A Semi-Structural Methodology for Policy Counterfactuals∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Semi-Structural Methodology for Policy Counterfactuals∗ A Semi-structural Methodology for Policy Counterfactuals∗ Martin Berajay Massachusetts Institute of Technology and NBER November 26, 2020 Abstract I propose a methodology for constructing counterfactuals with respect to changes in policy rules which does not require fully specifying a structural model, yet is not subject to Lucas Critique. It applies to a class of dynamic stochastic models whose equilibria are well approx- imated by a linear representation. It rests on the insight that many such models satisfy a principle of counterfactual equivalence: they are observationally equivalent under a bench- mark policy rule and yield an identical counterfactual equilibrium under an alternative one. As an application, I use the methodology to quantify how US fiscal integration contributes to regional stabilization. ∗I am indebted to my advisors Fernando Alvarez, Erik Hurst, and Veronica Guerrieri, for their encouragement, support, and guidance during my stay in Chicago, for our many insightful conversations, and for their patience and skill in distilling the important points from my presentations. For their valuable suggestions, I owe George- Marios Angeletos, Andy Atkeson, Philip Haile, Ricardo Lagos, John Leahy, Martin Schneider, Gianluca Violante, and Ivan Werning as well as my classmates Jonathan Adams, Philip Barret, and Chanont Banternghansa. I thank those at the Review of Economic Studies Tour, Minneapolis Fed Junior Scholar Conference, SED, “Pizzanomics,” NBER SI Dynamic Equilibrium Models, and Macro Seminars at MIT, Harvard, Yale, Wharton, UCLA, GWU, Stanford, Princeton, NYU, Michigan, Northwestern, Cornell, Brown, LSE, BU, Berkeley, Fed Board, Atlanta Fed, Chicago Fed, BCRA, and Norges Bank. I thank all participants of the Capital Theory Working Group, especially Harald Uhlig and Nancy Stokey. Finally, I thank Juliette Caminade for her support and comments on preliminary versions of this paper. yE-mail: [email protected]. Web: economics.mit.edu/faculty/maberaja 1 Introduction Economists commonly follow either structural or reduced-form (and semi-structural) approaches in order to answer counterfactual questions. The former relies on specifying primitives of a par- ticular model and identifying its parameters. This is a daunting task whenever researchers are uncertain about features of alternative models that are both difficult to distinguish with avail- able data and reasonable a-priori. If counterfactuals differ under these alternative models, their credibility is undermined because they lack robustness. The latter approaches require less com- mitment to particular model assumptions and have proven very useful to identify consequences of observed policy changes that are robust across models, as in Sims (1980). However, the struc- tural approach is the leading paradigm for studying unobserved, potential changes in policy rules because structural counterfactuals are not subject to the critique in Lucas (1976). Are there then reasonable circumstances when we can analyze the consequences of a counterfactual policy rule change without knowing the full structure of a model? And, relatedly, can we tell which features of disparate models crucially determine such consequences? In this paper, I propose a novel semi-structural method for constructing counterfactuals with respect to policy rule changes. It is useful in circumstances when a linearization approach is reasonable and we do not wish to fully specify a structural model, yet we are worried about using approaches that contain too little information for the analysis to be immune to Lucas Critique — like those based on structural VARs.1 The method hinges on an insight about dynamic stochastic models with equilibria that are well approximated by a linear, stable recursive representation. The insight is that many models that can match an economy’s recursive equilibrium under a benchmark policy rule—i.e., observationally equivalent models—will also generate an identical counterfactual equilibrium under an alternative policy rule. Thus, regardless of their specific microfoundations, such models will satisfy this Principle of Counterfactual Equivalence. The method has three steps. The first is using data from an economy under a benchmark policy rule to estimate a recursive representation of the equilibrium of dynamic stochastic models (e.g., a SVAR representation). The second is describing assumptions that lead to linear restrictions on these models’ structural equilibrium equations (e.g., exclusion restrictions). They need to be enough to identify all combinations of policy-invariant parameters in these equations — what I call a structure — given the benchmark recursive representation. The last step is solving for the counterfactual recursive representation under an alternative policy rule, given the identified structure. As such, the method is in the spirit of the literature on “sufficient statistics” (e.g., Chetty (2009), Alvarez, Le Bihan, and Lippi (2016)) as well as earlier ideas advanced at the Cowles Commission (e.g., Koopmans (1950), Marschak (1974), Hurwicz (1962)).2 Together, the 1Bernanke, Gertler, and Watson (1997) and Sims and Zha (2006) propose to analyze counterfactual policy rules in SVARs by “zeroing-out” policy responses to shocks. Despite being subject to Lucas Critique, this methodology is com- monly used in many policy institutions, as are macroeconometric models like FRB/US. Del Negro and Schorfheide (2009) studies interest rate counterfactuals in New Keynesian models and asses the sensitivity of results to model misspecification by considering perturbations around their equilibrium SVAR representation. 2For an excellent discussion of these ideas see Heckman and Vytlacil (2007). As they explain, Marschak’s Maxim 1 benchmark and counterfactual representations define a set of structures — which is larger than a singleton containing the identified structure — characterizing models that can generate them, and, therefore, are counterfactually equivalent. The counterfactual is immune to Lucas Critique if the data was generated by a model whose structure is in this set too. I begin the paper by formally describing the principle of counterfactual equivalence, and give necessary and sufficient conditions for a model’s structure to belong to a counterfactually equiv- alent set (Section 2). Then, I present the semi-structural method to construct counterfactuals with respect to policy rule changes (Section 3), which I call Robust Policy Counterfactuals. Parallel to the general treatment, I present an example in the context of fiscal union models where members receive federal transfers according to a transfer policy rule which summarizes how resources are redistributed in a state-contingent manner. In the Online Supplementary Material S.4, I present additional examples in the context of New Keynesian and DMP-style search and matching mod- els. Finally, in order to show how to construct Robust Policy Counterfactuals in practice, I use US state-level data to quantify how fiscal unions contribute to regional stabilization (Section 4) — a question for which, despite plenty of empirical and theoretical research (e.g., Sala-i Martin and Sachs (1991), Asdrubali, Sorensen, and Yosha (1996), Feyrer and Sacerdote (2013), Farhi and Werning (2014)), quantitative work is surprisingly scarce (see Evers (2015) for an exception). There are two main findings. First, in a counterfactual US economy without a transfer policy rule, the standard deviation of employment across states increases by about 1 percent in the Great Recession and 1.5 percent in the long-run. This is because the rule redistributes resources from well to poorly performing states, thus stabilizing regional economies.3 Moreover, had we used the “zeroing-out” methodology in Sims and Zha (2006) to construct the long-run counterfactual, we would have found an increase of only 0.5 percent — thus underestimating the stabilizations gains by ignoring changes in agents’ behavior and expectation-formation as they internalize the policy change. These results can therefore help inform policy-makers when weighing the stabilization benefits against the costs of future fiscal arrangements for the European Monetary Union. Second, exogenous shifters of the Euler equation are a key feature of fiscal union models that generate large stabilization gains, whereas other features like the particular form of wage stickiness or adjustment costs, whether there is discounting due to behavioral agents, or how hand-to-mouth agents are introduced seem to be less crucial. The counterfactually equivalent set I study includes the structures of many models with such features. This finding can thus help organize and rationalize previous quantitative results coming from seemingly disparate models which implied small stabilization gains from fiscal integration (Evers (2015)) and risk-sharing arrangements more generally (as in Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland (1992) and the subsequent literature). says that for many questions of policy analysis it may not be necessary to fully identify a structural model, but only combinations of subsets of the structural parameters. Hurwicz (1962) noted that these should also be policy invariant. 3For a sense of magnitudes, aggregate output volatility declined by about 0.7 percent during the “Great Modera- tion” (Clarida, Gali, and Gertler (2000)). The stabilization gains from fiscal integration are of similar magnitude. 2 2 The Principle of Counterfactual Equivalence This section describes how to characterize a set of models that are counterfactually
Recommended publications
  • Putting Auction Theory to Work
    Putting Auction Theory to Work Paul Milgrom With a Foreword by Evan Kwerel © 2003 “In Paul Milgrom's hands, auction theory has become the great culmination of game theory and economics of information. Here elegant mathematics meets practical applications and yields deep insights into the general theory of markets. Milgrom's book will be the definitive reference in auction theory for decades to come.” —Roger Myerson, W.C.Norby Professor of Economics, University of Chicago “Market design is one of the most exciting developments in contemporary economics and game theory, and who can resist a master class from one of the giants of the field?” —Alvin Roth, George Gund Professor of Economics and Business, Harvard University “Paul Milgrom has had an enormous influence on the most important recent application of auction theory for the same reason you will want to read this book – clarity of thought and expression.” —Evan Kwerel, Federal Communications Commission, from the Foreword For Robert Wilson Foreword to Putting Auction Theory to Work Paul Milgrom has had an enormous influence on the most important recent application of auction theory for the same reason you will want to read this book – clarity of thought and expression. In August 1993, President Clinton signed legislation granting the Federal Communications Commission the authority to auction spectrum licenses and requiring it to begin the first auction within a year. With no prior auction experience and a tight deadline, the normal bureaucratic behavior would have been to adopt a “tried and true” auction design. But in 1993 there was no tried and true method appropriate for the circumstances – multiple licenses with potentially highly interdependent values.
    [Show full text]
  • The Art and Practice of Economics Research: Lessons from Leading Minds (Edward Elgar Publishing, 2012) Simon W. Bowmaker, New Yo
    The Art and Practice of Economics Research: Lessons from Leading Minds (Edward Elgar Publishing, 2012) Simon W. Bowmaker, New York University Interview with Robert E. Lucas, Jr. University of Chicago (July 25, 2011) 1 Robert Lucas was born in Yakima, Washington in 1937 and graduated with both a BA in history and a PhD in economics from the University of Chicago in 1959 and 1964 respectively. Between 1964 and 1975, he taught at the Graduate School of Industrial Administration at Carnegie Mellon University, before moving to the University of Chicago, where he has remained ever since, currently serving as the John Dewey Distinguished Service Professor in Economics and the College. Professor Lucas is widely acknowledged as one of the most influential macroeconomists of the twentieth century. He is perhaps best known for his work on the development of the theory of rational expectations, but he has also made significant contributions to the theory of investment, the theory of endogenous growth, the theory of asset pricing and the theory of money. In addition, he introduced the ‘Lucas critique’ of the use of econometric models in policy design. His most-cited articles in chronological order include ‘Expectations and the Neutrality of Money,’ Journal of Economic Theory (1972), ‘Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs,’ American Economic Review (1973), ‘Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,’ Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy (1976), ‘Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy,’ Econometrica (1978), and ‘On the Mechanics of Economic Development,’ Journal of Monetary Economics (1988). His books include Studies in Business- Cycle Theory (MIT Press, 1983), Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics (Harvard University Press, 1989), co-authored with Nancy Stokey and Edward Prescott, and Lectures on Economic Growth (Harvard University Press, 2004).
    [Show full text]
  • Browse the Program from the Conference
    Research and Policy: A Golden Minnesota Partnership ound economic research is the bedrock of solid economic policy. A CELEBRATION Great research, in turn, is often inspired by confronting key policy Sissues in a supportive and independent environment. This conference OF INTELLECTUAL honors an intellectual revolution galvanized by bringing these elements to- gether a half century ago and launching a remarkable relationship between INDEPENDENCE the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and the University of Minnesota. This alliance transformed how economists conduct research and how AND COLLEGIAL policy is made. In a sense, it was modeled on the close bond between Walter Heller, the COOPERATION policy-oriented chair of the Council of Economic Advisers under President John F. Kennedy, and Leonid Hurwicz, the brilliant theoretician and future Nobel laureate. They built the University’s world-class economics department that joined with Fed policymakers in the late 1960s to develop better forecasting models, an effort soon usurped by the then-radical theory of rational expectations. What followed were research and policy ranging from time consistency to early childhood education, from sovereign debt to distributional inequality, from real business cycles to too big to fail. And, along the way, improvements in forecasting—the spark that began it all. We’ve convened to review lessons learned over the past 50 years about successful policy-academia collaboration and to explore current research that will shape the theory and practice of economics over the next 50 years. This is a celebration of all involved, past and present, and of the spirit of intellectual independence and collegial cooperation that lies at the heart of the partnership.
    [Show full text]
  • Private Notes on Gary Becker
    IZA DP No. 8200 Private Notes on Gary Becker James J. Heckman May 2014 DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Private Notes on Gary Becker James J. Heckman University of Chicago and IZA Discussion Paper No. 8200 May 2014 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author. IZA Discussion Paper No. 8200 May 2014 ABSTRACT Private Notes on Gary Becker* This paper celebrates the life and contributions of Gary Becker (1930-2014).
    [Show full text]
  • NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ECONOMIC IMPERIALISM Edward
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ECONOMIC IMPERIALISM Edward P. Lazear Working Paper 7300 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7300 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1999 This research was supported in part by the National Science Foundation through the NBER. I am grateful to Kenneth Arrow, James Baron, Gary Becker, Roger Faith, Claudia Goldin, Morley Gunderson, Larry Katz, Robert Lucas, Michael Schwartz, Andrei Shleifer, and Nancy Stokey for helpful comments and discussions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 1999 by Edward P. Lazear. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Economic Imperialism Edward P. Lazear NBER Working Paper No. 7300 August 1999 ABSTRACT Economics is not only a social science, it is a genuine science. Like the physical sciences, economics uses a methodology that produces refutable implications and tests these implications using solid statistical techniques. In particular, economics stresses three factors that distinguish it from other social sciences. Economists use the construct of rational individuals who engage in maximizing behavior. Economic models adhere strictly to the importance of equilibrium as part of any theory. Finally, a focus on efficiency leads economists to ask questions that other social sciences ignore. These ingredients have allowed economics to invade intellectual territory that was previously deemed to be outside the discipline’s realm. Edward P. Lazear Graduate School of Business Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305-5015 and NBER [email protected] Edward P.
    [Show full text]
  • Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (Born 1921)
    K000067 Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (born 1921) Kenneth Arrow is the author of key post-Second World War innovations in economics that have made economic theory a mathematical science. The Arrow Possibility Theorem created the field of social choice theory. Arrow extended and proved the relationship of Pareto efficiency with economic general equilibrium to include corner solutions and non-differentiable pro- duction and utility functions. With Gerard Debreu, he created the Ar- row–Debreu mathematical model of economic general competitive equilibrium including sufficient conditions for the existence of market-clear- ing prices. Arrow securities and contingent commodities extend the model to cover uncertainty and provide a cornerstone of the modern theory of finance. Kenneth Arrow is a legendary figure, with an enormous range of contribu- tions to 20th-century economics, responsible for the key post-Second World War innovations in economic theory that allowed economics to become a mathematical science. His impact is suggested by the number of major ideas that bear his name: Arrow’s Theorem, the Arrow–Debreu model, the Ar- row–Pratt index of risk aversion, and Arrow securities. Four of his most distinctive achievements, all published in the brief period 1951–54, are as follows: Arrow Possibility Theorem. Social Choice and Individual Values (1951a) created the field of social choice theory, a fundamental construct in theo- retical welfare economics and theoretical political science. Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics. ‘An extension of the basic theorems of classical welfare economics’ (1951b) presents the First and Sec- ond Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics and their proofs without requiring differentiability of utility, consumption, or technology, and in- cluding corner solutions (zeroes in quantities of inputs or outputs).
    [Show full text]
  • Executive Committee Meeting of April 14, 2017
    AEA Papers and Proceedings 2018, 108: 621–627 https://doi.org/10.1257/pandp.108.621 Minutes of the Meeting of the Executive Committee Chicago, IL April 14, 2017 The first meeting of the 2017 Executive extensive discussion of the importance and likely Committee was called to order at 10:00 am on lasting effects of the research contributions of April 14, 2017 in the Malpensa Room of the candidates, the Honors and Awards Committee Hyatt Regency O’Hare Hotel, Chicago, IL. and Executive Committee, acting together as an Members present were: David Autor, Olivier Electoral College, VOTED to award the 2017 Blanchard, Nicholas Bloom, John Campbell, John Bates Clark Medal to Dave Donaldson. It Esther Duflo, Erica Field, Hilary Hoynes, was also VOTED to designate Philippe Aghion Rachel Kranton, Alan Krueger, Valerie Ramey, and Ernst Fehr as Foreign Honorary Members of Alvin Roth, Peter Rousseau, Robert Shiller, the Association. and Richard Thaler. Joel Sobel Chair and Nancy Stokey participated in part of( the )meet- Report of the Nominating Committee ing and Daron Acemoglu, Lawrence Katz, and Nordhaus .—Nordhaus, who chaired the Ariel Pakes participated by phone as mem- Committee( ) consisting also of Marianne bers of the Honors and Awards Committee. Bertrand, Dora( Costa, Dennis Epple, Drew William Nordhaus Chair participated in part Fudenberg, Malmendier, Cecilia Rouse, and of the meeting and (Ulrike) Malmendier partici- Hal Varian , reported nominations for the indi- pated by phone as members of the Nominating cated offices) in 2018: Vice-President: Susan Committee. Anil Kashyap Chair participated Athey, Pinelopi Goldberg, Robert Moffitt, and in part of the meeting and( Amy) Finkelstein Michael Woodford; Executive Committee: participated by phone as members of the Ad Matthew Gentzkow, Adriana Lleras-Muney, Hoc Committee on AEA Journals.
    [Show full text]
  • ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR* University of Chicago, USA
    MONETARY NEUTRALITY Prize Lecture, December 7, 1995 by ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR* University of Chicago, USA INTRODUCTION The work for which I have received this prize was part of an effort to under- stand how changes in the conduct of monetary policy can influence infla- tion, employment, and production. So much thought has been devoted to this question and so much evidence is available that one might reasonably assume that it had been solved long ago. But this is not the case: It had not been solved in the 1970s when I began my work on it, and even now this question has not been given anything like a fully satisfactory answer. In this lecture I will try to clarify what it is about the problem of bringing available evidence to bear on the assessment of different monetary policies that makes it so difficult, and to review the progress that has been made toward solving it in the last two decades. From the beginnings of modern monetary theory, in David Hume’s mar- velous essays of 1752, Of Money and Of Interest, conclusions about the effect of changes in money have seemed to depend critically on the way in which the change is effected. In formulating the doctrine that we now call the quantity theory of money, Hume stressed the units-change aspect of changes in the money stock, and the irrelevance of such changes to the behavior of rational people. “It is indeed evident,” he wrote in Of Money, “that money is nothing but the representation of labour and commodities, and serves only as a method of rating or estimating them.
    [Show full text]
  • A Course in Networks and Markets
    A Course in Networks and Markets Rafael Pass Cornell Tech Last updated: September 26, 2017 c 2018 Rafael Pass All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission by the author. ISBN: 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 First pre-edition: February 2017 Introduction In this course, using tools from game theory and graph theory, we explore how network structures and network effects play a role in economic and information markets. Let us start by providing an overview through a few examples. Markets with Network Effects: iPhone vs. Android Consider a mar- ket with two competing mobile phone brands, where the buyers are connected through a social network (see Figure 0.1). Each phone has some intrinsic value to a buyer, but the actual value of phone is affected by how many of the buyer's friends (i.e., the nodes connected to them in the social network) have the same phone|this is referred to a network effect: For instance, even if I prefer iPhones in isolation (i.e., they have a higher intrinsic value to me), I may prefer to get an Android phone (or even switch to one, if I currently have an iPhone), if enough of my friends have an Android. Some questions that naturally arise are: • Will there eventually be a stable solution, where everyone is happy with their phone, or will people keep switching phones? • If we arrive at a stable solution, what will it look like? (For instance, will everyone eventually have the same phone, or can we get a market for both?) A A A A I I A I Figure 0.1: An example of a small social network for the Android/iPhone game.
    [Show full text]
  • A Menu Cost Model with Price Experimentation∗
    A Menu Cost Model with Price Experimentation∗ David Argente Chen Yeh University of Chicago University of Chicago February 15, 2016 Preliminary and incomplete Abstract We document a new set of salient facts on pricing moments over the life-cycle of U.S. products. First, entering products change prices twice as often as the average product. Second, the average size of these adjustments is at least 50 percent larger than the av- erage price change. We argue that a menu cost model with price experimentation can rationalize these findings. The firm is uncertain about its demand elasticity under this setting, but can experiment with its price to endogenously affect its posterior beliefs which are updated in a Bayesian fashion. As a result, firms face the trade-off between increasing the speed of learning through price experimentation and maximizing their static profits. This mechanism can endogenously generate large price changes, without the use of fat-tailed idiosyncratic shocks, and can replicate the life-cycle patterns we document. We show quantitatively that the cumulative output effect of an unantic- ipated monetary shock is 40 percent larger than in Golosov and Lucas(2007). On impact, selection is weakened as the experimentation motive alters the distribution of desired price changes and decreases the fraction of firms near the margin of adjustment. Furthermore, the notion of a product's life-cycle generates an additional form of cross- sectional heterogeneity in the frequency of price adjustment. This causes the monetary shock to be further propagated. JEL Classification Numbers: D4, E3, E5 Key words: menu cost, firm learning, optimal control, fixed costs, monetary shocks, hazard rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Making a Miracle Author(S): Robert E
    Making a Miracle Author(s): Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Source: Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 2 (Mar., 1993), pp. 251-272 Published by: The Econometric Society Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2951551 Accessed: 07/12/2010 13:08 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=econosoc. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. The Econometric Society is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Econometrica. http://www.jstor.org Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 2 (March, 1993), 251-272 MAKING A MIRACLE1 BY ROBERT E. LUCAS, JR. This lecture surveys recent models of growth and trade in search of descriptions of technologies that are consistent with episodes of very rapid income growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Paul Milgrom to Receive CME Group-MSRI Prize in Innovative Quantitative Applications
    February 6, 2018 Paul Milgrom to Receive CME Group-MSRI Prize in Innovative Quantitative Applications Distinguished Panel to Discuss Leading Research on Financial Market Design before Award Ceremony CHICAGO, Feb. 6, 2018 /PRNewswire/ -- CME Group, the world's leading and most diverse derivatives marketplace, and the Mathematical Sciences Research Institute (MSRI) announced Paul Milgrom, Shirley and Leonard Ely Professor of Humanities and Sciences in the Department of Economics at Stanford University, as the 2017 recipient of the CME Group- MSRI Prize in Innovative Quantitative Applications. A ceremony honoring Milgrom will take place at CME Group headquarters on Monday, Feb. 12, at 9:30 a.m. CT and will feature a dynamic discussion on the topic of leading research on financial market design. Past CME Group-MSRI Prize winners have included distinguished luminaries in economics and mathematics. Five out of 10 of these past recipients have gone on to receive the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences. A complete list of past recipients is available at cmegroup.com. The CME Group-MSRI Prize recognizes individuals who contribute original concepts in mathematical, statistical or computational methods for the study of the markets' behavior and global economics. Milgrom has done extensive research on this year's panel topic. He is best known for his contributions to microeconomic theory, his pioneering innovations in the practical design of multi-item auctions, and the extraordinary successes of his students and academic advisees. "I am honored to be able to accept this prize for myself and to honor my collaborators, who have helped me both to conduct my most important research and to bring my ideas to practice," said Milgrom.
    [Show full text]