their implementation of regulations and are more willing to cooperate with overseas investors. Indeed their practices can be seen as various degrees of cor- ruption. Yet, such a moral judgment can hardly help us to understand the local pol- itics of foreign direct investment in China. Many of the Taiwanese and Hong Kong investors whom I interviewed agreed that it is faster and simpler to deal with the local than the provincial or central authorities. For export-oriented manufacturing, in which most of the overseas Chinese investors were engaged, speedy production and delivery are the most important competitive edges in the world market. Delayed deliveries often result in reduction of payment or cancellation of orders. The need to bypass the formal, bureaucratic procedures and to keep production and delivery moving as quickly as possible is important, particularly for the small- and medium- sized producers with limited operational capital. Lower-level officials at the county and city levels, motivated by the new fiscal schemes, are more willing to accom- modate the need of overseas investors to speed up the application process of invest- ment projects and are often willing to make flexible arrangements with individual investors. The possibility of making “flexible” deals with the low-level Chinese officials has been a major attraction to the small- and medium-sized investors from Taiwan and Hong Kong. Some medium-sized to large-sized investors even split their investment into a number of smaller projects so as to avoid the involvement of higher-level gov- ernment officials. For instance, one Taiwanese shoe company has built six estab- lishments in different towns in the Pearl River Delta region, hiring more than four thousand workers altogether. Yet each establishment was kept small enough, in terms of the total amount of capital, the number of employees, and the size of land used for factory buildings, in order to qualify as a small project that could be approved by the county government. Investors had to cultivate good relations with local officials of various agencies such as the Public Security Bureau, electricity, water, and telephone companies (which were publicly owned), customs, the Public Health Department, the Tax Bureau, the Committee of Foreign Economic and Trade, the Labor Department, local banks, and so on, in order to ensure a smooth BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 367 operation of production. The definition of efficiency in this case was the level of cooperativeness of the local officials. It was to the benefit of local officials to attract foreign investors in order to strengthen the economic base of the localities. These officials also gained personal benefits such as a large salary raise as a result of bonuses based on the profits of the joint ventures and collective enterprises. In fact the income levels of government officials in southern China, which vary from town to town, have been an indicator of the success the town has enjoyed in their joint- venture arrangements with overseas investors (interview, China, O-1). By taking advantage of the linguistic and cultural affinity, Taiwanese investors can successfully cultivate the interpersonal relationship with local Chinese officials and have built social networks with various governmental agencies in the region. It is true that building interpersonal networks between the investors and governmen- tal officials can be corrupt. For example, the owner of a Taiwanese shoe factory, which is located in a fishing village two hours from Shenzhen, told me that he had made a deal with the local party secretary of the county so that if he helped to pay the remittance for the county to the provincial government, the county customs would not inspect the company’s exports and imports too closely, nor would the tax bureau audit its accounting books. If I refer to a Chinese idiom, the official would “open one eye, with the other closed” when he visited the factory. Another large shoe factory has managed to maintain good relations with local custom offi- cials. Once every few months this large company reserves an entire Karaoke singing bar to entertain their friends in customs. As a result, the containers of the company’s imported materials have never been opened and inspected. The story about smug- gling operations is even more stunning. Because of the frequent rotation of custom officers from station to station, a broker might ship the goods to one port this week and to another port the next week in order to follow a particular custom officer who is a “friend” and will help to make sure that the broker’s containers go through customs quickly and without being inspected. It is true that cultural understanding between the investors and local agents does not guarantee the success of the investment projects, and it is very difficult to measure how critical cultural understanding and interpersonal networks are to the formation and operation of the enterprises. However, as they were expressed so fre- quently in the interviews with Taiwanese investors in China, the cultural factors cannot be ignored. In the following section I will discuss the cultural basis of the interpersonal networks built between Taiwanese investors and local officials in southern China.

Interpersonal Relationship between Taiwanese Investors and Local Chinese Officials Many Taiwanese investors whom I have interviewed agree that, compared with other overseas production sites, China is more attractive to them because of the cul- tural and linguistic affinity between Taiwanese and Chinese. Further, Taiwanese investment in China has grown faster than that in the ASEAN (Association of South- east Asian Nations) countries since the late 1980s. Such cultural affinity has facili- tated the establishment of interpersonal relationships between Taiwanese investors and local Chinese officials. Yet, the significance of these interpersonal relationships 368 Y. HSING is by no means unique to Taiwanese investment in China. The question is, if inter- personal relationships are a key factor in the success of Taiwanese investment in southern China, and the cultural affinity between the investors and their local agents is crucial for the establishment of such relationships, what are the culturally embedded principles of the establishment of such interpersonal relationships? I adopt Ong’s (1987) approach in her analysis of shop-floor gender politics in the Japanese-funded factories in Malaysia, in which she does not see culture as a given set of values, but as a historically and institutionally situated dynamism. She argues that, while culture highlights core social values, there is no direct relationship between values and behavior that is independent of institutional or organizational contexts. From this historical and institutional contingent perspec- tive of culture, I will examine the way cultural factors have shaped the processes and strategies of Taiwanese manufacturing investment in southern China. I focus on the principles and the practices of interpersonal network building between Taiwanese investors and local Chinese bureaucrats on the basis of gift exchange in a specific institutional context in southern China since the reform started in the late 1970s.

Flexible Interpretation and Implementation of Laws As suggested before, the increasing local economic authority in China, at the macro level, has provided the institutional basis for the flexible arrangement between Taiwanese investors and Chinese officials. At the micro level, one important element that affects the extent and forms of the networks established between business and the state is that Chinese bureaucrats are traditionally flexible when they come to interpreting and implementing the law. It has been a skill of Chinese bureaucrats to make decisions based on what higher-level officials would not oppose rather than what they would allow. In Chinese this policy is called “looking for holes” (zuan kong-zi). The philosophy is “if something is not explicitly prohibited, then move ahead; if something is allowed, then use it to the hilt” (Vogel, 1989, p. 81). The application of such a philosophy in the local decision-making process is demon- strated by the flexible interpretation and implementation of the regulations that are imposed by the higher-level governments. A Chinese idiom reflects well such a trend of superficial compliance of top-down policies and the tension between the high- and low-level authorities: “policies from the top, counterstrategies at the bottom” (shangyou zhengce xiayou duece). The degree of autonomy of local officials and the width of the gap between the written regulations and the actual practices depend on how well such a culture of superficial compliance is developed and how fiscally independent the local govern- ment in question is. An official in charge of foreign trade and investment in Xiamen, Fujian Province, explained to me why Guangdong has been one step ahead of Fujian in economic reform: “leaders in Guangdong have been more willing and daring to push to the limits of the policies imposed by the central government. They are also readier to try out new strategies before they receive clear signals from Beijing.” Facing the problems of rapidly declining tax revenue to the central government, in the early 1990s Beijing began to tighten up the control of loans and project approval authority. However, in a city district of Guangzhou, an officer of the Land Bureau BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 369 told me that since the central government imposed the austerity policies in 1993 and placed a greater restriction on the size of lots that the district government could lend to developers, the district government had adopted the strategy of “small is beautiful,” dividing the lot for one project into several smaller lots and granting land-use permission individually in order to avoid the involvement and scrutiny of higher government units. The culture of shangyou zhengce xiayou duece thus has blossomed in the institutional context in which opportunities for local accumula- tion present themselves. Taiwanese investors obtained favorable investment conditions from local officials on the basis of their understanding of such a flexibility in the interpretation and implementation of regulations. A Taiwanese investor commented that the way he dealt with mainland Chinese officials was very similar to the way he had dealt pre- viously with the Taiwanese officials (interview, China, E-l). Given the loose control of the central government on small business, and the negotiable policy implemen- tation in Taiwan, Taiwanese investors have found little “cultural barrier” to “finding the holes” in southern China. The degree of flexibility tends to increase as the level of government decreases. The tax relief has been one of the most critical favorable investment conditions. The standard enterprise income tax rate of foreign-funded joint ventures was 33%. This tax was totally exempted for the first 2–3 profitable years. For the next 3–4 years half of the tax was exempted. In many cases the tax- free period was extended, or tax rates were kept at 15% after the tax-free period was over. Other favorable investment conditions that local governments had the authority to grant to foreign ventures entailed the transfer of profit out of China; relaxation of the rules on foreign exchange balance; reduction of power fees, water fees, and land price for factory buildings; exemption of import licenses; provision of cheap loans; relaxation of restrictions on the hiring of nonlocal workers; and exemption of social welfare contributions, etc. There are no upper limits on the size of loans to be granted to enterprises, nor are there any clearly stated policies on the criteria for loan approval. Therefore, local banks have enjoyed a high degree of flexibility in the acquisition and granting of loans. Underneath the guise of stated policies which were supposed to be applicable universally, the actual investment arrange- ments were mostly tailor-made for individual enterprises and investors, and the prof- itability of the investment package was mostly dependent upon the relationship between the investor and the local officials. As a Taiwanese investor forthrightly put it, “No favorable investment policies issued by the government can be as favorable as the special deals I made with the local officials.” The increasing economic autonomy of Chinese local governments, combined with the culture of Chinese local bureaucracy in their flexible interpretation and implementation of centrally imposed laws, has provided an institutional frame- work in which the actual practice of gift exchange is carried out. In Sahlins’s (1972) and Malinowski’s (1961) works on gift economy, gift exchange differs from market exchange in that it is highly personalized, embedded in ongoing personal relations. The meaning and the effect of the gift depends on who gives it and who receives it and what their relation is and will be. Unlike market exchange, the value of the gift is not always measurable in monetary terms, and gifts have a utility independent of their monetary value. To sustain the exchange relationship 370 Y. HSING it is crucial to meet the expectation of reciprocity and make a fair return. The timescale for returning the gift is not fixed and one is not required to return the gift immediately. I have identified four cultural–institutional elements that have shaped the practice of gift exchange. These are, measurements of the value of the gift; the sense of time in Chinese culture, which includes the meaning of efficiency, the timelessness of the exchange relationship, and the importance of timing in the giving of gifts; the sense of space in Chinese culture, especially the vague boundaries between the public and the private domain; and last, linguistic com- monality as a tool of communication between gift givers and receivers, especially in the understanding of the hidden messages that lie underneath the spoken words, which plays a crucial role in the establishment of personal relations through gift exchanges.

Measurements of the value of the gift Gift exchange is not always an equal exchange in quantitative terms and the exchanged “gift” is not necessarily of a material form. In fact, the art of gift exchange is to maintain the balance between offering material favors and expressing friendship and loyalty to each other as the basis of mutual trust, which goes beyond immediate material benefits. One needs cultural understanding to perceive where the balance point is and the value of the gift in nonmonetary terms. In many cases the nonmaterial form of gift is even more valuable than the material gifts, especially if the nonmaterial gift can express a greater degree of loyalty. For example, a Chinese official might ask an overseas investor to be the sponsor of his or her child who has planned to attend a US university. The over- seas investor might or might not have to take the financial responsibility for the child, but to be a sponsor involves greater risks than simply offering some luxuri- ous gifts or cash. A favor that involves a certain degree of risk is far more effective in winning the trust of the other partner; and it paves a smoother path for future collaboration. Gifts also have a use-value independent of their monetary value (Sahlins, 1972, p. 12). A rare, but not necessarily expensive gift that cannot be bought “just because one has the money” demonstrates greater sincerity and respect for others. Conse- quently, a return of the favor of even greater value can be expected.

Sense of time: efficiency, timelessness, and timing In gift exchange the persons who are engaged in the exchange relationship deter- mine the nature of the exchange. Unlike the market exchange, gift exchange cannot happen between strangers. It only happens between those who have a certain type of preexisting interpersonal relationship, such as classmates, people from the same native place, relatives, colleagues, or those who were sent down to the country vil- lages together during the Sending-Down period in the 1960s and 1970s. When such a preexisting social connection is absent, potential participants can be linked up with the others through a mutual acquaintance and need to establish a basis of familiarity before they can progress in the exchange relationship. BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 371

Therefore, although good interpersonal relationships facilitate the investment process and move things along quickly and more efficiently, it takes time to build such relationships. When an investor boasts that he or she could “solve any problem immediately by making a phone call to the governor of the town or the chief officer of the custom,” it means that he or she has invested a vast amount of time and energy in advance in order to reach such a level of “efficiency.” The relationship between the participants in a gift exchange does not end imme- diately after the exchange is completed. It is important to pay back more than one has received, as a Chinese idiom says: “When given a foot, give back a yard.” Because gift exchange is not always an equal exchange in quantitative terms, the “favor debts” rarely get cleared in one transaction. As a result, favors are accumu- lated and interpersonal relationships are strengthened as the exchanges of gifts and favors continue. According to one Taiwanese investor, the least effective way of making friends with local officials is to shower them with cash or luxurious gifts at the beginning, or to present the gift in a once-and-for-all fashion. Instead, a “constant drizzle” of gifts will facilitate a more stable and lasting relationship. It is also important to present the gift before asking for favors. A joint venture that had a number of trucks frequently delivering materials and finished products had managed to obtain a good relationship with the traffic policemen in town. Three times a year the company would present imported liquor or other gifts to the public security bureau before the three major Chinese festivals of the year – the Dragon Boat Festival, the Mid-Autumn Day, and the Chinese New Year. However, last Chinese New Year (1993) the company did not send the gifts. As a result, immediately after the New Year, their drivers started getting speed tickets. The company soon got the message and brought gifts to the bureau. But the gifts were returned. The policemen told the company that they could not accept the gifts because “it is obvious that you are trying to bribe us.”

Sense of space: vague boundaries between the public domain and the private domain It is often argued that the Chinese do not see the public domain and the private domain as two polar opposites. Instead, the public and the private are considered to be a continuous spectrum or as two concentric circles. The public domain is a congregation of private, individual entities, and there are different levels of public- ness. Therefore, the expansion of the private domain is not always considered to be an invasion of the public domain, but an adjustment to the level of publicness (or privateness) in different situations. However, such statements can be overgeneral- ized. Nevertheless, the way Chinese local officials deal with overseas investors in China qualifies the general observation. As China has been undergoing a transfor- mation from a socialist system in which the public sector is pervasive and because a clear legal framework that redefines the “private” has yet to be built, border cross- ing between the public and the private domain has been a matter in which legal considerations are mixed with culturally informed interpersonal relations. The public and the private domain are often intertwined and private and public interests are not always in conflict. A Taiwanese investor commented that the best 372 Y. HSING way to maintain and to enforce the relationship with an official is to offer the opportunity for him or her to gain personal benefits while benefiting his or her insti- tute. For example, if a state-owned factory needs new machinery, it will help the broker to get the contract if he or she can arrange a trip for the decision-makers in the government to visit the foreign equipment supplier. Those who get to repre- sent the customer organization and take the trip gain a direct benefit of a free trip abroad, and therefore owe a favor to the broker, and at the same time the entire organization benefits from getting more information about the new equipment. In fact a US equipment supplier told me that a free trip to visit the suppliers abroad has been part of the deal in his negotiation with his Chinese customers. It has been built into the system as a routine and his company has had a long-term contract with a travel agent who arranged all the trips for his Chinese customers. In the typical 1–2-week visit to the USA, there was a one-day visit to the supplier’s factory; the rest of the time usually included trips to Las Vegas, New York, Los Angeles, and so on. As the benefits are shared by the group, so is the responsibility. One of the most widely used terms in the government is “collective discussion.” The official in charge of granting import licenses might tell the applicant, who wishes to have more gen- erous tax breaks on import materials, that the case needs to be discussed collec- tively with his or her colleagues in the department. This means that the favor expected from the applicant will be shared by a group of officials at different ranks, and so will the risks involved in granting a special tax break to the applicant.

Hidden messages in the language As mentioned before, when asked about the major advantage of investing in China, compared with other overseas production sites in Southeast Asia, most Taiwanese investors answer that it was the common language they share with local Chinese. The gift receiver is expected to understand what is expected of him or her, without explicit explanations, if he or she is a true friend of the gift giver. To reach such a subtle balance between explicitness and implicitness, it requires effective communi- cation between the participants. In Xiamen, southern Fujian, Taiwanese speak the same dialect as the southern Fujianese. In Guangdong, the successfully promoted official language in both Taiwan and mainland China, Mandarin, has been an effective tool for communi- cation between the overseas investors and their local agents. Although linguistic commonality is not the only tool to build trusting relationships, it opens doors more quickly. On many occasions what is spoken is not as important as what is unspoken. Therefore, one of the participants in a gift exchange requires both technical under- standing of the spoken words and cultural understanding of the hidden meaning to grasp fully the expectations of the other participant. For example, when an investor asks for a greater allowance of products to be sold in the local markets, the official in charge might tell the investor, “Let me ‘yanjiu’, ‘yanjiu’ about it.” Literally “yanjiu” means doing research or looking into the matter carefully. Yet, the conclusion of the research often depends on the favor BLOOD, THICKER THAN WATER 373 that the applicant is willing to offer to the official. As the pronunciation of “yanjiu” is close to “cigarettes and liquor” in Mandarin, in the early days of the reform “yanjiu” literally implied the demand of cigarettes and liquor as gifts. The three ele- ments described before – the type (therefore the monetary and the use-value) of the gift, the timing of the offer of the gift, and the occasion on which the gift is presented and received – are all parts of the hidden message. If the cigarettes offered by the applicant are not good enough, the official may reject the gift and at the same time offer one, which is usually of the most expensive brand, to the appli- cant, as a way to show the applicant the type of cigarettes that is preferred. If the official gives the applicant her or his home address and invites the applicant to have a cup of tea with him or her at home, it usually implies that the gift should be presented and the negotiation made in the official’s residence rather than in the office. Furthermore, whether the official accepts the gift or not indicates the chances of whether the favor will be granted to the applicant. If the official feels the favor asked by the applicant is too unrealistic or beyond his or her realm of influence, the official will not accept the gift as a way to tell the applicant that no help can be expected.

Conclusion Taiwan’s economy has been restructuring. After three decades of export-oriented industrialization, the rising production costs in the island and the shrinking world markets have left Taiwanese small-export manufacturers with few choices but to look elsewhere for alternative production sites and markets. Southern China, with its abundant supply of unprotected yet trainable migrant workers, attractive invest- ment packages, and accommodating local officials, fulfills the demand of the Taiwanese small producers. This is an accommodating institutional environment for small investors in southern China, who are matched well with the desperate small Taiwanese export manufacturers, whose competitiveness in the world markets depends heavily on time and low costs. The marriage between Taiwanese capital and mainland Chinese agents is further lubricated by a shared language, the insti- tutional culture of Chinese bureaucracy, and the common cultural tools that facili- tate the establishment of interpersonal networks between Taiwanese investors and Chinese local officials. The dynamism of development comes from the interaction between the national state, the local states, foreign capitals, and the new social forces that are generated from such interactions. Further, as Yang (1994, p. 45) has pointed out, although interpersonal relations are usually regarded as being in line with bureaucratic power, whether as official corruption or as patron–client ties, they are also a force working against state power. To elaborate on this point, the establishment of interpersonal ties between Taiwanese investors and Chinese local officials should be seen as a way that the local states bypass the control of the central state and link up directly with the world market. “Gift exchange” may be seen as a general principle of the establishment of inter- personal relationships in Chinese societies. It might also be safe to argue that the Chinese tend to rely on gift exchange-based interpersonal relationships more than some other people (Ruan, 1993). Yet, the importance of interpersonal ties is not 374 Y. HSING unique to Chinese societies, nor is gift exchange a principle of establishing inter- personal relations that is adopted only by the Chinese. However, the practice and the form of gift exchange vary, depending on the specific historical and institutional contexts. The culturally available tools that facilitate the practice of gift exchange are unique to the processes of establishing interpersonal networks with local Chinese officials by Taiwanese investors. These tools include the linguistic connection, an understanding of the nonmarket value of gifts, and the sense of time and space in Chinese culture. The principle is applied and the tools are used in an institutional context which is characterized by the increasing autonomy of local Chinese officials and their tradition of flexible interpretation and implementation of the regulations imposed by the central government. As a preliminary effort to tackle the question of cultural mechanism in develop- ment processes, in this paper I have also brought up several questions to be explored further in the search for “Chinese capitalism.” First of all, when I try to identify the cultural elements of the Chinese-style economic activities, I am not looking at atomized cultural factors or the impact of these cultural factors on all the dimen- sions in the process of economic development. Instead I am looking at the rela- tionship between certain cultural elements and certain development issues, such as the relationship between familism and firm organizations, the relationship between the definition of partnership and the establishment of business alliances, or the rela- tionship between the definition of public and private sphere and the way the gov- ernment intervenes in the market. This seems to me to be a more promising way to avoid making the sweeping arguments that are often seen in works on the rela- tionship between the Confucian values and East Asian Economic Miracles (see Hamilton and Biggart, 1988, for a very comprehensive critique of this approach). By moving down the ladder of abstraction and reducing the number of definitional attributes of “Chinese capitalism,” we might be able to find some measurable vari- ables and therefore a more manageable research project. Also, the connection between culture and ideology needs to be further developed in the search for Chinese capitalism. For example, the cultural factor in the development of small business, such as familism, is associated with the ideology that being one’s own boss is an indicator of success. Therefore it justifies the self- exploitation by the owners of small shops; or, the phenomenon of concentration of investment in property is supported by the cultural association between land, security, and success; and the ideological implication that ownership provides independence. In the meantime, local government-oriented projects have facilitated a more decentralized process of industrialization and urbanization in China. Overseas investors provide alternative sources of capital and technology transfer for local gov- ernments. A coalition of local governments and foreign capital has also strength- ened the bargaining power of local governments against the national government, creating, in turn, a basis for local governments to take more initiative in regional and urban planning and development. Increasingly, most key planning, manage- ment, and financing issues are decided at the local level. This provides an opportu- nity for local planners to respond to local situations more directly and to shift urban and regional standards of governance away from universal norms set by the central government. Chapter 24 From Registered Nurse to Registered Nanny: Discursive Geographies of Filipina Domestic Workers in Vancouver, BC

Geraldine Pratt

At the first of a series of workshops with Filipina domestic workers, held at the Philippine Women Centre in Vancouver in 1995, we went around the room and introduced ourselves. With the exception of some of the workshop facilitators, all of the 18 participants were domestic workers, admitted to Canada under the Live- in Caregiver Program. But as we went around that room, there was a surprising (for me) disruption of this uniformity. We heard from women who were trained and certified as midwives or as registered nurses, about the difficulties of finding work in the Philippines as a secondary school science teacher, and about the occupational experiences of a trained social worker. We heard about working in a bank in the Philippines and about the experiences of a bookkeeper. As I listened to these diverse personal histories, I puzzled over a colleague’s finding that Filipinas are the most occupationally ghettoized of all women (classified by ethnicity) in the Vancouver labor market (Hiebert, 1999). Analyses of the 1991 census data for Vancouver indi- cate that Filipinas are especially overrepresented in three occupations: housekeeper, childcare worker (essentially the same occupation labeled in two ways), and medical assistant (e.g., nurses’ aid). The Live-in Caregiver Program requires of participants that they work as a live-in caregiver for two full years before applying for an open visa (at which point they are released from the obligation to do live-in domestic work). However, the experience of coming to Canada as a nanny evidently narrows occupational opportunities long after the requirements of the program have been fulfilled. This is a particular, though extreme, case of a familiar immigrant story: deskilling through immigration, followed by ghettoization within marginal occupations. If the story is familiar, our ability to accommodate it within contemporary labor market theory is less clear. It has become a common, almost clichéd, critique of labor segmentation theory to point to its inadequacy at explaining why and how some groups (women, visible minorities, immigrants) end up in marginal jobs (e.g., Hanson and Pratt, 1995). Recognizing the complexity and specificity of these processes for different groups and in different places has led some (Hanson and Pratt, 1995; Hiebert, 1999; Peck, 1996) to suggest that a lower or middle range of 376 GERALDINE PRATT theory and a close attention to empirical detail may be more productive for under- standing these processes. While this position helpfully highlights the contingency and variability of social and economic processes, I now think that it is also poten- tially misleading. This is because it can be interpreted as positing the social and cul- tural processes that lead to the marginalization of certain groups in the labor market as empirical rather than theoretical puzzles. The point is not only that empirical work is never theory free, but that hiving off the empirical from the theoretical might lead us to miss what a substantial body of contemporary cultural theory can offer to our understanding of labor markets. If much contemporary cultural theory stresses the importance of the everyday and the local, it nonetheless rests on some highly abstract ideas about subjectivity and social and economic life. An emphasis on the local speaks to methodology and not to levels of theoretical abstraction. Foucault (1979), for example, blurred the distinctions between micro/macro, scales of analyses, and levels of abstraction when he observed that even as power relations ultimately become linked to the logic of a great strategy (a logic not conceived as theoretical abstraction), the appropriate starting point for analysis lies in everyday local power relations. . . . By analogy, even as labor market segmentation exists and persists as a grand strategy of capitalist imperialist labor control, our point of departure for understanding how individu- als are drawn into this system of class relations lies in a close examination of local power relations and situated practices. It is unhelpful, however, to conceive of local relations and practices as more empirical than systematic strategies. Cultural theo- ries, including theories of subjectivity, are no less abstract when they pertain to individuals and local power relations. Poststructural theories posit a subject and perspectives on language that are useful for understanding processes of labor market segmentation. Poststructural theorists such as Foucault drew from Althusser’s antihumanism to conceive the subject as produced through discourse, rather than as a coherent rational subject who exists prior to language. Language does not simply reflect the world; it is a regulated prac- tice that structures our sense of reality and notions of our own identity. Discourse is material in the sense that it brings into being classifications of objects, bodies, and identities (Butler, 1990; Haraway, 1991) and exists as situated practices, sup- ported by institutions, buildings, and so forth (Mills, 1997). Critics sometimes argue that discourse analysis dissolves the materiality of the world into language, but this misses the messiness of the relations being posited between the material and the dis- cursive (Natter and Jones, 1993). It is not that discourse theorists deny the materi- ality of the world; they argue that how we conceive the world is inextricably bound up with discourse. Despite the innovative uses to which poststructuralism has been put by political economists (e.g., Gibson-Graham, 1996), suspicion remains that cultural theorists miss the determinate effects of the economy and lose a position from which to cri- tique them (cf. Fraser, 1997; Watts and McCarthy, 1997). Spivak (1988) has argued that discourse analysis can take the form of empiricist reportage, in which the intel- lectual abdicates his or her role as critic. Spivak urges a reconsideration of material interests and the ways in which they come to be represented in discourse; she is par- ticularly concerned with the ways that the international division of labor reflects and structures material interests and how representations veil capitalist, imperialist FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 377 relations. Without claiming an exhaustiveness for discourse analysis, we can see it as a means of theorizing how subjects come to understand themselves and their capabilities and how material inequalities are produced through everyday situated practices. It is also a powerful tool for disrupting these situated practices. Poststructural theories of the subject and discourse indicate three possibilities for disruption. First, discourses are productive in the sense that they produce subject positions. These subject positions subjugate individuals but they also function as resources. In the labor market, we can think of how claims of class standing (in solidarity with the working class, for example) work as political resources. A second political possibility comes from the understanding that individuals are “hailed” by multiple, sometimes contradictory, discourses. Managing these contradictions, or bringing one discourse into relation with another, can open points of resistance. Lisa Lowe argues, for example, that the liberal principles of American democracy (including claims to universal rights) are at odds with the various ways that Asian American citizens enter discourse: as “the model minority,” or “the invading multitude, the lascivious seductress, the servile yet treacherous domestic, the automaton whose inhuman efficiency will supersede American ingenuity” (1996, p. 18). Placing these discourses in tension creates a space from which to criticize con- structions of the American nation and an economic system “that profits from racism” (1996, p. 26). Third, poststructuralists influenced by deconstruction have been attentive to the contradictions within any discourse. In Spivak’s view (1988), it is by uncovering the disruptions and contradictions between and within discourses that a critical vantage point on discourse is gained. Discourse analysis can lead to an incisive critique of ideology by revealing the “mistakes” that found knowledge, the contradictions within discourses, and the things that are left unsaid or cannot be said, by “measuring silences, if necessary – into the object of investigation” (Spivak 1988, p. 296; original emphasis). It is not simply that geographers have much to gain by drawing on poststruc- tural theory; a close reading of geography has much to offer to cultural studies. This is because discourses emerge as situated practices in particular places (they thus are inherently geographic (Pred, 1992)). There are sociospatial circuits through which cultural and personal stories are circulated, legitimated, and given meaning. By mapping these circuits we map types of discursive geography. Moving between places may also be one way in which individuals become aware of contradictions between various discourses. But additionally, geographic terms have important effects within discourse. Feminists have long recognized how constructions of home influence women’s work experiences; Moss (1995) and Gregson and Lowe (1994) provide recent examples of how constructions of home affect paid labor performed within that space. We can usefully consider how other discursively embedded geo- graphies work to structure labor markets. In the following case study, I map discursive constructions that circumscribe subject positions available to Filipina women, delineating for them a limiting space within the labor market. In so doing, I pay special attention to how geographic terms function within discourse. A central discursive struggle surrounds whether domestic workers are interpreted in racial/immigration or class terms. I will examine this struggle, and attempt to get some critical perspective on discursive construc- tions by attempting to measure some of the silences and contradictions within them. 378 GERALDINE PRATT

But I also want to suggest that ruptures between subject positions, as prescribed in different discourses and in different places, open spaces for agency and opportuni- ties for rewriting the meaning of “Filipina” in Vancouver. My discussion of subject positions is organized by considering paired terms, each defined in relation to the other, reflecting my understanding that identities are rela- tional constructs and that they are defined in relation to what they are not: live-in caregiver is defined in opposition to Canadian citizen; and Filipina domestic workers are constructed in relation to European ones, through the terms “housekeeper” and “nanny,” respectively. Within the Filipino community, nanny takes on meaning in relation to the term “immigrant.” These categories supplement each other and rigid- ify Filipina domestic workers’ occupational trajectories, such that their entry into the Canadian labor market via the Live-in Caregiver Program narrows their choices thereafter. Complex geographies are woven throughout this trajectory. To fully understand Filipinas’ positionings, one would have to consider conditions within the Philippines that drive them to migrate. My analysis is restricted to discursive constructions of Filipinas in Vancouver, but the last discourse considered, one that circulates within the Filipino community in Vancouver, begins to gesture toward important class relations in the Philippines that continue to construct “Filipina” in Vancouver. Mapping discourse is a vast, open-ended task. I rely on interview material col- lected between 1994 and 1996. In 1994 I interviewed ten agents operating in the Vancouver area, the only ones who would speak with me and, by their own assess- ment, the ones who handled the largest volume of placements (see Pratt, 1997 for details of the methodology). In the summer of 1995, I interviewed a randomly selected sample of 52 households in the Vancouver metropolitan area who had advertised for nannies in the previous year in one of two local newspapers. Most were currently employing a nanny when we came to do the interview. Through the summer and fall of 1995 and spring of 1996, I collaborated with the Philippine Women Centre to conduct a series of focus groups with 14 domestic workers. All interviews and focus groups were unstructured, taped, and transcribed, a necessity for a study of discourse in which the framing of meaning is the object of inquiry.

Live-in Caregiver: Noncitizen, Not-Yet-Immigrant The live-in caregiver is defined in relation and in opposition to the category Canadian citizen, and it is the noncitizen status of job occupants that structures the work conditions of live-in caregivers. Over the years a larger proportion of the mostly women who have come through these programs have come from the Philippines; by 1996 fully 87 percent came from the Philippines. In its informa- tional booklet, the federal government explicitly locates occupants of this job as non-Canadians: “The Live-in Caregiver Program is a special program whose objec- tive is to bring workers to Canada to do live-in work as caregivers when there are not enough Canadians available to fill the available positions. The Live-in Caregiver Program exists only because there is a shortage of Canadians to fill the need for live-in care work. There is no shortage of Canadian workers available for caregiv- ing positions where there is no live-in requirement” (Citizenship and Immigration Canada, 1999). A provincial employee who administers the Live-in Caregiver FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 379

Program in one Vancouver employment office stated in a telephone interview in May 1994: “The reason that we have to bring in from abroad is that the occupation is so poorly paid and no one wants to do it. . . . The program is set up for the Canadian employer, to allow them to get on with their lives and get out to work.” This difference between live-in caregivers and Canadian citizens has been encoded in stark terms by provincial employment regulations, which govern the work con- ditions of live-in caregivers. Regulations vary by province. In British Columbia, until March 1995 live-in domestic workers (along with farm workers and other home- workers) were excluded from regulations governing overtime pay and hours of work. As the West Coast Domestic Workers’ Association (1993, p. 2) put it in their brief to the Employment Standards Act Review Committee in March 1993: “by imposing a daily [as opposed to hourly] minimum wage and excluding domestics from hours of work protection, [provincial regulations], in effect, work with the federal immigration program to provide foreign domestic workers as cheap labor.” Why is it that Canadians so readily accept that some categories of people living within Canada are undeserving of protective labor codes available to other citizens? Why are some categories of people assumed to have minimal subsistence require- ments? Three geographic concepts are used to negotiate what would seem to be an untenable contradiction between universal rights of Canadian citizens and unequal treatment of workers in different occupational categories. First, the promise of potential citizenship works in a potent way to legitimate labor conditions acknowl- edged by the Canadian government as unacceptable to Canadians. While, strictly speaking, the Live-in Caregiver Program is a work visa (and not an immigration) program, in practice it entitles the occupant to apply for immigrant status after working two full years as a live-in caregiver. There is a widespread understanding that live-in caregivers endure short-term hardship for the opportunity of applying for landed immigrant status after two years working as a live-in caregiver. As Agent E put it: “Filipinos have a very different motivation [from European nannies]. . . . they are coming to immigrate, to get citizenship, to bring in their families. They will put up with a lot in order to have a clean record, which makes for a whole other set of problems. But it means that they’re likely to stay on the job” (interview, May 1994). Since changes to the Employment Standards Act in 1995, overtime and minimum hourly wage regulations cover all domestic workers in British Columbia. But it is interesting to listen to nanny agents argue against these changes when they were first proposed in 1994. Agents indirectly threatened domestic workers that changes to labor regulations would restrict their opportunities to immigrate.

Agent D: You’re not getting 19 bucks an hour [working as a domestic worker], but the majority of Canadians treat you nicely. And you’re getting Canadian citizenship, which is what people are lining up for, dying to come. Agent C: And not costing yourself anything. Like I said before, the West Coast Domes- tic Association [sic] will argue that [domestic workers are exploited]. And they’re going to do themselves out of a job. Agent D: They’ll wreck it for these women, who come in and 99.9 percent of them are happy to be here. And they’re not militants. That’s just so sad. Because it’s just that little few that are banging on. 380 GERALDINE PRATT

To me, what is of interest in these passages is the way in which benefits to the Canadian state and Canadian households (which allow Canadian men and women “to get on with their lives and get out to work”) are translated into a benefit for domestic workers. A discourse of free and fair exchange (immigration for two years of servitude) is commonplace but it is staged without a careful weighing of the units in exchange; indeed, Agent C cancels out the costs to the domestic worker entirely: “And not costing yourself anything.” We need to measure this silence about costs, in part through a more serious analysis of the terms of exchange – that is, whether an opportunity to immigrate can and should be valued against two years of paid servitude. This discussion must be broadened to consider Canada’s responsibilities in relation to global patterns of uneven development. There is a second, fragmented geography that confuses live-in caregivers’ rights as employees . . . The federal government has responsibility over the Live-in Care- giver Program, whereas the provincial government regulates employment standards. There is, then, a type of discursive rupture in the way that live-in caregivers are defined in relation to the two levels of the government. For the federal government they are defined as visa holders; for the provincial governments, they are employ- ees. Of particular concern to domestic workers is the federal government’s prohi- bition against educational training for those registered in the Live-in Caregiver Program. In their view, the effect of this prohibition is deskilling:

Susan: It is stated in the work permit that you cannot go to college, you cannot work for others and you cannot work in other provinces. After you have not worked for two years in the trade or profession that you have trained for, you begin to doubt if you still have the ability to do your previous work. Jeorgie: Things are not fresh in your mind anymore.

[The conversation continues and culminates with:]

Mhay: What you know now is only how to clean and polish the bathroom. Elsie: That’s your skills these days. (Focus group discussions, August 1995)

Domestic workers perceive that living within the regulations of the Live-in Care- giver Program makes it difficult to recover a previous occupational identity. Yet it is difficult for them to make a strong case to the federal government because this exceeds the discursive boundaries of the Live-in Caregiver Program, which positions them as noncitizen visa holders. The governmentally fragmented administration of the Live-in Caregiver Program makes lobbying for change a complicated process. It also lends an air of confusion about entitlements as employees. Among women attending the focus groups, for example, there was a great deal of uncertainty about their entitlement to the federal government’s Employment Insurance (EI) program, despite the fact that they paid into the program. This confusion about entitlement is of considerable importance because access to employment insurance benefits could allow a domestic worker to leave an especially exploitative or abusive employment situation. FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 381

A third geography is literally written into the Live-in Caregiver Program: regis- trants must live in their employers’ homes. The requirement that domestic workers live “in” clearly lowers the costs for employers, because they can deduct $300 a month for room and board from the required minimum wage payment. It thus brings privatized childcare (which costs the employer approximately $900 a month after this deduction) within the reach of middle income families. Problems attend- ing live-in requirements have long been recognized by domestic worker advocacy groups. Living in an employer’s home dampens wages, tends to stretch the work day, and can make domestic workers vulnerable to sexual abuse. It also makes it more difficult for the domestic worker to challenge her employer because her work- place is also her home. Discourses of home and family are woven through these material effects. Aitken (1987) documents how constructions of home as a private space have been used in Ontario to justify minimal state intrusion into the home and thus very weak regu- lation of domestic workers’ employment situations (see also Stiell and England, 1997). The domestic worker is sometimes constructed as a family member, who is loved and cherished as such; some have argued that regulation of domestic work within the framework of employer–employee relations penalizes the domestic worker because it degrades her status as a family member. The West Coast Domestic Workers’ Association argues that “Live-in domestic workers can keep time and should be paid for the hours worked” (1993, p. 4). In arguing thus, they were entering a discursive battle, attempting to redefine the domestic worker, not as family member, not as potential immigrant who should be grateful for her temporary lot as a domestic worker, but, quite simply, as an employee. There is much at stake: hours of work and overtime regulations would likely raise wages and shorten hours of work. It is also a struggle to redefine the domestic worker in the language of class so that the politics of class solidarity can be brought into play. Framed in this way, and following Gibson-Graham (1996), we can interpret changes in the Employment Standards Act as a moment of progressive class transformation.

Colonial Geographies: Filipina as Housekeeper There is another grid of identity formation in which Filipinas are marginalized; they are often unfavorably compared to European women who come to Canada via the same visa program. Filipinas are constructed as housekeepers, while European women are called nannies. The ways that these two groups of women are positioned differently within the same occupational category points to the importance of under- standing the intertwined cultural and social processes of identity formation and labor market segmentation. Nanny agents who were interviewed in 1994 were very clear on the distinctions between Filipino and European nannies. Many employers absorb the agents’ distinction between European nanny and Asian housekeeper, something that came across clearly in interviews with employers who had employed Filipina and European domestic workers. Consider, for example, the comments of a family who first employed a Filipina nanny. She was replaced when their child turned two, 382 GERALDINE PRATT an age when the employers became more concerned about the intellectual stimula- tion of their child. The Filipina nanny was subjected to a covert test, which involved asking her to read to their child during the day and leaving designated books in a marked position on the table. The nanny failed the test – the books were in the same place at the end of the day – and a Slovakian nanny was hired as her replace- ment. The employers were clearly fond of the Filipina nanny, in part because she did not intrude. They admired their Slovakian nanny for her skills as an early child- hood educator, and they spoke in some detail about her other training and skills. They did not, however, like her much, and they were appalled by what they per- ceived to be her persistent overstepping of social boundaries. I quote from the inter- view transcript because they express these distinctions in such an open way.

Bob: But I think the big difference between the two was that Rosa [Filipina nanny] never took anything for granted, and when we honored her a privilege, which she thought was a privilege, she would never take advantage of that privilege again unless the honor was there again, whereas with, unfortunately with Brigid [Slovakian nanny] ... Wendy: She’s very good as a caregiver. Bob: Wonderful and stimulating, a good teacher and the whole bit, but as soon as we grant her something . . . Say once she asked if she could use Wendy’s skis for the weekend, and we said OK, but after that she used them for the whole season and never asked anymore. Wendy: And she often uses my things. Bob couldn’t see my point at first. I mean I had only skied once since Aidan was born. So I said to him, “How would you feel if we hired a gardener and he just used all your golf clubs and stuff?” And that soon put things in perspective! Bob: It was funny, when we would have people over with Rosa we would feel Rosa was part of our family. And a lot of times – not so much on the weekends because she was never here – but on the weekdays, if someone was coming over after work or whatever and we were going out for dinner, we would always invite her to eat with us ... Wendy: But she would always have eaten before we got home. Whereas with Brigid we feel like we’re practically serving her and she’s talking back and forth [with our guests].

A little later in the interview, they turned once again to differences between Filipina and Slovakian nannies in terms of intellect and perceptions of entitlement.

Bob: We basically decided in lieu of a Filipino nanny to go with a European nanny, because of the learning skills, the interaction. We were finding that Rosa was really good and loving and hugging and doing everything proper for him and feeding him, but the alphabet, the numbers, the colors, those things weren’t happening. ...I think that’s the trade-off. But you’ve gotta remember that they’re educated ladies [Slovakian nannies], and I don’t think . . . well I don’t know, but I kind of think somewhere down the line it’s gonna be: “Well, why am I ironing this man’s shirt when I used to be a university scholar?” When we come home at the end of the day, Brigid will have read the paper from front to back. She knows everything in The Vancouver Sun. And then she would pull out extracts about taxes going up or the minimum wages going up and she would say to us, “Look, I need a raise, the minimum wage has gone up” ...Well FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 383

you’ve got to remember that these women [Slovakian nannies] are intellects, and you’re not going to have six intellects living in a house at the weekend, sleeping on the floor. Whereas with Filipino nannies, they love to roll all over each other all weekend! [He is referring to the common practice among Filipina nannies of sharing rental accom- modations during the weekend.]

Agents themselves play a powerful role in constructing for the prospective employers the idea of Filipina woman as servant/housekeeper. This begins with advice to Filipina women on how they should represent themselves to their prospective employers. Women at the Philippine Women Centre spoke of agents’ recommendations to include two pictures of themselves in their files, one showing them caring for children and another displaying them cleaning. Some agents told women not to send a picture that displays them as attractive. Some women were instructed to take off jewelry, wear no makeup, and tie their hair back. An agent in the Philippines cautioned that a picture that displayed a woman as attrac- tive would suggest that “maybe she would go to Canada and seduce her employer.” The text that supplements these images of hard-working servants also signals to prospective employers that these women are ripe for exploitation: several domestic workers were told to indicate on their applications forms a willingness to work long hours. Further, it is often the case that Filipina live-in caregivers have worked previously as domestic workers in Singapore or Hong Kong. Both the agents and employers attempt to bring the highly exploitative conditions for domestic workers from these places to Vancouver. They do this by calling upon personal experiences as domes- tic workers in Singapore or Hong Kong as they ask Filipina domestic workers to work longer hours and at a wider range of non-childcare-related tasks (such as washing the car) than would be required of European women. Historical geographies of colonialism and racism continue to define housekeeper and nanny within Vancouver. Filipinas are discursively constructed as house- keepers, with inferior intellects and educations relative to European nannies. Agents encourage Filipina women to represent themselves as exploitable, and they are reminded of their personal and collective histories as domestic workers in Hong Kong and Singapore in the Vancouver context.

Stigmatization within Vancouver’s Filipino Community: Filipina Domestic Workers as Husband Stealers Hegemonic white Canadians have no monopoly on constructions of Filipina domes- tic workers as inferior. Domestic workers who participated in the focus groups told painful stories about a stigmatization process within the Filipino community, one that revolved around a distinction between immigrant and nanny. The term immi- grant was used to refer to individuals who entered Canada through the “regular” immigration system. Some of these would have entered through the family reunifi- cation program, some through business class programs, and others through the point system. The point system is complex and the criteria for assembling points periodically readjusted by the federal government, depending on labor require- ments. But, among other criteria, points are given for having a sponsor (business 384 GERALDINE PRATT sponsorship earns more points than family sponsorship) or specialized training in specifically designated occupations (often technical ones). Feminized skills are usually undervalued and typically do not score many points. While, strictly speaking, the Live-in Caregiver Program is not an immigration program, in practice it is often the most accessible route for a Filipina woman who wishes to initiate immigration to Canada. Once she has obtained landed immigrant status, she is able to sponsor her family through another immigration program, that of family reunification. The distinction between immigrant and nanny thus carries both class and gender associations; in the former case the lead family member is more likely to be male, with considerable capital and/or educational resources, in the latter a woman. These class and gender dimensions are laden with moral ones: domestic workers who participated in the focus groups saw themselves as being per- ceived, not only as inferior in class terms, but as promiscuous husband stealers.

Mhay: Because most of us, especially we Filipinos, we go into small groups. One group will say, “Oh, there go the nannies, out on their day off together.” It’s mostly Filipinos like us who say that. And then there’s that other issue about being, since you’re a nanny, you’re, you know, someone who steals husbands. That’s why wives are angry with us. [Mhay is referring to Filipino men and their wives within the Filipino community – not to employers.] (Focus group discussion, September 1995)

This stigmatization may be understandable in the context of what Rafael (1997) has identified as an identity crisis for Filipinos, one that he ties to massive state- encouraged movements of Filipino workers and immigrants over the last 25 years. He argues that middle-class Filipinos are sometimes embarrassed by being mistaken as domestic workers when they travel outside the Philippines: “Embarrassment arises from their inability to keep social lines from blurring (thereby rendering prob- lematic their position as privileged representatives of the nation) and maintaining a distinction between ‘Filipino’ as the name of a sovereign people and ‘Filipino’ as the generic term for designating a subservient class dependent on foreign economies” (Rafael, 1997, pp. 276–77). There are, however, contradictions and silences. In Vancouver, the line between immigrant and nanny may be blurred through a repression of memory and family history. Again, Mhay’s remarks are instructive. They follow an incident when she had been insulted by other Filipinos in a public place.

Mhay: It was okay with me, because I really am a nanny, but it was my companion who was hurt. (Laughs) So I asked my friend why he was going into this dark mood, when it was me who was a nanny, not him! [He said,] “No, it’s because those people look down on nannies. Where are their roots, anyway?” I said, “Well, from nannies.” I was also curious [about his reactions] so I said, “And what about you? If your girl- friend was a nanny, what will you tell your parents about her? Will you say she’s a nanny?” “Well, yes” he said. “What if your family looks down on her?” “Well, many people here are like that. If they do that, then they’re denying where they came from.” It turns out that his family was able to come here because his sister was a nanny. So it was funny that he was reacting like that. But it’s really hurting here, that people look down on nannies. (Focus group discussion, September 1995)

Mhay’s story shows how the line between nanny and immigrant for many Filipino families in Vancouver is blurry indeed (before this encounter she assumed her friend FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 385 to be a “regular” immigrant and not an immigrant sponsored by a nanny) and sug- gests that the distinction is constructed in part through some strategic forgetting within self-identified immigrant families. There is an interesting geography to these narratives of stigmatization. Moments of stigmatization tend to take place in transit, often quite literally on public transit. The following is typical:

Inyang: I was on the Sky Train and we planned to recruit a person [I saw] to the Centre [Philippine Women Centre]. We had just said, “Oh, you’re probably new here, right?” After saying yes, she immediately said, “Wait, but I’m not a nanny, okay?” Look at that! So that time, we never talked to her again. It turns out she was brought over by relatives. (Focus group discussion, September 1995)

These narratives may reflect the fact that contact with other Filipinos is transitory, given that domestic workers live in their employers’ homes and work long hours, and that class and other social differences divide the Filipino community. This geog- raphy of transition nevertheless stabilizes the construction of Filipina nanny as infe- rior and immoral because the insults come as incidental, glancing slights, against which she has (literally) no ground for retaliation or renegotiation of discursive cat- egories. She must find other spaces and other grounds for reestablishing self-respect.

Reworking Discourse in Other Spaces and through Boundary Crossings Although my concern has been to demonstrate how discourses tightly patrol the construction of Filipina in Vancouver, discourses are also productive, open, and polyvalent. In outlining constructions of Filipina, I have tried to mark places where the discursive boundaries might be destabilized by noting silences, contradictions, and patterns of forgetfulness within these constructions. I now turn to other sites where other discourses might be constructed, and then consider how bringing dif- ferent discourses into tension can be disruptive. Filipinas undoubtedly construct meanings that disrupt and repair their sense of themselves as supplicant-preimmigrant, inferior nanny, and immoral husband stealer. A number of those who took part in the focus groups spoke of the pressures to earn wages as a dutiful daughter or mother with financial responsibilities in the Philippines. This counterdiscourse of responsibility and duty may reestablish or maintain self-esteem and simultaneously empower women to demand higher wages. It does, however, have mixed effects. Mikita (1994), from her survey of 100 Filipina domestic workers in Vancouver in 1992, estimated the mean monthly remit- tance to be $245 a month (about 33.4% of gross wages). With such a large pro- portion of wages going toward family remittances, it is extremely difficult for individual women to contemplate and manage educational upgrading, even when released from the restrictions of the Live-in Caregiver Program. Understanding oneself as a dutiful daughter or sister or mother thus has material effects; in the long run it may lock Filipina women into jobs as domestic workers if the burden of monthly remittances cuts off possibilities for upgrading skills. Another counterdiscourse may emerge around the identity of consumer, as an individual with the rights and freedoms to consume. Women at the Philippine 386 GERALDINE PRATT

Women Centre spoke critically of the many Filipina domestic workers who con- gregate at the Pacific Center Mall in downtown Vancouver on weekends. One can imagine, however, how consumer consciousness may prepare the ground for resist- ance if the desire for goods leads domestic workers to challenge employers to comply with new minimum wage and overtime provisions in the Employment Standards Act. Domestic workers learn another identity at the Philippine Women Centre; they learn to see themselves as exploited Third World women and to understand their situations within a socialist feminist theory of imperialism. We have seen a peda- gogic process at work, especially when Cecilia Diocsin, director of the Philippine Women Centre, urges Susan to apply for unemployment insurance for her immedi- ate material benefit and to “learn something about whether there is a different set of rights between you and other Canadians.” A critical potential also emerges from border crossings between sites and dis- courses, by bringing one discourse into relation with another. The educational process at the Philippine Women Centre, for example, involves not only an exchange of information but a good deal of support and an effort to dislodge the rhetoric of the home as a private, unregulated space, as well as domestic workers’ identifica- tion with the needs of their employers. The identity of exploited Third World woman that domestic workers learn at the Philippine Women Centre is then intro- duced to Canadian employers within their homes. In some instances, domestic workers first role play their challenge to their employer with other domestic workers in the safe space of the Centre. As domestic workers attempt to establish their rights as employees rather than family member or supplicant-preimmigrants, they are forcing employers to reconfigure their relations within the terms of labor relations, away from constructions of family or a liberal reading of immigration (which would see individuals entering Canada as lucky, with no appreciation of complicated webs of political economic relations and dependencies between Canada, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and the Philippines). Individuals draw strength from transporting meanings from one context to another, even as they recognize the bitterness of their situations in the translation exercise. At the first workshop, I was introduced to a joke among domestic workers in Vancouver when Lisa said: “I was an R.N. in the Philippines and I’m an R.N. in Canada. Only in the Philippines I was a Registered Nurse and in Canada I’m a Reg- istered Nanny” (focus group discussion, August 1995). Their joke points to links between power, discourse, regulation, labor market segmentation, and one geogra- phy (transnational migration within neocolonial relations) that mediates them. The joke is political and empowering because it is simultaneously an act of remember- ing and a recognition of present circumstances. As they remember their professional training in the same term that defines their current situation, memories of the former are reactivated within the latter.

And Back to Labor Market Theory The challenge of reactivating professional qualifications obtained in the Philippines in the Canadian labor market is clearly going to require more than small instances of decisive wordplay. I have argued that discourses create definitional and social FROM REGISTERED NURSE TO REGISTERED NANNY 387 boundaries that contain the horizons of possibilities for individuals and social groups who must live within them. In the case of Filipinas, the discourses of domes- tic worker seem to constrain them long after they obtain their open visa, given their long-term segregation in the Vancouver labor market. Powerful overlapping of dis- cursive frames of meaning leads to a multiple and polyvalent devaluing of certain categories of people. The word “Filipina” is not only equated with “supplicant- preimmigrant”; the term also connotes “just-a-housekeeper” and “husband stealer.” Contemporary cultural theory also suggests that the overlap of discourses is incomplete, however, and fails to totally envelop individuals caught within them; R.N. is also R.N. In the slippage between discourses and through the contradictions within them, as they are taken up and lived by creative individuals and organized social groups, there is room for agency, and for the creative redirection and redef- inition of subject positions. I am not suggesting that redefining subjective meanings of particular subject posi- tions is sufficient to disrupt labor market segmentation. I do believe that we have to understand how these cultural processes can be put to work as part of this process of disruption. I have attempted to demonstrate how government policy, state regu- lation, and the informal negotiations that take place between domestic workers, nanny agents, and their employers are all framed within particular discourses that persistently devalue Filipinas. Criticizing these discourses is an important element of disrupting these oppressive institutional practices. This is a process of critique that sees itself as resistant to, but fully implicated in, the discourses under scrutiny; there is no privileged point from which to claim truth or a vision of nonoppressive social relations. The Philippine Women Centre, for example, is a source of a powerful and productive criticism of neocolonialism, racism, and gender and class oppression in Filipino and Canadian societies. However, their discourse, from a Foucauldian perspective, is no less neutral or “true” than other discourses, although it does produce different subject positions and political possibilities. The task for the critic is not one of uncovering the truth of one discourse but of understanding how subjectivity is produced within these multiple discourses, and to evaluate their effects. Foucault challenges us to gener- ate a critical discourse “whose power effects are limited as much as possible to the subversion of power” (Poster, 1989, p. 30). Like others (Fraser, 1997; Gibson- Graham, 1996; Watts and McCarthy, 1997), I attempt to wed discourse analysis with a critique of exploitation, in my case by assessing how the effects of discourse emerge out of and further exploitative north/south international relations through the sedimentation of Filipina immigrants to Canada within a limited range of low- paid occupations. Whether I have been successful in generating a critique of exploitation that is limited to the subversion of power is an entirely open question. An Immigration Legislative Review, entitled “Not Just Numbers,” commissioned by the Ministry of Citizenship and Immigration Canada and released in December 1997, recommended the termination of the Live-in Caregiver Program, in part because of the kinds of criticisms (voiced by academics and activists) leveled in this paper. One assessment (e.g., Philippine Women Centre, 1998) is that the recommended changes would mean that women currently working in Canada as live-in caregivers or admitted through the proposed Foreign Worker Program will no longer be eligible for 388 GERALDINE PRATT permanent resident status and possible citizenship. Indeed, current debate among domestic worker advocacy groups in Vancouver turns on how far to criticize the Live-in Caregiver Program, recognizing that one potential effect of this criticism is termination of the program. Nevertheless, the exposure, politicization, and disruption of conceptual bound- aries can be conceived as an important geographic task. My argument has been that geographies are deeply embedded within these boundary projects, in the construc- tion and control of discursive borders. In this sense, geographers have much to bring to cultural theory. Immigration, colonialism, and domestic space are part of the pro- duction of borders that define workers as worthy or unworthy, competent or incom- petent, skilled or unskilled. These classifications are then intimately tied to the segmentation of labor markets and, in particular, the processes through which par- ticular categories of workers are both allocated to and assume particular occupa- tional niches. Subject positions of “Filipina” are often about, and constructed in relation to, specific places: live-in caregiver is defined through the meanings attri- buted to the “home”; imagined geographies of “the Philippines” and “Britain” enter into definitions of skills and evaluations of wage requirements. Careful genealogies of place-meanings thus become part of the project of unraveling particular subject positions and releasing certain social categories from particular labor segments. The case study suggests that geographic strategies of discursive disruption are multiple and complex. When terms from one discourse are used to transform the meanings in another – for example, when a class analysis disrupts the framing of domestic worker as member of the family – we encounter an enabling type of dis- cursive porosity. On the other hand, when the definition of “domestic worker” in Singapore and the definition of the same category of worker in Vancouver leads to more exploitative conditions in Vancouver, we encounter the negative effects of dis- cursive and geographic porosity as poor labor conditions are dragged from one place to another. To point to the particularity and contingency of geographic effects and political strategy is not, however, the same as arguing that low-level theorizing is adequate to the task of conceptualizing these processes. “Big theory” lurks within contemporary claims about subjectivity; this paper is one effort to bring discourse theory into sharper analytical focus in relation to processes of labor market segmentation. Chapter 25 Discourse and Practice in Human Geography

Erica Schoenberger

What I want to do in this article is to step outside my own work, as much as that can be imagined possible, and try to set up an encounter between my usual analyti- cal style and position and other approaches. There are several reasons for doing this. One is that I think it’s a good exercise and good discipline – a way of check- ing into the rigor of one’s own thinking. Another is that I have argued strongly that the inability of corporate strategists to do something like this contributes impor- tantly to the problem of industrial competitiveness, so I thought I ought to try it myself, just as a way of staying honest (Schoenberger, 1997). A third is that it seems a good way of moving out of my comforting little cocoon of thought and engaging productively with other approaches and other concerns. The point is to see if one can critically engage with one’s own thought-style (cf. Fleck, 1935). The alternative terrain on which I want to position myself for this is composed of a couple of themes that crop up in feminist, postimperialist, and/or Foucauldian writings in the history and philosophy of science and social theory. One has to do with the status of the subject and the other with the status of discourse. Given the way I have traditionally worked (spending a lot of time talking with the men who run corporations) you might think that I could hardly have avoided addressing these themes directly, but you would be wrong. The first issue, then, has to do with what we can say about the knowing subject and the knowledge she produces. Here I wish to follow Harding who provides an intrigu- ing distinction between what she calls weak and strong objectivity in the practice of science. The entire scientific edifice, of course, is built upon and socially legitimated by the claim to objectivity: that the scientist’s perception and analysis of “the facts” will not be colored by a priori judgments, and that the scientist has no personal stake in the outcome of her research. Objectivity in this sense underwrites the authority of the scientist and her ability to establish widely accepted matters of fact. In the official ideology of science, objectivity, combined with careful adherence to “the scientific method,” guarantees the validity of the information produced. Harding, however, claims that normal scientific practice is only “weakly” objec- tive (Harding, 1991; cf. also Shapin, 1994). Weak objectivity, in this usage, describes 390 ERICA SCHOENBERGER the detached and dispassionate stance of the scientist towards the object of research, whether it be a virus or a supernova. It is nothing more than the job of the scien- tist to analyze rigorously and impartially the data associated with the object or process under study. It is not, however, the normal job of the scientist to subject herself, her lab organization, her choice of research questions, and the like to the same careful, dispassionate analysis. For Harding, however, it is precisely this act of locating oneself socially and historically and analyzing how this affects the process of doing science that would constitute “strong” objectivity. This doesn’t amount to a claim that strong objectivity would change what you saw under the microscope or in the particle accelerator. It might make you think twice, though, about why you find certain problems interesting or particularly satisfying, why you ask certain kinds of questions of the data and not others, or how you understand the contributions of different categories of people working with or around you (e.g., lab technicians). And your answers to these new kinds of question might plausibly affect the trajectory of scientific inquiry that you follow. The second theme I want to draw on has to do with the ways in which discourse enters into the constitution of our social reality and, indeed, of us as social agents. In part here I’m following the lead of McCloskey’s (1985) The rhetoric of economics which inquires into the nature of the conversation within that discipline, viewing the analysis of rhetoric as an exercise in self-understanding. I am guided also by Poovey’s careful investigation of the historical development of epistemological domains such as “the social” and “the economic” in Victorian England (Poovey, 1995). This process involves the establishment of boundaries between domains and the development of discourses and analytical styles appropriate to them. As Poovey shows, the discursive strategies and technologies of representation employed within these domains are involved in the creation of the very social categories they purport to define and analyze. A conceptual apparatus, in this way, takes on the property of materiality: the abstraction becomes a real social entity. At the same time, academic disciplines, such as sociology or economics, can be seen as nothing more than the study of these epistemological domains and the insti- tutions associated with them. As academics, then, we also have to wrestle with an epistemological and discursive history that not only guides us in the production of knowledge but also tells us in important ways who we are and what we do. Taking the two themes together, what I’m trying to do is to be strongly objective about how the discursive strategies of others affect my own discursive constructions and how these, in turn, enter into the material work that I do. In other words, what difference does it make that I accept certain ways of talking about the world I’m trying to analyze and what happens if I challenge those rhetorical and discursive conventions? In what follows, I want to examine the meaning and use of the concept of “com- petitiveness.” The analysis claims, in essence, that the term is not merely an “objec- tive” description of a fact of economic life, but also part of a discursive strategy that constructs a particular understanding of reality and elicits actions and reactions appropriate to that understanding. This is followed by a discussion of why the dis- course has the power that it does and how it may influence how we think about and act in the world. I then work through some examples of how an unexamined acceptance of a discursive convention may obscure as much as it reveals. DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 391

Competitiveness as an Economic Category and Discursive Strategy I’m going to make this as simple as possible for myself by reducing the whole problem of discourse to one word: competitiveness. For economic geographers in general and for me in particular, the categories of competition, competitive strat- egy, and competitiveness have a great deal of importance and might even be thought to pervade our work, even when they are not directly under analysis. All sorts of industrial and spatial economic outcomes are implicitly or explicitly linked to some notion of “competitiveness” (cf. Krugman, 1994). The rise and decline of particu- lar industrial regions have something to do with the competitiveness of the labor force (generally understood in terms of comparative costs and unionization), which (for geographers if for no one else) has something to do with the competitiveness of the region in the first place, understood as its particular mix of resources, infra- structure, location, and cost profile. More than that, though, “competitiveness” seems to me a term that has become truly hegemonic in the Gramscian sense. It is a culturally and socially sanctioned category that, when invoked, can completely halt public discussion of public or private activities. There is virtually no counterargument available to the simple claim that “doing X will make us uncompetitive,” whatever X and whomever “us” might be. In a capitalist society, of course, it is more than reasonable to be concerned with competition and competitiveness. No matter what your theoretical orientation, mainstream to Marxist, these must be seen as real forces shaping real outcomes in society. They are not just intellectual constructs that lend a false sense of order to a messy world. On the other hand, we can also analyze them as elements of a dis- cursive strategy that shapes our understanding of the world and our possibilities for action in it. In that case, it seems to me the first questions to ask are whose dis- cursive strategy is it, what do they really mean by it, where does its power come from, and what kinds of actions does it tend to open up or foreclose.

Whose discourse? The discourse on competitiveness comes from two principal sources and in part its power is their power. In the first instance, it is the discourse of the economics pro- fession which doesn’t really need to analyze what it is or what it means socially. The market is the impartial and ultimate arbiter of right behavior in the economy and competitiveness simply describes the result of responding correctly to market signals. The blandness of this “objective” language conceals the underlying harshness of the metaphor. For Adam Smith, the idea of competition plausibly evoked nothing more disturbing than a horse race in which the losers are not summarily executed. Since then, the close identification of marginalist economics with evolutionary theory has unavoidably imbued the concept with the sense of a life or death strug- gle (cf. Niehans, 1990). In short, on competitiveness hangs life itself. As Krugman (1994, p. 31) defines it: “when we say that a corporation is uncompetitive, we mean that its market position is . . . unsustainable – that unless it improves its perform- ance it will cease to exist.” 392 ERICA SCHOENBERGER

As with evolutionary theory, our ability to strip the moral and ethical content from the concepts of life and death is not so great as the self-image of modern science suggests. Competitiveness becomes inescapably associated with ideas of fitness and unfitness, and these in turn with the unstated premise of merit, as in “deserving to live” and “deserving to die.” Secondly, competitiveness is the discourse of the business community and repre- sents both an essential value and an essential validation. More generally, it serves as an all purpose and unarguable explanation for any behavior: “We must do X in order to be competitive.” Again, the implied “or else” is death. As hinted, though, the discourse of competitiveness has seeped out beyond these sources and is becoming socially pervasive. University presidents, hospital adminis- trators, and government bureaucrats also discourse quite fluently now about com- petitiveness and its related accoutrements: customers, total quality, flexibility, and so forth. It will be objected that competitiveness is a deeply ingrained social category and value in the USA and elsewhere and there is no particular reason to single out econ- omists and business persons as culprits in its dissemination. That objection is true enough, and no doubt contributes to the general power of the discourse since it resonates so well with this broader heritage. But “competitiveness” in the sense of “deserving to live” is not what was commonly meant by this more diffuse social understanding. It is, however, what is meant in economic analysis and business life, and it is increasingly what is meant in other institutional and social settings as well.

The power of the discourse In my own work, I am constantly engaged in discussions of competitive strategy and competitiveness with the people who run firms. In this context I strive to be a critical and detached interlocutor whose job it is to analyze and interpret – rather than simply report – responses to my questions. When I’m talking with people about what it takes for them to be competitive in a particular market, or whatever, I am not especially shy about debating the substance of their answers. That is to say, I will argue with them about whether or not a given strategy is a good way of being competitive and what you really need to do to implement it. But that there is some irreducible category called competitiveness, the fulfilling of which, in extremis, over- rides all other considerations – that I don’t argue about. Or I haven’t up to now. I have simply accepted the general idea of competitiveness as the ultimate demon- stration of the validity of that behavior. I don’t think I’m alone in this. I think it’s characteristic of economic geography to assume the categories of competition and competitiveness in order to answer other questions rather than asking what these categories themselves might be about. I think also that an unexamined notion of competitiveness plays an increasingly strong, if not decisive role in many political and institutional debates with enor- mous consequences for real people. So it is important to try to understand why the concept is so powerful that it enjoys a kind of social immunity. You can discuss what is more and what is less competitive, but you can’t call the category into question. DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 393

Within the academy, the power of the discourse of economics has a lot to do with the social power of the discipline. This, in turn, involves some complicated mix of command over material resources, claims of social utility, a certain amount of proselytizing in other disciplines, asserting a family resemblance with other powerful and “hard” disciplines such as physics by virtue of its mathematized and abstract style of reasoning, and so on. Social power, in turn, can be deployed to set a standard of what constitutes “science” in the social sciences against which other forms of social science (e.g., geography) are implicitly or explicitly valued (cf. Clark, 1998). As McCloskey (1985, p. 82) notes, “The metaphors of economics often carry . . . the authority of Science and . . . its claims to ethical neutrality.” One doesn’t have to suppose the least degree of cravenness on the part of other social scientists to imagine that the social norms established in this way gradually become part of the general environ- ment and become more generally valued as they are within economics (Foucault, 1995). Certain practices and ways of thinking, as in a Marshallian industrial dis- trict, are “in the air” and we are all hard-pressed to avoid inhaling them. The best evidence of this effect within economic geography that I can think of is actually in the writings of the Marxists within the field, especially in the 1970s and early 1980s. There was a time when none of us could write anything without a lengthy introductory section in which we took great pains to demolish the assump- tions and analytical tropes of neoclassical economics. We couldn’t leave it alone, and I think it must be the case that the long struggle to valorize an alternative world- view and scientific method has left its mark on all of us. But we’re marked in sur- prisingly subtle ways and it takes real work to see the effects. But economics also derives some of its power from being able to deploy concepts such as competitiveness which have tremendous ideological weight. Market com- petition is the guarantor of the fairness of the social system as a whole because markets, by the definition of the discipline, are impartial and competitiveness, though a life or death affair, proceeds on a purely technical basis. That is to say, you are not competitive or uncompetitive because of who you are, but merely as a result of how you respond to market signals that provide the same information to everyone. Further, the idea of economic competitiveness meshes so perfectly with evolutionary theory that it takes on exactly the natural and timeless air that makes it so unarguable. The discipline that owns such a concept – whose discourse this is – is bound to seem inevitable. In sum, the social power of economics within the academic hierarchy helps anchor the power of its discourse which, in true virtuous circle fashion, reinforces the social power of the discipline. On top of all this, the discourse is shared with another extraordinarily powerful social group: the “business community.” The problems of competition, competitive strategy, and competitiveness are deeply meaningful to people who run businesses. They really see them as authentic life and death issues and, at the limit, they are right. But there is arguably a broad range of issues and conditions in which life and death are not at stake, but com- petitiveness is automatically invoked anyway as the unchallengeable and “natural” explanation for what is about to happen. The degree to which this is accepted and even imitated by people in other spheres entirely is remarkable. 394 ERICA SCHOENBERGER

What the discourse produces What is the relationship, then, between discourse and our material reality and between discourse and our ability to act in the world – at least as it relates to the issue of competitiveness? Here are some thoughts. The relationship between discourse and material reality/action is mediated by the social power of the discursive agent. The social resources deployed in validating the discourse on competitiveness are really quite impressive. But they can be deployed with great economy or remain entirely latent because of the way the discourse has been successfully naturalized. The beauty of it is that, once the conversation moves on to this terrain, we more or less automatically fall silent of our own accord. This may be a particular instance of Foucault’s notion of disciplinary individualism, in which the essence of freedom is voluntary compliance with the rules – in this case, the established order of a particular discipline (Foucault, 1995; cf. Poovey, 1995). Once the word is uttered, its disciplinary force is made manifest. This isn’t meant to imply that we unavoidably end up by simply parroting the economists and business persons. But it does suggest that we may be subtly deflected from certain kinds of questions or challenges to the discourse and the practices asso- ciated with it, whether this is in an academic setting or a more general public arena. This rather simple observation has, I want to stress, real consequences for aca- demics and nonacademics alike. For academics, the substance of our questions and challenges is our stock in trade. We get research funds on the basis of them and write articles which will anchor our careers, allowing us to ask new questions to get more funding and so on. Meanwhile we are contributing to the collective construction of a body of knowledge – an interpretive structure – which shapes a more general under- standing of the world. We make and validate ourselves through our discourse. The silencing and deflecting effect of the discourse on competitiveness can also be seen in various forms of public discourse about any number of issues: the envi- ronment, welfare reform, healthcare reform, and, more obviously, the competitive- ness of the national economy. Again, when all goes well, no specific exercise of overt power has to be undertaken. The disciplining effect of the discourse has been naturalized and internalized, so it is effective even with people whose interests are plainly not served by it. It also makes it all the more remarkable when some undis- ciplined groups of people do, in the end, fight back.

The Discourse and Practice of Competitiveness in Everyday Life In this section, I want to work through a couple of examples of discourse in action on the issue of competitiveness to get a clearer idea of what is at stake. The first example asks to what degree Nike’s “competitiveness” depends on having access to low-cost labor in offshore production sites. The second looks at issues of urban competitiveness through an examination of the living wage campaign in Baltimore.

Nike Nike as a corporation needs no introduction. It is not so much global as omnipresent. It has spread its interests out from athletic shoes to sports equipment DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 395 and sports clothing, but it is mainly known for transforming athletic shoes into a design and fashion-intensive business, and the company became phenomenally rich in the process (Katz, 1994). According to its 1996 10-K report to the SEC, it is the largest athletic footwear company in the world (Nike, 1996). Nike also pioneered a shifting international division of labor in athletic shoe pro- duction which relies largely on subcontractors in a hierarchically nested set of off- shore production locations (cf. Donaghu and Barff, 1990). If local costs become too high, a given location may be either upgraded in its tasks so that costs are not out of line, or abandoned in favor of less expensive locales. This is a production strat- egy that has been imitated by most of Nike’s major competitors. Shoe assembly remains a highly labor-intensive operation, so wage rates are an obvious location factor. Or we could say that Nike needs access to low-cost labor in order to remain competitive. Unsurprisingly, virtually all the company’s athletic shoe output is produced in six Asian countries: Indonesia (38%), the People’s Republic of China (34%), South Korea (11%), Taiwan (5%), Thailand (10%), and Vietnam (2%) (Nike, 1996). Lately the company has come under some fire for the treatment of workers – especially women workers – in these offshore facilities. As well as offering poor wages and working conditions, Nike subcontractors are accused of physical and sexual abuse. In response, Nike has developed a code of conduct for its subcon- tractors and hired former UN Ambassador and civil rights activist Andrew Young and his consulting firm, Goodworks, to monitor the human rights situation in its offshore operations (ILO, 1996; The New York Times, 1997a, 1997b). Most recently, Nike and several other apparel and footwear companies have reached an agreement with labor and human rights groups to support minimum labor standards in offshore facilities. The standards specify a maximum 60-hour workweek and onsite monitoring for abuses. They ban the employment of children under 15 except where it is permissible to employ 14-year-olds. Companies must pay at least the local minimum wage. Particular points of contention in the negoti- ations leading up to this agreement reportedly included the independence of the monitors (companies will be allowed to appoint their own) and whether companies should try to pay a local “living wage” – that is, a wage sufficient to live on in the country in question – rather than the local minimum wage. So far, the companies involved have insisted that the legal minimum wage is the appropriate standard (The New York Times, 1977c, 1997d). On another front, Nike has also recently joined a consortium which is working to eliminate pervasive child labor in the soccer ball sewing industry in Pakistan. It was reported that children received 60 cents for sewing a ball that might retail for $30–50. An experienced child can sew two in a day. Here, then, is the issue. In a labor-intensive industry, we might all agree, low wages have something to do with competitiveness. But how much exactly do they have to do with “competitiveness,” or the ability to survive economically in a market system, and how much with something else? I was forced to think, in reading about soccer balls in Pakistan, that no company’s ability to exist in the world could pos- sibly depend on paying children 60 cents to sew a $50 soccer ball. Why not 90 cents? Why not $3.00? What difference would it make? Similarly, why is it so impor- tant to companies that they obligate themselves only to pay the legal minimum wage 396 ERICA SCHOENBERGER in places like Vietnam? Would it make such a difference to pay enough to live on there? I thought I would try to construct a crude numerical analysis of Nike’s produc- tion costs for its footwear in order to see to what degree the company’s competi- tiveness can be linked to the wages it is actually paying in its low-cost offshore operations – or, at any rate, the wages that its subcontractors are paying on its behalf. In effect, I want to find out what would happen to the company if it 1) simply doubled the prevailing local wage; 2) paid all its offshore workers ten times the prevailing local wage; and 3) paid its offshore workers roughly the USA minimum wage. A first constraint is that it can’t pass the cost increase along to its customers so the wage increase presumably won’t affect its competitiveness in the market or its revenues. Would it still make money? This can’t be calculated with any great precision, but the method is as follows. Nike acknowledges a total employment figure of 17,200 worldwide. However, this figure almost certainly doesn’t include precisely the workers we are interested in, so we simply have to guess. One guess would be that a roughly equivalent number of workers is employed by subcontractors – say 20,000 for ease of calcu- lation. Another guess would be that the number of subcontracted workers is con- siderably larger – say 50,000. Average monthly or annual earnings for manufacturing workers in various coun- tries is provided by the ILO’s Yearbook of Labor Statistics for 1996. Unfortunately, data for Vietnam and Taiwan are unavailable. Because their share of total Nike pro- duction in Asia is relatively small (7% total), I took the liberty of simply assimilat- ing them to the nearest Nike country in terms of economic development levels, so that workers in Vietnam are treated as though they earned the same wages as Indonesians in 1990, and workers in Taiwan are treated as though they were Korean women. Korea was the only country on the list for which it was possible to obtain data specifically for women and so all Nike workers in Korea and Taiwan are treated as though they were female. This might tend to understate the actual wage bill for these countries, but on the other hand, using averages for men and women in all the other countries probably overstates their actual wage bills. If there are 20,000 Nike subcontract workers apportioned to each country according to its share in total output, the annual wage bill amounts to some $44 million (see Table 25.1). If there are 50,000 workers, the annual wage bill comes to $111 million. Table 25.2 shows the results of intervening in the actual wage levels by first dou- bling them, and then multiplying them by a factor of ten. In both these operations, I have held wages in Korea/Taiwan to current actual levels which happen to be almost exactly equivalent to the annual earnings of a full-time worker in the USA who is paid the current minimum wage of $4.75/hour. In other words, I have granted raises only to workers in Indonesia, the People’s Republic of China, Thailand, and Vietnam. If there are 20,000 workers, doubling low incomes increases the total wage bill by $13.5 million or roughly 31%. Multiplying by ten yields an increase of $122 million or 274%. If there are 50,000 workers, the increases are $34 million and $304 million, respectively (the percentages are the same). DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 397

Table 25.1: Estimation of Nike’s offshore employment costs

Country Average annual If 20,000 offshore workers If 50,000 offshore workers per capita earnings in manufacturing Employment Annual Employment Annual ($US) wage bill wage bill (US$000s) (US$000s)

Indonesia 5731,2,3 7,600 4,354.8 19,000 10,887.0 Vietnam 5731,2,3 400 229.2 1,000 573.0 People’s 7393,4 6,800 5,025.2 17,000 12,563.0 Republic of China South 9,6435,6 2,200 21,214.6 5,500 53,036.0 Korea Taiwan 9,6435,6 1,000 9,643.0 2,500 24,107.5 Thailand 1,9553,4 2,000 3910.0 5,000 9,775.0 Total 20,000 44,376.0 50,000 110,942.0

Notes: 1. Indonesia, 1990; 2. Total labor cost including overheads; 3. Average for men and women; 4. 1994; 5. Korea, 1995; 6. Women only. Figures calculated using exchange rates for March 21, 1997. Sources: ILO, 1996; Nike, 1996.

Table 25.2: Estimated total annual wage bill under varying conditions, Nike offshore manufacturing Employment Increase Employment Increase (20,000) (US$000s) (50,000) (US$000s) At current earnings 44,377 – 110,942 – Earnings in low-income 57,896 13,519 144,740 33,798 countries1 doubled Earnings in low- 166,050 121,673 415,124 304,183 income countries1 ¥10 All country earnings 192,860 148,483 482,150 371,208 at level of Korea

Note: 1. Indonesia, The People’s Republic of China, Thailand, and Vietnam. Source: Table 25.1.

I then raise everybody to the level of Korea or, roughly, the USA minimum wage. At 20,000 workers, this produces an increase of $148 million or 335%. At 50,000 workers, the wage bill increases by $371 million. This latter figure represents a little under 10% of Nike’s total costs in 1996, which were $3.9 billion. Table 25.3 provides various reference points for judging the impact of these wage increases on Nike’s financial results. We can highlight the worst-case scenario to get an overall sense of what is at risk. In the worst case (50,000 workers at Korean wage rates), Nike revenues stay constant at $6.5 billion while costs rise to $4.3 billion. Gross margins accordingly decline from 39.6% to 33.9%. This is 398 ERICA SCHOENBERGER

Table 25.3: Financial impact of raising wages, worst case scenario (50,000 workers at Korea-level wages)

Nike 1996 actual results Projected results

Revenues (US$000s) 6,470,625 6,470,625 Costs (US$000s) 3,906,756 4,277,964 Income before taxes (US$000s) 899,090 527,822 Net income (US$000s) 553,190 203,235 Net income/common share (US$) 3.77 1.38 Gross margin (US$000s) 2,563,879 2,192,661 Gross margin (%) 39.6 33.9 Return on equity (%) 25.2 9.3 Return on assets (%) 15.6 5.7

Sources: Tables 25.1 and 25.2; Nike, 1996. significant, given that Nike’s gross margins have been at least 38% since 1990, but it is clearly not fatal. Income before taxes was $899 million in 1996. If we deduct the cost increase entirely from this figure, income before taxes declines to $527.8 million, which is still ahead of the comparable figure for 1994 ($490.6 million). Holding the company’s effective income tax rate constant at 38.5%, this yields a net income of $203 million compared with the $553 million actually recorded. Since 1990, Nike’s net income has not dropped below $243 million. Net income per common share drops from $3.77 to something like $1.38. Nike’s net income per share has not gone lower than $1.61 since 1990. In 1996, Nike recorded a 25.2% return on equity and a 15.6% return on assets. As near as I can tell (and I know that this is inexact), these ratios drop to 9.3% and 5.7%, respectively. The lowest recorded values for these categories since 1990 are 17.7% and 13.1%. This worst-case scenario assumes there is zero slack in the system. One might wish to consider, for example, that Nike spent $642.5 million on advertising and promotion in 1996 or roughly 72% of its income before taxes. Now it may be that this is exactly the optimal figure to spend and that any reduction would generate a decline in revenues. On the other hand, it might not be the optimal figure, and it might be possible to lay off some of the increased wage costs against this sum. Or it might be possible to sew the equivalent of a little dolphin on each pair of shoes that has been made under certified humane conditions and charge a little bit more for them. That doesn’t matter, though. What is clear is that if you assume 50,000 offshore workers and you decide to pay them all roughly the USA minimum wage – which is, for most of them, something more than ten times their present earnings – Nike still makes money. The company can absorb 100% of the increased costs and still earn a half billion dollars before taxes. That is to say, the company is still competitive. Another way of putting this is to say that relying on low-wage offshore workers has nothing to do with Nike’s competitiveness. What does it have to do with, then? It may be more accurate to say that, rather than being a necessary part of the firm’s DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 399 competitive strategy, low-wage offshore women workers are a core part of the company’s accumulation strategy and its stock market strategy. In sum, using ultra-cheap female labor in the Third World allows the company to accelerate the rate at which it accumulates and can redeploy capital, either in expanded and more productive production, or in the kind of global advertising cam- paigns that simply squash the competition. At the same time, it allows it to boost its financial statistics to more attractive levels. This isn’t stupid from a corporate point of view, and companies have the legal right to operate this way. But it is not what we meant by competitive. It is not a life or death situation, and it is not unarguable. I don’t imagine for a minute that anyone really thought that Nike was utterly compelled to pay exactly Indonesian wage levels in order to stay alive. But I do find it possible to imagine that we generally find it plausible that Nike finds it necessary, under the pressures of a competitive market, to pay “low” wages without figuring out what the boundaries of the category of “low” ought to be. I think also that this plausibility reflects the power and pervasiveness of a particular discourse.

Baltimore Baltimore is, in many ways, a classic case of urban decline. A once robust and diver- sified manufacturing base has all but collapsed, a thriving port has been downsized and automated, and the white middle class has long since fled to the surrounding counties. Beginning in the 1970s, tremendous state and federal subsidies fed an urban renewal project centered on tourism and services that has redeemed Baltimore’s image in the eyes of many without changing the essential fact that an appalling proportion of the city’s majority black population lives in poverty. Indeed, the kind of jobs generated by the urban renewal strategy, because they often pay at or near the minimum wage, guarantee that even people working full time will con- tinue to live in poverty. Working full time at a minimum wage of $4.25/hour pro- vides an annual income of just under $9000 a year, assuming no time off. The recent increase to $4.75/hour brings that to $9880. The federal poverty line for a family of four is just under $16,000. Needless to say, these jobs ordinarily do not offer benefits of any sort. Among the first to decide to take this issue head on was a group of highly respected and influential pastors with long experience in the civil-rights movement. They could hardly avoid noticing that many of the people who were regulars at the soup kitchens run by their churches held full-time jobs and were still a long way from being able to support themselves and their families. The pastors, working through a group called Baltimoreans United in Leadership Development (BUILD), allied themselves with an Industrial Areas Foundation group trying to organize low- income workers. The resulting Solidarity Sponsoring Committee (SSC) is also sup- ported by AFSCME. As a result of their efforts, Baltimore in 1994 became the first city in the USA to pass a “Living Wage” ordinance. The ordinance requires all providers of services working on contract for the city to pay their employees a living wage – that is to say, an hourly wage sufficient to lift its recipients above the poverty line. That wage is currently pegged at $7.70/hour 400 ERICA SCHOENBERGER

(compared with the current minimum wage of $4.75) although the ordinance phases in the increase. Thus, at the time of writing the current minimum under the ordi- nance is $6.60/hour, rising to $7.10 on 1 July 1997 and to $7.70 the following year. Workers employed directly by the city are already paid at or above this level so the immediate budgetary impacts are restricted to the effects of raising wages on contract costs to the city. The total number of workers involved is thought to be somewhere on the order of 4000, implying that the total direct economic impact on the city will be quite constrained. However, we can suppose that raising the wages of the lowest paid will lead to a certain degree of upward wage drift. And we know that SSC is working hard to organize other low-wage service workers around the living wage. Johns Hopkins University, the largest private employer in Maryland, has so far promised to institute a $6.00 minimum wage on its service contracts in response to this organizing campaign. The ultimate aim in fact is to make the living wage the minimum wage in Baltimore. Debate about the impacts of the living wage has centered on the costs to the city government and the “competitiveness” of the city. Baltimore’s competitiveness or lack thereof is, of course, an extraordinarily touchy subject in the city which has been strenuously fighting to revalorize itself in very particular ways for decades. The revalorization strategy has essentially had two aspects. The first has been to subsidize publicly the costs to private capital of doing business in the city. The second has been to create geographic enclaves, centering on the Inner Harbor and central business district and including selected outposts such as universities and hospitals, and making these areas “safe” for investment. By safe, of course, we mean (but could never say) free of any threat posed by dangerously poor (black) people. Safest of all is free of their presence entirely. The living wage appears to be at odds with the first strand of the strategy and essentially irrelevant to the second. The enclave strategy is exclusionary and implies keeping poor people away, not bringing them in and remedying their circumstances. In any case, the second part of the strategy can’t be discussed, and so the prevail- ing discourse, emanating from the traditional centers of power in this city and others where similar proposals are on the table, has been about costs and competitiveness (Weisbrot and Sforza-Roderick, 1996). And this, indeed, has been the discourse engaged by researchers such as myself. I have been involved in a study designed to assess the impacts of the living wage on Baltimore. This is a follow-up to a 1996 study by the Preamble Foundation which found, actually, that the real cost of city contracts declined slightly and the value of business investments increased in the year following passage of the ordinance. Indeed, positive side-effects of the law appear to be a drastic decrease in turnover and absenteeism and an increase in productivity associated with rising wages (Weisbrot and Sforza-Roderick, 1996). Now, there’s nothing wrong with assessing the costs of this or any other activ- ity. I just went through a whole song and dance about Nike’s costs, and I’m very interested to find out what the longer-run cost impacts of the living wage bill are in Baltimore. What if, though, the data had turned out differently in the Preamble Center study, or turn out differently in ours? What if all we can show is that yes, the city’s costs increased and at the same time, for whatever reasons, investment in the city declined? DISCOURSE AND PRACTICE IN HUMAN GEOGRAPHY 401

What is disturbing is that the discourse of costs and competitiveness defines the entire terrain of discussion – it constitutes the only valid currency of argument. In part, this is because there is so much going on that can’t be said in polite society and in part this is because the “scientifically valid” data that one can find are almost wholly about these categories. To demonstrate this, I tried to imagine doing an entirely different kind of research project related to the living wage in Baltimore. The hypothesis is that high costs are not a significant deterrent to productive investment in Baltimore; the significant deterrent is poverty, and the insecurity that poverty generates for poor and rich alike. Poverty means no market and poorly prepared workers whose lives are con- stantly disrupted by small catastrophes which in turn disrupt their ability to work. Poverty also means poor health and a lack of physical security for workers and employers. Poverty means a meager tax base and poor urban infrastructure and services. The cost of doing business could be zero here, and still investment might not be forthcoming. The living wage, in this context, would be the leading policy tool to encourage investment and economic growth. There’s another aspect of the kind of place and person that poverty creates that is worth mentioning. Poverty creates scary “others” who, in Baltimore, are pre- dominantly African-American. By the usual social sleight-of-hand, race comes to stand for the general suitability of a person for employment. Or, to put this another way, it is no longer the competitiveness of the person, but the competitiveness of the body that counts in the first instance in creating a labor supply that is seen to be appropriate for investment (cf. Martin, 1992; Wright, 1996; Harvey, 1998). In a capitalist society, however, the scariness of the Other can be mitigated to the degree that the Other provides a productive basis for accumulation. Again the living wage would seem to be the appropriate policy. I’m acutely aware that I can’t demonstrate any part of this argument in an accept- able scientific fashion. That’s the point, really. The discourse, and the real resources that support the discourse, open up a terrain for some kinds of research and make others quite difficult and less valid looking. One is still free to make a moral argu- ment, but that has nothing to do with one’s status as a researcher or a scientist in society. Academic freedom or no, it turns out that we’re quite constrained in doing our jobs, and as a result, we may end up tacitly supporting the very discourse and practices that constrain us in the first place.

Conclusion Colonial subjects have long had to struggle with what it means to use the language of the master – even in postcolonial times. In our normal understanding of academic life, we aren’t supposed to have anything in common with colonial subjects on this or any other issue. But if we are strongly objective about ourselves and our work as Sandra Harding urges, can we be sure that the desired objectivity of our research is not subtly undermined by our reliance on a language and a discourse that is not entirely of our own choosing and, arguably, is a language and a discourse that rep- resents the interests of particular social groups and not others? The answer, I think, is that we can’t be sure, so we have to check repeatedly and try to figure out what difference it makes. What difference, for example, does it 402 ERICA SCHOENBERGER make to conclude that Nike’s offshore manufacturing is an accumulation strategy rather than a competitive strategy, or that Baltimore’s competitive status is under- mined by poverty, not by costs? I don’t think it necessarily means specific, nameable things. I suspect, rather, that over time, if we keep checking back on ourselves and our work in this way, we will contribute to building an alternative ensemble of intellectual and material resources that can be used to pose and answer different kinds of question – our own ques- tions, and questions arising from the discourses and material circumstances of dif- ferent sorts of people. Among other things, I suspect this would help us to liberate ourselves from the constraining shadows of other disciplines, such as economics, and to re-create geography as a central arena of inquiry and debate within the uni- versity and outside it (cf. Clark, 1998). I don’t at all want to argue that, having absorbed the hegemonic discourse, we are all doomed to be Stepford geographers who can only serve that discourse. But I think it must help us to know more clearly why we’re doing what we’re doing, and why we do it in a particular way. Examining and debating our own discourse and the practices deeply associated with it with some of the same intensity and care with which we examine and debate the world “out there” will help us understand these things better. Bibliography

Abernathy, W. J., Clark, K. B., and Kantrow, A. M. 1983. Industrial Renaissance: Produc- ing a Competitive Future for America. New York: Basic Books. Abo, T. 1996. The Japanese production system: The process of adaptation to national set- tings. In R. Boyer and D. Drache (eds). States Against Markets: The Limits of Globaliza- tion. London: Routledge, 136–54. Achebe, C. 1983. The Trouble with Nigeria. Ibadan: Heinemann. Acker, J. 1990. Hierarchies, jobs, bodies: A theory of gendered organisations. Gender and Society, 4, 139–58. Adam, B. 1995. Timewatch. Cambridge: Polity Press. Adams, P. 1995. A reconsideration of personal boundaries in space-time. Annals of the Asso- ciation of American Geographers, 85, 267–85. Aglietta, M. 1979. A Theory of Capitalist Regulation. London: New Left Books. Agrawal, R. G. 1981. Third-World joint ventures: Indian experience. In K. Kumar and M. G. McLeod (eds). Multinationals from Developing Countries. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 115–31. Aitken, J. 1987. A stranger in the family: The legal status of domestic workers in Ontario. Law Review, 45, 394–415. Akrich, M. 1992. The description of technological objects. In W. Bijker and J. Law (eds). Shaping Technology, Building Society: Studies in Sociotechnical Change. London: MIT Press, 205–24. Albert, M. 1993. Capitalism against Capitalism. New York: Four Walls Eight Windows. Allen, J. and Hamnett, C. (eds). 1995. A Shrinking World? Global Unevenness and Inequal- ity. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Allen, J. 1988. The geographies of service. In D. Massey and J. Allen (eds). Uneven Re- Development: Cities and Regions in Transition. London: Hodder and Stoughton, 124–41. Altamira, R. 1923. Ideario Pedagógico. Madrid: Editorial Reus. Altvater, E. 1993. The Future of the Market: An Essay on the Regulation of Money and Nature. London: Verso. Altvater, E. 1994. Ecological and economic modalities of time and space. In M. O’Connor (ed.). Is Capitalism Sustainable? New York: Guilford, 76–90. Amariglio, J. 1988. The body, economic discourse and power: An economist’s introduction to Foucault. History of Political Economy, 20, 583–613. 404 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Amariglio, J. and Ruccio, D. 1994. Postmodernism, Marxism and the critique of modern economic thought. Rethinking Marxism, 7, 7–35. Amariglio, J. and Ruccio, D. 1999. Modern economics and the case of the disappearing body. In M. Woodmansee and M. Osteen (Eds), The New Economic Criticism: Studies at the Intersection of Literature and Economics. London: Routledge. Amariglio, J., Resnick, S., and Wolff, R. 1988. Class, power and culture. In C. Nelson and L. Grossberg (eds). Marxism and the Interpretation of Culture. London: Macmillan, 487–502. Amendola, G., Guerrieri, P., and Padoan, P. C. 1992. International patterns of technological accumulation and trade. Journal of International and Comparative Economics, 1, 173–97. Amin, A. 2000. Organisational learning through communities of practice. Paper presented at the workshop on “The Firm in Economic Geography,” University of Portsmouth, 9–11 March. Amin, A. 1992. Big firms versus the regions in the Single European Market. In M. Dunford and G. Kafkalas (eds). Cities and Regions in the New Europe: The Global–Local Inter- play and Spatial Development Strategies. London: Belhaven Press, 127–49. Amin, A. and Graham, S. 1998. The ordinary city. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 22, 411–29. Amin, A. and Hausner, J. (eds). 1997. Beyond Market and Hierarchy: Interactive Gover- nance and Social Complexity. Aldershot: Edward Edgar. Amin, A. and Malmberg, A. 1992. Competing structural and institutional influences on the geography of production in Europe. Environment and Planning A, 24, 401–16. Amin, A. and Thrift, N. J. 1995. Institutional issues for the European regions: From markets and plans to socioeconomics and powers of association. Economy and Society, 24, 41–66. Amin, A. and Thrift, N. J. (eds). 1994. Globalisation, Institutions and Regional Develop- ment in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Amin, A. and Thrift, N. J. 1994. Living in the global. In A. Amin and N. J. Thrift (eds). Globalisation, Institutions and Regional Development in Europe. Oxford: Oxford Uni- versity Press, 1–22. Amin, A. and Thrift, N. J. 1997. Globalization, socio-economics, territoriality. In R. Lee. and J. Wills (eds). Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold, 147–57. Amuzegar, J. 1982. Oil wealth: A very mixed blessing. Foreign Affairs, 60, 814–35. Anderson, B. 1983. Imagined Communities. London: Verso. Anderson, P. 1984. Lineages of the Absolutist State. London: Verso. Angoustures, A. 1995. Historia de España en el Siglo XX. Barcelona: Editorial Ariel. Appadurai, A. 1990. Disjuncture and difference in the global cultural economy. Public Culture, 2, 1–24. Arce, A. and Marsden, T. 1993. The social construction of international food: A new research agenda. Economic Geography, 69, 291–311. Arnold, E. 1984. Competition and Technical Change in the UK Television Industry. London: Macmillan. Asanuma, B. 1989. Manufacturer–supplier relationships in Japan and the concept of relation-specific skill. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 3, 1–30. Asheim, B. 1997. “Learning regions” in a globalised world economy: Towards a new competitive advantage of industrial districts? In S. Conti and M. Taylor (eds). Interdependent and Uneven Development: Global–Local Perspectives. London: Avebury, 143–76. Azorín. 1982. Obras Selectas, 5th edn. Madrid: Editorial Biblioteca Nueva. Babbage, C. 1835. On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures. New York: A. M. Lelley. BIBLIOGRAPHY 405

Bagguley, P., Mark-Lawson, J., Shapiro, D., Urry, J., Walby, S., and Warde, A. 1990. Restruc- turing: Place, Class and Gender. London: Sage. Bagnasco, A. 1977. Tre Italie: La Problematica Territoriale Dello Sviluppo. Bologna: Il Mulino. Bagnasco, A. 1988. La Costruzione Sociale Del Mercato. Bologna: II Mulino. Bakshi, P., Goodwin, M., Painter, J., and Southern, A. 1995. Gender, race and class in the local welfare state: Moving beyond regulation theory in analysing the transition from Fordism. Environment and Planning A, 27, 1539–54. Block, F. 1990. Postindustrial Possibilities. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Baldwin, T., McVoy, D., and Steinfield, C. 1996. Convergence: Integrating Media, Informa- tion and Communication. London: Sage. Balibar, E. 1995. The Philosophy of Marx. London: Verso. Ballance, R. H. 1987. International Industry and Business: Structural Change, Industrial Policy and Industry Strategies. London: Allen and Unwin. Barlow, J. and Savage, M. 1986. The politics of growth: Cleavage and conflict in a Tory heartland. Capital and Class, 30, 156–82. Barnes, T. J. 1994. Probable writing: Derrida, deconstruction and the quantitative revolution in human geography. Environment and Planning A, 26, 1021–40. Barnes, T. J. 1996. Logics of Dislocation: Models, Metaphors and Meanings of Economic Space. New York: Guilford. Barnes, T. J. 2000. Inventing Anglo-American economic geography, 1889–1960. In E. S. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 11–26. Barratt-Brown, M. 1993. Fair Trade. London: Zed Books. Barrett, H. and Browne, A. 1991. Environment and economic sustainability: Women’s horticultural production in The Gambia. Geography, 776, 241–48. Bartlett, C. A. and Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing Across Borders: The Transnational Solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Bassett, T. 1988. The political ecology of peasant–herder conflicts in the northern Ivory Coast. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 78, 453–72. Bataille, G. 1988. The Accursed Share. New York: Zone Books. Batty, M. 1993. The geography of cyberspace. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design, 20, 615–61. Bauman, Z. 1992. Intimations of Postmodernity. London: Routledge. Becattini, G. and Rullani, E. 1993. Sistema locale e mercato globale. Economia e Politica Industriale, 80, 25–40. Becattini, G. 1987. L’unita d’indagine. In G. Becattini (ed.). Mercato e forze f Locali: Il Dis- tretto Industriale. Bologna: Il Mulino, 35–48. Beechey, V. 1977. Unequal Work. London: Verso. Belk, R. 1995. Consuming Societies. New York: Routledge. Bell, D. 1973. The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. New York: Basic Books. Bellamy, E. 1897. Equality. New York: Appleton. Bender, J. and Welbery, D. E. (eds). 1991. Chronotoypes. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Benedikt, M. 1991. Introduction. In M. Benedikt (ed.). Cyberspace: First Steps. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1–18. Bennett, T. (ed.). 1981. “Christmas.” Popular culture: themes and issues. Milton Keynes: Open University Press (book 1, units 1/2). Bennington, G. 1995. Introduction to economics. In C. Gill (ed.). Bataille: Writing the Sacred. London: Routledge, 63–108. Benton, T. 1989. Marxism and natural limits: An ecological critique and reconstruction. New Left Review, 178, 51–86. 406 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Benton, T. 1991. The Malthusian challenge: Ecology, natural limits and human emancipa- tion. In P. Osborne (ed.). Socialism and the Limits to Liberalism. London: Verso, 241–69. Benton, T. 1992. Ecology, socialism and the mastery of nature: A reply to Reiner Grundmann? New Left Review, 194, 55–72. Benton, T. (ed.). 1996. The Greening of Marxism. New York: Guilford. Berkes, F. 1985. Fishermen and “the tragedy of the commons.” Environmental Conserva- tion, 12, 199–206. Berry, S. 1986. Concentration without privatisation: Agrarian consequences of rural land control in Africa. In Conference on agricultural policy and African food security: Issues, prospects and constraints, toward the year 2000. Champagne-Urbana, IL: Center for African Studies, University of Illinois. Berry, S. 1989. Social institutions and access to resources. Africa, 59, 41–55. Bianchi, P. 1993. The promotion of small-firm clusters and industrial districts: European policy perspectives. Journal of Industry Studies, 1, 16–29. Bierstecker, T. 1988. Reaching agreement with the IMF: The Nigerian negotiations 1983–1986. Unpublished manuscript, School of International Relations, University of Southern California, Los Angeles. Billig, M., Condor, S., Edwards, D., Gare, M., Middleton, D., and Radley, A. 1988. Ideo- logical Dilemmas. London: Sage. Bingham, N. 1996. Objections: From technological determinism towards geographies of rela- tions. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 14, 635–57. Blaikie, P. and Brookfield, H. 1987. Land Degradation and Society. New York: Methuen. Blanc, H. and Sierra, C. 1999. The internationalisation of R&D by multinationals: A trade- off between external and internal proximity. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, 187–206. Blauhof, G. 1994. Non-equilibria dynamics and the sociology of technology. In L. Leydesdorff and P. van der Desselaar (eds). Evolutionary Economics and Chaos Theory. London: Pinter, 152–66. Block, F. 1994. The roles of the state in the economy. In N. Smelser and R. Smedberg (eds). The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 691–710. Block, F. and Hirschborn, L. 1979. New productive forces and the contradictions of contemporary capitalism: A post-industrial perspective. Theory and Society, 7/3, 363–96. Bluestone, B. and Harrison, B. 1982. The Deindustrialization of America. New York: Basic Books. Boddy, M. and Fudge, C. 1984. Local Socialism. London: Macmillan. Boden, D. 1994. The Business of Talk: Organizations in Action. Cambridge: Polity. Bohm, D. 1980. Wholeness and the Implicate Order. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Bohm, D. 1994. Thought as System. London: Routledge. Boisot, M. H. 1995. Information Space. London: Routledge. Bonnett, K., Bromley, S., and Jessop, B. 1990. Farewell to Thatcherism? Neo-liberalism and “new times.” New Left Review, 179, 81–102. Boothroyd, P. and Davis, C. 1993. Community economic development: Three approaches. Journal of Planning Education and Research, 12, 230–40. Bordo, S. 1989. The body and the reproduction of femininity: The feminist appropriation of Foucault. In A. Jagger and S. Bordo (eds). Gender, Body, Knowledge. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 3–34. Bourdieu, P. 1984. Distinction. London: Routledge. Boyer, C. 1996. Cybercities: Visual Perception in an Age of Electronic Communication. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. BIBLIOGRAPHY 407

Boyer, R. (ed.). 1988. The Search for Labour Market Flexibility: The European Economies in Transition. Oxford: Clarendon. Braczyk, H.-J., Cooke, P., and Heidenreich, M. 1998. Regional Innovation Systems. London: UCL Press. Bradby, B. 1982. The remystification of value. Capital and Class, 17, 114–33. Bradley, H. 1989. Men’s Work, Women’s Work. Cambridge: Polity. Braudel, F. 1973. The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the Age of Philip II. New York: Harper and Row. Braudel, F. 1982. The Wheels of Commerce. New York: HarperCollins. Braverman, H. 1974. Labour and Monopoly Capital. New York: Monthly Review Press. Brennan, D. and O’Donnell, C. 1986. Caring for Australia’s Children. Sydney: Allen and Unwin. Brennan, T. 1994. History after Lacan. London: Routledge. Brooks, R. 1992. Maggie’s man: We were wrong. The Observer, June 21, p. 21. Brotchie, J., Hall, P., and Newton, P. (eds). 1987. The Spatial Impact of Technological Change. London: Croom Helm. Brown, J. S. and Duguid, P. 1996. Organizational learning and communities-of-practice. In M. D. Cohen and L. S. Sproull (eds). Organizational Learning. London: Sage. Brown, J. S. and Duguid, P. 2000. Balancing act: How to capture knowledge without killing it. Harvard Business Review, 78, 73–80. Browning, H. L. and Singelmann, J. 1975. The Emergence of a Service Society. Springfield, VA: National Technical Information Service. Brusco, S. 1982. The Emilian model: Productive decentralisation and social integration. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6, 167–84. Bryan, D. 1992. Wage policy and the Accord: Comment. Journal of Australian Political Economy, 29, 99–110. Bryant, R. 1992. Political ecology: An emerging research agenda in Third World studies. Political Geography, 11, 12–36. Busch Cooper, B. 1985. The War Against the Seals. Montreal: McGill Queen’s University Press. Business Week. 1983. How the PC project changed the way IBM thinks. October 3, pp. 43–4. Business Week. 1984. Just-in-time inventories: combating foreign rivals. May 14, pp. 44–9. Butler, J. 1990. Gender Trouble: Feminism and the Subversion of Identity. London: Routledge. Butler, J. 1993. Bodies That Matter: On the Discursive Limits of Sex. New York: Routledge. Butler, J. 1997. The Psychic Life of Power: Theories of Subjection. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Buttimer, A. 1982. Musing on helicon: Root metaphors and geography. Geografiska Annaler, 64B, 89–96. Cable, V. and Clarke, J. 1981. British Electronics and Competition with Newly Industrial- ized Countries. London: Overseas Development Institute. Cairncross, F. 1997. The Death of Distance: How the communications revolution will change our lives. London: Orion Business Books. Callari, A. 1983. Adam Smith, the theory of value and the history of economic thought. Association of Economic and Social Analysis Discussion Paper No. 3, University of Massachusetts-Amherst. Callon, M. 1991. Techno-economic networks and irreversibility. In J. Law (ed.). A Sociology of Monsters. London: Routledge, 132–61. Callon, M. 1986. Some elements of a sociology of translation: Domestication of the scallops and the fisherman of St Brieuc bay. In J. Law (ed.). Power, Action and Belief: A New Sociology of Knowledge. London: Routledge, 196–232. 408 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Callon, M. and Latour, B. 1981. Unscrewing the big leviathan. In K. Knorr-Cetina and A. Cicourel (eds). Advances in Social Theory and Methodology. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 277–303. Callon, M. and Law, J. 1995. Agency and the hybrid collectif. South Atlantic Quarterly, 94, 481–507. Cameron, J. 1995. Ironing out the family: Class, gender and power in the household. Mimeo, Department of Geography and Environmental Sciences, Monash University, Clayton VIC, Australia. Campbell, B. 1993. Goliath. London: Methuen. Cano García, G. 1992. Confederaciones Hidrográficas. In A. Gil Olcina and A. Morales Gil (eds). Hitos Históricos de los Regadíos Españoles. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura/Pesca y Alimentación, 309–34. Carling, A. 1986. Rational choice Marxism. New Left Review, 160, 24–62. Carling, A. 1992. Analytical Marxism. London: Verso. Carney, J. 1980. Regions in crisis: Accumulation, regional problems and crisis formation. In J. Carney, R. Hudson, and R. Lewis (eds). Regions in Crisis. London: Croom Helm, 28–59. Carney, J. 1986. The social history of Gambian rice production: An analysis of food secu- rity strategies. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley. Carney, J. 1988. Struggles over crop rights within contract farming households in a Gambian irrigated rice project. Journal of Peasant Studies, 15, 334–49. Carney, J. 1991. Indigenous soil and water management in Senegambian rice farming systems. Agriculture and Human Values, 8, 37–58. Carney, J. 1992. Peasant women and economic transformation in The Gambia. Development and Change, 23, 67–90. Carney, J. 1994. Contracting a food staple in The Gambia. In P. Little and M. Watts (eds). Peasants under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin, 167–87. Carney, J. and Hudson, R. 1978. Capital, politics and ideology: The North East of England, 1870–1946. Antipode, 10, 64–78. Carney, J. and Watts, M. 1991. Disciplining women? Rice, mechanization, and the evolution of Mandinka gender relations in Senegambia. Signs, 16, 651–81. Carnoy, M. 1993. Multinationals in a changing world economy: Whither the nation-state? In M. Carnoy, M. Castells, S. Cohen, and F. H. Cardoso (eds). The New Global Economy in the Information Age. University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 45–96. Carr, R. 1983. Espana: de la Restauración a la Democracia, 1875–1980. Barcelona: Editorial Ariel. Carrier, J. G. 1995. Maussian occidentalism: Gift and commodity systems. In J. G. Carrier (ed.). Occidentalism: Images of the West. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 85–108. Castells, M. 1989. The Informational City. Oxford: Blackwell. Castells, M. 1983. The informational economy and the new international division of labor. In M. Carnoy, M. Castells, S. Cohen, and F. H. Cardoso (eds), The New Global Economy in the Information Age. University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 15–44. Castells, M. 1996. The Rise of the Network Society. Oxford: Blackwell. Castree, N. 1995. The nature of produced nature: Materiality and knowledge construction in Marxism. Antipode, 27, 12–48. Cavendish, R. 1982. Women on the Line. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Caves, R. 1982. Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. BIBLIOGRAPHY 409

Ceesay, M., Jammeh, O., and Mitchell, I. 1982. Study of Vegetable and Fruit Marketing in The Gambia. Banjul, The Gambia: Ministry of Economic Planning and Industrial Devel- opment and the World Bank. Center for Research on Economic Development [CRED]. 1985. Rural Development in the Gambian River Basin. Ann Arbor, MI: CRED. Cerny, P. G. 1990. The Changing Architecture of Politics. London: Sage. Cerny, P. G. 1991. The limits of deregulation: Transnational interpenetrations and policy change. European Journal of Political Research, 19, 173–96. Chandler, D. A. 1977. The Visible Hand. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Belknap. Chang, K.-T. and Thomson, C. N. 1994. Taiwanese foreign direct investment and trade with Thailand. Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography, 15, 112–27. Chase-Dunn, C. 1989. Global Formation. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell. Chaudhry, K. 1989. The price of wealth: Business and state in labor remittance and oil economies. International Organization, 43, 101–45. Cheal, D. J. 1988. The Gift Economy. London: Routledge. Chisholm, G. G. 1889. Handbook of Commercial Geography. London and New York: Longman, Green, and Co. Christopherson, S. 1993. Market rules and territorial outcomes: The case of the United States. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 17, 274–88. Christopherson, S. 1999. Rules as resources: How market governance regimes influence firm networks. In T. J. Barnes and M. S. Gertler (eds). The New Industrial Geography: Regions, Regulation and Institutions. London: Routledge, 155–75. Christopherson, S. and Storper, M. 1986. The city as studio; the world as back lot: The impact of vertical disintegration on the location of the motion picture industry. Environ- ment and Planning D: Society and Space, 4, 305–20. CILSS [Permanent Interstate Committee for Drought Control in the Sahel]. 1979. Develop- ment of Irrigated Agriculture in Gambia: General Overview and Prospects. Proposal for a second program 1980–1985. Paris: Club du Sahel. CILSS. 1990. Study on Improvement Irrigated Farming in The Gambia. Paris: Club du Sahel. Ciriacy Wantrup, S. V. and Bishop, R. C. 1975. Common property as a concept in natural resource property. Natural Resources Journal, 15, 713–26. CIS [Counter Information Services] n.d. Anti-Report on Ford. London: Counter Information Services. Citizenship and Immigration Canada. 1999. The Live-in Caregiver Program: Information for Employers and Live-In Caregivers from Abroad. Ottawa: Minister of Public Works and Government Services. City of Camberwell. 1987. Melbourne Inter-Council Comparison. 3rd edn. Melbourne: City of Camberwell. Clark, G. L., Gertler, M., and Feldman, M. (eds). 2000. The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Clark, G. L., Mansfield, D., and Tickell, A. 2001. Emergent frameworks in global finance: Accounting standards and German supplementary pensions. Economic Geography, 77, 250–71. Clark, G. L., Mansfield, D., and Tickell, A. 2002. Global finance and the German model: German corporations, market incentives, and the management of employer-sponsored pension institutions. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 27, 91–110. Clark, C. 1940. The Conditions of Economic Progress. London: Macmillan. Clark, G. 1998. Stylized facts and close dialogue: Methodology in economic geography. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 88, 73–87. Clavel, P. 1982. Opposition planning in Wales and Appalachia. Philadelphia: Temple Uni- versity Press. 410 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Coase, R. H. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405. Coase, R. H. 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44. Cochrane, A. 1983. Local economic policies: Trying to drain an ocean with a teaspoon. In J. Anderson, S. Duncan, and R. Hudson (eds). Redundant Spaces in Cities and Regions? London: Academic Press, 285–312. Cockburn, C. 1985. Machinery of Dominance: Women, Men and Technical Know-How. London: Pluto Press. Cohen, S. S. and Zysman, J. 1987. Manufacturing Matters: The Myth of the Post-Industrial Economy. New York: Basic Books. Collins, H. M. 1981. The role of the core set in modern science. History of Science, 19, 6–19. Collinson, D. and Hearn, G. 1994. Naming men as men: Implications for work, organisa- tion and management. Gender, Work and Organisation, 1, 2–22. Colomina, B. (ed.). 1992. Sexuality and Space. New York: Princeton Architectural Press. Cook, I. and Crang, P. 1996. The world on a plate: Culinary culture, displacement and geo- graphical knowledges. Journal of Material Culture, 1, 131–53. Cooke, P. (ed.). 1989. Localities. London: Hyman. Cooke, P. 1997. Regions in a global market: The experiences of Wales and Baden- Wurttemberg. Review of International Political Economy, 4, 349–81. Cooke, P. and Morgan, K. 1998. The Associational Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Corn, J. 1986. Epilogue. In J. Corn (ed.). Imagining Tomorrow: History, Technology and the American Future. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 219–29. Corn, J. and Horrigan, B. 1984. Yesterday’s Tomorrows: Past Visions of the American Future. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Coronil, F. 1987. The black El Dorado: Money fetishism, democracy and capitalism in Venezuela. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago. Coronil, F. and Skurski, J. 1991. Dismembering and remembering the nation: The semantics of political violence in Venezuela. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 26, 288–337. Cosmides, L. and Tooby, J. 1994. Better than rational: Evolutionary psychology and the invisible hand. American Economic Review, 84, 327–32. Costa, J. 1892. Política Hidráulica y Misión Social de los Riegos en España. Madrid: Edición de la Gaya Ciencia. Costello, V. 1981. Tehran. In M. Pacione (ed.). Problems and Planning in Third World Cities. New York: St. Martin’s, 137–56. Cox, K. R. 1992. The politics of globalization: A sceptic’s view. Political Geography, 11, 427–9. Crang, P. 1994. It’s showtime: On the workplace geographies of display in a restaurant in Southeast England. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 12, 675–704. Crompton, R. 1992. Where did all the bright girls go? Women’s higher education and em- ployment since 1964. In N. Abercrombie and A. Warde (eds). Social Change in Britain. Cambridge: Polity Press. Crompton, R. and Sanderson, K. 1990. Gendered Jobs and Social Change. London: Unwin Hyman. Cronon, W. 1991. Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West. New York: A. A. Norton. Curran, C. 1991. Change of heart: Interview with Meg Smith, Peter Ewer, Chris Lloyd and John Rainford, four of the authors of “Surviving the Accord: From Restraint to Renewal.” Australian Left Review, 134, 24–9. Curry, M. 1991. On the possibility of ethics in geography: Writing, citing, and the con- struction of intellectual property. Progress in Human Geography, 15, 125–48. BIBLIOGRAPHY 411

Curtin, P. 1984. Cross-Cultural Trade in World History. New York: Cambridge University Press. Cusumano, M. A. 1985. The Japanese Automobile Industry. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Uni- versity Press. Dahrendorf, R. 1968. Market and plan: Two types of rationality. In R. Dahrendorf (ed.). Essays in the Theory of Society. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 215– 31. Daniels, P. 1988. Producer services and the post-industrial space-economy. In D. Massey and J. Allen (eds). Uneven Re-development: Cities and Regions in Transition. London, Hodder and Stoughton, 107–23. de Reparez, G. 1906. Hidráulica y Dasonomiá. Diario de Barcelona, July 21. Dear, M. and Wolch, J. 1987. Landscapes of Despair. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press. Dear, M. J. and Wolch, J. R. 1989. How territory shapes social life. In J. R. Wolch and M. J. Dear (eds). The Power of Geography. Boston: Allen and Unwin, 1–18. Debord, G. 1978. Society of the Spectacle. Detroit: Black and Red Books. DeCosse, P. and Camara, E. 1990. A Profile of the Horticultural Production Sector in Gambia. Banjul, The Gambia: Department of Planning and Ministry of Agriculture. del Moral Ituarte, L. 1996. Sequía y Crisis de Sostenibilidad del Modelo de Gestión Hidráulica. In M. V. Marzol, P. Dorta, and P. Valladares (eds). Clima y Agua: La Gestión de un Recurso Climático. Madrid: La Laguna, 179–87. del Moral Ituarte, L. 1998. L’état de la Politique Hydraulique en Espagne. Hérodote, 91, 118–38. Deleuze, G. and Guattari, F. 1983. Anti-Oedipus. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Delorme, R. 1997. The foundational bearing of complexity. In A. Amin and J. Hausner (eds). Beyond Market and Hierarchy: Interactive Governance and Social Complexity. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Demeritt, D. 1994. The nature of metaphors in cultural geography and environmental history. Progress in Human Geography, 18, 163–85. Derman, W. 1984. USAID in the Sahel. In J. Barker (ed.). The Politics of Agriculture in Tropical Africa. Beverly Hills: Sage, 77–97. Derrida, J. 1982. Given Time: Counterfeit Money. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Derrida, J. 1992. Given Time. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Derrida, J. 1995. The Gift of Death. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Dex, S. 1987. Women’s Occupational Mobility. London: Macmillan. Dey, J. 1981. Gambian women: Unequal partners in rice development projects? Journal of Development Studies, 17, 109–22. Dicken, P. 1990. Seducing foreign investors: The competitive bidding strategies of local and regional agencies in the United Kingdom. In M. Hebbert and J.-C. Hansen (eds). Unfamiliar Territory: The Reshaping of European Geography. Aldershot: Avebury, 162–86. Dicken, P. 1992a. Global Shift. 2nd edn. London: Chapman. Dicken, P. 1992b. International production in a volatile regulatory environment: The influ- ence of national regulatory policies on the spatial strategies of transnational corporations. Geoforum, 23, 303–16. Dicken, P. 1994. Global–local tensions: Firms and states in the global space-economy. Eco- nomic Geography, 70, 101–28. Dicken, P. 1998. Global Shift. 3rd edn. New York: Guilford. Dicken, P., Peck, J., and Tickell, A. 1997. Unpacking the global. In R. Lee and J. Wills (eds). Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold, 158–66. 412 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Dicken, P. and Thrift, N. J. 1992. The organization of production and the production of organization: Why business enterprises matter in the study of geographical industrializa- tion. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 17, 279–91. Dominic, G. 1983/84. Beyond the transformation riddle: A labor theory of value. Science and Society, 47, 427–50. Donaghu, M. and Barff, R. 1990. Nike just did it: International subcontracting and flexibil- ity in athletic footwear production. Regional Studies, 24, 537–52. Dore, R. 1983. Goodwill and the spirit of market capitalism. British Journal of Sociology, 34, 459–82. Doremus, P., Keller, W., Pauly, L., and Reich, S. 1998. The Myth of the Global Corporation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Dorfman, N. S. 1983. Route 128: The development of a regional high technology economy. Research Policy, 12, 299–316. Dorsey, K. 1991. Putting a ceiling on sealing: Conservation and cooperation in the interna- tional arena, 1909–11. Environmental History Review, 15, 27–46. Dosi, G., Pavitt, K., and Soete, L. 1990. The Economics of Technical Change and Interna- tional Trade. London: Harvester. Douglass, D. and Krieger, J. 1983. A Miner’s Life. Henley: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Doz, Y. 1986. Strategic Management in Multinational Companies. Oxford: Pergamon. Driever, S. L. 1998. “And since Heaven has filled Spain with goods and gifts”: Lucas Mallada, the Regeneracionist Movement, and the Spanish Environment, 1881–90. Journal of His- torical Geography, 24, 36–52. DuGay, P. 1996. Consumption and Identity at Work. London: Sage. Dunning, J. H. 1992. The global economy, domestic governance strategies and transnational corporations: Interactions and policy implications. Transnational Corporations, 1, 7–45. Dunning, J. H. 1993. Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Dunning, J. H. and Norman, G. 1985. Intra industry production as a form of international economic involvement: An exploratory analysis. In A. Erdilek (ed.). Multinationals as Mutual Invaders: Intra Industry Foreign Direct Investment. New York: St. Martin’s, 9–28. Dunsmore, J. R. 1976. The Agricultural Development of The Gambia: An Agricultural, Envi- ronmental and Socio-Economic Analysis. Land Resource Study No. 22. Surrey: Land Resources Division, Ministry of Overseas Development. Eagleton, T. 1997. Spaced out. London Review of Books, April 27, pp. 22–3. Eckersley, R. 1992. Environmentalism and Political Theory: Toward an Ecocentric Approach. London: University College Press. Eckersley, R. 1993. Free market environmentalism: Friend or foe? Environmental Politics,2, 1–19. Edge, S. 1995. Consuming in the face of hatred. Soundings, 1, 163–74. Edquist, C. (ed.). 1997. Systems of Innovation: Technologies, Institutions and Organizations. London: Pinter. Edwards, R. 1979. Contested Terrain. New York: Basic Books. EITB [Engineering Industry Training Board]. 1981. Maintenance Skills in the Engineering Industry. Stockport, Cheshire: Engineering Industry Training Board. Ekpo, E. 1985. IMF Loan Comes to Nigeria. Apapa: Nigerian Problems and Issues. Eli, M. 1990. Japan Inc.: Global strategies of Japanese Trading Corporations. London: McGraw-Hill. Elson, D. (ed.). 1979. Value: The Representation of Labour in Capitalism. London: CSE Books. BIBLIOGRAPHY 413

Elson, D. 1989. The cutting edge: Multinationals in the EEC textiles and clothing industry. In D. Elson and R. Pearson (eds). Women’s Employment and Multinationals in Europe. London: Macmillan, 80–110. Elster, J. 1979. Logic and Society. Chichester: John Wiley. Elster, J. 1986. Making Sense of Marx. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Emecheta, B. 1982. Naira Power. London: Macmillan. Encarnation, D. J. 1992. Rivals Beyond Trade: America versus Japan in Global Competi- tion. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Encarnation, D. J. and Wells, L. T. 1986. Competitive strategies in global industries. In M. E. Porter (ed.). Competition in Global Industries. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School, 267–90. Enderwick, P. (ed.). 1997. Foreign Investment: The New Zealand Experience. Palmerston North: Dunmore Press. Ernst, D. 1990. Global Competition, New Information Technologies and International Tech- nology Diffusion: Implications for Industrial Latecomers. Paris: OECD Development Centre. Featherstone, M. 1991. Consumer Culture and Postmodernism. London: Sage. Featherstone, M. (ed.). 1990. Global Culture: Nationalism, Globalisation, and Modernity. London: Sage. Ferenczi, S. 1950. Sex in Psychoanalysis. New York: Holmes. Fernández Clemente, E. 1990. La Política Hidráulica de Joaquín Costa. In T. Pérez Picazo and G. Lemeunier (eds). Agua y Modo de Producción. Barcelona: Editorial Crítica, 69–97. Fincher, R. 1987. Space, class and political processes: The social relations of the local state. Progress in Human Geography, 11, 496–515. Fine B., Heasman, M., and Wright, J. 1996. Consumption in the Age of Affluence: The World of Food. London: Routledge. Fisher, G. B. A. 1952. A note on tertiary production. Economic Journal, 62, 820–34. Fitzsimmons, M. 1989. Reconstructing nature. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 7, 1–3. Fleck, L. 1935. Genesis and Development of a Scientific Fact. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Florida, R. 1995. Toward the learning region. Futures, 27, 527–35. Folbre, N. 1993. Who Pays for the Kids? Gender and the Construction of Constraint. New York: Routledge. Fontana, J. 1975. Cambio Económico y Actitudes Políticas en la España del Siglo XIX. Barcelona: Editorial Ariel. Food and Agriculture Organization. 1983. Rice Mission Report to The Gambia. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization. Foucault, M. 1973. The Order of Things: An Archaeology of the Human Sciences. New York: Vintage Books. Foucault, M. 1979. History of Sexuality. Vol. 1. London: Allen Lane. Foucault, M. 1995. Discipline and Punish. 2nd edn. New York: Pantheon. Fox, S. 1981. John Muir and his Legacy: The American Conservation Movement. Boston, MA: Little Brown. Fraad, H., Resnick, S., and Wolff, R. 1994. Bringing it all Back Home: Class, Gender, and Power in the Modern Household. London: Pluto. Francis, J. 1993. The Politics of Regulation. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell. Frank, A. G. 1980. Crisis in the World Economy. London: Heinemann. Franke, R. and Chasin, B. 1980. Seeds of Famine. Montclair, NJ: Allanheld. Frankel, H. 1977. Money: Two Philosophies. Oxford: Blackwell. 414 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Fransman, M. 1994. Information, knowledge, vision and theories of the firm. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3, 1–45. Fraser, N. 1997. Justice Interruptus: Critical Reflections of the “Postsocialist” Condition. London: Routledge. Freud, S. 1955. Standard Edition of the Complete Psychological Works. London: Hogarth Press. Friedland, W., Busch, L., Buttel, F., and Rudy, A. 1991. Towards a New Political Economy of Agriculture. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Fröbel, F., Heinrichs, J., and Kreye, O. 1980. The New International Division of Labor. New York: Cambridge University Press. Fuchs, V. 1968. The Services Economy. New York: Columbia University Press. Fujita, M., Krugman, P., and Venables, A. J. 1999: The Spatial Economy: Cities, Regions and International Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Fukuyama, F. 1995. Trust. New York: Free Press. Gabriel, P. 1966. The investment in the LDC: Asset with a fixed maturity. Columbia Journal of World Business, 111, 3–20. Gamble, D. 1955. Economic Conditions in Two Mandinka Villages: Kerewan and Keneba. London: Colonial Office. Garrabou, R. 1975. La Crisi Agrária Espanyola de Finals del Segle XIX: Una Etapa del Desenvolupament del Capitalisme. Recerques, 5, 163–216. Gatens, M. 1991. Representations in/and the body politic. In R. Diprose and R. Ferrel (eds). Cartographies: The Mappings of Bodies and Spaces. Sydney: Allen & Unwin, 79–87. Gates, W. 1995. The Road Ahead. London: Viking. Gelb, A. 1984. Adjustment to Windfall Gains: A Comparative Analysis of Oil Exporting Countries. Washington, DC: World Bank. Gelerntner, D. 1991. Mirror Worlds. New York: Oxford University Press. Gerber, J. 1997. Beyond dualism: The social construction of nature and the natural and social construction of human beings. Progress in Human Geography, 21, 1–17. Gerlach, M. L. 1992. Alliance Capitalism: The Social Organization of Japanese Business. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Gershuny, J. 1976. After Industrial Society. London: Macmillan. Gertler, M. S. 1992. Flexibility revisited: Districts, nation-states and the forces of production. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 17, 259–78. Gertler, M. S. 1995. “Being there”: Proximity, organization, and culture in the development and adoption of advanced manufacturing technologies. Economic Geography, 71, 1–26. Gertler, M. S. 1996. Worlds apart: The changing market geography of the German machin- ery industry. Small Business Economics, 8, 87–106. Gertler, M. S. 1999. The production of industrial processes. In T. J. Barnes and M. S. Gertler (eds). The New Industrial Geography: Regions, Regulation and Institutions. London: Routledge, 225–37. Giansante, C. 1999. In-Depth Analysis of Relevant Stakeholders: Guadalquivir River Basin Authority. Mimeo, Department of Geography, University of Seville. Gibson, W. 1984. Neuromancer. London: Harper and Collins. Gibson-Graham, J.-K. 1996. The End of Capitalism (As We Knew It): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy. Oxford: Blackwell. Gibson-Graham, J.-K. 2000. Poststructural interventions. In E. Sheppard and T. Barnes (eds). Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 95–110. Giddens, A. 1979. Central Problems in Social Theory. London: Macmillan. Giddens, A. 1981. A Contemporary Critique of Historical Materialism. London: Macmillan. Giddens, A. 1990. The Consequences of Modernity. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Giddens, A. 1991. Modernity and Self-Identity. Cambridge: Polity. BIBLIOGRAPHY 415

Giddens, A. 1994. Beyond Left and Right. Cambridge: Polity. Giffen, J. 1987. An Evaluation of Women’s Vegetable Gardens. Banjul: Oxfam. 1 Gille, D. 1986. Maceration and purification. In ZONE /2. New York: Urzone, 226–83. Gillespie, A. 1992. Communications technologies and the future of the city. In M. Breheny (ed.). Sustainable Development and Urban Form. London: Pion, 67–77. Gilpin, R. 1975. US Power and the Multinational Corporation: The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. New York: Basic Books. Ginzberg, E. and Vojta, G. 1981. The service sector of the US Economy. Scientific American, 244/3, 48–65. Glickman, N. J. and Woodward, D. P. 1989. The New Competitors. New York: Basic Books. Gluek, A. C. 1982. Canada’s splendid bargain: The North Pacific Fur Seal Convention of 1911. Canadian Historical Review, LXIII, 179–200. Goffman, E. 1963. Behavior in Public Places. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. Gómez Mendoza, J. 1992. Regeneracionismo y Regadíos. In A. Gil Olcina and A. Morales Gil (eds). Hitos Históricos de los Regadíos Españoles. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura. Pesca y Alimentación, 231–62. Gómez Mendoza, J. and del Moral Ituarte, L. 1995. El Plan Hidrológico Nacional: Criterios y Directrices. In A. Gil Olicna and A. Morales Gil (eds). Planificación Hidráulica en España. Murcia: Fundación Caja del Mediterráneo, 331–98. Gómez Mendoza, J. and Ortega Cantero, N. 1987. Geografía y Regeneracionismo en España. Sistema, 77, 77–89. Gómez Mendoza, J. and Ortega Cantero, N. 1992. Interplay of state and local concern in the management of natural resources: Hydraulics and forestry in Spain 1855–1936. Geo- Journal, 26, 173–79. Goodman, D. and Watts, M. 1994. Reconfiguring the rural or fording the divide? Capitalist restructuring and the agro-food system. Journal of Peasant Studies, 22, 1–49. Gordon, D. M. 1988. The global economy: New edifice or crumbling foundations? New Left Review, 16, 824–64. Gordon, H. S. 1954. The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 124–42. Gottmann, J. 1982. Urban settlements and telecommunications. Ekistics, 302, 411–16. Gould, S. J. 1991. Bully for Brontosaurus: Reflections on Natural History. New York: Norton. Goux, J.-J. 1989. Symbolic Economies after Marx and Freud. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univer- sity Press. Goux, J.-J. 1990. General economies and postmodern capitalism. Yale French Studies, 78, 206–24. Government of The Gambia. 1966. Five Year Plan for Economic and Social Development. Banjul: Ministry of Economic Planning and Industrial Development. Government of The Gambia. 1987. Donors’ Conference on the Agricultural Sector in The Gambia. Banjul: Ministry of Agriculture. Grabher, G. and Stark, D. (eds). 1997. Restructuring networks in postsocialism: Linkages and localities. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Grabher, G. (ed.). 1993. The Embedded Firm. London: Routledge. Graham, S. 1996. Imagining the real-time city: Telecommunications, urban paradigms, and the future of cities. In S. Westwood and J. Williams (eds). Imagining Cities: Scripts, Signs and Memories. London: Routledge, 31–49. Graham, S. 1997. Liberalized utilities, new technologies, and urban social polarization: The UK case. European Urban and Regional Studies, 4, 135–50. Graham, S. 1998. Spaces of surveillant-simulation: New technologies, digital representations, and material geographies. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 16, 483–504. 416 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Graham, S. and Aurigi, A. 1997. Virtual cities, social polarisation and the crisis in urban public space. Journal of Urban Technology, 4, 19–52. Graham, S. and Marvin, S. 1996. Telecommunications and the City: Electronic Spaces, Urban Places. London: Routledge. Gramsci, A. 1978. Selections from Political Writings, 1921–26. London: Verso. Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 481–510. Granovetter, M. and Swedberg, R. (eds). 1993. The Sociology of Economic Life. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Graycar, A. and Harrison, J. 1984. Ageing populations and social care: Policy issues. Australian Journal on Ageing, 3, 3–9. Greenblatt, S. 1992. Marvellous Possessions: The Wonder of the New World. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Gregory, D. and Urry, J. (eds). 1985. Social Relations and Spatial Structures. London: Macmillan. Gregson, N. and Lowe, M. 1994. Servicing the Middle Classes. London: Routledge. Grossman, H. 1978. Marx, classical political economy and the problem of dynamics. Capital and Class, 2, 67–99. Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Grosz, E. 1994. Volatile Bodies: Towards a Corporeal Feminism. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Grundmann, R. 1991. Marxism and Ecology. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Grundmann, R. 1992. The ecological challenge to Marxism. New Left Review, 187, 103–120. Guisinger, S. 1985. Investment Incentives and Performance Requirements. New York: Praeger. Gumbrecht, H. U. and Pfeiffer, K. L. (eds). 1994. Materialities of Communication. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Hall, S. 1991. The local and the global: Globalization and ethnicity. In A. King (ed.). Culture, Globalization, and the World-system: Contemporary Conditions for the Representation of Identity. Binghamton, NY: State University of New York Press, 21–40. Hamelink, C. (ed.). 1983. Finance and Information. Norwood, NY: Greenwood Publishing Group. Hamilton, G. and Biggart, N. W. 1988. Market culture, and authority: A comparative analy- sis of management and organization in the Far East. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S52–S94. Hamilton, G. 1991. The organizational foundations of Western and Chinese commerce: A historical and comparative analysis. In G. Hamilton (ed.). Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia. Hong Kong: Centre of Asian Studies, University of Hong Kong, 48–65. Hamilton, G. and Biggart, N. W. 1992. Market, culture, and authority: A comparative analy- sis of management and organization in the Far East. In M. Granovetter and R. Swedberg (eds). The Sociology of Economic Life. Oxford: Westview Press, 81–221. Hanson, S. and Pratt, G. 1988. Reconceptualizing the links between home and work in human geography. Economic Geography, 64, 299–321. Hanson, S. and Pratt, G. 1995. Gender, Work and Space. London: Routledge. Haraway, D. 1991. Simians, Cyborgs, and Women: The Reinvention of Nature. New York: Routledge. Hardin, G. 1968. The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–8. BIBLIOGRAPHY 417

Harding, S. 1991. Whose Science? Whose Knowledge? Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Harrison, B. 1994. Lean and Mean: The Resurrection of Corporate Power in an Age of Flexibility. New York: Basic Books. Hartshorne, R. 1939. The Nature of Geography: A Critical Survey of Current Thought in Light of the Past. Lancaster, PA: Association of American Geographers. Harvey, C. 1990. Improvements in Farmer Welfare in The Gambia: Groundnut Price Subsi- dies And Alternatives. Institute of Development Studies Discussion Paper No. 277. Sussex: Institute of Development Studies. Harvey, D. 1974. Population, resources and the ideology of science. Economic Geography 50, 256–277. Harvey, D. 1975a. Class structure in a capitalist society and the theory of residential differ- entiation. In R. Peel, M. Chisholm, and P. Haggett (eds). Process in Physical and Human Geography: Bristol Essays. London: Heinemann, 354–69. Harvey, D. 1975b. The geography of accumulation: A reconstruction of the Marxian theory. Antipode, 7, 9–21. Harvey, D. 1982. The Limits to Capital. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvey, D. 1985a. Consciousness and the Urban Experience. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvey, D. 1985b. The Urbanization of Capital. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvey, D. 1987. Flexible accumulation through urbanization: Reflections on post- modernism in the American city. Antipode, 19, 260–86. Harvey, D. 1989. The Condition of Postmodernity. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvey, D. 1993a: From space to place and back again: Reflections on the condition of post- modernity. In J. Bird, B. Curtis, T. Putnam, G. Robertson, and L. Tickner (eds). Mapping the Futures: Local Cultures, Global Change, London: Routledge, 3–29. Harvey, D. 1993b. The nature of environment: The dialectics of social and environmental change. Socialist Register, 29, 1–51. Harvey, D. 1996. Justice, Nature and the Geography of Difference. Oxford: Blackwell. Harvey, D. 1998. The body as an accumulation strategy. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 16, 401–21. Harvey, D. 2000. Spaces of Hope. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Harvey, D. and Scott, A. J. 1988. The practice of human geography: Theory and empirical specificity in the transition from Fordism to flexible accumulation. In W. D. Macmillan (ed.). Remodelling Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 217–29. Hausner, J. 1995. Imperative vs. interactive strategy of systematic change in central and eastern Europe. Review of International Political Economy, 2, 249–66. Haussman, R. 1981. State landed property, oil rent and accumulation in Venezuela. Unpub- lished Ph.D. dissertation, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Hay, C. 1995. Re-stating the problem of regulation and re-regulating the local state. Economy and Society, 24, 387–407. Hayek, F. A. 1948. Individualism and the Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hays, S. 1959. Conservation and the Gospel of Efficiency. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Healey, P., Cameron, S., Davoudi, S., Graham, S., and Madani Pour, A. (eds). 1995. Managing Cities: The New Urban Context. London: Wiley. Hearn, G. and Parkin, P. W. 1987. Sex at Work. Brighton: Wheatsheaf. Helgasen, P. 1990. The Female Advantage. London: Sage. Helm, D. and Pearce, D. 1991. Economic policy towards the environment: An overview. In D. Helm (ed.). Economic Policy Towards the Environment. Oxford: Blackwell, 1–25. 418 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Helou, A. 1991. The nature and competitiveness of Japan’s keiretsu. Journal of World Trade, 25, 99–131. Henderson, J. and Appelbaum, R. P. 1992. Situating the state in the East Asian development process. In J. Henderson and R. P. Appelbaum (eds). States and Development in the Asian Pacific Rim. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1–26. Herrigel, G. 1994. Industry as a form of order: A comparison of the historical development of the machine tool industries in the United States and Germany. In J. R. Hollingsworth, P. C. Schmitter, and W. Streeck (eds). Governing Capitalist Economies: Performance and Control of Economic Sectors. New York: Oxford University Press, 97–128. Hiebert, D. 1999. Local geographies of labor market segmentation: Montreal, Toronto, and Vancouver, 1991. Economic Geography, 75, 339–69. Hill, S. 1988. The Tragedy of Technology. London: Pluto. Hirsch, J. 1991. From the Fordist to the post-Fordist state. In B. Jessop, H. Kastendiek, K. Nielson, and O. K. Pederson (eds). The Politics of Flexibility. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 67–81. Hirst, P. 1994. Associative Democracy. Cambridge: Polity. Hirst, P. and Thompson, G. 1992. The problem of “globalization”: International economic relations, national economic management and the formation of trading blocs. Economy and Society, 21, 357–96. Hirst, P. and Thompson, G. 1996. Globalization in Question. Cambridge: Polity. Ho, S. P. S. and Huenemann, R. W. 1984. China’s Open Door Policy: The Quest for Foreign Technology and Capital. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Hobsbawm, E. 1977. Some reflections on “the break-up of Britain.” New Left Review, 105, 3–24. Hochschild, A. 1983. The Managed Heart. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Hodgson, G. M. 1988. Economics and Institutions. Cambridge: Polity. Hodgson, G. M. 1993. Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Back Into Economics. Cambridge: Polity. Hogdson, G. M. 1998. The approach of institutional economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 162–92. Hogdson, G. M., Samuels, W. J., and Tool, M. R. (eds). 1993. The Elgar Companion to Insti- tutional and Evolutionary Economics. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Howe, A. 1986. Aged care services: An analysis of provider roles and provision outcomes. Urban Policy and Research, 4, 2–20. Hsing, Y.-T. 1997. Making Capitalism in China: The Taiwan Connection. New York: Oxford University Press. Hudson, R. 1999. The learning economy, the learning firm and the learning region: A sympathetic critique of the limits to learning. European Urban and Regional Studies, 6, 59–72. Hudson, R. 1986. Producing an industrial wasteland: Capital, labour and the state in North East England. In R. L. Martin and B. Rowthorne (eds). The Geography of Deindustriali- sation. London: Macmillan, 169–213. Hudson, R. and Lewis, J. (eds). 1982. Regional Planning in Europe. London: Pion. Hudson, R. and Sadler, D. 1983a. The closure of Consett steelworks: Anatomy of a disaster. Northern Economic Review, 6, 2–17. Hudson, R. and Sadler, D. 1983b. Region, class and the politics of steel closures in the European Community. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 1, 405–28. Hudson, R. and Williams, A. M. 1995. Divided Britain. Chichester: Wiley. Hutchinson, P. 1983. The Climate of The Gambia. Banjul: Ministry of Water Resources and the Environment. Hutton, W. 1995. The State We’re In. London: Jonathan Cape. BIBLIOGRAPHY 419

Hymer, S. H. 1975. The multinational corporation and the law of uneven development. In H. Radice (ed.). International Firms and Modem Imperialism. Harmondsworth: Penguin, 37–62. Hymer, S. 1976. The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Ichigo, K., von Krogh, G., and Nonaka, I. 1998. Knowledge enablers. In G. von Krogh, J. Roos, and D. Kleine (eds). Knowing in Firms: Understanding, Managing and Measur- ing Knowledge. London: Sage, 173–203. Imam-Jomeh, I. 1985. Petroleum-based accumulation and the state in Iran: Aspects of social and geographical differentiation, 1953–1979. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Los Angeles. Ingham, G. 1996. Some recent changes in the relationship between economics and sociology. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 20, 243–75. Izard, M. 1986. Tierra Firme: Historia de Venezuela Contemporanea. Madrid: Alianza America. Jack, I. 1990. Export Constraints and Potentialities for Gambian Horticultural Produce. Banjul: Ministry of Agriculture. Jackson, P. and Thrift, N. J. 1995. Geographies of consumption. In D. Miller (ed.). Acknowl- edging Consumption. London: Routledge, 204–37. Jacobs, M. 1994. The limits to neo-classicism: Towards an institutional environmental eco- nomics. In M. Redclift and T. Benton (eds). Social Theory and the Global Environment. Routledge, London, 67–91. Jeng, A. A. O. 1978. An economic history of The Gambian groundnut industry 1830–1924: The evolution of an export economy. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Birmingham. Jenkins, R. 1987. Transnational Corporations and Uneven Development: The Internation- alization of Capital and the Third World. London: Methuen. Jessop, B. 1982. The Capitalist State. Oxford: Martin Robertson. Jessop, B. 1994. Post-Fordism and the state. In A. Amin (ed.). Post-Fordism: A reader. Oxford: Blackwell, 251–79. Jo, S.-H. 1981. Overseas direct investment by South Korean firms: Direction and pattern. In K. Kumar and M. G. McLeod (eds). Multinationals from Developing Countries. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 53–77. Jobson, R. 1623. The Golden Trade. Devonshire: Speight and Walpole. Johnson, C. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Economic Miracle: The Growth of Industry Policy, 1925–1975. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Johnston, R. J. 1986. The state, the region, and the division of labor. In A. J. Scott and M. Storper (eds). Production, Work, and Territory: The Geographical Anatomy of Indus- trial Capitalism. Boston, MA: Allen and Unwin, 265–78. Johnston, R., Gregory, D., Pratt, G. et al. (eds). 2001: The Dictionary of Human Geogra- phy. Oxford: Blackwell. Johnston, R., Gregory, D., and Smith, D. M. (eds). 1994: The Dictionary of Human Geography. Oxford: Blackwell. Jones, D. T. 1983. Technology and the UK automobile industry. Lloyds Bank Review, 148, 14–27. Jones, D. K. 1980. A Century of Servitude. Washington, DC: University Press of America. Joseph, M. 1998. The performance of production and consumption. Social Text, 16, 25–62. Julius, DeAnne. 1990. Global Companies and Public Policy. London: Pinter. Kanter, R. 1977. Men and Women of the Organization. New York: Basic Books. Kaplinsky, R. 1984. Automation. Harlow: Longman. 420 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Kapuscinski, R. 1982. Shah of Shahs. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Karl, T. 1982. The political economy of petro-dollars: Oil and democracy in Venezuela. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, California. Karl, T. 1997. The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Katouzian, H. 1981. The Political Economy of Modern Iran 1926–1979. New York: New York University Press. Katz, D. 1994. Just do it: The Nike Spirit in the Corporate World. New York: Random House. Kay, J. 1993. Foundations of Corporate Success. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kay, J. 1996. The Business of Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kelly, J. 1983. Scientific Management, Job Redesign and Work Performance. London: Academic Press. Kerfoot, D. and Knights, D. 1994. The gendered terrains of paternalism. In S. Wright (ed.). Anthropology of Organisations. London: Routledge. Kimmel, M. 1988. Changing Men. London: Sage. Kindleberger, C. P. 1988. The “new” multinationaliation of business. ASEAN Economic Bulletin, 5, 113–24. King, A. 1993. Identity and difference: The internationalization of capital and the global- ization of culture. In P. Knox (ed.). The Restless Urban Landscape. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Kinnear, D. and Graycar, A. 1982. Family care of elderly people: Australian perspectives. Social Welfare Research Centre Research Paper 23, University of New South Wales, Kensington NSW, Australia. Kinnear, D. and Graycar, A. 1983. Non-institutional care of elderly people. In A. Graycar (ed.). Retreat from the Welfare State: Australian Social Policy in the 1980s. Sydney: Allen and Unwin. Kirby, V. 1992. Addressing essentialism – thought on the corporeal. Women’s Studies Occa- sional Paper Series # 5, University of Waikato, New Zealand. Kirsch, S. 1995. The incredible shrinking world? Technology and the production of space. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 13, 529–55. Kittler, F. A. 1990. Discourse Networks 1800/1900. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Kobrin, S. J. 1987. Testing the bargaining hypothesis in the manufacturing sector in devel- oping countries. International Organization, 41, 609–38. Kondo, D. K. 1990. Crafting Selves: Power Gender and Discourses of Identity in a Japanese Workplace. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Krugman, P. 1990. Rethinking International Trade. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Krugman, P. 1994. Competitiveness: A dangerous obsession. Foreign Policy, 73, 28–44. Krugman, P. 1995. Development, Geography and Economic Theory. London: MIT Press. Kuhn, T. S. 1962. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. 2nd edn. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Lakatos, I. 1970. Falsification and the methodology of scientific research programmes. In I. Lakatos and A. Musgrave (eds). Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 91–195. Lall, S. 1985. Multinationals, Technology and Exports: Selected Papers, A Study of Multi- national and Local Firm Linkages in India. New York: St Martin’s. Land, N. 1994. Machinic desire. Textual Practice, 7, 471–82. Land, N. 1995. Machines and technocultural complexity. Theory, Culture and Society, 12, 131–40. BIBLIOGRAPHY 421

Landell Mills Associates. 1989. A Market Survey for Gambian Horticultural Crops in the UK, Sweden, The Netherlands and The Federal Republic of Germany. London: Commonwealth Secretariat. Lane, C. 1997. The social regulation of inter-firm relations in Britain and Germany: Market rules, legal norms and technical standards. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21, 197–215. Lash, S. and Urry, J. 1994. Economies of Signs and Space. London: Sage. Lash, S. and Urry, J. 1987. The End of Organized Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity. Latour, B. 1986. The powers of association. In J. Law (ed.). Power, Action and Belief. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 264–80. Latour, B. 1987. Science in Action. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Latour, B. 1993. We Have Never Been Modern. Brighton: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Law, J. 1986. On the methods of long-distance control: Vessels, navigation and the Portuguese route to India. Sociological Review Monograph, 32, 234–63. Law, J. (ed.). 1991. A Sociology of Monsters. London: Routledge. Law, J. 1994. Organising Modernity. Oxford: Blackwell. Law, J. and Bijker, W. 1992. Postscript: Technology, stability and social theory. In W. Bijker and J. Law (eds). Shaping Technology, Building Society: Studies in Sociotechnical Change. London: MIT Press, 290–308. Le Heron, R. 1994. Globalized Agriculture. Oxford: Pergamon. Lebergott, S. 1966. Labor force and employment, 1800–1960. In National Bureau of Eco- nomic Research. Output, Employment and Productivity after 1800. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 117–210. Lebowitz, M. 1977–8. Capital and the production of needs. Science and Society, 41, 430–48. Lee, R. and Wills, J. (eds). 1997. Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold. Lefebvre, H. 1991. The Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell. Leidner, R. 1991. Fast Food, Fast Talk. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Levins, R. and Lewontin, R. 1985. The Dialectical Biologist. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Uni- versity Press. Lewontin, R. 1997. Genes, environment, and organisms. In R. B. Silvers (ed.). Hidden His- tories of Science. London: Granta Books, 115–39. Lewontin, R. 1993. The Doctrine of DNA: Biology as Ideology. Harmondsworth: Penguin. Ley, D. 1980. Liberal ideology and the post-industrial city. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 70, 238–58. Leyshon, A. 1992. The transformation of regulatory order: Regulating the global economy and environment. Geoforum, 23, 249–67. Leyshon, A. 1994. Under pressure: Finance, geo-economic competition and the rise and fall of Japan’s postwar growth economy. In S. Corbridge, N. J. Thrift, and R. L. Martin (eds). Money, Power and Space. Oxford: Blackwell, 116–46. Leyshon, A., Thrift, N. J., and Twommey, C. 1989. The rise of the British provincial finan- cial centre. Progress in Planning, 31, 151–229. Leyshon, A., Thrift, N., and Daniels, P. 1987. The urban and regional consequences of the restructuring of world financial markets: The case of the City of London. Working Papers on Producer Services No. 4, Department of Geography, University of Liverpool. Leyshon, A. and Thrift, N. J. 1997. Money/Space. London: Routledge. Leyshon, A. and Tickell, A. 1994. Money order? The discursive construction of Bretton Woods and the making and breaking of regulatory space. Environment and Planning A, 26, 1861–90. Li, T. K. 1992. Why we invest in Canada. Dialogue, 6 (1), 8. Lim, L. and Fong, P. E. 1982. Vertical linkages and multinational enterprises in developing countries. World Development, 10, 585–95. 422 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Lindstrom, D. 1978. Economic Development of the Philadelphia Region, 1810–50. New York: Columbia University Press. Lipietz, A. 1980. Inter-regional polarisation and the tertiarisation of space. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 44, 3–17. Lipietz, A. 1986. New tendencies in the international division of labor: Regimes of accumu- lation and modes of social regulating. In A. J. Scott and M. Storper (eds). Production, Work, Territory: The Geographical Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism. Boston, MA: Allen and Unwin, 16–40. Lipietz, A. 1992. Towards a New Economic Order: Post-Fordism, Ecology and Democracy. New York: Oxford University Press. Livingstone, D., Luxton, M., and Seccombe, W. 1982. Steelworker Families: Workplace, Household and Community in Hamilton, Ontario. Ottawa: Social Sciences and Humani- ties Research Council of Canada. Lloyd, G. 1993. Being in Time. London: Routledge. Lloyd, P. E. and Dicken, P. 1977. Location in Space. London: Harper and Row. Lodge, D. 2001. Thinks. New York: Viking Press. Loh, M. 1987. On-the-job child care. Australian Society, April, 38. Longino, H. 2002. The Fate of Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Lovering, J. 1989. The restructuring debate. In R. Peet and N. J. Thrift (eds). New Models in Geography. Vol. 1. London: Unwin Hyman, 198–223. Lowe, D. 1995. The Body in Late Capitalist USA. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Lowe, L. 1996. Immigrant Acts. Durham, NC: Duke University Press. Lubeck, P. 1993. Restructuring Nigeria’s urban-industrial sector within the West African region: The interplay of crisis, linkages, and popular resistance. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 16, 7–23. Lundvall, B. A. 1988. Innovation as an interactive process: From user–producer relations to the national system of innovation. In G. Dosi, C. Freeman, G. Silverberg, and L. Soete (eds). Technical Change and Economic Theory. London: Pinter, 349–69. Lundvall, B. A. (ed.). 1992. National Systems of Innovation: Towards a Theory of Innovation and Interactive Learning. London: Pinter. Lupton, D. 1986. Food, the Body and the Self. London: Sage. Macías Picavea, R. 1899. El Problema Nacional. Madrid: Instituto de Estudios de Administración Local. Mackintosh, M. 1989. Gender, Class and Rural Transition. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Zed. MacWilliam, S. 1990. Manufacturing, nationalism and democracy: A review essay. Journal of Australian Political Economy, 24, 100–20. Malinowski, B. 1961. Argonauts of the Western Pacific. New York: E. P. Dutton. Malmberg, A. 1996. Industrial geography: Agglomeration and local milieu. Progress in Human Geography, 20, 392–403. Maluquer de Motes, J. 1983. La Despatrimonialización del Agua: Movilización de un Recurso Natural Fundamental. Revista de Historia Económica, 1, 76–96. Mandel, E. 1980. Long Waves of Capitalist Development: The Marxist Interpretation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mann, R. 1987. Development and the Sahel disaster: The case of The Gambia. The Ecologist, 17, 84–90. Mansell, R. 1994. Introductory overview. In R. Mansell (ed.). Management of Information and Communication Technologies. London: ASLIB, 1–7. Mark-Lawson, J., Savage, M., and Warde, A. 1985. Gender and local politics: Struggles over welfare policies, 1918–1939. In L. M. Murgatroyd, M. Savage, D. Shapiro, J. Urry, S. Walby, and A. Warde with J. Mark-Lawson (eds). Localities, Class and Gender. London: Pion, 195–215. BIBLIOGRAPHY 423

Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan. Marshall, A. 1932. Industry and Trade. 3rd edn. London: Macmillan. Marshall, J. 1984. Women Managers. London: John Wiley. Marshall, M. 1987. Long Waves of Regional Development. London: Macmillan. Martin, E. 1986. The meaning of money in China and the United States. Mimeo, University of Rochester, New York. Martin, E. 1992. Flexible Bodies. Boston, MA: Beacon Press. Martin, R. L. 1994. Stateless monies, global financial integration and national autonomy: The end of geography? In S. Corbridge, N. J. Thrift, and R. L. Martin (eds). Money, Power and Space. Oxford: Blackwell, 253–78. Martin, R. L. and Rowthorn, B. (eds). 1986. The Geography of Deindustrialisation. London: Macmillan. Martin, R. and Sunley, P. 1997. The post-Keynsian state and the space economy. In R. Lee and J. Wills (eds), Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold, 278–89. Martinez, J. I. and Jarillo, J. C. 1989. The evolution of research on coordination mechanisms in multinational corporations. Journal of International Business Studies, 20, 489–514. Marvin, C. 1988. When Old Technologies were New: Thinking about Electric Communica- tion in the Late Nineteenth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Marx, K. 1963. Early Writings (ed. T. Bottomore). Harmondsworth: Penguin. Marx, K. 1967. Capital. Vol. 1. New York: International Publishers. Marx, K. 1973. Grundrisse. New York: Vintage. Marx, K. 1974. Capital: Volume 1 (trans. B. Fowkes). New York: Vintage. Marx, K. 1975. Early Writings. New York: Vintage. Maskell, P., Eskelinen, H., Hannibalsson, I., Malmberg, A., and Vatne, E. 1998. Competi- tiveness, Localised Learning and Regional Development. London: Routledge. Maskell, P. and Malmberg, A. 1999. Localised learning and industrial competitiveness. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, 167–85. Mason, C. 1987. Venture capital in the United Kingdom: A geographical perspective. National Westminster Bank Quarterly Review, May, 47–59. Massey, D. 1979. In what sense a regional problem? Regional Studies, 13, 233–43. Massey, D. 1984. Spatial Divisions of Labor. New York: Methuen. Massey, D. 1988. A new class of geography. Marxism Today, May, 12–17. Massey, D. 1993. Power-geometry and a progressive sense of place. In J. Bird, B. Curtis, T. Putnam, G. Robertson, and L. Tickner (eds). Mapping the Futures: Local Cultures, Global Change. London: Routledge, 59–69. Massey, D. and Allen, J. (eds). 1984. Geography Matters! Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Massey, D. and Allen, J. (eds). 1988. Uneven Re-Development: Cities and Regions in Tran- sition. London: Hodder and Stoughton. Massey, D. and Meegan, R. 1982. The Anatomy of Job Loss. London: Methuen. Mateu Bellés, J. F. 1994. Planificación Hidráulica de las Divisiones Hidrológicas 1865–1899. Mimeo, Department of Geography, University of Valencia. Mateu Bellés, J. F. 1995. Planificación Hidráulica de las Divisiones Hidrológicas. In A. Gil Olicna and A. Morales Gil (eds). Planificaion Hidráulica en España. Murcia: Fundación Caja del Mediterráneo, 69–106. Matthews, J. 1990. Towards a new model of industrial development in Australia. Industrial Relations Working Paper Series 78, School of Industrial Relations and Organizational Behaviour, University of New South Wales, Kensington NSW, Australia, 1–21. Maurice, M., Sellier, F., and Silvestre, J.-J. 1986. The Social Foundations of Industrial Power: A Comparison of France and Germany. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Mauss, M. 1967. The Gift. New York: W. W. Norton. 424 BIBLIOGRAPHY

McCay, B. and Acheson, D. (eds). 1987. The Question of the Commons: The Culture and Ecology of Communal Resources. Phoenix, AZ: Arizona University Press. McCloskey, D. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. McDowell, L. 1991. Life without father and Ford: A new gender order of post-Fordism. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 16, 400–19. McDowell, L. and Massey, D. 1984. A woman’s place. In D. Massey and J. Allen (eds). Geography Matters! Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 128–47. McDowell, L. 1997. Capital Culture: Gender at Work in the City. Oxford: Blackwell. McDowell, L. and Court, G. 1994a. Gender divisions of labour in the post-Fordist economy: The maintenance of occupational sex segregation in the financial services sector. Environ- ment and Planning A, 26, 1397–418. McDowell, L. and Court, G. 1994b. Missing subjects: Gender, power, and sexuality in mer- chant banking. Economic Geography, 70, 229–51. McEvoy. A. F. 1986. The Fisherman’s Problem: Ecology and Law in the California Fisheries, 1850–1980. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. McGrath, M. E. and Hoole, R. W. 1992. Manufacturing’s new economies of scale. Harvard Business Review, May–June, 94–102. McMichael, P. 1996. Development and Social Change: A Global Perspective. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. McPherson, M. and Posner, J. 1991. Structural adjustment in sub-Saharan Africa: Lessons from The Gambia. Paper presented at the 11th annual symposium of the Association for Farming Systems Research Extension, Michigan State University. Metcalfe, J. S. 1998. Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction. London: Routledge. MEWU [Metal and Engineering Workers’ Union]. 1992. The Australian Economy and Indus- try Development: Issues and Challenges for Metal Works in the 1990s. Sydney: Metal and Engineering Workers’ Union. Mikita, J. 1994. The influence of the Canadian state on the migration of foreign domestic workers to Canada: A case study of the migration of Filipina nannies to Vancouver, British Columbia. Unpublished M.A. thesis, Department of Geography, Simon Fraser University. Miller, D. 1993. Unwrapping Christmas. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Miller, P. and Rose, N. 1990. Governing economic life. Economy and Society, 19, 1–31. Mills, S. 1997. Discourse. London: Routledge. Ministerio de Obras Públicas y Urbanismo. 1990. Plan Hidrólogico – Síntesis de la Docu- mentación Básica. Madrid: Dirección General de Obras Hidraulicas. Ministerio de Obras Públicas y Transportes 1993. Plan Hidrólogico Nacional – Memoria. Madrid: Dirección General de Obras Hidraulicas. Mirowski, P. 1995. More Heat than Light. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mirowski, P. 1995. Natural Images in Economic Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mishrah, R. 1984. The Welfare State in Crisis. Brighton: Harvester Press. Misztal, B. 1996. Trust in Modern Societies. Cambridge: Polity. Mitchell, W. 1995. City of Bits: Space, Place and the Infobahn. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Miyoshi, M. 1997. A borderless world. In C. David and J. F. Chevrier (eds). Politics-Poetics Documenta X. Munich: Kassel, 102–202. Mol, A. and Law, J. 1994. Regions, networks and fluids: Anaemia and social topology. Social Studies of Science, 24, 641–71. Morales, R. 1994. Flexible Production: Restructuring of the International Automobile Indus- try. Cambridge: Polity. Morgan, K. 1983. Restructuring steel: The crises of labour and locality in Britain. Interna- tional Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 7, 175–201. BIBLIOGRAPHY 425

Morgan, K. 1997. The learning region: Institutions, innovation and regional renewal. Regional Studies, 31, 491–503. Morgan, K. and Sayer, A. 1985. A modern industry in a mature region: The restructuring of labour–management relations. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,9, 383–404. Morris, D. and Hergert, M. 1987. Trends in international collaborative agreements. Columbia Journal of World Business, 22, 15–21. Morris, M. 1992. Ecstasy and Economics. Sydney: EMPress. Mort, F. 1995. Archaeologies of city life: Commercial culture, masculinity and spatial rela- tions in the 1980s. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 13, 505–630. Mosco, V. 1996. The Political Economy of Communication. London: Sage. Moss, P. 1995. Inscribing workplaces: The spatiality of the production process. Growth and Change, 26, 23–57. Moulaert, F. and Swyngedouw, E. 1989. A regulation approach to the geography of flexible production systems. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 73, 27–45. Moulaert, F., Swyngedouw, E., and Wilson, P. 1988. Spatial responses to Fordist and post- Fordist accumulation and regulation. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 64, 11–23. Mowbray, M. 1984. Localism and austerity: The community can do it. Journal of Australian Political Economy, 16, 3–14. Mowery, D. (ed.). 1988. International Collaborative Ventures in US Manufacturing. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Mueller, F. and Loveridge, R. 1995. The “Second Industrial Divide”? The role of the large firm in the Baden-Wurttemberg Model. Industrial and Corporate Change, 4, 555–82. Murdoch, J. 1995. Actor-networks and the evolution of economic forms: Combining descrip- tion and explanation in theories of regulation, flexible specialisation and networks. Envi- ronment and Planning A, 27, 731–57. Murdoch, J. and Marsden, T. 1995. The spatialization of politics: Local and national actor- spaces in environmental conflict. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 20, 368–80. Murdock, G. 1993. Communications and the constitution of modernity. Media, Culture and Society, 15, 521–39. Murgatroyd, L. 1985. Occupational stratification and gender. In The Lancaster Regional Group. Localities, Class and Gender. London: Pion. Murray, F. 1983. The decentralization of production – the decline of the mass-collective worker. Capital and Class, 19, 74–99. Murray, R. 1972. Underdevelopment, the international firm and the international division of labour. In European Conference of the Society for International Development. Towards a New World Economy. Rotterdam: Rotterdam University Press, 159–247. Mytelka, L. (ed.). 1992. Strategic Partnerships: States, Firms, and International Competition. Rutherford, NJ: Farleigh Dickinson University Press. Nadal Reimat, E. 1981. El Regadío Durante la Restauración. Revista Agricultura y Sociedad, 19, 129–63. Nath, K. 1985. Women and vegetable gardens in The Gambia: Action aid and rural devel- opment. African Studies Center Working Paper No. 100. Boston, MA: Boston University. Natter, W. and Jones, J. P. 1993. Signposts toward a poststructuralist geography. In J. P. Jones, W. Natter, and T. R. Schatzki (eds). Postmodem Contentions: Epochs, Politics, Space. New York: Guilford,165–203. Naughton-Treves, L. and Sundcrson, S. 1995. Property, politics and wildlife conservation. World Development, 23, 1265–75. Negroponte, N. 1995. Being Digital. London: Hodder & Stoughton. 426 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Nelson, K. 1986. Labor demand, labor supply and the suburbanization of low-wage office work. In A. J. Scott and M. Storper (eds). Production, Work, Territory: The Geographi- cal Anatomy of Industrial Capitalism. Boston, MA: Allen and Unwin, 149–71. Nelson, R. R. 1995. Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change. Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 48–90. Nelson, R. R. (ed.). 1993. National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press. New York Times. 1997a. Peering into the shadows of corporate dealings. March 25, p. D1. New York Times. 1997b. Nike’s boot camps. March 31, p. A21. New York Times. 1997c. Apparel industry group moves to end . April 9, p. A14. New York Times. 1997d. Accord to combat sweatshop labor faces obstacles. April 13, p. A1. Niehans, J. 1990. A History of Economic Theory. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Nike. 1996. 10-K statement of US Securities and Exchange Commission. SEC File 001-10635. Washington, DC: Securities and Exchange Commission. Nixson, F. 1988. The political economy of bargaining with transnational corporations: Some preliminary observations. Manchester Papers on Development, 4, 377–90. N’Jang, A. 1990. Characteristics of Tourism in The Gambia. Banjul: Ministry of Informa- tion and Tourism. Nooteboom, B. 1999. Innovation, learning and industrial organisation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23, 127–50. O’Connor, J. 1973. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. New York: St. Martin’s. O’Connor, J. 1989a. Capitalism, nature, socialism: A theoretical introduction. Capitalism, Nature, Socialism, 1, 11–38. O’Connor, J. 1989b. Political economy and ecology of socialism and capitalism. Capitalism, Nature, Socialism, 1, 93–106. O’Connor, J. 1989c. Uneven and combined development and ecological crisis: A theoretical introduction. Race and Class, 30, 1–11. O’Neill, P. M. 1997. So what is internationalisation? Lessons from restructuring at Australia’s “Mother Plant”. In S. Conti and M. Taylor (eds). Interdependent and Uneven Develop- ment: Global–Local Perspectives. Aldershot: Ashgate, 283–308. Oberhauser, A. 1987. Labour, production and the state: Decentralization of the French auto- mobile industry. Regional Studies, 21, 445–58. Oberhauser, A. 2000. Feminism and economic geography: Gendering work and working gender. In E. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). Companion to Economic Geography, Oxford: Blackwell, 60–76. Offe, C. 1975. The theory of the capitalist state and the problem of policy formation. In L. N. Lindberg, R. Alford, C. Crouch, and C. Offe (eds). Stress and Contradiction in Modern Capitalism. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 125–44. Offe, C. 1976. Political authority and class structures. In P. Connerton (ed.). Critical Sociol- ogy. London: Penguin, 388–421. Offe, C. 1984. Contradictions of the Welfare State. London: Hutchinson. Offe, C. 1985. Disorganized Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity. Ohmae, K. 1990. The Borderless World: Power and Strategy in the Interlinked Economy. London: Collins. Ohmae, K. 1995. The End of the Nation State: The Rise of Regional Economies. New York: Free Press. Ohno, T. 1982. How the Toyota production system was created. Japanese Economic Studies, 10, 83–103. BIBLIOGRAPHY 427

Okoth-Ogendo, H. 1989. Some issues of theory in the study of tenure relations in Africa agriculture. Africa, 59, 56–72. Olman, B. 1993. Dialectical Investigations. London: Routledge. Ong, A. 1987. Spirits of Resistance and Capitalist Development: Factory Women in Malaysia. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press. Ong, A. 1991. The gender and labor politics of postmodernity. Annual Review of Anthrop- ology, 20, 279–309. ORC [Opinion Research and Communications]. 1985. The Great Debate: What Is IMF? Owerri: Gunson Headway Press. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1993. International Direct Investment-Policies and Trends in the 1980s. Paris: OECD. Orillard, M. 1997. Cognitive networks and self-organisation in a complex socio-economic environment. In A. Amin and J. Hausner (eds). Beyond Market and Hierarchy: Interactive Governance and Social Complexity. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Orrù, M., Biggart N. W., and Hamilton, G. 1991. Organizational isomorphism in East Asia. In W. Powell and P. DiMaggio (eds). The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analy- sis. London: University of Chicago Press, 361–89. Ortega, N. 1975. Política Agraria y Dominación del Espacio. Madrid: Editorial Ayuso. Ortega, N. 1992. El Plan Nacionál de Obras Hidráulicas. In A. Gil Olcina and A. Morales Gil (eds). Hitos Históricos de los Regadíos Españoles. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura. Pesca y Alimentación, 335–64. Ortí, A. 1976. Infortunio de Costa y Ambigüedad del Costismo: Una Reedición Acrítica de “Política Hidráulica.” Agricultura y Sociedad, 1, 179–90. Ortí, A. 1984. Política Hidráulica y Cuestión Social: Orígenes, Etapas y Significados del Regeneracionismo Hidráulica de Joaquín Costa. Revista Agricultura y Sociedad, 32, 11–107. Ortí, A. 1994. Política Hidráulica y Emancipación Campesina en el Discurso Político del Populismo Rural Español entre las dos Repúblicas contemporáneas. In J. Romero and C. Giménez (eds). Regadíos y Estructuras de Poder. Alicante: Instituto de Cultura “Juan Gil-Albert,” Diputación de Alicante, 241–67. Ostry, S. 1990. Governments and Corporations in a Shrinking World. New York: Council on Foreign Relations. O’Sullivan, M. 2000. Contests for Corporate Control: Corporate Governance in the United States and Germany. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Pahl, R. 1988. On Work, Oxford: Blackwell. Pahl, R. 1995. After Success. Cambridge: Polity. Pankhurst, F. 1984. Workplace Child Care and Migrant Parents. Canberra: National Women’s Advisory Council/AGPS. Park, M. 1983. Travels into the Interior of Africa. London: Eland. Parkes, D. and Thrift, N. J. 1980. Times, Spaces, Places. Chichester: John Wiley. Parry, J. and Bloch, M. (eds). 1989. Money and the Morality of Exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Patel, P. and Pavitt, K. 1991. Large firms in the production of the world’s technology: An important case of non-globalization. Journal of International Business Studies, 22, 1–21. Pauly, L. W. and Reich, S. 1997. National structures and multinational corporate behavior: Enduring differences in the age of globalization. International Organization, 51, 1–30. Pavitt, K. and Patel, P. 1995. Corporate technology strategies and national systems of inno- vation. In J. Allouche and G. Pogorel (eds). Technology Management and Corporate Strate- gies: A Tricontinental Perspective. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 313–40. Peck, J. 1996. Work-place: The Social Regulation of Labor Markets. New York: Guilford. 428 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Peck, J. and Tickell, A. 1994. Searching for a new institutional fix: The after-Fordist crisis and global–local disorder. In A. Amin (ed.). Post-Fordism: A Reader. Oxford: Blackwell, 280–316. Pérez De La Dehesa, R. 1966. El Pensamiento de Costa y su Influncia en el 98. Madrid: Edi- torial Sociedad de Estudios y Publicaciones. Pérez, J. 1999. Historia de España. Barcelona: Editorial Crítica. Perlmutter, H. V. 1969. The tortuous evolution of the multinational corporation. Columbia Journal of World Business, January–February, 24–31. Petras, J. and Morley, M. 1983. Petrodollars and the state: The failure of state capitalist development in Venezuela. Third World Quarterly, 5, 8–27. Philippine Women Centre. 1998. Commentary on “Not just numbers.” Brief to the Hon- ourable Lucienne Robillard, Minister of Citizenship and Immigration, March 9, 1998. Philips, D. 1987. Structural Adjustment of What, by Whom, for Whom? Lagos: Centre for Management Development. Phillips, A. 1989. Divided Loyalties. London: Virago. Picciotto, S. 1991. The internationalization of the state. Capital and Class, 43, 43–63. Pigou, A. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan. Pile, S. 1994. Cybergeography: 50 years of Environment and Planning A. Environment and Planning A, 26, 1815–23. Pimlott, B. 1978. The Englishman’s Christmas. Hassocks: Harvester Press. Piore, M. and Sabel, C. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books. Pitelis, C. 1991. Beyond the nation-state? The transnational firm and the nation-state. Capital and Class, 43, 131–52. Plant, S. 1994. Beyond the screens: Film, cyberpunk and cyberfeminism. Variant, 16, 12–17. Platteau, J.-P. 1994a. Behind the market stage where real societies exist – Part I: The role of public and private order institutions. Journal of Development Studies, 30, 533–77. Platteau, J.-P. 1994b. Behind the market stage where real societies exist – Part II: The role of moral norms. Journal of Development Studies, 30, 753–817. Plotkin, H. C. 1994. Darwin, Machines and the Nature of Knowledge. Harmondsworth: Penguin. Plummer, P. 2000. The modeling tradition. In E. S. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). A Com- panion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 27–40. Polanyi, K. 1944. The Great Transformation. New York: Rinehart. Polanyi, M. 1958. Personal knowledge: Towards a Post-Critical Philosophy. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Polanyi, M. 1966. The Tacit Dimension. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Pollert, A. 1981. Girls, Wives, Factory Lives. London: Macmillan. Poovey, M. 1995. Making a Social Body. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Porter, G. and Livesay, H. 1971. Merchants and Manufacturers. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive Strategy. New York: Free Press. Porter, M. E. 1990. The Competitive Advantage of Nations. New York: Free Press. Porter, M. E. 1994. The role of location in competition. Journal of the Economics of Busi- ness, 1, 35–9. Porteres, R. 1970. Primary cradles of agriculture in the African continent. In J. Fage and R. Oliver (eds). Papers in African Prehistory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 43–58. Poster, M. 1989. Critical Theory and Poststructuralism: In Search of a Context. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Poynter, T. A. 1985. Multinational Enterprises and Government Intervention. London: Croom Helm. BIBLIOGRAPHY 429

Pratt, G. 1990. Feminist analyses of the restructuring of urban life. Urban Geography, 11, 594–605. Pratt, G. 1997. Stereotypes and ambivalence: Nanny agents’ stereotypes of domestic workers in Vancouver, B.C. Gender, Place and Culture, 4, 159–77. Pred, A. 1966. The Spatial Dynamics of Urban Growth in the United States, 1800–1914. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pred, A. 1973. Urban Growth and the Circulation of Information, 1790–1840. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pred, A. 1980. Urban Growth and City Systems in the United States, 1840–60. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Pred, A. 1992. Languages of everyday practice and resistance: Stockholm at the end of the nineteenth century. In A. Pred and M. Watts (eds). Reworking Modernity: Capitalisms and Symbolic Discontents. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 118–54. Pringle, R. 1989. Secretaries Talk. London: Verso. Putnam, R. 1993. Making Democracy Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Rada, J. 1982. Structure and behaviour of the semiconductor industry. Mimeo, United Nations Center on Transnational Corporations, New York. Radice, H. 1984. The national economy – a Keynesian myth? Capital and Class, 22, 111–40. Rafael, V. 1997. “Your grief is our gossip”: Overseas Filipinos and other spectral presences. Public Culture, 9, 267–91. Rahman, A. K. 1949. Unpublished notes on land tenure in Genieri, courtesy of David Gamble. Redclift, M. 1987. The reproduction of nature and the reproduction of the species. Antipode, 19, 222–30. Reich, R. 1990. Who is us? Harvard Business Review, January–February, 53–64. Reich, R. 1991. The Work of Nations: Preparing Ourselves for 21st Century Capitalism. New York: Vintage Books. Reich, S. 1989. Roads to follow: Regulating direct foreign investment. International Orga- nization, 43, 543–84. Resnick, S. and Wolff, R. 1987. Knowledge and Class: A Marxian Critique of Political Economy. Chicago: Chicago University Press. Restad, P. L. 1995. Christmas in America. A History. New York: Oxford University Press. Riley, F. 1967. Fur Seal Industry of the Pribil of Islands, 1786–1965. Bureau of Commercial Fisheries Circular No. 275, U.S. Department of Interior, Fisheries and Wildlife Service, Washington, DC. Ritzer, G. 1996. The McDonaldization of Society. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. Roberts, R. and Emel, J. 1991. Uneven development and the tragedy of the commons: Com- peting images for nature-society analysis. Economic Geography, 67, 247–71. Robins, K. 1995. Cyberspace and the world we live in. In M. Featherstone and R. Burrows (eds). Cyberpunk/Cyberspace/Cyberbodies. London: Sage, 135–56. Robinson, J. F. F. 1983. State planning of spatial change: Compromise and contradiction in Peterlee New Town. In J. Anderson, S. Duncan, and R. Hudson (eds). Redundant Spaces in Cities and Regions? London: Academic Press, 263–84. Robinson, J. F. F. and Sadler, D. 1985. Routine action, reproduction of social relations and the place market: Consett after the closure. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 3, 109–20. Rogers, G. 1976. An economic analysis of the Pribil of Islands. 1870–1946. U.S. Department of Justice, Indian Claims Commission Dockets 352 and 369, Institute of Social, Economic and Government Research, University of Alaska, Fairbanks AL. Roppel, A. Y. and Davey, S. P. 1965. Evolution of fur seal management on the Pribilof Islands. Journal of Wildlife Management, 29, 448–63. 430 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Rorty, R. 1989. Contingency, Irony and Solidarity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rosdolsky, R. 1977. The Making of Marx’s Capital. London: Pluto Press. Rose, G. 1993. Feminism and Geography: The Limits of Geographical Knowledge. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Ross, R. J. S. and Trachte, K. C. 1990. Global Capitalism. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press. Ruan, D. 1993, Interpersonal networks and workplace controls in urban China. Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, 20, 89–105. Ruccio, D. 1992. Failure of socialism, failure of socialists? Rethinking Marxism, 5, 7–22. Rugman, A. M. and Verbeke, A. 1992. Multinational enterprise and national economic policy. In P. J. Buckely and M. Casson (eds). Multinational Enterprises in the World Economy: Essays in honor of John Dunning. Aldershot: Edward Elgar, 194–211. Ruiz, J. M. 1993. La Situación de los Recursos Hídricos en España, 1992. In L. R. Brown (ed.). La Situación en el Mundo – 1993. Madrid: Ediciones Apóstrofe S.L., 385–450. Russell Smith, J. 1913. Industrial and Commercial Geography. New York: Henry Holt & Co. Russo, M. 1985. Technical change and the industrial district: The role of interfirm relations in the growth and transformation of ceramic tile production in Italy. Research Policy, 14, 329–43. Sabel, C. 1989. Flexible specialization and the re-emergence of regional economies. In P. Hirst and J. Zeitlin (eds). Reversing Industrial Decline? Oxford: Berg, 17–70. Sabel, C. 1994. Learning by monitoring: The institutions of economic development. In N. Smelser and R. Swedberg (eds). Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 137–65. Sabel, C. and Zeitlin, J. 1985. Historical alternatives to mass production: Politics, markets and technology in nineteenth-century industrialization. Past and Present, 108, 133–76. Sack, R. D. 1980. Conceptions of Space in Social Thought. London: Macmillan. Sadler, D. 1984. Works closure at British Steel and the nature of the state. Political Geogra- phy Quarterly, 3, 297–311. Sahlins, M. 1972. Stone Age Economics. New York: Aldine. Salais, R. and Storper, M. 1992. The four “worlds” of contemporary industry. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 16, 169–93. Salzinger, L. 1997. From high heels to swathed bodies: Gendered meanings under produc- tion in Mexico’s export-processing industry. Feminist Studies, 43, 549–74. Samuels, W. 1995. The present state of institutional economics. Cambridge Journal of Eco- nomics, 19, 569–90. Sassen, S. 1990. The Global City. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Sassen, S. 1996. Analytic borderlands: Race, gender and representation in the new city. In A. King (ed.). Re-Presenting the City. London: Macmillan. Savage, M., Barlow, J., Dickens, P., and Fielding, T. 1992. Property, Bureaucracy and Culture. London: Routledge. Sawhney, H. 1996. Information superhighway: Metaphors as midwives. Media, Culture and Society, 18, 291–314. Saxenian, A. 1983. The urban contradictions of Silicon Valley. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 17, 237–61. Saxenian, A. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Sayer, A. 1982a. Abstraction: A realist approach. Radical Philosophy, 28, 6–15. Sayer, A. 1982b. Explanation in economic geography. Progress in Human Geography,6, 68–88. BIBLIOGRAPHY 431

Sayer, A. 1984. Method in Social Science: A Realist Approach. London: Hutchinson. Schmidt, A. 1971. The Concept of Nature in Marx. London: New Left Books. Schoenberger, E. 1987. Technological and organizational change in automobile production: Spatial implications. Regional Studies, 21, 199–214. Schoenberger, E. 1997. The Cultural Crisis of the Firm. Oxford: Blackwell. Schoenberger, E. 1999. The firm in the region and the region in the firm. In T. J. Barnes and M. S. Gertler (eds). The New Industrial Geography: Regions, Regulation and Institutions. London: Routledge, 205–24. Schonberger, R. J. 1982. Japanese Management Techniques: Nine Hidden Lessons in Sim- plicity. New York: Free Press. Schroeder, R. 1992. Shady Practice: Gendered Tenure in The Gambia’s Garden/Orchards. Yundum: Department of Agriculture Horticultural Unit and Oxfam America. Schroeder, R. 1994. Cyberculture, cyborg postmodernism and the sociology of virtual reality technologies. Futures, 26, 519–28. Schroeder, R. and Watts, M. 1991. Struggling over strategies, fighting over food: Adjusting to food commercialization among Mandinka peasants. Research in Rural Sociology and Development, 5, 45–72. Sciberras, E., Swords-Isherwood, N., and Senker, P. 1978. Competition, technical change and manpower in electronic capital equipment: A study of the UK minicomputer industry. Occasional Paper No. 8, Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex, Brighton, Sussex. Scott, A. M. (ed.). 1994. Gender Segregation and Social Change. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Scott, A. 1994. Hark, the herald cash tills ring . . . Financial Times, December 24, p. 7. Scott, A. J. 1988a. Metropolis: From the Division of Labor to Urban Form. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Scott, A. J. 1988b. New Industrial Spaces. London: Pion. Scott, A. J. 1995. The geographic foundations of industrial performance. Competition and Change, 1, 51–66. Scott, A. J. 1996. Regional motors of the global economy. Futures, 28, 391–411. Scott, A. J. 2000. Economic geography: the great half century. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 24(4), 483–504. Scott, A. J. and Angel, D. 1987. The US semiconductor industry: A locational analysis. Envi- ronment and Planning A, 19, 875–912. Scott, A. J. and Storper, M. 1987. High technology industry and regional development: A theoretical critique and reconstruction. International Social Science Journal, 112, 215–32. Scott, A. J. and Storper, M. 1986a. Industrial change and territorial organization: A summing up. In A. J. Scott and M. Storper (eds). Production, Work, Territory. Boston, MA: Allen and Unwin, 301–11. Scott, A. J. and Storper, M. (eds). 1986b. Production, Work, Territory. Boston, MA: Allen and Unwin. Scott, J. 1988a. Deconstructing equality versus difference; or, the uses of post-structuralist theory for feminism. Feminist Studies, 14, 33–50. Scott, J. 1988b. Gender and the Politics of History. New York: Columbia University Press. Sennett, R. 1977. The Fall of Public Man. New York: Knopf. Sercovich, F. C. 1984. The case study of Brazil. World Development, 12, 575–600. Serequerberhan, T. 1990. Karl Marx and African emancipatory thought: A critique of Marx’s Eurocentric metaphysics. Praxis International, 10, 161–81. Serres, M. and Latour, B. 1995. Conversations on Science, Culture, and Time. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Shapin, S. 1994. A Social History of Truth. Chicago: Chicago University Press. 432 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Shell, M. 1982. Money, Language and Thought: Literary and Philosophic Economies from the Medieval to the Modern Era. Los Angeles: University of California Press. Sheppard, E. S. 2000. Competition in space and between places. In E. S. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 169–86. Sheppard, E. S. 2002. The spaces and times of globalization: Place, scale, networks, and posi- tionality. Economic Geography, 78, 307–30. Sheppard, E. S. and Barnes, T. J. (eds). 2000. A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell. Shohat, E. and Stam, R. 1994. Unthinking Eurocentrism: Multiculturalism and the Media. New York: Routledge. Simmel, G. 1978. The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge. Simon, H. A. 1959. Theories of decision-making in economic and behavioral sciences. American Economic Review, 49, 253–83. Singelmann, J. 1978. From Agriculture to Services. Beverly Hills: Sage. Sklair, L. 1991. Sociology of the Global System. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Skocpol, T. 1995. Bringing the state back in: Strategies of analysis in current research. In P. B. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer, and T. Skocpol (eds). Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1–43. Slater, D. 1992. On the borders of social theory: Learning from other regions. Society and Space, 10, 307–28. Slouka, M. 1995. War of the Worlds: The Assault on Reality. London: Abacus. Smelser, N. and Baltes, P (eds). 2001. International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences. Oxford: Pergamon, 26 vols. Smelser, N. and Swedberg. R. (eds). 1994. The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Smelt, S. 1980. Money’s place in society. British Journal of Society, 31, 204–23. Smith, A. 1776. The Wealth of Nations. Harmondsworth: Penguin. Smith, F., Jack, I., and Singh, R. 1985. The Survey of Rural Women’s Vegetable Growing and Marketing Programme. Banjul: Action Aid. Smith, G. 1994. Toward an ethnography of idiosyncratic forms of livelihood. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 18, 71–87. Smith, M. and Marx, L. 1995. Does Technology Drive History? The Dilemma of Techno- logical Determination. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Smith, N. 1984. Uneven Development: Nature, Capital, and the Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell. Smith, N. 1996. The production of nature. In G. Robertson, M. Mash, L. Tickner, J. Bird, B. Curtis, and T. Putnam (eds). Future-Natural: Nature/Science/Culture. London: Routledge, 35–54. Smith, N. and O’Keefe, P. 1985. Geography, Marx and concept of nature. Antipode 17, 79–88. Smith, P. and Brown, P. 1983. Industrial change and Scottish nationalism since 1945. In J. Anderson, S. Duncan, and R. Hudson (eds). Redundant Spaces in Cities and Regions? London: Academic Press, 241–62. Solinas, G. 1982. Labour market segmentation and workers careers: The case of the Italian knitwear industry. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6, 331–52. Solinger, D. J. 1987. Uncertain paternalism: Tensions in recent regional restructuring in China. International Regional Science Review, 11, 23–42. Sparke, M. 1995. Writing on patriarchal missiles: The chauvinism of the “Gulf War” and the limits of critique. Environment and Planning A, 27, 1061–89. Spivak, G. C. 1988. Can the subaltern speak? In C. Nelson and L. Grossberg (eds). Marxism and the Interpretation of Culture. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press, 271–313. BIBLIOGRAPHY 433

Sproul, C. 1993. Mastering the other: an ecofeminist analysis of neoclassical economics. PhD dissertation. Department of Economics, University of Massachusetts-Amherst. Stanback, T. 1979. Understanding the Service Economy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Stanback, T. and Noyelle, T. 1982. Cities in Transition. Totowa, NJ: Allenhheld. Stanback, T., Bearse, P., Noyelle, T., and Karasek, R. 1981. Services: The New Economy. Totowa, NJ: Allenheld. Staple, G. 1993. Telegeography and the explosion of place: Why the network which is bring- ing the world together is also pulling it apart. CITI Working Papers No. 656, Columbia University, New York. Stefik, M. 1996. Internet Dreams: Archetypes, Myths and Metaphors. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Stiell, B. and England, K. 1997. Domestic distinctions: Constructing difference among paid domestic workers in Toronto. Gender, Place and Culture, 4, 339–59. Stigler, G. J. 1951. The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy, 59, 185–93. Stigler, G. 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Man- agement, 2, 3–21. Stiglitz, J. E. and Weiss, A. 1991. Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. In G. Mankiw and D. Romer (eds). New Keynesian Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 247–76. Stilwell, F. 1991. Wages policy and the Accord. Journal of Australian Political Economy, 28, 27–53. Stopford, J. M. and Strange, S. 1991. Rival States, Rival Firms: Competition for World Market Shares. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Storper, M. 1996. The world of the city: Local relations in a global economy. Mimeo, School of Public Policy and Social Research, University of California, Los Angeles. Storper, M. 1997. The Regional World. New York: Guilford. Storper, M. and Christopherson, S. 1987. Flexible specialization and regional industrial agglomeration: The case of the US motion picture industry. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 77, 104–17. Storper, M. and Salais, R. 1997. Worlds of Production: The Action Frameworks of the Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Strange, S. 1997. The Retreat of the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Strathern, M. (ed.). 1995. Shifting Contexts, London: Routledge. Streeck, W. 1996. Lean production in the German automobile industry: A test case for convergence theory. In S. Berger and R. Dore (eds). National Diversity and Global Capitalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 138–70. Sumberg, J. and Okali, C. 1987. Workshop on NGO-sponsored Vegetable Gardening Projects in The Gambia. Yundum: Department of Agriculture Horticultural Unit and Oxfam America. Sunley, P. 1996. Context in economic geography: The relevance of pragmatism. Progress in Human Geography, 20, 338–55. Swedberg, R. 1994. Markets as social structures. In N. J. Smelser and R. Swedberg (eds). The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton and New York: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation, 255–82. Swyngedouw, E. 1993. Communication, mobility and the struggle for power over space. In G. Giannopoulos and A. Gillespie (eds). Transport and Communications in the New Europe. London: Belhaven, 305–25. Swyngedouw, E. 2000: The Marxian alternative: Historical-geographical materialism and the political economy of capitalism. In E. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). Companion to Eco- nomic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 41–60. 434 BIBLIOGRAPHY

The Economist. 1996a. Past masters: Present pupils. November 23, p. 16. The Economist. 1996b. Showing Europe’s firms the way. July 13, p. 15. Thorne, L. 1997. Towards ethical trading space? Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Depart- ment of Geographical Sciences, University of Bristol. Thrift, N. J. 1977. Time and theory in human geography: Part 1. Progress in Human Geography, 1, 65–103. Thrift, N. J. 1986. The geography of international economic disorder. In N. J. Thrift and P. Williams (eds). Class and Space. London: Pion, 207–53. Thrift, N. J. 1989. Images of social change. In C. Hammnett. L. McDowell, and P. Sarre (eds). The Changing Social Structure. London: Sage, 12–42. Thrift, N. J. 1993. The light fantastic: Culture, postmodernism and the image. In G. L. Clark, D. K. Forbes, and R. Francis (eds). Multiculturalism, Difference and Postmodernism. Melbourne: Longman Cheshire, 1–21. Thrift, N. J. 1994. On the social and cultural determinants of international financial centres. In S. Corbridge, N. J. Thrift, and R. L. Martin (eds). Money, Power and Space. Oxford: Blackwell, 327–55. Thrift, N. J. 1995. A hyperactive world. In R. Johnston, P. Taylor, and M. Watts (eds). Geo- graphies of Global Change. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 18–35. Thrift, N. J. 1996a. New urban eras and old technological fears: Reconfiguring the goodwill of electronic things. Urban Studies, 33, 1463–93. Thrift, N. J. 1996b. Spatial Formations. London: Sage. Thrift, N. J. 2000. Pandora’s box? Cultural geographies of economics. In G. Clark, M. Gertler, and M. Feldman (eds). The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 689–704. Thrift, N. and Olds, K. 1996. Refiguring the economic in economic geography. Progress in Human Geography, 20, 311–37. Thu Nguyen, D. and Alexander, J. 1996. The coming of cyber space-time and the end of polity. In R. Shields (ed.). Cultures of Internet: Virtual Spaces, Real Histories, Living Bodies. London: Sage, 125–32. Tickell, A. and Peck, J. 1992. Accumulation, regulation and the geographies of post- Fordism: Missing links in regulationist research. Progress in Human Geography, 16, 190–218. Tickell, A. and Peck, J. 1995. Social regulation after Fordism: Regulation theory, neoliberal- ism and the global–local nexus. Economy and Society, 24, 357–86. Tolliday, S. and Zeitlin, J. 1986. Introduction: Between Fordism and flexibility. In S. Tolliday and J. Zeitlin (eds). The Automobile Industry and its Workers: Between Fordism and Flexibility. Cambridge: Polity, 1–26. Tomlinson, J. 1982. The Unequal struggle: British Socialism and the Capitalist Enterprise. Andover: Methuen. Torres Campos, R. 1907. Nuestros Ríos. Boletín de la Sociedad Geográfica de Madrid, 37, 7–32. Tryon, R. 1917. Household Manufacturers in the United States, 1640–1860. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Tuan, Y.-F. 1977. Space and Place: The Perspective of Experience. London: Arnold. Tuñón De Lara, M. 1971. Medio Siglo de Cultura Española 1885–1936. 2nd edn. Madrid: Editorial Tecnos. Turner, B. 1986. Simmel, rationalisation and the sociology of money. Sociological Review, 34, 93–114. Tyson, L. D. 1991. They are not us. The American Prospect, Winter, 49–54. Tyson, L. D. 1993. Who’s Bashing Whom? Trade Conflict in High-Technology Industries. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics. BIBLIOGRAPHY 435

Underhill, G. 1994. Conceptualising the changing global order. In R. Stubbs and G. Underhill (eds). Political Economy and the Changing Global Order. London: Macmillan. United Nations Center on Transnational Corporations. 1991. World Investment Report 1991: The Triad in Foreign Direct Investment. New York: United Nations. United Nations Commission on Trade and Development. 1986. Post-Harvest Handling and Quality Control for Export Development of Fresh Horticultural Produce. Geneva: United Nations Commission on Trade and Development. United Nations Development Program. 1977. Development of the Gambia River Basin: Multi-disciplinary Mission and Multidonor Mission. Programme of action. New York: United Nations Development Program. Usman, B. 1986. Nigeria Against the IMF. Kaduna: Vanguard Printers. Vance, J. 1970. The Merchant’s World. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Vernon, R. 1966. International investment and international trade in the product life cycle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 190–207. Vernon, R. and Spar, D. L. 1989. Beyond Globalism: Remaking American Foreign Economic Policy. New York: Free Press. Vilar, P. 1984. A History of Gold and Money. London: Verso. Villanueva Larraya, G. 1991. La “Politica Hidráulica” durante la Restauración 1874–1923. Madrid: Universidad Nacional de Educación a Distancia. Virilio, P. 1993. The third interval: A critical transition. In V. Andermatt-Conley (ed.). Rethinking Technologies. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 3–10. Vogel, E. 1989. One Step Ahead in China: Guangdong Under Reform. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Von Bohm-Bawerk, E. 1891. The Positive Theory of Capital. New York: G. E. Stechert. Wade, L. L. and Gates, J. B. 1990. A new tariff map of the United States (House of Repre- sentatives). Political Geography Quarterly, 9, 284–304. Walby, S. 1990. Theorizing Patriarchy. Oxford: Blackwell. Walker, R. 1984. Class, division of labor and employment in space. In D. Gregory and J. Urry (eds). Social Relations and Spatial Structures. London: Macmillan: 164–89. Walker R. and Greenberg, D. 1982. Post-industrialism and political reform in the city: A cri- tique. Antipode, 14, 17–32. Walker, R. and Storper, M. 1983. The theory of labor and the theory of location. Interna- tional Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 7, 1–44. Wallerstein, I. 1974. The Modern World System. New York: Academic Press. Ward, C. 1997. Reflected in Water – A Crisis of Social Responsibility. London: Cassell. Waring, M. 1988. Counting for Nothing: What Men Value and What Women are Worth. Sydney: Allen and Unwin. Wark, M. 1994. Virtual Geography. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press. Watts, M. 1984. State, oil and accumulation: From boom to crisis. Environment and Plan- ning D: Society and Space, 2, 403–28. Watts, M. 1992. The shock of modernity. In A. Pred and M. Watts (eds). Reworking Moder- nity. New York: Rutgers University Press, 21–64. Watts, M. 2000. Political ecology. In E. S. Sheppard and T. J. Barnes (eds). A Companion to Economic Geography. Oxford: Blackwell, 257–74. Watts, M. and Lubeck, P. 1989. Structural adjustment, academic freedom and human rights in Nigeria. Bulletin of Concerned Africanist Scholars, 28. Watts, M. and McCarthy, J. 1997. Nature as artifice, nature as artefact: Development, environment and modernity in the late twentieth century. In R. Lee and J. Wills (eds). Geographies of Economies. London: Arnold, 71–86. 436 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Webb, P. 1989. lntrahousehold Decisionmaking and Resource Control: The Effects of Rice Commercialization in West Africa. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. Webber, M. 1964. The urban place and the nonplace urban realm. In M. Webber, J. Dyckman, D. Foley, A. Guttenberg, W. Wheaton, and C. Whurster (eds). Explorations into Urban Structure. Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press, 79–153. Webber, M. 1994. Enter the dragon: Lessons for Australia from Northeast Asia. Environ- ment and Planning A, 26, 71–94. Weil, P. 1973. Wet rice, women, and adaptation in The Gambia. Rural Africana, 19, 20–29. Weil, P. 1982. Agrarian production, intensification and underdevelopment: Mandinka women of The Gambia in time perspective. In Proceedings of the Title XII conference on women in development, University of Delaware, Newark, DE. Weisbrot, M. and Sforza-Roderick, M. 1996. Baltimore’s Living Wage Law. Washington, DC: Preamble Center for Public Policy. Wells, L. T. 1983. Third World Multinationals: The Rise of Foreign Investment from Devel- oping Countries. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Wenger, E. C. 1998. Communities of Practice: Learning, Meaning and Identity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wenger, E. C. and Snyder, W. M. 2000. Communities of practice: The organizational fron- tier. Harvard Business Review, 78, 139–45. West Coast Domestic Workers’ Association. 1993. Brief to Employment Standards Act Review Committee, West Coast Domestic Workers’ Association, #302, 119 West Pender Street, Vancouver, BC. Westaway, J. 1974. The spatial hierarchy of business organizations. Regional Studies,8, 145–55. Wever, K. 1995. Negotiating Competitiveness: Employment Relations and Organizational Innovation in Germany and the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Whatmore, S. 1994. Global agro-food complexes and the refashioning of rural Europe. In A. Amin and N. J. Thrift (eds). Globalization, Institutions and Regional Development in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 46–67. Whatmore, S. 1997. Dissecting the autonomous self: Hybrid cartographies for a relational ethics. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 15, 37–53. Whatmore, S. and Boucher, S. 1993. Bargaining with nature: The discourse and practice of environmental planning gain. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 18, 166–78. White, E. 1981. The international projection of firms from Latin American countries. In K. Kumar and M. G. McLeod (eds). Multinationals from Developing Countries. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 155–86. White, G. 1993. Towards a political analysis of markets. IDS Bulletin, 24, 4–11. White, J. 1995. Two days to go. The Independent, December 23, p. 6. White, M. 1986. Child care funding: A change of direction. Australian Journal of Early Child- hood, 11, 38–41. Whitley, R. 1991. The social construction of business systems in East Asia. Organization Studies, 12, 1–28. Whitley, R. 1992a. Business Systems in East Asia: Firms, Markets and Societies. London: Sage. Whitley, R. (ed.). 1992b. European Business Systems: Firms and Markets in their National Contexts. London: Sage. Whitley, R. 1998. Internationalization and varieties of capitalism: The limited effects of cross national coordination of economic activities on the nature of business systems. Review of International Political Economy, 5, 445–81. BIBLIOGRAPHY 437

Whitley, R. 1999. Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Willems-Braun, B. 1997. Buried epistemologies: The politics of nature in (post)colonial British Columbia. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 87, 3–32. Williams, R. 1976. Keywords: A vocabulary of society and nature. London: Fontana. Williams, R. 1980. Problems in Materialism and Culture. London: Verso. Williams, S. 1995. All I want for Christmas . . . The Independent, December 16, p. 5. Williamson, B. 1982. Class, Culture and Community. Henley: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free Press. Williamson, O. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press. Womack, J., Jones, D., and Roos, D. 1990. The Machine that Changed the World. New York: Macmillan. Wong, S.-L. 1991. Chinese entrepreneurs and business trust. In G. Hamilton (ed.). Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia. Hong Kong: Centre of Asian Studies, University of Hong Kong, 13–29. World Bank. 1981. The Gambia: Basic needs in The Gambia. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. 1990. Women in Development project: Staff appraisal report. Washington, DC: World Bank. Wright, M. W. 1996. Third world women and the geography of skill. Unpublished Ph.D. dis- sertation, Department of Geography and Environmental Engineering, The Johns Hopkins University, Baltimore, MD. Wright, M. W. 1997. Crossing the factory frontier: Gender, place and power in a Mexican maquiladorda. Antipode, 29, 278–302. Wright, M. W. 1998. The maquiladora mestiza and a feminist border politics: Revisiting Anzaldua. Hypatia: A Journal of Feminist Philosophy, 13, 114–31. Wright, E. O. 1978. Class, Crisis and the State. London: New Left Books. Wright, E. O. 1985. Classes. London: Verso. Wrigley, N. and Lowe, M. (eds). 1995. Retailing, Consumption and Capital: Towards the New Retail Geography. Harlow: Longman. Yang, M. M-h. 1988. The modernity of power in the Chinese socialist order. Cultural Anthrop- ology, 3, 408–427. Yang, M. M-h. 1989. The gift economy and state power in China. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 31, 25–54. Yang, M. M-h. 1994. Gifts, Favors and Banquets: The Art of Social Relationships in China. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Yergin, D. 1991. The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money and Power. New York: Simon and Schuster. Yoffie, D. B. and Milner, H. V. 1989. An alternative to free trade or protectionism: Why cor- porations seek strategic trade policy. California Management Review, 31, 111– 31. Young, A. 1928. Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal, 38, 527–42. Young, I. M. 1990. Justice and the Politics of Difference. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univer- sity Press. Zelizer, V. 1989. The social meaning of money: Special monies. American Journal of Sociol- ogy, 95, 342–77. Zhang, A. and Zou, G. 1994. Foreign trade decentralization and its impact on central–local relations. In J. Hao and L. Zhimin (eds). Changing Central– Local Relations in China: Reform and State Capacity. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 153–80. Zimmerer, K. 1991. Wetland production and smallholder persistence: Agricultural change in a highland Peruvian region. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 81, 443–63. 438 BIBLIOGRAPHY

Zonis, M. 1991. Majestic Failure: The Fall of the Shah. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Zuboff, S. 1988. In the Age of the Smart Machine. London: Heinemann. Zucker, L. 1986. Production of trust: Institutional sources of economic structure, 1840–1920. Research in Organizational Behaviour, 8, 53–111. Zukin, S. 1991. Landscapes of Power. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Zukin, S. 1995. The Cultures of Cities. Oxford: Blackwell. Zukin, S. and DiMaggio, P. (eds). 1990. Structures of Capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Index

Abernathy, W. J. 35, 131 practice-diffusion process 353–4 Abo, T. 360 technology and social worlds 337–8, 345–7 absenteeism rates 46, 400 actors 41–2, 174 abstract labor 27, 101, 104, 182 construction of markets 62 abstract theory 15, 30–1, 32–3, 45, 46–7 creative actor networks 50 academics 66, 387, 390, 394, 401 institutionalism 50, 51, 54, 55, 57 accessibility knowledgeability of 293–4 of care services 313, 314 local 57 land rights in the Gambia 173, 224–6, 228–9, maximization of gain 180 232, 233–4 and organizations 66–7 local labor markets 304, 308, 309 rationalities of 51, 55, 321 accumulation 81, 91, 183, 401 regional 54, 55 Gambian wetlands 220, 234 social 67, 256, 293 global pattern of 296 Adam, B. 67 local opportunities in China 369 Adams, P. 345 Nike strategy 334, 399, 402 adaptation over-accumulation cycles 92 by firms 92, 364 social structures of 76 of capital 45 Spanish waterscape 199–200 of capital accumulation 41 of surplus value 30, 76, 98, 104–8 economic 51, 53–5, 72, 86 technological 356 of labor 27, 45 transnational capital 363 sequential 83 see also capital accumulation; capitalism; see also post-Fordism flexible accumulation; Fordist administration sector accumulation growth of 103, 309–10 Achebe, Chinua 215 spatial structure 115, 116, 119–22 Acheson, D. 180 state expenditures 211 Acker, J. 323 administrative work, research biases 31, 32 acquisitions 79, 118, 354 advanced industrial nations action flexible production 128 explanation of 41–2 industrial location 36–7, 38, 40 institutional influence on 50, 51, 53–7 labor market 308 political 60 neo-liberalism 27 simultaneity as critical contingency of 67 post-industrialism 97 see also social action regional policy 48 actor-network theory (ANT) 50, 55, 173–4, role of the household 86 237–40, 246–7, 333–4 spatial impacts 338 440 INDEX advanced industrial nations (cont’d) Appadurai, A. 63, 66 trade unions 21–2 Apple 43 waged work 316 Applebaum, R. P. 142 welfare state 308 Arce, A. 237 women as reserve of cheap labor 322 architecture 316, 327, 328 advertising sector 101, 106, 317, 327, 398, 399 areal uniformity 338–9 affluence 38, 102, 103 Arezzo 133 agency 4, 340 Aristotle 218 natural resources 171, 172 Arnold, E. 39 and structure 237, 292–4, 295 artisanal industries 129, 132–3 subject positions 378, 387 Asanuma, B. 272, 280 see also rational agency; social agency Asheim, B. 52 theory 65 assembly work 93, 169, 276, 332 agglomeration 43, 52, 117 automation 38 flexible production systems 94, 129, 130, 131, growth of 114, 127 132, 133–4, 135 Mexican maquiladora 152, 155, 156–9, 164 territorialization 272, 281 move to Third World 38 urban 127 Nike workers 334, 395 Aglietta, M. 33, 125 research biases 31, 32 Agrawal, R. G. 363 see also Fordism; mass production agriculture 5, 108, 132, 169 asset specificity, territorialization 272, 280, 283 gender in the Gambia 173, 220–34 association, source of knowledge/learning 52, in Nigeria 213 53, 54, 369 political ecology 173 AT&T 102 as secondary status activity 80 Attah, Governor 215 in Spain 195–6, 197–8, 199 Aurigi, A. 336, 345 see also coffee networks Austin 134 agro-food regimes 235, 237, 241 Australia 72–3 aid, to the Gambia 173, 225, 226 growth strategies 81 Aitken, J. 381 new “model of industrial development” 83 Ake, Claude 214 relations in local labor market 308–10 Akrich, M. 346 relations in local state 310–14 Albert, M. 271 wage restraint 79, 81 Albuquerque 134 automation 38 Aleuts 186–8 automobile industry Alexander, J. 340 changes 39 Allen, J. 93, 254, 363 complementation 39–40 alliances see strategic alliances Fordism 127 Altamira, R. 196 optimal scales of production 34 Althusser, Louis 4, 376 social division of labor 100 Altvater, E. 175, 182 spatial structures 117 Amariglio, J. 77, 82, 85 technical innovations 35 Amendola, G. 273 world markets 40, 274, 277–8 American Commercial Company (ACC) 177, autonomy 55, 56, 144, 268, 269, 299 178, 187 branch plants 112 Amin, Ash 146, 149, 355 Chinese local government 362, 365–7, 368, contemporary cities 343 369, 374 globalization 236, 280 oil states 210, 217 institutionalism 16, 51, 52, 55 transnational corporations (TNCs) 138, 148 Amnesty International 26 within the workplace 120 Amuzegar, J. 205, 206–7 Azorín 196 analytical Marxism 65 Anderson, B. 291, 294, 295 Babangida, Ibrahim 217 Anderson, P. 207 Babbage, C. 129 Anderson, Robert O. 208 back offices 104, 346, 348 Angel, D. 132, 134 Baden Württemberg 49, 52, 53, 134 Angoustures, A. 196 Bagguley, P. 363 anorexia 74–5 Bagnasco, A. 49, 132 anthropology 84, 236, 321, 328, 364–5 Bakshi, P. 261 INDEX 441 balance of payments 43, 209, 211 Berry, S. 220, 233 Baldwin, T. 339 best practice concept 351, 353–4, 359, 360–1 Balibar, E. 193 Bhasker, Roy 15 Ballance, R. H. 274 Bianchi, P. 283, 286 Baltimore, living wage campaign 334, 395–401, Bierstecker, T. 217 402 Biggart, N. W. 61, 374 Bank of International Settlements 266 Bijker, W. 346 banking sector 106, 108, 124 Billig, M. 61 deregulation 72 Bingham, N. 237, 345, 346 flexibility in China 369 biophysical environment 5, 171 gender segregation 255–6, 320 biophysical processes 1–2 Iran 210 biotechnology 133 networks 239, 321 Bishop, R. C. 180 new service class 321 Blaikie, P. 220 regional decentralization 115 Blanc, H. 52 telebanking 342, 343, 346 Blauhof, G. 353 women workers 319 Bloch, M. 218 Barff, R. 141, 395 Block, F. 109, 252, 262–3 bargaining processes, international 144–8, Bluestone, B. 79, 254 149–50 Boddy, M. 308 Barnes, Trevor J. 3, 5, 13, 14, 18n Boden, D. 66, 67 critique of economics 70 the body 24, 25–7 mass production 169 at work 325–6 metaphor and language 246 cultural analyses 316 natural resources 170 feminism 17, 25, 74–5, 77 political economy 236 metaphor of the economy 17, 74–82, 85 Barratt-Brown, M. 241 radical rethinking of 74 Barrett, H. 230 reconceptualization of 63 barriers to entry 146, 276, 277 as sight of inscription 316 Bartlett, C. A. 138–9 topological presupposition of flow 70 base, and superstructure 92, 93, 105–6, 108 Bohm, D. 68, 69 Bassett, T. 220 Boisot, M. H. 63 Bataille, G. 70 Bologna 133 Batty, M. 336 Bonnett, K. 259 Baudrillard, Jean 62 Boothroyd, P. 64 Bauman, Z. 66 borderless world 25 Bavaria 134 Bordo, S. 74 Beauvoir, Simone de 82 Boston’s Route 128, 43, 132 Becattini, G. 52, 129 Boucher, S. 175 Beechey, V. 322 Boulder 134 behavioral economics 65 bounded regions 68, 69 behavioral tradition 50 boundedness 77 Beijing Women’s Conference (1996) 26 Bourdieu, P. 320, 326 Belgium bourgeois political economy 24 social economy 56 Boyer, Christine 345 works closures 290 Boyer, R. 130 Belk, R. 59 Braczyk, H.-J. 355, 360 Bell, Daniel 91, 97, 98, 102, 103, 110 Bradby, B. 105 Bellamy, Edward 339 Bradley, H. 323 benchmarking 351 branch-plant economy 39–40, 112, 113, 114–15, Bender, J. 70 116–17 Benedikt, M. 336, 340 Fordism 127 Benetton 141 transnational corporations (TNCs) 36, 332–3, Bennett, T. 59 352, 356–7 Bennington, G. 70 brands 61, 287, 358 Benton, T. 175, 182, 192 Braudel, F. 101, 102, 103, 207, 235 Bering Straits see fur seal industry Braverman, H. 33, 34, 104 Berkes, F. 180 Brazil 363 Berry, Brian 14 Brennan, D. 313 442 INDEX

Brennan, T. 70 capital British Association of Fair Trade Shops (BAFTS) centralization of 277 241 circulation of 26–7, 102, 107, 266, 269, 344 British Steel Corporation (BSC) 296, 297 conflict with working class 93, 292 British Steel (Industry) 300 devalorizations of 92, 295 British Telecom 44 enhanced and extended circuits of 257 Brookfield, H. 220 extractive 209 Brooks, R. 23 global hypermobility of 274 Brotchie, J. 347 internationalization of 39, 40, 43–4 Brown, J. S. 358, 359 movement of 5, 15 Brown, P. 298 ongoing concentration of 277 Browne, A. 230 peculiar nature of Japanese capital 45–6 Browning, H. L. 97 relation to labor 33–4, 45, 46, 292–3 Brusco, S. 129, 130 search for profit 182–3, 292 Bryan, D. 81 social-institutional forms of 44–6 Bryant, R. 220 surplus value 30, 76, 98, 104–8 Budd, Alan 22–3 transnational 259, 362, 363, 364, 365 Buhari, Muhammadu 217 capital accumulation 21, 27, 294 built environment 92, 307, 316, 320, 327–8, abstract analysis of 30, 32 332 barriers to 344 bureaucracies changes in nature of 257 Chinese flexibility 364, 365, 366, 368–73, concrete forms of 30–1 374 industrial reserve army of labor 22 Frankfurt School 21 as life force of capitalism 76, 126 globalization 235–6 Marx 22, 106 Iran 210 Marxism 76 Nigeria 215 natural resources 182 social practices 236 oil boom economies 211, 215–16 Venezuela 210, 211 rate of 106–7 bureaucratization 208 regulation theory 125, 126–8, 135, 261, 262 Busch Cooper, B. 177, 178 service sector 105, 106–7, 109 business community 392, 393 spatial division of labor 36, 41, 123–4 business cycle, as economic regulatory and the state 43, 257, 258, 259–60, 261, 262, mechanism 76 264, 266–8, 269 business journals, as codified knowledge 52 territorial division of labor 303 business services sector 103, 104, 115, 117, 118, threats to 264 129 see also flexible accumulation; Fordist business system concept 145–6, 356 accumulation Butler, Judith 26, 153–4, 157, 163, 316, 324, capital equipment sector 127 376 Capital (Marx) 14, 19–23, 32, 192 Buttimer, A. 337 capitalism 4, 14–15 buyer-supplier relations 35, 43, 53, 280, 357 and the body economic 76, 81–2 Chinese style 374 Cable, V. 38 conservatism of 92 Cabral, Amílcar 22 continuous upheaval 109 Cafédirect 241–6, 247 distributional processes of 258 Cairncross, Frances 332 dominance of 84, 85, 86 Callari, A. 75 dynamism of 92 Callon, Michel 50, 238, 239, 240, 345, 353 engineered crisis in 22–3 Camara, E. 230 genealogies of 83–6 Cambridge 133 growth episodes 93 Cameron, J. 86 instability of 92 Campbell, B. 319 internationalization of 281 Canada life force of capital accumulation 76, 126 Filipina domestic workers 333, 375–88 Marx’s abstract conception of 15, 31, 32 fur sealing 178, 179, 181, 185 production at base of 92, 93, 105–6, 108 Cano García, G. 201 relation to nature 170, 171, 175–6, 181–4 capability 55, 56, 355, 358 rentier 209, 211, 213 capillary power 324 replaced by post-industrialism 98 INDEX 443

reproduction of societies 292–5 Chasin, B. 226 rise of 262 Chaucer, Geoffrey 218 service sector 98, 102, 109 Chaudhry, K. 207 social class formation 294 Cheal, D. J. 59 social relations of 170, 171, 181, 182, 208, child labor 22, 395 293, 294, 303 child-care centers 80, 307, 308, 310–11, state engagement with 263–5 312–13, 314 structural reproduction 293 child-care cooperatives 313 subordination of noncapitalism 84, 85–6 China uneven development 92, 291 bureaucratic flexibility 364, 365, 366, 368–73, see also flexible production systems; Fordism 374 car industry see automobile industry business organization style 364–5 caregivers 312–13, 333, 375–88 gift exchange 333, 364–5, 369–74 see also child-care centers institutional culture 333, 364, 368–73 Carling, A. 65 investment in the Gambia 226 Carney, Judith local government autonomy 362, 365–7, 368, gender and agrarian change in the Gambia 369, 374 173, 222, 224, 225, 226, 228, 229, 230 Nike workers 395, 396, 397 works closures 291, 296, 299 Taiwanese investment 333, 362–74 Carnoy, M. 272, 273, 276, 285, 363 Chinese capitalism 374 Carpi 133 Chisholm, G. 169, 170, 173 Carr, R. 196 Christaller, Walter 3, 91 Carrier, J. G. 67–8 Christmas 16, 59–60, 68 case studies 4, 135, 141, 238, 258 Christopherson, S. 117, 132, 356, 357 agriculture and gender in the Gambia 173, circulation 220–34 of capital 26–7, 102, 107, 266, 269, 344 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 of commodities 5, 68, 101–2, 106–7, 109, Castells, M. 64, 68, 342, 363 199, 209, 269, 332 Castree, N. 170, 171–2, 176, 181, 191 information 68, 100–1, 102, 107, 271, 344 Castro, Fidel 22 labor 100–2, 103, 105, 106–7, 269, 344 Catalonia 53 money 76, 102, 107, 332, 344 causation 15, 41–2 use-values 97–8, 100–2, 104, 106–7 class struggle 33 Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. 180 information technology 338, 347–8 citizenship 51, 56, 63 Cavendish, R. 32 Ciudad Guayana 210 Caves, R. 276 Ciudad Juarez 152 CDC scheme 224 civil rights 19, 21 CECOOAC-Nor 242–4, 247 civil society 21, 210 Ceesay, M. 230 Clark, C. 98 Center for Research on Economic Development Clark, G. L. 4, 361, 393, 402 (CRED) 222, 226 Clarke, J. 38 centralization class see social class assets and responsibilities 139 Clavel, P. 299 of capital 277 clerical sector political 210 employment 104, 309, 310, 319 services 115 research biases 31, 32 see also decentralization Clinton, Bill 72, 73 Cerny, P. G. 142, 143, 262, 266, 267 clothing industry 38, 115, 132, 277–8, 287, 334 chambers of commerce 53, 203, 352, 355, 360 clustering 56, 119, 122, 332, 355 Chandler, D. A. 103 craft production 133 Chang, K.-T. 363 economics of association 53 change see economic change; environmental electronics industry 117, 121 change; social change; technical change; interrelated industries 51, 53 technological change learning-based 57 chaos, concept of 66 scientific and technical functions 114 chaotic conceptions 97, 277 coal industry 114, 126, 290, 299, 301 charismatic leaders 22, 55 Coase, R. H. 129, 180 Chase Manhattan 215 Cochrane, A. 300 Chase-Dunn, C. 259 Cockburn, C. 120 444 INDEX

Cocoa, Sugar, and Coffee Exchange (CSCE) community-based services 304 242–3, 244 Companion to Economic Geography 5, 7 coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 comparative advantage 226, 229, 230–2 Cohen, S. S. 80, 128, 131 competition 5, 27, 115, 196, 258 collaborative ventures 139, 141, 143 between capitals in search of profits 292 collective consumption 127, 299, 308, 313, 314, between states 44, 94–5, 141–8 349 contradictory nature of 34 Collins, H. M. 65 as economic regulatory mechanism 76 Collinson, D. 324 firm-firm 94, 138–41 Colomina, B. 327–8 flexible production systems 128, 131, 135 Colonial Development Corporation (CDC) 224 foreign 126, 127 colonialism 383, 388, 401 inter-union 46 The Gambia 173, 221, 223–4, 225, 231, 232 interregional 57–8, 118, 212, 300 Colorado Springs 134 less favored regions 48–9 Columbia Pictures 281 social relations of 183 command economies 142 spatial division of labor 41 commerce 223, 241, 282, 284 spatial effects 42 commercial geography 3 works closures 292, 294, 295, 297, 299, 300, commodification 26, 221, 223, 225, 228, 229, 301, 302, 303 268 competitive advantage 51, 52, 107, 109, 142, commodities 143, 147 circulation of 5, 68, 101–2, 106–7, 109, 199, competitive environment 139, 148, 358 209, 269, 332 Competitive Strategy (Porter) 358 definition 101 competitiveness 129, 334–5, 358, 389, 390 commodity Baltimore 334, 399–401, 402 booms 205–8, 209 discourse 391–402 chains 64, 282, 283, 285 as economic category 391–4 fetishism 22 industrial districts 286 model economies 67–8 international 24, 69, 79, 261, 267 production 41, 85, 102, 108, 109, 126, 151, learning as key factor 53–5 223, 225 less favored regions 48 relations 68 Nike 334, 394–9 trade 273–4, 277, 278 product innovation 107 “commons” problem 171, 179, 180, 183–4 state role 286 communication territorial proximity 49, 51–2 globalization 284 territorially specific assets 283 local conventions of 52 transnational corporations (TNCs) 138, 139, materiality of 70 148 openness in 267, 284 weakness of 72 communication channels 105 works closures 294, 295, 296, 300 communication infrastructure, investment in 48, complementation 39–40 332, 344 complexity 46–7 communications geography 333 computer industry communications technology 5, 102, 331–2 close access to customers 42 and the city 332, 341–3, 348–9 complementation 39 Internet 336–7, 338, 343, 346 flexible production systems 133 spatial impacts 338, 347–8 nation-state activity 44 technological determinism 332, 338–40, 341, computer-aided design and manufacture 344, 347–8 (CAD/CAM) 35, 43 communism 20, 21, 22 computerized numerical control (CNC) 35 The Communist Manifesto 28 computerized technology, post-Fordism 83, community 128 class relations 305 concrete forms 30–1, 32, 45, 46–7 care 312–13 Confederaciones Sindicales Hidrográficas 203 conflicts 307 conflict 81, 170, 261, 269 development 127 between capitalists and workers 93, 292 development banks 64 between workers 301 projects 56 community 307 support networks 310 firms and states 144, 145, 146 INDEX 445

gendered 173, 220, 221, 223, 224, 225, decision-making 151 228–9, 231–2 hierarchy, and region 37 interregional 196 corporations/firms social 56, 196 absorptive capacity 358 social class 126, 268 adaptability 92, 364 connectivity 5–6, 57, 237, 331–2, 333, 334 best practice 351, 353–4, 359, 360–1 as a mode of ordering 241, 244, 246, 247 capability-based view of 358 constructionism 69, 192, 204 communities of practice 358–9 consumer durables sector 127, 279 competition 94, 138–41 consumer industries deinternationalization 43 bias towards 31 diversity of types 84 growth of 102–3, 114 embeddedness of 320, 355, 357, 358 consumer services 97, 104 exchange of goods and services 101 decline of 102 growth of 101 globalization 279, 282, 287, 288 institutional concessions 287–8 growth of 103 institutional influence on practices 351, institutional concessions 288 354–9 consumer tastes 97, 278, 281, 283, 284, 287 interfirm relationships 51, 53, 94, 139, 280, consumerism 63 282, 352, 355 consumption 102–3 internal influence on practices 358–9 celebration of 318 internal practices 352 critical reassessment of 4 learning-in-working 358–9 flexible production systems 63 national institutional influence 356–7 habits 305 nonmarket interactions 35 patterns 36, 93, 102, 126 product-cycle theory 37–9 practices 26 regional institutional influence 355 rise of 63 relation to states 44, 94–5, 138, 144–50 see also collective consumption; mass social practices 236 consumption spatial structures 93, 111, 112–13, 116–22, contingency 67, 236, 255, 338, 376, 388 123 actor-networks 346 see also branch-plant economy; convergence bargaining processes 149 dynamics; transnational corporations institutionalism 16 (TNCs) spatial structure 113, 120, 121, 334 corporatism 43 technologies 338, 343, 344, 345, 346, 347, Corps of Engineers 201 348, 349 corruption 211, 219 works closures 290, 293, 294, 296, 300, China 367, 373 303 Nigeria 172–3, 213, 214, 215 contingent conditions 15, 30, 31, 41–2, 46–7, Cosmides, L. 50 126 Costa, Joaquín 196, 197, 198, 199, 200 conventions 52, 280, 353, 355, 358 Costa Rica 242 convergence dynamics 332–3, 350–61 Costello, V. 210 channels of 353–4 Court, G. 62, 64 definition 351–2 Cox, K. R. 260 internal firm influences 358–9 craft production 33, 107, 126, 132, 133, 134 national institutions 356–7 Crang, P. 62, 237 regional institutions 355 creativity 56, 57, 280 weak versus strong 352–3 credit system reforms 261 Cook, I. 237 credit unions 64 Cooke, P. 13, 51, 52, 53, 355, 360 critical reading 7–9 “core”, global networks 238 critical realism 4, 5, 15, 29–47 core regions 58, 132 Crompton, R. 64, 319 outflow of capital 127 Cronon, W. 170 and periphery 79, 127, 174, 238 cultural power and control 93 affinity 333, 362, 364, 367–8 Corn, J. 337, 340 analysis 14–15, 16, 17, 21, 316 Coronil, F. 206, 210 assumptions 321, 338 corporate characteristics 46 culture 328, 360 class 317–18, 321 446 INDEX cultural (cont’d) deconstruction 25–6, 377 determinants 70 DeCosse, P. 230 dupes 292, 303 deductive theories 3 geography 60 defense sector 115, 121, 211 hegemony 62 deindustrialization 72, 74, 93, 94, 306 industries sector 122, 317, 327 The Deindustrialization of America (Bluestone movements 21, 172 and Harrison) 79 powers 21 del Moral Ituarte, L. 189, 195, 199 sensibility 13 Deleuze, G. 69, 238 studies 27, 328, 377 Delorme, R. 50 theory 4, 5, 376, 387, 388 demarcation lines 83, 127 “cultural turn” 21, 27, 315 Demeritt, D. 191 culture 4, 5 Denmark 53, 134 Chinese institutional 333, 364, 368–74 deregulation 24, 48, 72, 143, 253, 259, 320, definition 364 321 and economy 16–17, 59–71 Derman, W. 226 radically decentered approach 25 deroutinization 300–1 Curran, C. 78 Derrida, J. 70 currency reforms 261 design-intensive industries 129, 133, 135 Curry, M. 6 desire 16, 21, 70, 77, 92, 323 Curtin, P. 365 deskilling 33–4, 40, 127, 375, 380 customer–supplier relations 149, 352, 358 deterritorialization Cusumano, M. A. 130 globalization 253, 271, 274, 276–9, 281–7 cybergeography 70 new cultural class 317–18 cyberspace 70, 336, 337, 340, 342, 346 devaluation cyborgs 191, 345 monetary 209, 216, 217, 218 Czech “Spring” 19, 21 product 154, 157 development Dahrendorf, R. 142 capitalist 30, 81, 83, 84, 98, 104 Daniels, P. 118, 120 in China 333, 373, 374 Darwin, Charles 14, 20 concrete forms of 30 Davey, S. P. 179 industrial development models 83, 84 Davis, C. 64 ladder of 83–7 day-care services 311, 312–13 organic metaphor 17, 83–6 de Reparez, G. 198 productive labor 104–8 Dear, M. J. 254–5, 308 service sector 98 The Death of Distance (Cairncross) 332 social 135, 192 Debord, G. 206, 207 technological 30, 65, 66, 341 debt 207, 209, 212, 213, 215, 216, 217, 226, territorialization 271–2, 278, 285, 288 229 see also post-Fordism; product development; decentering 25, 26, 74, 86 regional development; uneven decentralization 38, 39, 40, 43, 114–15, 285, development 307, 338 development economics 73 China 365, 374 development models, diversity of 84 flexible production systems 132, 135 Dex, S. 318, 319 Fordism 127 Dey, J. 226 institutions 56 dialectical materialism 170 service sector 115, 118, 341 dialectics 26, 103, 172, 191–4, 343, 360 transnational corporations (TNCs) 138, Dicken, Peter 94–5, 140, 145, 146, 147, 252, 141 253, 259, 260, 274, 276, 332, 358 decision-making 3, 151, 285 Dickens, Charles 170, 218 actor-networks 50 differentiation 46–7, 141, 148, 285, 294 China 368, 372 see also product differentiation; spatial core regions 93 differentiation deterritorialized institutions 271 Dikko, Alhaji Umaru 213–14, 215–16 institutionalism 55–6 DiMaggio, P. 320, 321 service sector 313 Diocsin, Cecilia 386 transnational corporations (TNCs) 36, 141, discourse 4, 70, 135, 390 145 competitiveness 391–402 INDEX 447

of economic change 82, 83 Dorsey, K. 185 economic restructuring 82, 84, 269 Dosi, G. 276, 280, 288 of the economy 17, 65, 70, 72–87 Douglass, D. 295 Filipina domestic workers 333, 376–88 downsizing 22, 27, 74, 128, 318, 399 Foucault 70, 82, 240, 376, 387 Doz, Y. 147 of globalization 24–5, 26–7, 28, 260, 269 Driever, S. L. 196 of intervention 78, 90 Du Gay, P. 317 neo-liberalism 257, 259 dual systems theory 86 of progress 340 Duguid, P. 358, 359 Spanish waterscape 193, 200, 201, 202, 204 Dunning, J. 140, 276, 283, 285, 287, 288 status of 389, 390 Dunsmore, J. R. 222 discursive shifts 23, 24 Dutch Disease 211 disembeddedness 64, 236 dynamic efficiency 259 disempowerment 24, 91, 344 dynamic vertical disintegration 130 disequilibrium 70 distance 42–3, 91 Eagleton, T. 23 acting at a distance 35, 174, 237–40, 241 Eastern Europe 62, 141 cultural 333 Eckersley, R. 175, 179, 180 importance of 331–2 ecological information technologies 332, 336–49 concern 292 relational proximity 359 crises 182 as a social product 331–2 economics 65, 66 tertiary labor 106 exploitation 91 distanciation 47, 64 harmony 198 distribution, propositions about 268–9 Marxism 176, 181, 182 distribution sector 115 problems 173 distributional outcomes 258, 261, 266, 267, the “economic” 390 268, 269 difficulty of stabilizing 70–1 division of labor reconfiguring of 60–1 binary oppositions 326 and the social 62 class structuration 305 economic adaptability 51, 53–5, 72, 86 dynamics of change 104–8 economic behavior 49–50, 51 gendered 221, 223, 306, 312–13, 322 economic change 32, 257, 258, 266, 306, 317, international 36, 93, 115, 118, 123, 124, 259, 327 376–7, 395 discourses of 82, 83 localized 284 East Asia 261 new international thesis (NIDL) 15, 37–9 Gambian wetlands 221, 223–5 service sector 97–108, 109 global 149 social 35, 75–6, 100, 117, 129, 130, 134 profit as engine of 91 spatial 36–42, 111, 112, 113, 114–16, 118, social class 254 121, 122–4 social implications of 109 technical 35, 112, 114–15, 117, 127 economic depression 126 territorial 288, 303 economic determinism 76 domestic workers 102, 333, 375–88 economic distance 331–2 domiciliary care 307, 308, 313 economic evolution 83–7 dominance 77–8, 93, 111, 112, 316 economic geography 1–4 of capitalism 84, 85, 86 changing focus of 252 of extractive and rentier capitals 209 critical reading of 7–9 institutional 55 differentiated nature of 2, 5 Japanese strategy 144 history of 3–4 metropolitan areas 342 new kinds of 60–1 of money 208, 218 non-English scholarship 6 spatial division of labor 118 paradigm change 14 domination 20 polycentrism 16–17, 60 Dominic, G. 105 refiguring of the “economic” 60 Donaghu, M. 141, 395 Economic Geography 170 Dore, R. 50 economic governance 49–51, 355 Doremus, P. 360 economic interventions 72–3, 78–81, 86 Dorfman, N. S. 132 economic performance 3 448 INDEX economic restructuring in learning regions 54 critical role of the state 269 preparation of worker 107 discourses of 82, 84, 269 as state’s natural domain 268 local labor markets 306 of women 319 regulation theory 261 education institutions 134, 352, 355, 360 Spain 196 as codified knowledge 52 The Gambia 226 education sector 114, 115 economic sociology 84, 252 Edwards, R. 104 concept of embeddedness 49–50, 62, 236, The Eighteenth Brumaire (Marx) 24 320–1, 325 Ekpo, E. 217 unity of socioeconomic processes 255 elderly economic stagnation 135, 209 community care 312–13 economic structures 3, 209, 251 domiciliary care 307, 308, 313 economics 16, 390 electronics industry 29, 114 behavioral 65 advantages of colocation 43 competitiveness 391–2 complementation 39 critiques of 70 declining relative importance of 117 ecological 65, 66 flexible production systems 133 environmental 179 runaway industry 38 evolutionary 49, 52, 65, 351 skilled jobs 34 globalization 271 spatial structure 121 institutional 49–51, 236 tendency to cluster 117, 121 social power of 393 Eli, M. 140 see also neoclassical economics elites 55, 345 economies of scale 34–5, 51, 127, 129, 130, networks of 321 139, 282, 284 Nigeria 214 The Economist 212, 351 Spain 196, 197, 199, 200, 203 economy spatial structures 119–22, 123 as bounded regions 68, 69 The Gambia 224, 228 changing perspectives on 65–8 Elliott, Henry 177–8, 185, 186 changing practices in 61–5 Elson, D. 141, 153, 163 and culture 16–17, 59–71 Elster, J. 40, 180 discourses of 17, 65, 70, 72–87 emancipatory politics 25, 26 disorganization of organizations 66–7 embeddedness 4, 252, 253, 355 erosion of orientalist and occidentalist beliefs collaborative ventures 139 67–8 economic sociology 49–50, 62, 236, 320–1, fall of the singular 65–6 325 as flows 68, 70 fair trade networks 240, 241, 242, 244, 246 gendering of 64 firms 320, 355, 357, 358 informalization of 64 information technologies 337, 341, 346 institutionalism 16, 48–58 institutions 16, 236, 251, 320–1, 357 as interlocking networks 68, 69 interpersonal networks 49–50, 364, 368, 369 metaphor of the body 17, 74–82, 85 Japanese businesses 140 metaphor of organic development 17, 83–6 local 5 metaphor of totality 75–6 natural resources 170, 192 pinhead 183 state behavior 141–2 social context of 251 transnational corporations (TNCs) 138, 145, social nature of 61–2 149 time and space 64–5 Emecheta, Buchi 213, 216 topological presuppositions 68, 69–70 Emel, J. 181 Ecstasy and Economics (Morris) 72 Emilia-Romagna 53 Edge, S. 64 empirical evidence 8, 261 Edozien, E. C. 216 dynamic networks 141 Edquist, C. 356 feminization of organizations 315 education 126 empirical material, interpretation of 8, 32, 140, expenditure 310 141 fair trade networks 242, 244 empirical research/studies 7, 29, 33, 41, 84, 135, Filipina domestic workers 380, 383, 385, 258, 294 386 on capital 44 INDEX 449

consistency of 15 environmental convergence 361 change 220, 221, 223–5 distance 331 degradation 179, 181, 184, 220, 225, Filipina domestic workers 376 231–2 financial services 320 economics 179 labor skills 34 embeddedness 241, 246 nation-states 258 processes 5 relationship between firms and states 94 environmentalism 26, 187 UK industrial base 93 free market 179, 180–1 workplace politics 95 Equal Exchange Trading Limited 241–2 employment creation schemes 300, 307, 308, Ernst, D. 273 310 ESPRIT 44 employment opportunities 22, 215, 299, 307, estheticization 318, 327 314 estrangement 208 Encarnation, D. J. 143, 147 ethnic Enderwick, P. 258 allegiance 171 endogenous growth theory 51 discrimination 188 England, works closures 290, 296, 297, 299 networks 69, 333 England, K. 381 ties, strengths of 61 enlightenment concepts 63 ethnicity 95, 321, 322, 363 enterprise support systems 51, 52 bounded regions 69 enterprise zones 300, 314 Gambia 223, 228–9 entrepreneurship 24, 53, 148 Marxian lack of concern 21 flexible production systems 128 Melbourne 313 fragility in small firms 57 Nigeria 212, 214 less favored regions 48 ethnography 4, 69, 70, 152, 154, 156, regional 56 164–5 rudimentary 56 Euclidean distance 331, 332, 335n environment Eurocentrism 6, 187 best practice 351, 356–7 “Europe of the regions” 144 biophysical 5, 171 European Commission 55 commercial sealing 183, 185 European Community 44, 230 commons model 183–4 bargaining power 149–50 discourse on competitiveness 394 state-state competition 142 ecological concern for 292 strategic alliances 141 financial services 320 subsidiarity 148 flexible production systems 131–2, 133 works closures 296–9 Gambian wetlands 173, 220–34 European Single Market 62 institutionalism 50, 52, 54, 55 European Union knowledge 50 emergence of 266 ladder of evolution 83 “Europe of the regions” 55 laissez faire 262, 263 increasing influence of 356 learning 52 institutional concessions 287 less favored regions 54 organic certification 246 market-based approaches 176 social economy 56 Marxism 21, 175–6, 181–2, 184, 186 evolution, ladder of 83–7 material 170 evolutionary economics 49, 52, 65, 351 organizational 67 evolutionary psychology 50 political 362 evolutionary theory 14, 85, 391, 392, 393 product-cycle theory 38 exchange see markets and society 181–2, 192 expenditure as excess theory 70 Spanish waterscape 196, 197, 204 expenditure without return 70 spatial effects 42 experimental games 50 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139, 143, expertise 52, 276, 282 145–6, 148, 149 agronomic 229 virtual 338, 340, 342 communities of practice 358 workplace 161, 327 corporate culture 328 see also built environment; competitive encouragement of diversity of 55 environment; natural resources; nature transnational corporations (TNCs) 139 450 INDEX exploitation 91 Filipina domestic workers 333, 375–88 capitalist 15, 21, 85–6 comparison to Europeans 381–3 of care-givers 311 noncitizen status 378–81 diversity of 86 stigmatization process 383–5 Filipina domestic workers 383, 387 film industry 132, 288 natural resources 171, 180, 181–4, 186, 187 financial flows 258, 349 noncapitalist forms of 85–6 financial institutions 215, 235 social class 105, 188, 318 financial markets surplus value production 104 deregulation of 24 of women outworkers 314 globalization of 118, 149, 344, 345, 350 external economies 129, 130, 134 state role 263, 265 externalities 51, 52, 143, 179–80, 181, 183, 272 financial services sector 102, 120 extractive capital 209 expansion of 117, 317, 327 gender segregation 255–6, 320, 323 face-to-face interaction 52, 65, 343, 347, 359, industrial spaces 327 364 internationalization of 118 factory outlet villages 63 regional decentralization 115 factory production system 93, 109, 126 regional specialization 93 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 Fincher, R. 252, 254, 255, 307, 308 fair trade organizations 241, 242, 244 Fine, B. 235 Fair Trademark 242 Fisher, G. B. A. 98 Fairtrade Foundation 242 fisheries industry 180, 181 Fallaci, Oriana 209 Fitzcarraldo 189 familiarity 52, 65, 370 Fitzsimmons, M. 175 familism 364, 374 Flanders 134 family 305 Fleck, L. 389 discourses of 381 flexibility 317, 392 as hidden welfare service 312–13 Chinese bureaucracy 364, 365, 366, 368–73, family commitments 120 374 family day-care services 311, 312–13 increased emphasis on 120 family responsibilities 310–11 labor market practices 351 FAO 225 marketing networks 279 farmers’ cooperatives 242 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139 farms, noncapitalist exploitation 86 women workers 308, 313, 319 fast food outlets 99, 103, 235, 325 workplace 160, 164 Father’s Day 63 see also post-Fordism Featherstone, M. 235, 317 flexible accumulation 94, 125, 126–31, 132, Feldman, M. 4 135, 136, 144, 307 feminism 4, 5, 95, 305, 326, 333, 389 see also post-Fordism and the body 17, 25, 74–5, 77 flexible production systems 63, 125–36, 307 constructions of home 377 agglomeration 94, 129, 130, 131, 132, 133–4, gender roles 316 135 gendered subjectivities 324 appearance of 128 hegemony of dominance 85 competition 128, 131, 135 household economy 86 decentralization 132, 135 poststructuralist 151 features of 128, 129 priority of paid over unpaid work 31 increased costs 130 rejection of the “economy” 86 industrial location 127, 131–5 second-wave 25 Italy 84, 132–3, 135 theory of imperialism 386 key industrial sectors 129 value of labor 152, 153 labor market 128, 129, 130–1, 134 women’s occupational segregation 322 and patterns of industrialization 129–31 feminist theory 252 rise of 64 feminization 40, 255–6, 315, 317, 318–20, social divisions of labor 129 321–3, 384 Florida, R. 355 Ferenczi, S. 205 flow economies 278–9, 281–3, 285–7 Fernández Clemente, E. 199, 200 Folbre, N. 86 Ferrari, Dr. 68 folklorism 63 fieldwork 1, 2, 9n Fong, P. E. 363 INDEX 451

Fontana, J. 196 Fuji 357 food Fujian province 362, 365–6, 372 alternative geographies of 235–47 Fujita, M. 3 escalating costs in oil states 211, 215 Fukuyama, F. 50 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 functionalism 76, 81 Gambian wetlands production 173, 220–34 Fur Seal Advisory Board 185 purity standards 262 fur seal industry 176–88 Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) 225 discursive production of nature 184–7 food outlets 99, 103, 235, 325 genesis of the crisis 176–9 footloose firms 42, 253 Marxist explanation 171–2, 181–4 Ford, Henry 169 neoclassical explanation 171, 179–81, 182 Ford Motor Company 145, 274, 276 furniture industry 132, 133 Fordism 45, 83, 84, 114, 117, 126–9, 257 decline of 94, 125, 127–8, 135, 144 Gabriel, P. 147–8 mode of social regulation 93–4, 261 Galileo 13, 14 see also mass production The Gambia Fordist accumulation 125, 126–8, 135, 136 accumulation 220, 234 foreign direct investment (FDI) 287, 332, 354 colonialism 173, 221, 223–4, 225, 231, 232 globalization 273, 274, 276, 277–8, 282 customary tenure laws 224 high-technology industries 276 economic change 221, 223–5 location in most advanced regions 40 elites 224, 228 Taiwanese in China 362, 366 ethnicity 223, 228–9 transnational corporations (TNCs) 140–1, foreign aid 173, 225, 226 273, 274, 276, 277–8 gender and agrarian change 173, 220–34 Foucault, M. 26, 83, 389 horticultural projects 173, 221, 225–6, 229, bounded regions 69 230–2, 233 constructing the self 324 irrigation 173, 220, 221, 224, 225, 233–4 disciplinary individualism 394 kamanyango 173, 224–5, 228–9, 231, 232, discourse 70, 82, 240, 376, 387 233 The Order of Things 82 land rights 173, 220, 224–6, 228–9, 232, organic structure 77, 82 233–4 power relations 376 maruo 224, 225, 228–9, 233, 234 social norms 393 peanut cultivation 221, 223, 225, 226, Fox, S. 185 231–2 Fraad, H. 74–5, 86 policy shifts 225–6 France rice cultivation 173, 221, 222, 223–4, 225, flexible production systems 133 226–9, 233 nationalist policies 44 wetlands 173, 221–33 social economy 56 Gamble, D. 223 telecommunications infrastructure 342 gambling industry 60 works closures 290, 296–7 gardening industry 60 Francis, J. 259 see also horticultural projects Franco, Francisco 203 Garrabou, R. 196 Frank, A. G. 295 Gatens, M. 74 Franke, R. 226 Gates, Bill 339 Frankel, H. 218 Gates, J. B. 143 Frankfurt School 21 GATT 142, 266 Fransman, M. 358 gay communities 64 Fraser, N. 376, 387 gay scholarship 324 free market environmentalism 179, 180–1 Gelb, A. 207, 209 freeports 314 Gelerntner, David 340 Freud, Sigmund 70, 172, 205 gender 4, 5, 13, 14 Friedland, W. 235 agrarian change in the Gambia 173, 220–34 friendly associations 61 and the body 17, 25, 74, 77–8 friendship 367, 370, 371, 372 bounded regions 69 Fröbel, F. 37, 259, 274, 282, 322, 363 as a colonizing regime 77 Fuchs, V. 97, 104 conflicts 173, 220, 221, 223, 224, 225, 228–9, Fudge, C. 308 231–2 fugitive resources 180–1, 184 division of labor 221, 223, 306, 312–13, 322 452 INDEX gender (cont’d) linguistic commonality 372–3 economies 64 measurements of value 370 employment shifts 64, 114, 130, 132, 152–4, sense of space 371–2 156–7, 255–6, 306, 315, 318–20, 321–3 sense of time 370–1 markets 251 Gille, D. 205 Marxian lack of concern 21 Gillespie, A. 339 organizations 316, 323–4 Gilpin, R. 271 as performance 316 Ginzberg, E. 97 production of value in the workplace 95, 151, GIS 63 152–4, 156–65 Glickman, N. J. 147, 274 relations in local labor market 255, 304–7, global business hierarchies 274–7, 278 308–10, 314 global cities 317–18, 327 relations in local state 255, 304–6, 307–8, global commodity systems 235 310–14 global financial system 118, 149, 344, 345, 350 segregation in the workplace 255–6, 305–7, global localization 148 310, 313–14, 320, 321–3 global networks 141, 236, 237–47, 349 see also masculinity global warming 26, 192 gender-in-organization model 323 global-local tensions 94–5, 137–50, 237, 239 gendered oppositions 77 globalization 3, 51, 52, 64, 137–8, 235–6, 246 General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) acting at a distance 174, 237–40 142, 266 business services sector 118 General Motors (GM) 43, 274, 276 commodity trade 273–4, 277 generalized interactivity 339 consumer services 279, 282, 287, 288 genetic engineering 64 as deterritorialization 253, 271, 274, 276–9, gentrification 121, 307, 317–18 281–7 geocentrism 14 discourse 24–5, 26–7, 28, 260, 269 Gephardt Amendment 143 dynamics of 281–5 Gerber, J. 191 effect on space 332 Gerlach, M. L. 140 foreign direct investment (FDI) 273, 274, 276, German model 271, 350, 357 277–8, 282 Germany global business hierarchies 274–7, 278 collapse of Berlin Wall 21 impact on states 259–60, 285–8 flexible production systems 134 institutions 235, 271–2, 285–9 industrial practices 360 local interpretations 363 lean production 360 mainstream arguments about 272–8 social economy 56 pure flow economies 278–9, 281–3, 285–7 transnational corporations (TNCs) 333, territorialization 253, 271–4, 277–8, 279–84, 356–7, 360, 361 285–9 see also West Germany transnational corporations (TNCs) 141, 148, Gershuny, J. 97, 98, 102, 108 235–6, 237, 247 Gertler, M. S. 4, 94, 144, 332–3, 353, 354, globe, image of 25, 26 356–7 Gluek, A. C. 178 GGFP 222 Goff, Charles J. 177 Ghoshal, S. 138–9 Goffman, E. 316 Giansante, C. 203 gold 205, 218 Gibson, Kathy 4, 17, 95, 376, 381, 387 gold boom 207 Gibson, W. 336 Gómez Mendoza, J. 189, 196, 197, 198, 199, Giddens, A. 64–5, 301 203 agency and structure 293–4 Goodman, D. 236 constructing the self 325 goods cultural dupes 292 changing nature of 99 globalization 363 circulation of 5, 100–2, 106–7, 109, 199, 209, social action 252 269 space and place 348 definition 99 theory of structuration 292, 300 distinction from services 97, 99 Giffen, J. 230 producer services 100 Gifford, Kathy Lee 22 replaced by services 98 gift exchange 59–60, 63, 67–8, 333, 364–5, Goodworks 395 369–74 Gordon, D. M. 145 INDEX 453

Gordon, H. S. 180 indirect economy 109 Gottmann, Jean 342 international transactions 258 Gould, Stephen Jay 83–4, 85 intraregional growth point policies 299 Goux, J.-J. 70, 208 Japanese economy 142 governance 5, 55, 56, 236, 264, 265, 349, 351, Keynesian regional policies 48 374 labor productivity 107 during Fordist period 261 living wage 401 economic 49–51, 355 manufacturing as center of 79–80 financial markets 263 manufacturing industry 119, 169, 309 hierarchical 139 of money 208 of industrial practices 354–9 neo-liberalist policies 259 institutional 266, 350, 351 networks 149 of private markets 257, 269 oil money 211 of production systems 285, 287 organizational 239 regulation theory 261 population 220 of trade 261 producer services 100, 114 governance structures 62 public sector 114, 119 government, as secondary status activity 80 regional 48, 49, 51, 57, 115–16, 117, 118, government intervention see state intervention 125, 299 government legislation 56, 57, 79, 126, 159, 246 regulation theory 261 governmentality, bounded regions 69 retailing sector 101 Grabher, G. 50, 54, 55, 68, 355 service sector 92, 105, 114, 115, 315, 317–18 Graham, Julie 4, 17, 95, 376, 381, 387 service sector as engine of 91, 97 Graham, S. 332, 334, 336, 337, 338, 339, 340, social compliance 261–2 342, 343, 345, 349 state’s reliance on 268 Gramsci, A. 21, 27–8 telebanking 343 Granovetter, M. 50, 351 urban 134 Graycar, A. 312, 313 and wage restraint 79 The Great Transformation (Polanyi) 252 Grundisse (Marx) 14, 192 Greater London Council 314 Grundmann, R. 175, 192 Greenberg, D. 103 Guangdong province 362, 365–6, 368, 372 Greenblatt, S. 186 guanxi 364 Gregory, D. 254 Guattari, F. 238 Gregson, N. 377 Guerrieri, P. 273 Grenoble 133 Guevara, Che 22 Grinnell, George Bird 185 Guisinger, S. 142, 147 Grossman, G. 276, 289 Gumbrecht, H. U. 70 Grossman, H. 32 Grosz, E. 74 habits 50, 52, 76, 164, 305 group learning 50 Hall, S. 27, 363 group routines 50 Halloween 63 growth 5, 78, 259, 264, 317 Hamelink, C. 108 administration sector 103, 309–10 Hamilton, G. 61, 68, 374 of assembly work 114, 127 Hammett, C. 363 Australian strategy 81 Handbook of Commercial Geography business services 104, 117 (Chisholm) 169 capitalist 76, 79, 81, 93, 94, 107, 182 Hanson, S. 8, 153, 322, 375 commodity trade 273 Haraway, Donna 74, 82, 172, 174, 176, 193 consumer industries 102–3, 114 conflict 81 corporate organization 101 cybernetic organisms 191, 345 employment 309 discourse 376 endogenous 51 natural dominance 85 financial services 117 theoretical vision 176 flexible production systems 131, 132, 134 Hardin, G. 171, 179, 180, 220 Fordism 93 Harding, Sandra 389–90, 401 foreign direct investment 140 Harré, Rom 15 global financial centers 344 Harrison, B. 79, 254, 277, 279 growth zones 299 Harrison, J. 312 high technology 134 Hartshorne, R. 14, 169, 170 454 INDEX

Harvey, C. 226 Ho, S. P. S. 366 Harvey, David 13, 14–15, 16, 17, 65, 91, 101, Hobsbawm, E. 291 135, 153, 163, 291, 344, 401 Hochschild, A. 325 capitalist behavior 45 Hodgson, G. M. 49, 50, 65, 351 conceptions of technology 352 Hoesch 298 dialectics as internal relations 172, 193 homework 307, 309 flexible accumulation 307 Hong Kong 362, 363, 364, 366, 383 labor of circulation 107 Hooghoven 298 money system 102, 218 Hoole, R. W. 149 place-specificity of devalorization 295 horizontal disintegration 129 postmodern turn to consumption 318 Hornaday, William T. 185, 186 rate of capital accumulation 106 Horrigan, B. 340 resources and nature 170, 175, 176 horticultural projects 173, 221, 225–6, 229, social class 305 230–2, 233 space economy 4 households space and place 348 class relations 305–6, 309 spatial fix 183 disaggregated production 307 The Limits to Capital 14 in the Gambia 173, 220, 221, 223, 224–5, urban areas 191 228–9, 233–4 use-value 32 gender roles 309 Hausner, J. 48, 51, 55 growing income needs 310 Haussman, R. 209, 210 noncapitalist exploitation 86 Hawke, Bob 72 as places of production 4 Hay, C. 266 replacement of labor 103 Hayek, F. A. 259 as secondary status activity 80 Hays, S. 185 housing market 318 Healey, P. 348 Howe, A. 312 health sector 114, 115, 244, 268, 310 Hsing, Y.-T. 332, 333, 362 Hearn, G. 323, 324 Hudson, R. 54, 252, 253–4, 258, 290, 296, 297, heavy engineering industry 290 299 hedonism 51 Huenemann, R. W. 366 Hegel, G. W. F. 218 human agency, see also agency Heinrichs, J. 274 human rights 26, 28, 395 Helgasen, P. 315 Hundiendonos en el excremento de diablo (Perez heliocentrism 13, 14 Alfonso) 205 Helm, D. 181 Hungarian uprising 21 Helou, A. 140 hunting see fur seal industry helping professions 317 Hurtado, Hector 207 Helpman, E. 276, 289 Hutchinson, P. 222 Henderson, J. 142 Hutton, W. 258, 262 Hergert, M. 141 hybrid collectif 240 heritage culture 63 hybrid networks 237, 241–7 Herrigel, G. 360 hybrids 172, 191–4, 204, 239 Herzog, Werner 189 hydrological cycle 191, 201 Hewlett Packard 43 hydrological engineering mission 172, 197–203 Hiebert, D. 375 Hymer, S. 274, 282, 286 high technology sector 129, 132, 133–4, 135, Hymer’s stereotype 36–7, 38, 40 143, 276, 280, 282, 285 hyperinflation 209 Hill, S. 338 hypermobility 274, 276, 303 Hirsch, J. 259 hyperspaces 64 Hirschborn, L. 109 Hirst, P. 51, 137–8, 267 IBM 38, 43 historical geography 126, 195, 291, 303, Ibrahim, Isyaku 214 383 Ichigo, K. 359 historical-geographical materialism 26 ICI 145 historical-geographical processes 193 iconography 70 history ideas, movement of 5 as organizing principle of knowledge 83 identities as a sequential ladder 83–7 commodity model economies 68 INDEX 455

correlation with skills/abilities 151 industrial districts 67, 282, 332–3, 393 de/reterritorializing 62 emergence of 129, 144 Filipina 381, 384, 386 Italian 49, 52, 53 flexible construction of 340 network relations 286 gendered 324 use of local assets 51 language 376 industrial growth 134, 211 masculine 323 industrial heartland 76 multiplicity of 325 industrial organization theory 279 national 155, 266 industrial policy interventions 72–3, 74, 78, 83, political 253–4 84 regional 297 industrial relations 31, 35, 254, 357, 360 as relational constructs 378 industrial restructuring 254 social 151, 155, 246 industrial revolution 101, 102, 107–8 work as central aspect of 325 industrial structures identity formation 4 diversity of 84 identity politics 21 Fordist 135 ideological repressions 20 regional differences 352 ideology industrial studies, criticism of 32–46 bourgeois 105, 199 industrialism 23, 98, 103, 104, 105, 108 and culture 374 industrialization 100, 106, 126–8 discourse analysis 377 China 374 fascist 203 development ladder 85 of individualism 321 oil boom economies 211, 212 of nature 171, 185 Spain 196 of science 389 Taiwan 373 Idiagbhon, Tunde 216 transformation of use-value 108 IFAD 226 see also flexible production systems; Fordism; IG Metall Union 298 post-Fordism ILO 395, 396 industry image consciousness 62–3 empirical studies of 15 imagined communities 291, 295 as key word in economic geography 60–1 Imam-Jomeh, I. 210 research biases 31, 32 IMF 24, 213, 216, 217, 225, 226, 230, and space 29–47 386 see also decentralization immigrant labor 130, 132, 308, 309, 313 inflation 22, 92, 94, 207, 209, 211, 217 Filipina domestic workers 333, 375–88 informalization 64 impact, metaphor of 338, 347–8 information 278, 352, 354 imperialism 25, 262, 386 based on face-to-face exchange 52 impersonal transactions 67, 68 central role of 63 import booms 211, 212, 213 circulation of 68, 100–1, 102, 107, 271, import substitution 211, 212, 226, 229 344 improvisation 66 communication channels 105 incentives 48, 53, 159, 365 costs of 130, 131 income redistribution 48 crucial role of 63 India 238 dissemination 51 Individual Transferable Quotas 181 economic openness in 267 individualism 49, 61, 180, 321, 394 global business hierarchy 274 indoctrination 20 informal 54 Indonesia 362, 364 property rights 344 Nike workers 22, 395, 396, 397 proximity/association as source of 52, 53, 54, industrial atmosphere 52 272, 369 Industrial and Commercial Geography as a social construction 1 (Russell Smith) 331 subsidiary firms 139 industrial concentration 35 tacit forms of 52 industrial development 302 use-value of products 108 high technology 134 information asymmetry 50, 63 in Nigeria 212 information economics 65 industrial development models 83, 84 information economy 102 industrial development zones 127 information exchanges 53, 130, 364, 386 456 INDEX information superhighway 336, 338, 339 fair trade 240, 241, 242, 246, 247 information technologies 67, 332, 336–49 Filipina domestic workers 376, 387, 390, 392 co-evolution perspective 332, 337, 340–5, 348 financial 215, 235 embeddedness 337, 341, 346 firm’s relations with 352 recombination perspective 332, 337–8, 345–7, forms of capital 44–6 348–9 globalization 235, 271–2, 285–9 as relational assemblies 347–9 influence on action 50, 51, 53–7 substitution and transcendence perspectives influence on firm practices 351, 354–9 337, 338–40, 343, 344, 347–8 informal economy 64 infrastructure 53, 263, 264, 273, 348 information technologies 342–3, 346 China 366 local labor markets 255, 304–7, 308–10, 314 communications 48, 332, 344 local state 255, 304–6, 307–8, 310–14 financial 93 market 62, 101, 251, 255 GM investment 274 national 333, 350, 356–7, 360–1 Nigeria 212 of organized labor 22 regulatory 235 politically created 262 technological 340 regional 355, 360 telecommunications 274, 342, 344, 346 social class 255, 304–14 transport 48, 331, 344 social learning processes 351 urban 401 territorialization 271–2, 279, 285–9 Ingham, G. 49 and the urban 348 inner cities 32, 116, 132, 302, 307, 309 women’s inferiority 324 innovation 45, 57, 144, 273, 274, 349 see also corporations/firms; education blocks on 55 institutions; states; supranational state centrality of the region 359 structures; transnational corporations cultures of 53 (TNCs) firm capability 355, 358 instrumentalist rationality 50 management techniques 35, 39 insurance sector 106, 115, 320 metropolitan dominance 342 intellectual property 261, 276, 277 practice-diffusion process 353–4 intelligent technologies 63 process technology 35, 39 interaction 54 promotion of 267 between firms 35, 138–41 proximity/association as source of 54, 369 between networks 68 regional innovation system 355 between states 141–4 in regions 56, 133 between states and firms 44, 94–5, 138, rise of consumption 63 144–50 see also product innovation; technological buyer-seller 35 innovation face-to-face 52, 65, 343, 347, 359, 364 innovation systems 356 local conventions of 52 instability 93, 129 practice-diffusion process 354 hybrid networks 244 social 54, 74, 293, 300, 306, 320, 321, 338, importance of 66 364 labor market 131, 134 socioecological 190 institutional care 312 trust 61 institutional economics 49–51, 236 user-producer 352 institutional thickness 51, 357 interactional structures 67 institutionalism 5, 16 intermediate inputs 100, 277, 282, 287 actors 50, 51, 54, 55, 57 International Coffee Agreement 242 decision-making 55–6 international competitiveness 69 economy and economic governance 49–51 International Fund for Agricultural Development institutional reform 55–6 (IFAD) 226 regional policies 48–58 International Labor Organization (ILO) 395, institutions 396 capitalist growth episodes 93 International Monetary Fund (IMF) 24, 213, Chinese culture 333, 364, 368–73 216, 217, 225, 226, 230, 386 decentralization 56 international political economy 69, 70 direct state participation 263–4 International Standards Organization 266 as economic regulator 76 internationalization 259, 268, 269, 281–5, 287 embeddedness of 16, 236, 251, 320–1, 357 of capital 39, 40, 43–4 INDEX 457

of capitalism 281 direct investment in Europe 44 finance sector 118 electronics industry 43, 44 of marketing 42 foreign direct investment (FDI) 140 of production 42, 291, 294, 352 fur sealing 178, 179, 181, 185 service sector 118, 140 investment in China 362 Internet 336–7, 338, 343, 346 “just-in-time” production 35, 43, 350 interpersonal relations 49–50, 280, 364–5, keiretsu 140, 146 367–8, 373–4 management methods 46 see also gift exchange nationalist policies 44 interventions 270 nature of capital 45–6 discourse of 78, 90 plan-rational economy 142 economic 72–3, 78–81, 86 state-state competition 142, 144 industrial policy 72–3, 74, 78, 83, 84 strategic alliances 141 planning 127 television production 39 political 1, 81, 264 transnational corporations (TNCs) 140, 363 see also state intervention US transnationals in 357 investment 38, 44, 48, 115 Japanese model 271, 350 Chinese in Gambia 226 Jarillo, J. C. 138 communication infrastructure 332, 344 Jeng, A. A. O. 223 in declining industries and regions 74 Jenkins, R. 363 in manufacturing 79 Jessop, B. 252, 260–1, 266, 269, 294 mobility of 273 jewelry industry 132, 133 in new technology 107 Jo, S.-H. 363 public sector 299 Jobson, R. 223 switching of 15 John Hopkins University 400 Taiwanese in China 333, 362–74 Johnson, C. 142 see also foreign direct investment (FDI) Johnston, R. 8 investment grants 43 Johnston, R. J. 363 investment policies 261 joint ventures 53, 357, 366, 367, 369, 371 investment regulations 43 Jones, D. K. 176, 186 Iran Jones, D. T. 34, 40 Islamic revolution 206 Jones, J. P. 376 modernity drive 210 Jordan, David Starr 185 oil resources 172, 173, 206, 207, 209, 210–11 Jordan, Michael 22 public investment 207 The Journal of Economic Geography 4 Ireland, social economy 56 Julius, DeAnne 140, 271, 274 iron industry 290 Junta Consultiva de las Obras Públicas 201 irrigation, in the Gambia 173, 220, 221, 224, Jura 134 225, 233–4 “just-in-time” production 35, 43, 116, 130, 131, Islamic Development Bank 230 350 Islamic revolution 206 Justice, Nature and the Geography of Difference isotropic plain 170 (Harvey) 23 Italy flexible specialization 84, 132–3, 135 kaizen/continuous improvement 350 industrial districts 49, 52, 53 kamanyango 173, 224–5, 228–9, 231, 232, 233 social economy 56 Kanter, R. 323 ITQ system 181 Kaplinsky, R. 43 Izard, M. 206 Kapuscinski, R. 206, 207, 211, 213, 216 Karl, T. 205, 206, 207, 209 J-firm 271 Katouzian, H. 210 Jack, I. 230 Katz, D. 395 Jackson, P. 63 Kawasaki 43 Jacobs, M. 181 Kay, J. 61, 358 Jaguar car company 35 Keating, Paul 72 Jahaly Pacharr project 224 keiretsu 140, 146 Jammeh, O. 230 Kelly, J. 33, 34 Japan Kerfoot, D. 320, 325 collectivism 61 Keynesianism 48, 73, 93, 94, 127, 128, 135, competitiveness 127 260 458 INDEX

Kimmel, M. 324 adaptation 27, 45 Kindleberger, C. P. 139 appropriation of natural resources 181–2 King, A. 318 auxiliary 106 King, Martin Luther 19, 28 circulation 100–2, 103, 105, 106–7, 269, 344 Kinnear, D. 312, 313 class relations in local labor market 255, Kinski, Klaus 189 304–7, 308–10, 314 Kirby, V. 74 collective 64, 97 Kirsch, Scott 337, 343 competitiveness 391 Kittler, F. A. 70 conceptions of 26–7 Knights, D. 320, 325 consumption of use-value 102–3 knowledge 75, 276, 278, 288 deskilling 33–4, 40, 127, 375, 380 abstract 41 distinction between productive and analytic 102 unproductive 98, 105–6 based on face-to-face exchange 52 dual character of 182 codified versus non-codified 52, 54 flexible working 319 construction of 26 gender relations in local labor market 255, customary forms of 280 304–7, 308–10, 314 dissemination of 51 gender segregation 255–6, 305–7, 310, of diverse exploitations 86–7 313–14, 320, 321–3 embedded 358 indirect 98, 106–8, 109 encouragement of diversity of 55 integration of 76 extra-academic generators of 66 international migration 261 Foucault 82 in learning regions 54 Gambian women 223, 229 living wage campaigns 334, 335n, 395–401, global business hierarchies 276 402 internal flow 139 of “management” 103–4 local 284 marginalization of 375–6 partial 240 part-time workers 130, 305, 306, 307, 308–9, practical 105 310, 319 production of 107, 274, 390 personal services 102 proximity/association as source of 52, 53, 54, primary 106, 107 369 production of use-value 98–100 representation of 70 quality of 152, 154, 157–64, 273, 280, 327 rise of History 83 relation to capital 33–4, 45, 46, 292–3 scientific 353 replacement in the household 103 sharing of 52, 53, 61 reserves of 22–3, 114, 123, 322 situatedness 24, 236, 325 reskilling 33–4 subsidiary firms 139 secondary 106, 107 tacit 52, 62, 355, 358, 359 services and goods as products of 97, 99 technical 120 shifts in the objects of 107–8 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139 social-institutional forms of 44–6 universal 174 spatial clustering 51 knowledge boundedness 50 state role 263, 265 knowledge dissemination 51 surplus value 30, 76, 98, 105–8 knowledge dynamics 285 technological change 22–4 knowledge environments 50 temporary workers 130, 318 knowledge-based society 111 territorialization 279–80, 281 Kobrin, S. J. 147 tertiary 106 Kondo, D. K. 152 useful 98 KPMG 351 valuation in the workplace 151–65 Kreye, O. 274 working from home 307, 309 Krieger, J. 295 see also division of labor; immigrant labor; Krugman, Paul 3, 51, 276, 391 local labor market; manual labor; Krupp 298 productivity; waged work; workers; Kuhn, Thomas 13, 14 workers, female; workplace Kuwait 209 labor market 54, 118, 122, 123 flexible production systems 128, 129, 130–1, labor 5 134 abstract 27, 101, 104, 182 see also local labor market INDEX 459

Labor and Monopoly Capital (Braverman) 33 Lee, R. 252 labor process studies, biases in 31 Lefebvre, H. 193 labor processes 26–7 legal profession, women workers 319 changes in 33–4 legal system 62, 92, 261, 262 class struggle 33 state role 263, 264 control over 120 legitimation activities 263, 265 dualism of nature and society 175 Leidner, R. 325 increased scale and complexity 103 Lenin, Vladimir Ilyich 21 management of in other firms 35 lesbian communities 64 resynthesized and deskilled 127 lesbian scholarship 324 see also flexible production systems; Fordism; less favored regions (LFRs) 16, 48–9, 54, 57, 58 post-Fordism LETS see local economic trading systems labor segmentation theory 375–6, 388 Lévi Strauss, Claude 23 labor unions see trade unions Levins, R. 193 labor-intensive production 38, 40, 231, 395 Lewis, J. 299 Lacan, J. 70 Lewontin, R. 85, 193, 204 ladder of evolution metaphor 83–7 Ley, D. 103 Lagos 213 Leyshon, A. 64, 70, 118, 120, 146, 258 Lall, S. 363 lifestyle 301, 312, 318 land concentration 221, 233–4 Lim, L. 363 Land, N. 70 Lindstrom, D. 108 land use, Gambian property regimes 173, 220–1, linguistic affinity 367, 370, 372, 374 222–34 linguistic distinctiveness 291 Landell Mills Associates 226 linkages 55 Lane, C. 356, 357 adjacent firms 348–9 Lar, Governor 215 among institutions 16 Lash, S. 62, 64, 65, 68, 119, 128, 327 buyer-supplier 53 latifundistas 195–6, 198, 199 external 128, 130 Latour, Bruno 69, 172, 192, 235, 237, 246 fiscal 210 actor-network theory 50, 173–4, 238, 345, global 277 346 horizontal 360 network collectivity 240 international 121 network lengthening 238 in learning regions 54 network mediation 239 local production 363 quasi-objects and hybrids 190, 191, 193, 239 oil boom economies 210 skein of networks 348 reproduction and territory 254 Law, John 68, 237–9, 240, 241, 244, 346 resources 253 Organizing Modernity 240 technological 346, 347, 348 Le Heron, R. 235 technology and social worlds 345 lean production techniques 350, 360 Lipietz, A. 36, 37, 83, 125, 126 learning 41–2 livelihood practices 64 communities of practice 358–9 Livesay, H. 101, 103 competitiveness factor 53–5 living wage campaigns 334, 335n, 395–401, dissemination of 51 402 in groups 50 Livingstone, D. 305 local culture of 333 Lloyd, C. 78 metaphor-making 337 Lloyd, G. 70 network ties 50 Lloyd, P. E. 252 proximity/association as source of 52, 53, 54, local actors 57 369 local agglomeration 52 technological 284 local assets 51, 283 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139 local autonomy 55, 144, 148 learning capacity 57 local champion firms 287 learning curve 37–8 local conventions 52 learning potential 57 local culture 13 learning regions 52, 53–4, 69, 355, 369 local economic development initiatives 52 leasing companies 105, 106 local economic trading schemes (LETS) 64, 65 leather goods industry 132 local economies of association 53, 57 Lebowitz, M. 103 local embeddedness 5 460 INDEX local employment practices 252 location local government 53, 134, 266, 269 branch and headquarters 113 China 333, 362, 365–7, 368, 369, 374 capital’s assessment of 46 employment 114 of cheap labor 38, 40 enlargement of powers of 55 deterritorialization 253, 271, 274, 276–9, social inclusion commissions 57 281–7 Third Italy 133 direct overseas investment 38 works closures 299–300 flexible production systems 127, 131–5 local industrial clusters 332 flow of practices between 359 local institutional base 55–6, 149 of functions 113 local “institutional thickness” 51, 357 gender segregation 320, 322 local integration 49, 57, 149 industrial 15, 29, 37, 124, 127 local labor market investment switching 303 accessibility 133, 134, 304, 308, 309 low-cost 124, 251, 253 characteristics of 306, 308–10 Nike strategy 395 class and gender relations 255, 304–7, product-cycle theory 37–8 308–10, 314 profit-maximizing 15 flexible production systems 130–1 radical economic changes 327 globalization 269 reduced importance of 42 institutions 255, 304–7, 308–10, 314 regional or Triad patterns 277 pliability 254 territorialization 253, 271–4, 277–8, 279–89 polarization within 118 transnational corporations (TNCs) 36–8, 39, reserves 123 144–5, 146 shortage of women workers 152 of workplaces 316, 326–8 transnational corporations (TNCs) 146 location patterns 331 local learning 333 location theories 3, 4, 91, 170, 331, 333 local networks 43, 253 locational mobility 92 local organizations 57, 355 locational substitutability 272, 274–6, 278–9, local path-dependencies 51 283, 284, 287, 288 local politics 47, 55, 253 lock-in threats 50 local renewal 56 Lodge, David 2 local resources 48, 57 Loh, M. 313 local specialization 53, 112 London 93, 114, 115, 117, 118–19, 121–2 local specificities 47, 53 technological networks 347 local state Longino, H. 2, 9 class and gender relations 255, 304–6, 307–8, Lorraine 297 310–14 Los Angeles 132 investment policies 261 Lösch, August 3, 91 local supply-base 49 Loveridge, R. 358 local-global tensions 94–5, 137–50, 237, 239 Lovering, John 92, 254 localities Lowe, D. 26 attachment to 290–1, 294–5, 296, 298, 300, Lowe, Lisa 377 302–3 Lowe, M. 63, 377 characteristics of 113 loyalty 50, 145, 370 class politics 253–4, 290, 291, 297–9, 302–3 Lubeck, P. 217 declining 31 Lundvall, B. A. 352, 356 globalization 363 international division of labor 36 M4 corridor 133 living wages 334 McCarthy, J. 376, 387 plant closures 253–4, 290–2, 295, 296–9, McCarthyism 19 302–3 McCay, B. 180 locality project 13 McCloskey, D. 70, 390, 393 localization 3, 42, 43, 68, 148, 183 McDonaldization 235 division of labor 284 McDowell, L. 62, 64, 95, 152, 252, 255–6, 318, flexible production systems 132 319, 322 money capital 210, 211 McEvoy, A. F. 180 relational assets 52 McGrath, M. E. 149 territorialization 272, 273, 280, 281, 282–3 Macías Picavea, R. 198 see also industrial districts McKinsey 351 INDEX 461

Mackintosh, M. 232 see also deindustrialization; flexible production McLuhan, Marshall 62 systems; Fordism; post-Fordism McMichael, P. 235 manufacturing studies, biases 31, 32 McPherson, M. 226 Mao Tse-tung 22 macroeconomic trends 263, 265 maquiladora 95, 151–65 MacWilliam, S. 81 Marche 133 Malaysia 362, 364 marginalist economics 391 Malinowski, B. 365, 369 Marinho, Festus 212 Malmberg, A. 52, 149, 358 Mark-Lawson, J. 313 Maluquer de Motes, J. 199 market management in economic geography 60–1 British traditional style 45 failure 171, 180, 259, 279 business services 103, 104 forces 46, 57, 180, 251, 253, 321 feminization of 315 gardening see horticultural projects headquarters activities 103, 104 mechanism 48–9, 180 Japanese methods 46 niches 133 managerial occupations 103–4 regulators 62 power of 151 segmentation 34, 267 social contract 127 uncertainty 50, 129 spatial relationship to R&D 42–3 market-ideological economies 142, 143 women workers 320 market-rational economies 142, 143 management gurus 66 marketing 317, 352 management and organization studies 252 funds for 107 management sector internationalization of 42 slackening growth of 120 neglect of 43 spatial structure 116, 119–22 new selling practices 63 management studies, research biases 31, 32 new service class 317 management techniques, innovations in 35, 39 research biases 31 managerial hierarchies 112 spatial relationship to R&D 41 Mandel, E. 295 specialist organizations 133 Mandinka ethnic group 223–4 strategic alliances 285–6 Mann, R. 225 strategies 155 Mansell, R. 338 use of GIS 63 manual labor 111, 113 marketing networks 279, 282 and management 45 markets masculinity 322 as anarchic 35 research biases 31, 32 changes in 33 semi-skilled 116 commodity model economies 67 skilled 116 European Single Market 62 unskilled 116, 132 free market environmentalism 179, 180–1 manufacturing industry gender 251 in Australia 309 governance of 257, 269 class relations 306 institutions 62, 101, 251, 255 critical role of 79 liberation of 24, 198–9 decentralization 114–15 narrow view of 251 decline of 114, 115, 306, 309, 317, 318 neoclassical economics 179–81 externalization of functions 117 not only mode of exchange 101 gender relations 306 “perfect” 179 globalization 279, 287 proximity to 42–3 growth of 119, 169, 309 reduced concentration of 277 industrial spaces 327 social construction of 49–50, 101, 369 institutional concessions 287 social nature of 62 investment in 79 social practices 236 as life blood of the body economic 79–80 social relations of 251 local labor markets 306 spatial structures 112 spatial structures 116–17 and the state 251, 252–3, 257–70 Taiwanese investment in China 333, as ultimate arbiter 391 362–74 world 207, 210, 266, 271, 276, 277–8, 282, unemployment 306 366, 373 462 INDEX markets (cont’d) resources 170, 171–2, 175–6, 181–4, 186, see also buyer-supplier relations; 187–8, 192 competitiveness; deregulation; financial service sector 91–2, 97 markets; labor market; local labor theoretical and political priorities of 31–2 market; neo-liberalism uneven development 15, 30, 32, 92, 291, 295 Markov chain analysis 13 see also ecological Marxism Marsden, T. 237, 238 masculinity 17, 64, 78 Marshall, A. 129 of products 152, 156, 157, 163, 164 Marshall, J. 323 professional sector 319 Marshall, M. 93 workplace 322, 323–4, 326, 327 Martin, Emily 218, 219, 401 Maskell, P. 52, 358 Martin, R. 93, 258, 352 Mason, C. 117 Martinez, J. I. 138 mass consumption 93, 101, 102, 105 maruo 224, 225, 228–9, 233, 234 mass media see media Marvin, Caroline 339, 340 mass production 43, 105, 126–7, 128, 133, 169, Marvin, Simon 337, 338, 342, 349 284 Marx, Karl 25, 26, 129, 235 bias towards 31, 32 abstract conception of capitalism 15, 31, 32 branch-plant economy 39, 40 Capital 14, 19–23, 32, 192 decline of 125 capital accumulation 22, 106 fast food outlets 99 capital goods production 100 flexibility 131 capitalist management 103, 104 parallel plant development 288 capital’s search for profit 182–3 regulation theorists 93 chaotic conception 97 see also assembly work; Fordism collective laborer 97 Massey, Doreen 36, 93, 94, 95, 113, 114, 118 detail division of labor 100 changing class relations 305 discourse 24 dispute with Harvey 14 distance 331–2 division of labor 322 dominant terms of debate 23–4 economic/social relationships 306 The Eighteenth Brumaire 24 elite occupational groups 119, 120, 122 essential character of capitalist societies industrial restructuring 254 292 male manual labor 322 Grundisse 14, 192 space and place 348 inspiration for political economy 4 Spatial Divisions of Labour 13 labor theory of value 105, 151–2, 153, 155 materiality of representation 186 money system 102, 173, 208, 215, 218 Mateu Bellés, J. F. 201, 203 natural foundations of social development mathematical models 4 192 Mathews, J. 83 nature and resources 170, 175, 181, 182–3 mature products 38–9 production 91 Maurice, M. 356 relevance to daily life 14, 19–23 Mauss, M. 70, 365 social power 208, 215, 216 Max Havelaar 242 suspicion of rights 28 meanings 26, 67, 292, 327, 385, 386, 387, 388 use-value 32 cultural 1, 194, 320 Marx, L. 340 de/reterritorializing 62 Marxian value analysis 13, 104 gender 77, 323 Marxism 14–15, 16, 19–23, 73, 393 of money 208 abstract theory 15, 30–1, 32–3 shared 62, 291 analytical 65 socially endowed 298 conceptions of technology 352 struggles over 221 devalorizations of capital 92 media 54, 349, 354 distance 331–2 expectations of women 75 dominant terms of debate 23–4 image consciousness 62 the economic body 76 proliferation of 66 environment 21, 175–6, 181–2, 184, 186 media technologies 336, 338, 342 industrial location 15 medical care 104, 107 labor theory of value 153 medical interventions 74, 75 portrayal of the state 260 medical services 242, 244 production 91, 92 Meegan, R. 254, 305 INDEX 463

Melbourne 304 Miyoshi, M. 25 local labor market relations 308–10 modeling 170 local state relations 310–14 modernism 23 men modernity 172, 191, 204, 208, 210, 340 educational under-achievement 319 modernization 114, 122, 299 elite occupational groups 120 Australian industry 79 male sexuality 323–4 regional programs 302 traditional male roles 64 Spain 190, 191, 192, 193–4, 195–204 see also gender; masculinity Wilsonian 120 mergers 79, 354 modes of ordering 237, 240, 241, 243–4, 246, merit 392 247 Metal and Engineering Workers’ Union (MEWU) Mol, A. 68 81 monetary networks 69 metanarratives 23 money 101, 105, 317, 326 metaphor 28, 62, 63, 87, 192, 261, 393 booms 205–8, 209 of the economy 17, 70, 74–82, 85 circulation of 76, 102, 107, 332, 344 of impact 338, 347–8 as enhancer 218 ladder of evolution 83–7 fetishism 209, 211, 218 and language 246 functions of 208 organic development 17, 83–6 mobility of 43 organic structure 76, 77, 82, 83 oil money 205–19 power of 246 as rent 208–9 spatial 336–7 as threat 218 technological 238, 336–7 under-utilization of 92 territorial 336–7 Montpellier 133 of totality 75–6 Morales, R. 276 Metcalfe, J. S. 49 Morgan, Kevin 15, 29, 52, 53, 132, 296, 355, methodological approaches/perspectives 40, 191, 360 316, 376 Morley, M. 210, 211 methodological nationalism 357 Morris, D. 141 methodological precepts 15 Morris, M. 72, 78 methodological schema 5 Mort, F. 64 methodological shift 4 mortgage markets 105 methodology, basic problems of 29–32 Mosco, V. 341 Mexico 242 Moss, P. 377 maquiladora workplace 95, 151–65 Motorola 43 Mexico On the Water (MOTW) 152–65 Moulaert, F. 144 micro-electronics industry 44 Mowbray, M. 311 Microsoft 336 Mowery, D. 277 microstudies 46 Mueller, F. 358 middle class 121, 200, 217, 304, 317, 327, multinational corporations see transnational 399 corporations (TNCs) migration 6 multiskilling 34 international labor 261 Murdoch, J. 236, 237, 238 out-migration of labor 131 Murdock, Graham 344 state policies 266 Murgatroyd, L. 120, 306 see also immigrant labor Murray, F. 43 Mikita, J. 385 Murray, R. 37, 46 Miliband, Ralph 21 music industry 60 Miller, D. 59, 60 mutual dependence 77, 138 Miller, P. 68 mutuality 50, 52, 54 Mills, S. 376 Mytelka, L. 276, 277 Milner, H. V. 147 Mirowski, P. 70, 246 Nadal Reimat, E. 197, 199 mirror worlds 339–40 Nagel, Charles 178, 185 Mishrah, R. 308 narrative communities 60 Misztal, B. 50 Nath, K. 230 Mitchell, I. 230 nation-states see states Mitchell, William 336, 337, 342–3 nationalism 43, 44, 291 464 INDEX nationality, production of value in the workplace collectivity 240, 246 95, 151, 152–3, 154–65 community support 310 nationalization 22, 210, 298, 299 durability 240, 246 Natter, W. 376 of elites 321 natural resources 5, 169–74 ethnic 69, 333 agency 171, 172 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 alternative geographies of food 235–47 globalization 141, 236, 237–47, 349 capital accumulation 182 hybrid 237, 241–7 “commons” problem 171, 179, 180, 183–4 immutable mobiles 239 embeddedness 170, 192 industrial districts 286 exploitation 171, 180, 181–4, 186, 187 interpersonal 49–50, 364–5, 367–8, 373–4 Gambian wetlands 173, 220–34 marketing 279, 282 images of 169 mediators 238–40 marginalization of study of 170 modes of ordering 237, 240, 241, 243–4, 246, markets 179 247 property rights 179, 180–1, 182, 184 partiality 247 as social artifacts 170–1, 181–4, 186 post-Fordism 83, 128 territorialization 279 situatedness 236, 247 see also fur seal industry; oil; waterscape social 117, 239, 320–1, 334, 353, 364–5, nature 367–8 discursive production of 175–6, 184–7 strengthening 244–6 first nature 170, 181–2, 193 topological presupposition of 68, 69 ideologies of nature 171, 175, 184, 185, 186 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139, 149 Marxism 170, 171–2, 175–6, 181–4, 186, see also actor-network theory (ANT) 187–8, 192 New African 215 production of 5, 170, 175–6, 181–2, 190, New Republic 209 191, 193, 194–5, 204 New Town developments 299–300 relation to capitalism 170, 171, 175–6, 181–4 New York 327 second nature 170, 175, 182 New York Times 22, 23, 395 and society 172, 175, 181–2, 191–4, 204, 239 newly industrializing countries 39, 142, 362 nature-nurture problem 25 foreign direct investment 140, 363 Naughton-Treves, L. 181 increased competition 94, 127 needs 77 rise of 67 of buyers 41 transnational corporations (TNCs) 363 hierarchy of 103 women as cheap labor 322 local services 57, 308, 313 see also Hong Kong; Indonesia; Malaysia; satisfaction of 26, 76, 91, 92, 102, 103 Singapore; South Korea; Taiwan; Thailand welfare 56 NIDL (New International Division of Labor) women workers 322 thesis 15, 37–9 negotiation, encouragement of 51 Niehans, J. 391 Negroponte, Nicholas 339 Nietzsche, Friedrich 70 Nelson, K. 307 Nigeria Nelson, R. R. 351, 356 and Britain 213–14 neo-conservatism 128 collapse of oil boom 213, 216–18 neo-Fordism 45 corruption 172–3, 213, 214, 215 neo-liberalism 16, 23, 24, 27, 48, 241, 253, 258 Dikko kidnapping 213–14, 215–16 conception of the state 259 oil boom 172–3, 212–13, 214–15 laissez-faire capitalism 257 oil resources 209, 212–18 macro-economic actions 57 Nigerian National Petroleum Company (NNPC) neoclassical economics 4, 32, 66, 73, 98, 179, 212 244, 393 Nike 22, 141, 334, 394–9, 402 neocolonialism 25, 386, 387 Nissan 43 nepotism 364 Nixon, Richard 22 Netherlands, social economy 56 Nixson, F. 147 network lengthening 238, 239, 240, 243 N’Jang, A. 230 networks 51, 54, 61 nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) 221, acting at a distance 174, 237–40, 241 225–6, 229, 230, 231, 232, 241 affinity networks 62 nonlinearity, concept of 66 banking sector 239, 321 Nooteboom, B. 52 INDEX 465 normalization, concept of 324 Organic Crop Improvement Association 244–6 Norman, G. 276, 287 organic development metaphor 17, 83–6 norms 50, 251, 326, 333, 355, 358, 374, 393 organic farm practices 244–6 business 93, 126 organic functionalism 81 as economic regulator 76 organic structure metaphor 76, 77, 82, 83 labor market 131 organismic totality 75–6 market exchange 321 Organization for Economic Cooperation and as relational asset 52 Development (OECD) 141, 362 North American Commercial Company (NACC) Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries 178, 187 (OPEC) 172, 206 North American Free Trade Agreement 266, 356 organizational growth 239 North Pacific Fur Seal Convention (1911) organizations 50, 56, 63 178–9, 180, 181, 184, 185 as always open 67 Norway 134 Chinese business 364–5 Noyelle, T. 97 contacts between 53 Nyerere, Julius 22 disorganization of 66–7 diversity within 359 Oberhauser, A. 4, 116 fair trade 241, 242, 244 object-subject relation 63 feminization of 315 objectivity 2, 389–90, 401 gender 316, 323–4 observation 1, 32, 95 global business hierarchies 274–7, 278 The Observer 214 interdependencies between 280 occidentalist beliefs, erosion of 67–8 Japanese business 140 occupational structure 98, 116 local 57, 355 O’Connor, J. 175, 182, 268 modes of ordering 240 O’Donnell, C. 313 new work processes 67 OECD 141, 362 Nigerian state 215 Offe, C. 252, 261, 263–4, 268 openness to influences 55 office developments 307, 309 requirement to improvise 66 Ohmae, K. 145, 253, 271, 274, 276, 350, 355, seen as in action 66–7 363 state strengthening of 265 Ohno, T. 35 supportive 123 oil 205–19 see also corporations/firms; institutions; centralizing impact of revenues 210 nongovernmental organizations (NGOs); enclave character 210 supranational state structures; trade as internationalized commodity 210 unions; transnational corporations (TNCs) meanings of oil money 208–9 orientalist beliefs, erosion of 67–8 nationalization 210 orientation, basic problems of 29–32 oil boom 172–3, 205–13, 214–15 Orillard, M. 50 oil crises 206 Orlando 339 see also money, Nigeria Orrú, M. 61 oil companies 35 Ortega Cantero, N. 196, 198, 199, 203 Okali, C. 230 Ortega, N. 196, 197, 199, 200 O’Keefe, P. 170 Ortí, A. 189, 196, 197, 198, 199 Okoth-Ogendo, H. 233 Ostry, S. 143 Olds, K. 16–17, 236 O’Sullivan, M. 356, 357 oligopolization 112, 273, 277, 278, 279, 284, other 285–7 reconceptualization of 63 Olman, B. 193 scariness of 401 Omnibus Trade Act (1988) 143 outwork 307, 309 O’Neill, P. M. 252–3, 258 overproduction 126 Ong, A. 363, 364, 368 overshooting 211 OPEC 172, 206 overspill plants 39 open-access problem 180 Oxfam 241, 242 open-door policies 44 Oxfam Trading 241–2 Opinion Research and Communications (ORC) ozone depletion 26, 182 217 optimism 24, 27–8, 198, 274 Padoan, P. C. 273 Orange County 134 Pahl, R. 316, 317, 318 466 INDEX

Pakistan, child labor 22, 395 attachment to 290–1, 294–5, 296, 297–300, Palander, Tord 91 302–3 Pankhurst, F. 313 co-evolution perspective 332, 337, 340–5, 348 paradigms 13–14 defense of 295–300 Pareto optimality 179, 181 information technologies 332, 336–49 Park, M. 225 key role for firms 355 Parkes, D. 67 recombination perspective 332, 337–8, 345–7, Parkin, P. W. 323 348–9 Parry, J. 218 as relational assemblies 347–9 participant observation 32, 95 substitution and transcendence perspectives participatory politics 56 337, 338–40, 343, 344, 347–8 particularity 26–7, 388 technological determinism 332, 338–40, 341, Pasteur, Louis 174 344, 347–8 Patel, P. 273, 276, 281, 356 see also space paternalism 45, 364 plan-ideological systems 142 patriarchy 86, 233, 322 plan-rational economies 142, 143 patriotism 154, 196, 198, 217 planning intervention 127 Pauly, L. W. 356, 357 plant closures see works closures Pavitt, K. 273, 276, 281, 356 Plant, S. 70 peanuts cultivation 221, 223, 225, 226, 231–2 Platteau, J.-P. 61–2 Pearce, D. 181 Plotkin, H. C. 50 Peck, J. 13, 94, 259, 260, 261, 375 Plummer, P. 4, 170 pelagic sealing 178, 179, 183 Poe, Edgar Allan 218 Perez Alfonso, Juan Pablo 205–6 Polanyi, Karl 50, 62, 252, 262, 359 Perez, Carlos Andres 209, 210 Polanyi, Michael 62 Pérez de La Dehesa, R. 197 political arenas 62, 313 Pérez, J. 196, 197 political centralization 210 performance, notion of 316, 325 political consciousness 45 peripheral regions 31, 299 political ecology 173, 191, 220, 221 branch plants 40 political economy 4, 5, 13, 173, 236–7, 252 and the core 79, 127, 174, 238 globalization 272 flexible production systems 132 international 69, 70 labor reserves 114 Marxian 24, 176, 179 “periphery”, global networks 238 poststructuralism 376 Perlmutter, H. V. 138 privileging of the social 174 personal health 26 supplanted by cultural analysis 14–15, 21 personal relationships 325 telecommunications and space 343–5 see also gift exchange; interpersonal two ideal types of 142 relations political institutions 16, 51 Peru 174, 242–4 political interventions 1, 81, 264 pessimism 27–8 political relations 126, 219, 251–2, 254, 307 Petras, J. 210, 211 political resistance 26, 131, 264 Pfeiffer, K. L. 70 political science 271–2 Pharaohism 207 political subject 75 Philippines 362 Pollert, A. 32 migrant Filipina domestic workers 333, Poovey, M. 390, 394 375–88 population growth 220 Phillips, A. 319 population problems 26 Phillips, D. 217 Port Harcourt 213 Philosophy of Money (Simmel) 208 Porter, G. 101, 103 Picciotto, S. 147 Porter, Michael 51, 53, 355, 358 Pigou, A. 180 Porteres, R. 223 Pile, Steve 336 Portugal 134 Pimlott, B. 59 Portuguese Empire 237–8 Piore, M. 84, 128 positional goods 317 Pitelis, C. 145, 147 positionality see situatedness place positivism 3, 4, 15, 197 anti-closure campaigns 253–4, 290–2, 295, Posner, J. 226 296–9, 302–3 post-colonialism 23, 173, 187 INDEX 467 post-Fordism 83, 84, 86, 144, 257 process post-industrialism 23, 97, 98, 109–10, 327 and space 31, 36–7 post-Keynesianism 73 process development, compatibility with product post-Marxism 23 development 43 Poster, M. 387 process engineering 39, 42 postmodernism 23, 82, 324 process technology 352, 353 postmodernity 23–8, 318 effect on labor processes 33 poststructuralism 4, 5, 23, 70, 236, 324, innovations in 35, 39 376–7 process technology standardization “the body” 25–6 branch-plant economy 39–40 materialization 153–4 product-cycle theory 37–9 poststructuralist feminism 151, 152 producer services 53, 97, 100, 114 potlatch, theory of 70 product development 39, 103, 108 Poulantzas, Nicos 21 compatibility with process development 43 poverty 80, 174, 241, 334, 399, 401 product differentiation 32, 34, 37, 39, 131, 133, power 280, 284 at local level 376 product diversification 33, 34 between TNCs and states 95, 137, 147, product innovation 148–50 advantages of proximity 42–3 changes in 30 indirect labor 107–8 core regions 93 neglect of 32–3 of corporate managers 151 product-cycle theory 37–9 disempowerment 24, 91, 344 product standardization 34, 41, 42, 279, 284 of elite occupational groups 93, 120 branch-plant economy 39–40 gendered organizations 323–4 Fordism 127 global networks 237, 238 product-cycle theory 37–9 local government 55 product-cycle 37–9, 127 nation-states 24, 144, 257, 260, 285 production 5, 91–6 oil boom economies 211, 216 administration 43 shareholders 351 as base of capitalism 92, 93, 105–6, 108 social class 104 commercial geography 3 social relations of 151 critical reassessment of 4 surplus value production 104 the division of labor 100 trade unions 30 driven by profit 91 transnational corporations (TNCs) 138, 141, driven by services 64 150, 277–8 internationalization of 42, 291, 294, 352 unequal relations of 112 “just-in-time” production 35, 43, 116, 130, unequal relationship in society 91 131, 350 within Spanish state 200, 202–3 lean techniques 350, 360 in the workplace 316 mature products 38–9 see also social power maximum-scale strategies 34–5 Poynter, T. A. 147 modularization of processes 43 pragmatism 69 optimal scales of 34–5 Prato 133 relations of 98, 104, 111, 112–13 Pratt, G. 153, 322, 375, 378 research biases 31, 32 pre-Fordism 83 routinization 40, 43, 127, 135, 279 Preamble Foundation 400 service sector 91–2, 97–110 Pred, A. 102, 103, 108, 377 social relations of 46, 92, 114, 119, 183, 317, prejudices 32 352 preservationism 171, 184–6 spatial relationship to R&D 43 Pribilof seals see fur seal industry spatial structures 93, 111, 112–13, 116–22, PricewaterhouseCoopers 351 123 Primo de Rivera, Miguel 203 unskilled labor-intensive 38, 40 Pringle, R. 323–4 of use-value 98–100 privatization 128, 180–1, 199, 217, 220, 253, see also commodity production; craft 259 production; decentralization; economies of problem solving 50 scale; factory production system; flexible problematization processes 61–5 production systems; Fordism; mass procedural actor rationality 50, 51, 54 production 468 INDEX production filières 63–4 as source of information 52, 53, 54, 272, production of nature 5, 170, 175–6, 181–2, 190, 369 191, 193, 194–5, 204 as source of innovation 54, 369 productivity 72, 98 as source of knowledge/learning 52, 53, 54, convergence 352 369 cultural characteristics 46 and space 42–3 falling 94, 127–8 territorial 49, 51–2 Gambian wetlands 173, 224 territorialization 272, 280–1, 288 indirect labor 106–7, 109 pseudoconcrete analysis 30, 40 interconnectedness 80 psychoanalysis 25, 70, 316 Keynesian regional policies 48 public arena 316, 326, 394 labor share in gains of 127 public choice theory 259 living wage 400 public goods state 263 low productivity sectors 80 public ownership 22, 291 maximum volumes 35 public relations sector 317 service sector 101 public sector spatial variations 46 adoption of enterprise cultures 267 professional sector 309–10, 317 capital accumulation 215 spatial structures 119–22 China 371 uneven development 114, 115, 116, 117 efficiency of 56 women workers 319 growth of 114, 119 profit 23, 35, 101, 102, 299, 321 impact of oil revenues on 210 capital’s search for 182–3, 292 investment programs 299 as central to management 104, 105 learning regions 355 centrality of 93 Nigeria 214, 215 China 365, 367, 369 scrutinizing of 56 as economic regulatory mechanism 76 women workers 319 as engine of economic change 91 public space 56, 349 flexible accumulation 307 public sphere 55 Gambian wetlands 232 pundits 66 Marxism 91, 182–3 Putnam, R. 56, 355 nature 170 niche markets 130 quality oil boom economies 212 child-care sector 311 product innovation 107 economies of association 54 sealing industry 171, 177, 178, 179, 180, 181, fair trade coffee networks 244 182–3 of goods 35, 152, 154, 157–64, 244, 281 steel industry 296 of labor 152, 154, 157–64, 273, 280, 327 temporary superprofits 276 obsession with 45 transnational corporations (TNCs) 144–5, 146 service sector 311, 312, 327 profit maximization 15, 33, 92, 183 supervision of 266 profitability 198, 332 quality certification 61 calls for wage restraint 79 quality circles 131 falls in 94 quality management 351, 352 Nike 334, 394–9 quantitative economic geography 331 progress, discourse of 340 quantitative revolution 3, 4, 91 project production 31 quasi-integration 117 proletarianization 120, 196 quasi-objects 191, 193, 204, 239 property rights 101, 344 queer theory 25, 324 land in the Gambia 173, 220, 224–6, 228–9, 232, 233–4 race 151, 324, 401 markets 62 conflict with capitalism 292 natural resources 179, 180–1, 182, 184 Marxian lack of concern 21 state role 43, 252, 262, 263, 264, 267 racial discrimination 188 protectionism 43, 44, 143, 199, 200 racial minorities 153 proximity Rada, J. 38 cultural 333 Radice, H. 44 customer-supplier relations 149 Rafael, V. 384 relational 359 Rahman, A. K. 224 INDEX 469 railway industry 299 innovation 56, 133 rational agency 291, 292–4, 303 innovation system 355 rational choice 4, 65 inter-area relations 112 rationality 50–1, 54–5, 78, 218, 239, 321, 323, political autonomy 55 328 power relationships 94 Ravenscraig steelworks 297–8 radical kinds 31, 32 reactive responses 50, 54 state involvement 266, 269 Reaganism 128, 142 works closures 290, 296, 297, 299 real estate speculation 211 see also core regions; peripheral regions recession 40, 45, 58, 115, 267, 295, 317, 318 Regulation School 76, 93, 125 reciprocity 52, 53, 56, 70 regulation theory 76, 93–4, 125, 126–8, 135, gift exchange 59–60, 67, 370 260–2 recombinant architecture 342 third wave 69 recursive rationality 50, 51 regulatory infrastructures 235 Redclift, M. 175 Reich, R. 137, 140, 145, 146, 271, 273, 274 redundant skills 55 Reich, S. 146, 356, 357 reengineering 351 reindustrialization programs 81, 291, 295 reflexive rationality 54 relational assets 52, 280, 284, 285, 286 reflexivity 57, 65, 335, 343, 349 remote control 238 regeneracionism 172, 196, 197–204 rentier capitalism 209, 211, 213 region-state, emergence of 355, 356 representation 70 regional decentralization 115 representational 62–3 regional development 29, 37, 252, 333 repression 19, 21, 91 flexible production systems 125–36 reproduction 75, 76, 78–9 institutions 48–58, 355, 360 reproductive strategies 26 see also uneven development research regional development agencies 53, 355 abstract and concrete 30 regional economies, reading 38, 40 biases 31–2 regional geography, move to spatial science 14, research analysts 66 170 research and development (R&D) 120, 277, regional growth 48, 49, 51, 57, 115–16, 117, 278, 280 118, 125, 299 coordination and funding 43 regional innovation system 355 funding 39, 107 regional locational patterns 277 growth of 114 regional policies laboratories as codified knowledge 52 cluster programs 51, 53 research biases 31 as firm-centered 48 spatial relationship to management 42–3 institutional reform 55–6 spatial relationship to marketing 41 institutional turn 51–2 spatial relationship to production work 43 institutionalism 16, 48–58 underestimation of 39 Keynesianism 48 research programs 3, 9n learning as key factor 53–5 reskilling 33–4 less favored regions (LFRs) 48–9, 54, 57, 58 Resnick, S. 85 and the macro-economy 57–8 Restad, P. L. 59 mobilization of the social economy 56–7 restaurant sector 99 modernization programs 114, 302 restricted selection threat 50 orientations of 52–7 retail developments 307 reindustrialization 295 retailing sector 63, 101, 112, 288, 309 strengthening of 302 revolution 22 regional science 3 Reza Shah Pahlavi 206, 207, 209, 210 regional studies, criticism of 32–46 rhetoric, analysis of 390 regions The rhetoric of economics (McCloskey) 390 autonomy of 144, 196 rights 386 competitiveness of 53, 56, 57–8, 391 civil 19, 21 corporate hierarchy 37 consumer 385 declining 31 human 26, 28, 395 economic specialization 93 intellectual property 276 firm embeddedness 355 universal 63, 377, 379 as fundamental geographical unit 169 see also property rights 470 INDEX

Riley, F. 178 global 137, 138, 139, 140, 141, 237, 259, Ritzer, G. 235 273–4, 350 Roberts, R. 181 industrial practices 354–9 Robins, Kevin 340–1 international 37, 61, 139, 144, 257, 287, 344 Robinson, J. F. F. 296, 299 local 138, 199, 237 robotized equipment 131 national 61, 199, 299, 351, 356–7 Rogers, G. 178 regional 299, 351, 355, 358, 360 Roppel, A. Y. 179 subnational 37 Rorty, Richard 14, 60, 70 supranational 265–8 Rosdolsky, R. 32 see also economies of scale Rose, G. 153 scent industry 60 Rose, N. 68 Schaefer, Fred 14 Ross, R. J. S. 259 Schmidt, A. 175, 192 rotating credit associations 61, 64, 65 Schoenberger, E. 116, 151, 320, 334–5, 353, routine production 40, 43, 127, 135, 279 357, 358, 389 Rowthorn, B. 93 Schonberger, R. J. 35, 46 Ruan, D. 373 Schroeder, R. 231, 232, 233, 340 Ruccio, D. 77, 86 Schumpeterian workfare state 261 Rugman, A. M. 147 Sciberras, E. 42 Ruiz, J. M. 189, 196 Scientific City 133 rule-following behavior 50 scientific knowledge 353 rules 50, 51 scientific sector 114, 115, 119–22 Rullani, E. 52 Scotland, works closures 290, 297–8, 299 runaway industries 38, 42 Scott, A. 59 rural regions 57, 116, 121 Scott, A. J. 3, 254, 332, 355 see also The Gambia flexible production systems 93–4, 95, 129, Russell Smith, J. 331 132, 134, 135, 144 Russia, fur sealing 178, 179 regions 51 Russian-American Company (RAC) 177, 186–7 Scott, A. M. 321 Russo, M. 133 Scott, J. 152, 322 seal hunting see fur seal industry Sabel, C. 54, 84, 128, 360 secretarial work 319, 323 Sack, R. D. 31 self sacred beliefs 63 construction of 324–5 Sadler, D. 252, 253–4, 296, 297, 298 reconceptualization of 63 Sahlins, M. 365, 369, 370 topological presupposition of flow 70 Salais, R. 84, 280 self-governance 56 Salzinger, L. 152, 156 self-organized network firms 69 Samuels, W. 49 self-surveillance 324 Sanderson, K. 64 selfish individualism 180 Sassen, S. 318, 327, 328 selling practices 63 Sassuolo 133 semiconductor industry 38, 44, 287 satisfaction semiotics 70 maximization of 179 Senegal 232 of needs 26, 76, 91, 92, 102, 103 Sennett, R. 316 Saudi Arabia 207, 209 sensation, topological presupposition of flow 70 Saussure, Ferdinand de 23 separatism 63 Savage, M. 317 Sercovich, F. C. 363 Sawhney, H. 337, 341 Serequerbehan, T. 187 Saxenian, A. 134, 281, 355 Serres, M. 239 Sayer, Andrew 16, 41, 42, 97 service sector critical realism 4, 5, 15, 30 capital accumulation 105, 106–7, 109 flexible production systems 132 capitalism 98, 102, 109 industrial restructuring 254 circulation 100–2, 106–7 uneven development 291 confusion with trade 101–2 scale 5, 47 consumption 102–3 bias of 241 decentralization 115, 118, 341 diseconomies of 40 decline of 318 geographic 137, 141, 143, 262 definition 99 INDEX 471

distinction from goods 97, 99 Sklair, L. 235 division of labor 97–108, 109 Skocpol, T. 265 employment in 91, 98, 115, 306, 309, 310, Skurski, J. 210 317–18 Slater, D. 187 feminization of 315 Slouka, M. 340 flexible production systems 129 small batch production 31 growth of 92, 105, 114, 115, 315, 317–18 Smelser, N. 49, 236 indirect labor 98, 106–8, 109 Smelt, S. 208 industrial spaces 327 Smith, Adam 75, 129, 391 inner cities 116 Smith, F. 230 interactive work 325 Smith, G. 63, 64 internationalization 118, 140 Smith, M. 340 Marxism 91–2, 97 Smith, Neil 170, 175, 181, 182, 184, 190, 193, organization and management 103–4 331 as principal output of economy 91, 97, 98 Smith, P. 298 as a product 97 smuggling 367 production 91–2, 97–100 Snyder, W. M. 359 quality 311, 312, 327 the social 60, 68, 171, 251–6, 390 rate of surplus value 106–7 expanded role of 16 replacement of goods 98 and the natural 174, 191, 192 uneven development 114, 115, 116, 118 networks of 240 “Seven Days’ War” 19 rise of 61–2 Seville 207 social action 252, 293–4, 347 sexual harassment 64, 323 social actors 67, 256, 293 sexuality 27 social agency 235–6, 239, 240, 244, 247, 256, and the body 25, 74 293, 301, 390 Marxian lack of concern 21 social breakdown 56 in the workplace 64, 323–4 social capital 56 Sforza-Roderick, M. 400 social change 318–19 Shagari, Alhaji Shehu 213, 217 oil boom economies 211 Shapin, S. 65, 389 possibilities for 109 Shapiro, Dr “Lou” 213–14 social citizenship 51 shareholder capitalism 351 social class 4, 5, 21 Shell, M. 218 anti-closure campaigns 253–4, 290, 291, Sheppard, Eric 5, 13, 169, 334 297–9, 302–3 shipbuilding industry 114, 290 attachment to place 290, 291, 294–5, Shockley, William B. 134 297–300, 302–3 Shohat, E. 187 changing class relations 305 shop stewards movement 45 class conflict 126, 268 shopping 16, 59, 68, 339, 346 class exploitation 105, 188, 318 shopping malls 63 class solidarity 296, 381 shops, noncapitalist exploitation 86 class struggle 22, 33, 196 Siemens 145 endurance of class cleavages 92 Sierra, C. 52 formation process 294, 304–5 Silicon Valley 43, 52, 134 foundations of class structure 111 Simmel, G. 172, 173, 207–8, 218 geography of 119–22 Simon, H. A. 50 as internally related 32 Singapore 142, 364, 383 legitimacy of class position 300–1 Singelmann, J. 97, 109 power 104 Singh, R. 230 relations in local labor market 255, 304–7, situated 308–10, 314 knowledge 24, 236, 325 relations in local state 255, 304–6, 307–8, networks 236, 247 310–14 practice 293, 376, 377 relations of production 112, 113 skills relations to each other 111–12 and identity 151 structural relation between capital and labor learning of 30 292–3 reskilling 33–4 structuration of 304–5 social skills 62 see also middle class; working class 472 INDEX social cohesion 200, 294 of production 46, 92, 114, 119, 183, 317, 352 social confidence 56, 57 of sexuality 323 social conflict 56, 196 structures of 41 social contract 127 social reproduction 254–5, 304, 305, 314 social control 238 of capitalist societies 293 social cooperation 264 Fordism 127 social costs 180, 295 social division of labor 75 social development 135, 192 women’s role 4 social dialog 53 social status 113, 233 social disintegration 172, 219 social structure 4, 62, 116, 119–22, 247, 326 social distance 331–2 social structures of accumulation (SSA) theory social economy 76 mobilization of 56–7 social systems modernization of 200 distinct from structure 293 social exclusion 56, 91 market competition 393 social inclusion 56–7 Marxism 171 social integration 76, 219 state’s natural domain 268 social interaction 54, 74, 293, 300, 306, 320, socialism 21, 22, 76, 86, 92, 371 321, 338, 364 socialist command economies 142 social networks 117, 239, 320–1, 334, 353, society 364–5, 367–8 as an organic structure 76, 81 social norms see norms art of governance 56 social power 200, 204 basic building blocks of 111 corporate management 151 and the body 26 discourse of economics 393, 394 control over 119, 120 Marx 208, 215, 216 dependence on material environment 170 money as 172–3, 208, 215, 219 economic processes 5 regional culture of 56–7 fundamental class cleavages 92 telecommunications infrastructures 344, 348 globalization 26 social practices 240, 247, 254, 292–3, 347 held together by superstructure 92 built environment 328 and nature 172, 175, 181–2, 191–4, 204, 239 as embodied and routinized 236 unequal power relationship 91 gendered 322, 324 see also civil society jobs 322 socioeconomics 49, 351 recursive nature of 293 sociology 390 simultaneous performance of 238 Soete, L. 276 urban landscapes 327 software sector 41, 104, 133, 342–3 working class 302, 303 Solidarity Sponsoring Committee (SSC) 399, 400 social rationalization 235, 246 Solinas, G. 133 social reform 196, 200 Solinger, D. J. 366 social relations 126, 251–2, 254, 324, 327, 348, Sony 43, 281 387 Sophia Antipolis 133 between neighbors 348 South Korea between workers 323 chaebol 146 of capitalism 170, 171, 181, 182, 208, 293, multinational corporations 363 294, 303 Nike workers 395, 396, 397 of competition 183 plan-rational economy 142 of consumption 217 Soviet Union, Czech “Spring” 19, 21 ecological problems 173 Soviet Union, former 141 gendered nature of 173, 220–34 space influence in economic life 49 annihilation of 42 in local labor market 255, 304–7, 308–10, changes in understanding of 64–5 314 co-evolution perspective 332, 337, 340–5, 348 in local state 255, 304–6, 307–8, 310–14 cyberspace 70, 336, 337, 340, 342, 346 of markets 251 hyperspaces 64 nature 170, 171, 172, 173, 174, 192 importance of 331–2 oil boom economies 173, 207, 208, 209, 210, and industry 29–47 219 information technologies 332, 336–49 of power 151 proximity 42–3 INDEX 473

as relational assemblies 347–9 spillovers 130, 143, 272, 273, 288–9 as a social product 331–2 Spivak, G. C. 188, 376–7 substitution and transcendence perspectives Sproul, C. 78 337, 338–40, 343, 344, 347–8 stagflation 127–8 technological determinism 332, 338–40, 341, Stam, R. 187 344, 347–8 Stanback, T. 97, 101, 102, 103 see also place; public space standardization space-time, recognition of 236 of regional policy 48 Spaces of Hope (Harvey) 14, 28 of tastes 278, 284 Spain technological 282 agriculture 195–6, 197–8, 199 see also assembly work; mass production; Corps of Engineers 201 process technology standardization; dams 195 product standardization decision-making 201 Stanford University 134 depatrimonialization of water 199 Staple, G. 343 economic restructuring 196 Stark, D. 54, 55 elites 196, 197, 199, 200, 203 state 5 flexible production systems 134 accumulation processes 43, 257, 258, 259–60, hydrological engineering mission 172, 261, 262, 264, 266–8, 269 197–203 aid 48 importance of water 189–90, 195 attachment to 291 industrialization 196 bargaining processes with TNCs 144–8, modernization 190, 191, 192, 193–4, 149–50 195–204 bounded regions 69 power 200, 202–3 competition between 44, 94–5, 141–8 regeneracionism 172, 196, 197–204 conceptions of 257 social tensions 203 deterritorialized flow economies 279, 285–7 waterscape 172, 189–91, 193–204 development programs 209 Spar, D. L. 276, 283 diminution of powers 24, 257, 260, 285 Sparke, M. 176 distribution processes 257, 258, 259, 261, spatial analysis 331–2 262, 266–7, 268–9 spatial clustering see clustering engagement with capitalism 263–5 spatial differentiation 42, 251, 310 financial market role 263, 265 spatial division of labor 36–42, 111, 112, 113, financial policies 149 114–16, 118, 121, 122–4 Frankfurt School 21 Spatial Divisions of Labour (Massey) 13 global-local tensions 141–9 spatial fetishism 332 hollowing-out of 258, 260–1, 266, 269 spatial fixes 183, 343–5 impact of globalization 259–60, 285–8 spatial flows 331 incentives 48, 53, 365 spatial hierarchy 36 influence over firm practices 356–7 spatial interaction 331, 332 internationalization of 210 spatial metaphors 336–7 intervention 48, 257–8, 259, 262, 263–5, 267 spatial science 14, 170 distributional outcomes 268, 269 spatial segregation 36 markets 252 spatial stereotypes 36–42 natural resources 180, 199–200 spatial structures 4, 93, 111, 112–14, 116–22, markets 251, 252–3, 257–70 123, 305, 334 neglect of 43–4 spatial studies, criticism of 32–46 neo-liberalist conception of 259 spatial uniformity 338–9 oil boom economies 209, 210, 211, 212–13, specialization 216 economies of 51, 52 overloaded 267–8 flexible production systems 84, 129 property rights 43, 252, 262, 263, 264, 267 of functions 39 qualitative view of 257, 258, 260, 262–5, geographical 37 268–70 local 53, 112 reduced role of 350, 355 regional economic 93 regulation theory 260–2 see also division of labor; task specialization relations with transnational corporations speculation 79, 149, 211, 215 (TNCs) 44, 94–5, 138, 144–50 spillover expertise 52 repression 19, 21 474 INDEX state (cont’d) superstructure 92, 93, 105–6, 108 rise of capitalism 262 suppliers see buyer-supplier relations role in economic restructuring 269 supranational state structures 143–4, 146, 148 supranational state structures 265–8, 269, bargaining power 149–50 350, 355, 356 emergence as new regulators 260–1 territorialization 285–9 impact on states 265–8, 269, 350, 355, 356 theory of 21 works closures 291, 296 statistical testing 4 surplus value 30, 76, 98, 104–8 status hierarchy 31, 32 capitalist management 104 steel industry 290, 296–9 mass of 105–6 Stefik, M. 336 rate of 106–7 Stiell, B. 381 shifts in the objects of labor 107–8 Stigler, G. 129, 259 sustainability 65 Stiglitz, J. E. 63 sweatshop campaign 334 Stilwell, F. 79 Swedberg, R. 49, 62, 236, 351 stock market crashes 92 Switzerland 134 Stopford, J. M. 138, 141, 145, 147, 149 Swyngedouw, Eric 4, 144, 172, 173, 343–4 Storper, M. 117, 132, 253, 254, 255, 332, 349 symbolic orders, power of 25 division of labor 100 system see social systems economic sociology 320 systems of provision 235 industrial development models 84 key role of place 355 tacit knowledge 52, 62, 355, 358, 359 proximity and association 52, 280 Taft, William 178, 185 surplus value 104 Taft-Hartley Act 287 Strange, S. 138, 141, 145, 147, 149, 350 Taiwan strategic alliances 261, 286, 363 assistance to the Gambia 226 transnational corporations (TNCs) 139, 141, industrialization 373 276 investment in China 333, 362–74 strategic monitoring 50 money as form of social integration 219 strategic vision 51, 360 Nike workers 395, 396, 397 Strathern, M. 236 plan-rational economy 142 Streeck, W. 356, 360 Tanzania 242 structuralism 23–4, 69, 241 tariffs 43, 44, 197, 211, 230 structuration theory 292, 293, 300 task specialization 53, 76, 100 structure tastes 97, 278, 281, 283, 284, 287 and agency 237, 292–4, 295 Taylorism 45 distinct from system 293 technical change 5, 114–15, 254 duality of 293 technical efficiency 259 see also economic structures; industrial technical sector 114, 117, 119–22 structures; infrastructure; social structure; technological accumulation 356 superstructure technological change 22, 62, 127, 148 The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (Kuhn) technological determinism 332, 338–40, 341, 13 344, 347–8 student radicalism 20 technological developments 30, 65, 66, 341 subaltern groups 55, 188 technological innovation 281 subcontractors 130, 131, 134, 288, 395, 396 flexible production systems 128, 133 subject global business hierarchies 276 social construction of 153–4, 315–16 Internet 336–7, 338, 343, 346 status of 389 lack of 72 subject positions 78, 377–8, 387, 388 spatial clustering 51 subject-object relation 63 technological lock-in 276 subjectivity 75, 77, 324, 325, 376, 387, 388 technological metaphors 238, 336–7 subsidiaries 138–9 technological rationality 21 substantive rationality 50, 54 technological spillovers 273, 288–9 suburbs 132, 133–4, 307, 308, 309, 313 technology Sumberg, J. 230 capital’s control over labor 33–4 Sunderson, S. 181 investment in 48 Sunley, P. 52, 258, 352 neglect of 32–3 superstores 63 rise of new intelligent technologies 63 INDEX 475

territorialization 279–80, 281 Thorne, L. 173–4, 237, 334 see also communications technology; high Thrift, Nigel 4, 118, 121, 237, 345, 349, 355 technology sector; process technology; actor-network theory 347 telecommunications technology alternative institutions 64 technology sector see high technology sector Christmas 59 technology transfers 261, 374 consumption 63 technopoles 49, 133–4 economic sociology 320 telebanking 342, 343, 346 economy and culture 16–17 telecommunications elite occupational groups 120, 121 banking demands for 108 face-to-face interaction 65 GM investment in 274 globalization 236, 246, 259, 280 proliferation of 66 institutions 51 spatiality of 6 labor qualities 280 telecommunications industry 39, 44 new service class 317 telecommunications infrastructure 274, 342, order in economic system 66 344, 346 professional sector 120 telecommunications technology 63, 332 proximity/association ties 52 and the city 332, 341–3, 348–9 time 67, 70 Internet 336–7, 338, 343, 346 transnational corporations (TNCs) 145 production of space 343–5 Thu Nguyen, D. 340 technological determinism 332, 338–40, 341, Thyssen 298 344, 347–8 Tickell, A. 13, 70, 94, 259, 260, 261 teleport 336 time 64–5, 70 television production 39 multiplication of 67 temporal contingencies 67 time-space compression 64 Terman, F. 134 time-space distanciation 64 territorial boundaries management 263, 264 tip sheet editors 66 territorial metaphors 336–7 Tolliday, S. 128 territorial proximity 49, 51–2 Tomlinson, J. 33 territorialization Tooby, J. 50 asset specificity 272, 280, 283 topological presuppositions 68, 69–70 definition 272 Torres Campos, R. 198 development 271–2, 278, 285, 288 totality 74, 79, 81, 82, 83, 85, 90, 92, 191, 281 globalization 253, 271–4, 277–8, 279–84, metaphor of 75–6 285–9 Toulouse 133 institutions 271–2, 279, 285–9 toxic waste generation 26 localization 272, 273, 280, 281, 282–3 Trachte, K. C. 259 location 253, 271–4, 277–8, 279–89 trade 101, 132 proximity 272, 280–1, 288 empirical trends in 138 textile industry 291 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 Thailand 362, 395, 396, 397 fur seal industry 177, 181, 183, 186 Thatcher, Margaret 22 Gambian wetlands 224 Thatcherism 128, 142 global 27, 140, 284 theory 3, 4 intra-industry 273–4 basic problems of 29–32 intrafirm 274, 276, 277, 282, 287 Third World Nigeria 213, 217 as competitor 115, 118, 362 openness in 267, 284 environmental change 220, 221, 223–5 Portuguese Empire 237–8 fair trade coffee networks 174, 237, 240–6 rules created by state 267 fair trade organizations 241, 242, 244 shift from free to fair 142–3 noncapitalist exploitation 86 Spain 195–6, 199 oil resources 205 state competition 142 as production sites 38 see also commodity trade; supranational state women’s growing militancy 221 structures Third World Information Network – TWIN trade alliances 364 241 trade associations 53, 364 Thompson, E. P. 188 trade disputes 142 Thompson, G. 137–8, 267 trade fairs 54 Thomson, C. N. 363 trade governance 261 476 INDEX trade liberalization 199, 217 transport 53 trade patterns 331 costs of 130, 177 trade unions 21–2, 53, 263 employment in 105 changes in workforce 306–7 improvements in 278, 280 globalization 24 investment in 48 powers 30 reduced costs and times 42 social contract 127 transport barriers 278, 282 steel industry 297, 298 transportation flows 339, 341, 342 trends in Britain 46 transportation geography 333 United States 287 transportation infrastructure 48, 331, 344 wage restraint 79 transportation technologies 5, 284, 332 West Germany 298 Triad locational patterns 277 Traidcraft 241–2 tribalization 343 training 53, 56, 311, 353, 360, 380 The Trouble with Nigeria (Achebe) 215 investment in 48 trust 50, 52, 56, 61, 65, 355, 357 in learning regions 54 Chinese business organization 364–5, 370 low value labor 159, 160, 163 contemporary cities 343 training courses 52 customer-supplier relations 149 training institutions 52, 352, 355 gift exchange 370, 372 transaction costs 51, 52, 67 money as symbol of 218 transaction network structures 67 Tryon, R. 103 transactional rules 62 Tuan, Y.-F. 291 transnational corporations (TNCs) Tuñon De Lara, M. 197 autonomy 138, 148 Turner, B. 208 bargaining processes 144–8, 149–50 Twin Trading 241–2 bounded regions 69 Twommey, C. 118 branch-plant economy 36, 332–3, 352, 356–7 Tyson, L. D. 145, 273, 281 collaborative ventures 139, 143 competitiveness 138, 139, 148 Uganda 242 control of international capital 259 unboundedness 77 corporate power 138, 141, 277–8 uncertainty 50, 129, 280 deterritorialization 253, 271, 274, 276, 277–9, hybrid networks 244 281–3, 285–7 waged work 316–17, 325 environment 139, 143, 145–6, 148, 149 UNCTAD 226, 230 firm-firm competition 94, 138–41 UNCTC 140 foreign direct investment (FDI) 140–1, 273, Underhill, G. 236 274, 276, 277–8 unemployment 22, 92, 94, 123, 127–8 foreign investment 79 Australia 308 German 333, 356–7, 360, 361 deroutinization 300–1 global business hierarchies 274–7, 278 employment creation schemes 307, 308, 310 global-local tensions 138–41, 144–9 male 64, 306 globalization 141, 148, 235–6, 237, 247 manufacturing industry 306 hierarchical internal structure 36–7 migrants 308 influence of national institutions 356–7 new service sector 318 international integration 39 restraining forces of 46 location 36–8, 39, 144–5, 146 structural 56 national origin imprint 356 women 307, 308 newly industrialized countries 363 youth 306, 307, 308 organizational models 138–9 see also works closures relations to states 44, 94–5, 138, 144–50 uneven development 3, 44, 46, 91, 92–3, restructuring 138 111–24, 255, 380 rising power of 350 advances in theory of 29 rootedness of 273 attachment to place 291, 292, 295, 299, 300, specialization of functions 39 303 state regulatory structures 146–7 capitalism 92, 291 strategic alliances 139, 141, 276 concrete forms of 30 territorialization 253, 271–4, 277–8, 279–84, Marxism 15, 30, 32, 92, 291, 295 285–9 and the nation-state 43 uneven development 36, 37 professional sector 114, 115, 116, 117 INDEX 477

service sector 114, 115, 116, 118 institutions 348 social structure 116, 119–22 the natural and the social 191 spatial division of labor 36–42, 111, 112, 113, new technologies 332, 341–3, 345, 347, 114–16, 118, 121, 122–4 348–9 spatial structures 93, 111, 112–13, 116–22, spatial glue 338 123 urban competitiveness 399–401 transnational corporations (TNCs) 36, 37 urban construction booms 211, 212 United Kingdom urban design 327 Christmas 59–60 urban development 129 employment changes 316–20 urban dissolution 338–9 Enterprise Zones 300, 314 urban enterprise zones 314 fair trade movement 174, 241–6 urban growth 134 flexible production systems 133 urban infrastructure 401 fur sealing 178 urban life, estheticization of 327 management and shop stewards movement 45 urban sociology 316, 328 nationalization 299 urban theory 135, 252 New Towns 299–300 urban uprisings 19 and Nigeria 213–14 urban-rural shift 121 occupational structure 116 urbanization open-door policies 44 China 374 regional modernization programs 302 global trends 341–2 salaries divide 122 oil boom economies 211, 212 sectoral divisions 117 Urry, J. 62, 119, 254 spatial division of labor 114–16, 118 economy as flows 68 spatial structures 116–22, 123 flexible production systems 128 telecommunications industry 39, 44 industrial spaces 327 television production 39 reflexivity 65 uneven development 93, 114–24 service sector 64 unionization trends 46 US Steel Corporation 108 works closures 290, 296, 297–8, 299 use-value United Nations Development Program (UNDP) circulation of 97–8, 100–2, 104, 106–7 226, 230 consumption of 102–3 United States household economy 86 Asian-Americans 377 management of 103–4 Baltimore living wage campaign 334, neglect of 32–3 395–401, 402 productive labor 98–100 communications technology 102 shifts in the objects of labor 107–8 flexible production systems 133–4, 135 user-producer interaction 352 foreign direct investment (FDI) 140 Usman, B. 217 fur sealing 178, 179, 181, 185 individualism 61 value institutional concessions 287–8 circulation of 100–2, 106–7 investment in China 362 construction in products 151–65 money as form of social disintegration 219 construction in workers 151–65 service-intensive economy 109 neoclassical economics 32 state-state competition 142–3, 144 productive labor 98 strategic alliances 141 see also surplus value; use-value trade unions 287 Vance, J. 101 wage restraint 79 Vancouver, Filipina domestic workers 333, wholesale trade 101 375–88 works closures 299 Veblen, Thorstein 16 Universal Declaration of Human Rights 28 Venables, A. J. 3 universal rights 63, 377, 379 Venezuela universality 26–7 modernity drive 210 urban agglomeration 127 oil resources 172, 173, 205–6, 209, 210–11 urban areas venture capital 117 existence in a network 191 Verbeke, A. 147 high technology industry 133–4 Vernon, R. 37, 276, 283 industrial elites 200 vertical disintegration 117, 129, 130, 134 478 INDEX

Vietnam, Nike workers 22, 395, 396, 397 welfare state 22, 267–8 Vietnam War 19, 21 expenditure on 310 Vilar, P. 207 reforms of 56, 252, 394 Villaneuva Larraya, G. 199, 201 restructuring of 254, 308, 345 Virilio, Paul 68, 339 welfare state expenditures 21 virtual cities 336 welfare-statism 93, 94, 127, 128, 135, 260 virtual communities 336, 346 Wellbery, D. E. 70 Vogel, E. 368 Wells, L. T. 147, 363 voice, encouragement of 51 Wenger, E. C. 358, 359 Vojta, G. 97 West Africa 214, 215, 216 von Bohm-Bawerk, E. 129 West Germany von Thünen, Johan Heinrich 3, 91 works closures 290, 298 see also Germany Wade, L. L. 143 Westaway, J. 36 wage restraint 79, 81 wetlands, Gambian 173, 220–34 waged work 4, 255 Wever, K. 356, 357, 359 acceptance of 293, 300–1, 303 Whatmore, S. 173–4, 175, 236, 237, 334 Aleuts 186–7 When old technologies were new (Marvin) 339 embodiment of 325–6 White, E. 363 employment changes in 316–20 White, G. 62 Gambian wetlands 224, 228, 229, 233 White, J. 68 living wage campaigns 334, 335n, 395–401, White, M. 311 402 Whitley, R. 61, 145–6, 356, 357 uncertainty of 316–17, 325 wholesale trade 101 women 64, 114, 130, 132, 152–4, 156–7, Wilde, Oscar 251 255–6, 306, 315, 318–20, 321–3, 395–9 Willems-Braun, B. 187 Wal-Mart 22 Williams, A. M. 258 Walby, S. 318, 322 Williams, Raymond 27, 28, 174, 175 Wales, works closures 290, 299 Williams, S. 59 Walker, R. 91–2, 95, 98, 100, 103, 104 Williamson, B. 295 Wall Street Journal 216 Williamson, O. 129 Wallerstein, I. 207 Wills, J. 252 Ward, C. 191 Wilson, P. 144 warehouse clubs 63 Wolch, J. R. 254–5, 308 Waring, M. 86 Wolff, R. 85 Wark, M. 62, 70 Womack, J. 350 Warri 213 women waterscape, Spanish 172, 189–91, 193–204 as care providers 312–13 depatrimonialization of water 199 control over own bodies 26 government intervention 199–200 educational performance 319 hydrological engineering mission 172, elite occupational groups 120 197–203 land access rights in the Gambia 173, 224–6, regeneracionism 172, 196, 197–204 228–9, 232, 233–4 Watts, Michael 236, 376, 387 in process of social reproduction 4 Gambian wetlands 223, 224, 232 representation of female body 74–5 oil boom economies 172–3, 209, 217 sexuality in the workplace 64, 323–4 Wayas, Joseph 214 social construction of female body 74 We Are Sinking in the Devil’s Excrement (Perez social construction in the workplace 151, 154, Alfonso) 205 157, 163 Webb, P. 229 see also feminism; gender; workers, female Webber, M. 258, 349 women in development (WID) projects 230 Weber, Alfred 3, 91 women’s banks 65 Weber, Max 20 Wong, S.-L. 62 webs of enterprise 139–40 Woodward, D. P. 147, 274 Weil, P. 223, 225 work 5 Weisbrot, M. 400 changing nature of 316–20 Weiss, A. 63 feminization of 40, 255–6, 315, 317, 318–20, welfare maximization 179, 181, 183, 259, 267 321–3, 384 welfare policies 48 informalization of 64 INDEX 479

intersubjective nature of 64 threats to everyday lives 301 new attitudes towards 317–18 unity of 295 priority of paid over unpaid 31, 64 works closures 298–9 see also labor; waged work working class movements 24 work culture 46 workplace work fragmentation 127 autonomy within 120 work routines 234 British workers’ strength within 45 work rules 127, 131 gender segregation 255–6, 305–7, 310, work studies, research biases 31, 32 313–14, 320, 321–3 workaholism 45 location of 316, 326–8 worker reproduction 107 management of 103 workers masculinity 322, 323–4, 326, 327 Leftist ideals of 32 Mexican maquiladora 95, 151–65 power from large agglomerations 43 physical construction of 316 radical kinds 31 production of value in 95, 151, 152–4, research biases 31, 32 156–65 social construction of 315–16, 322 reformulating practices 260 see also manual labor rigidities in 131 workers, female sexuality in 64, 323–4 branch-plant economy 40 social construction of women 151, 154, 157, flexible production systems 130, 132 163 flexible working 319 social construction of workers 315–16 horticultural projects in the Gambia 173, 221, social relations 254, 305–6 225–6, 229, 230–2, 233 workplace skills 52 Mexican maquiladora 152–4, 156–7 works closures 253–4, 290–303 migrant Filipina domestic workers 333, anti-closure campaigns 290–2, 295, 296–9, 375–88 302–3 Nike workers 395–9 World Bank 24, 213, 216, 226, 230, 231 as part-time workers 305, 306, 307, 308–9, World Development Movement 241 310, 319 World Trade Organization 266, 356 research biases 32 Wright, E. O. 292, 304 reserves of 123, 322 Wright, M. W. 95, 152, 155, 255, 401 as unpaid workers 64 Wrigley, N. 63 valuation in the workplace 151, 152–4, 156–65 Xerox corporation 357 in the waged workforce 64, 114, 130, 132, 152–4, 156–7, 255–6, 306, 315, 318–20, Yang, M.M-h. 365, 373 321–3, 395–9 Yearbook of Labor Statistics 396 wetland cultivation in the Gambia 173, 221, Yergin, D. 208 223–6, 228–32, 233–4 Yoffie, D. B. 147 workforce Young, A. 129 changes in nature of 306–7 Young, Andrew 395 product-cycle theory 37–8 Young, I. M. 326 working class 123, 304, 309, 317, 377 yuppies 317, 321 changing alliances 307 changing class relations 305 Zeitlin, J. 128 competition amongst 292 Zelizer, V. 208 conflict with capital 93, 292 Zhang, A. 366 exclusion from labor force 132 Zimmerer, K. 220 gender relations in Melbourne 305 Zonis, M. 207 legitimacy of class position 301 Zou, G. 366 legitimation of wage labor 303 Zuboff, S. 63 politicized 131 Zucker, L. 62 reducing strength of 22 Zukin, S. 320, 321, 327 social practices 302, 303 Zuwo, Bakin 215 state spatial policies 302 Zysman, J. 80, 128, 131