Geoeconomic Policies for Regional Development: Turkey As a Catalyst for Eastern Europe

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Geoeconomic Policies for Regional Development: Turkey As a Catalyst for Eastern Europe ISSN 1392-1258. EKONOMlKA 2005 69 GEOECONOMIC POLICIES FOR REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT: TURKEY AS A CATALYST FOR EASTERN EUROPE Sukru Inan Research Assistant Inonu University, Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences, Department of Economics Malatya, Turkey Phone: +90 (0) 422 341 0010 Office: 4343 Fax: +90 (0) 422 341 00 43 E-mail: [email protected] This paper examines the influence of geoeconomic policies on development. The new age is characterized by not political or ideological rivalry but by economic competition. States do not aim at conquering lands but rather at dominating and controlling markets. That process brings the discussion that the age is whether a geoeconomic age or a neo-mercantilist age with the writings of pundit writers of geoeconomics in terms of the economic policies of developed and developing countries. In the geoeconomic world developed countries mainly apply neo-mercantilist policies towards the developing countries, and as a response developing countries that were "second orders" or "middle powers" of the geopolitical era generate their own regional geo-mercantilist policies and closer economic relations with neighbor countries. Turkey's strategic and geopolitical importance is continuing with its geoeconomic importance in the new era. Since the 1980s Turkey's growth and industry-oriented policies have shifted from the realm of public policy to a market-driven domain. And later, with the collapse of the USSR and the end of the Cold War, the "Iron Curtain" around Turkey has absented. These two transformations gave Turkey a great chance with her historical, cultural and economic ties to form a geoeconomic space and to become an engine of regional development. This study investigates the importance of Turkey for regional development with its geoeconomic policies in terms of energy. trade, and investment policies. Turkey as a bridge or a frontier between East and West could play an effective role. For Eastern Europe, Turkey will create a catalyst effect as a bridge, however, its effect will be an impediment as a frontier. Keywords: geoeconomics, neo-mercantilism, geo-mercantilism, Eastern Europe, Turkey Introduction economic policies. From this point of view I The central argument of this theoretical stressed on some concepts, which are geoeco­ paper is that in the new world order geoecono­ nomics, neomercantilism and geomercantilism, mics is the primary instrument of states' to explain the new formations on the globc. 30 My argument rests on the proposition that cohesion. The New World Order emerges second order states (Turkey is taken into instead of the Old World Order as the novel consideration in this paper) will play an framework that guides the behavior of interna­ effective role in the geoeconomic world with tional institutions and of the important their geographical position, population and regional entities. The power behind today's economic potential. headlines is the eagerness of a nation state to Until recently, most of those who studied expand its markets, guarantee its supply lines power thought of it largely in geopolitical and thrust upon its antagonist its competitive rather than geoeconomic terms. But events advantages. The central feature of the era of over the last two decades have resulted in Geopolitics was immobility. The superpower increased attention to geoeconomic power and rivalry had a static effect on the overall global conflicts in international relations (Nester, situation. In the days of Geoeconomics the 1995). primary feature is dynamism. There is an The British economist Hawtrey wrote of a interrelation between markets, states and world where 'the major concern of the state is technology. prestige. The means to prestige is power. Power is economic productivity capable of being Geoeconomics applied as a force'. Samuel Huntington (1993) has expressed the same point in a modern Geoeconomics was initially part of geopolitics. th idiom 'Economists are blind to the fact that Since the beginning of the 20 century geoeco­ economic activity is a source of power, as well nomists have been studying the relationships as well being. It is, indeed, probably the most between "homo economicus" and space, the important source of power and in a world in influence of space on production and goods which military conflict between major states is flows, as well as the possibilities of space usage unlikely economic power will be increasingly for the progress of economic activities. Space important in determining the primacy or factors are comprised of geographical location, subordination of states'. The model which is the distribution of natural and human re­ implicit in this view is a kind of zero sum game sources, location of production knots and in which the gains of one country (primacy) poles, the structure and specification of are seen as canceling out the losses of another railroad and telecommunication networks, (subordination) even if both achieve growing costs of exploitation and transportation of prosperity. It has been called 'geo-economics' resources, etc. From an epistemological point by Edward Luttwak (1990). 'the pursuit of of view, geoeconomics is a synthesis of adversarial goals with commercial means'. economics, history and politics. Geoeconomics National security involves winning this is an applied science, which takes into account economic 'war' (Cable, 1995). spatial, historical, cultural, ethno-psycho­ Our age is characterized by three main and logical, etc. factors. It elaborates technologies, powerful trends (Andrianopoulos, 2004): for promoting national economic interests Geoeconomics is replacing Geopolitics as the abroad and for strategic operating in geoeco­ major force behind inter-state relations. New nomic space, with the aim of identifying and Economy rivals Old Economy as the engine of occupying the most advantageous patterns and growth and as the principal means of social niches that will assure the participation of the 31 national economy in global product creation states, especially those regarding international and global income distribution (Prohnitchi, trade. Finally, the geographer and former 2003). Herodote editor Michel Foucher (1997) has The old version of state rivalry is now called also discussed geoeconomics as a new dogma. geoeconomics. Countries acting as a firm He emphasizes that geoeconomics is practiced would maximize their profits. Some of the by states among which war is no longer strategies they might use against their oppo­ conceivable. Geoeconomics point out the fact nents are investment capital provided by the that states compete with each other for state for industry, subsidizing product develop­ economic power, and no more for territorial ment, and penetrating the market. This is what power (Mamadouh, 1999). is called geoeconomics. Some other strategies "Geoeconomics elevates the entrepre­ are to use tariffs through taxes, quota limits to neurial interests of investors and consumers; cope with too little money. In the past, most in contrast to the geopolitical focus on national people thought that in the future there would borders and place, geoeconomic discourse be no trading blocks, but the fact remains that privileges networks and pace; and instead of they are actually increasing. In economic terms, concentrating international politics on building it is wise to maintain these relationships with alliances for "security" against supposed "evil other countries, but countries do not always empires," geoeconomics is primarily con­ act according to economic terms. The logic of cerned with building international partnership conflict between two countries involved in war that advance "harmonization," "efficiency," is a zero-sum relationship. That means that "economic leverage" and "growth" against the when one of them has gains, the other must supposed threats of political "radicalism," have losses. In commerce, both countries can "anachronism" and "anarchy." Both Sum and gain (Luttwak, 2004). Jessop use geoeconomics in a similarly critical, Geoeconomics purports to place interna­ postnational way, applying it largely to the tional politics on an economic basis. In the macro, continental-scale dynamics associated words of Edward Luttwak, "everyone, it with the relations between the so-called "triad" appears, now agrees that the methods of regions of the EU, NAFTA and the Yen-bloc commerce are displacing military methods - (Spark and Lawson, 2004). with disposable capital in lieu of firepower, According to Savona and Jean (2004), civilian innovation in lieu of military-technical geoeconomics as a discipline deals with aspects advancement, and market penetration in lieu of international competition in which the main of garrisons and bases. States, as spatial entities protagonists are not corporations, trusts or structured to jealously delimit their own banks, but states. The interpretation of world territories, will not disappear but reorient development emphasizes economic and themselves toward geoeconomics in order to geopolitical processes seen as interstate rivalry. compensate for their decaying geopolitical "Geoeconomics is economic geopolitics which roles." In geoeconomic state rivalry, the "logic is coming to replace the predominantly military of conflict" will be expressed in the "grammar geopolitics of the past", write the authors in of commerce" (Owens, 1999). the preface to the Russian edition. According to Lorot (1997), geoeconomics There are many definitions of "geoeco­ is the analysis of the economic strategies
Recommended publications
  • Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: the Role of Economic Factors
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Crossref Hindawi Publishing Corporation ISRN Economics Volume 2013, Article ID 954071, 14 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/954071 Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: The Role of Economic Factors Natalia Melgar,1 Juliette Milgram-Baleix,2 and Máximo Rossi1 1 Department of Economics, University of the Republic, Constituyente 1502, 11200 Montevideo, Uruguay 2 Department of Economic eory and History, University of Granada, Campus Cartuja, 18071 Granada, Spain Correspondence should be addressed to Natalia Melgar; [email protected] Received 8 November 2012; Accepted 26 November 2012 Academic Editors: T. M. Dall and D. Mitra Copyright © 2013 Natalia Melgar et al. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. We �nd that individuals’ opinions concerning protectionist policies match with how their revenue could be affected in the medium or long term by trade liberalisation in line with predictions of the comparative advantage models. An adverse macroeconomic context (large increase in the unemployment rate or in�ation rate) increases protectionist attitudes, thus re�ecting that people do not trust that free trade will lead to lower prices or create jobs despite trade theory optimism. People share a mercantilist view of trade since more imports increase protectionism support, while people positively value exports, especially in small countries. Regarding policy measures, while protectionist measures do not in�uence protectionism support in general, easy access to exports reduces people’s support for protectionism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Food Insecurity in East Asia
    Rice, politics and power: the political economy of food insecurity in East Asia Paul Belesky Master of International Studies (International Relations) The University of Queensland A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy The University of Queensland, 2016 School of Political Science and International Studies School of Social Science Abstract This thesis has three main objectives: (1) to provide a critical political economy study of the complex interplay between rice, politics and power in East Asia; (2) to make a contribution to understanding the evolution of the regional and global food system through an historically-contextualised exploration of the political economy of rice in the East Asian region; and (3) to make a contribution towards an alternative analytical framework for the political economy of food insecurity in the region. This study focuses on the agricultural commodity of rice as a prism through which to examine and explore the complex and multidimensional nature of food insecurity in the region, with rice providing a lens through which to explore social relations and relations of power that underpin the political economy of food and agriculture. This study has identified a gap in literature in relation to a contemporary analysis of the political economy of rice, with a second gap appearing in relation to the evolution of the global food system from an East Asian perspective. This thesis aims to make a contribution towards addressing these gaps in literature. With these objectives in mind, this thesis responds
    [Show full text]
  • On the Crisis of the “Liberalization Policy” in the Economics of Interdependence
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Lorenz, Detlef Article — Digitized Version On the crisis of the “liberalization policy” in the economics of interdependence Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Lorenz, Detlef (1978) : On the crisis of the “liberalization policy” in the economics of interdependence, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Verlag Weltarchiv, Hamburg, Vol. 13, Iss. 7/8, pp. 169-173, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02929188 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/139551 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu WORLD TRADE On the Crisis of the "Liberalization Policy" in the Economics of Interdependence by Detlef Lorenz, Berlin* In spite of all protestations and exhortations it is a fact that trade liberalization, the modern version of free trade, is caught in a crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • 9. Information Technology in the Learning Economy: Challenges for Developing Countries Dieter Ernst and Bengt-Åke Lundvall
    9. Information technology in the learning economy: challenges for developing countries Dieter Ernst and Bengt-Åke Lundvall The engine of growth should be technological change, with international trade serving as a lubricating oil and not as fuel. (Lewis 1978, p. 74) Both the pace and the acceleration of innovation are startling; nay terrify- ing...No one can predict the ...range of skills which will need to be amassed to create and take advantage of the next revolution but one. (And thinking about the next but one is what everyone is doing. The game is already over for the next.) (Anderson 1997) Research in industrialized countries has shown that the ability to learn determines the economic success not only of firms and industries but also of whole regions (industrial districts) and countries (OECD 1996a, 1996b, 1996c). This has given rise to the concept of the learning economy, which is based on the following propositions (Lundvall and Johnson 1994; Lundvall 1994, 1996): learning is an interactive, socially embedded process; its efficiency depends on the institutional setup, the national innovation system. The content of the knowledge generated through learning is criti- cal: tacit knowledge is essential for adjusting to change (flexibility) and for implementing change (innovation). This chapter inquires how the concept of the learning economy can be applied to the requirements of developing countries (DCs). Its main purpose is to develop an analytical framework for understanding how learning and capability formation can foster industrial upgrading, with special emphasis on the spread of information technology (IT). Under what conditions can DCs use this set of generic technologies to improve their learning capabilities? As a growing amount of knowledge becomes accessible through worldwide information networks, the establishment of national IT capabilities should help to accelerate knowledge creation and diffusion.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Response to the Great Depression of the 1930S: Turkish Neomercantilism in the Balkan Context
    Turkish Studies ISSN: 1468-3849 (Print) 1743-9663 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/ftur20 Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context Adnan Türegün To cite this article: Adnan Türegün (2016) Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context, Turkish Studies, 17:4, 666-690, DOI: 10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 Published online: 01 Sep 2016. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 234 View related articles View Crossmark data Citing articles: 1 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ftur20 Download by: [Cankaya Universitesi] Date: 22 September 2017, At: 06:32 TURKISH STUDIES, 2016 VOL. 17, NO. 4, 666–690 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context Adnan Türegün Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada ABSTRACT In examining the Turkish response to the crisis of the 1930s, this paper contributes to existing literature at three levels: economic policy conception, comparative case selection, and mode of explanation. First, it takes a holistic approach to economic policy (neomercantilism) by looking at its foreign trade and finance (autarkic), microeconomic (etatist), and macroeconomic (neoclassical orthodox) dimensions. Second, it locates the Turkish response in the Balkan context, where other small states responded to comparable stimuli. Third, while viewing the macroeconomic conservatism of Turkish neomercantilism as a situational necessity, it explains the autarkic dimension by the shared German metropolitan linkages of the Balkans as a region, and the etatist dimension by the Kemalist bureaucracy’s larger room for maneuver in a context of wider gap between political modernization and economic backwardness.
    [Show full text]
  • Neomercantilism and Great-Power Energy Competition in Central Asia and the Caspian
    University of Louisville ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository Faculty Scholarship Summer 2014 Neomercantilism and great-power energy competition in Central Asia and the Caspian. Charles E. Ziegler University of Louisville, [email protected] Rajan Menon Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.library.louisville.edu/faculty Part of the Asian Studies Commons, Comparative Politics Commons, International Relations Commons, and the Soviet and Post-Soviet Studies Commons Original Publication Information This article was originally published in Strategic Studies Quarterly, volume 38, issue 4, in Summer 2014. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Neomercantilism and Great-Power Energy Competition in Central Asia and the Caspian Charles E. Ziegler Rajan Menon Russia, China, and the United States are vying for political influence and control of natural resources in Central Asia in what has been labeled a twenty-first-century Great Game.1 Among the conditions drawing these major powers to the region are its location at the heart of the Eur- asian landmass and its bountiful natural resources. China and Russia are driven in roughly equal measure by political and economic consider- ations. They have adopted neomercantilist policies (i.e., state-directed efforts aimed at making asymmetric economic gains at the expense of competitors, a concept we discuss at length below) to realize their goals in the region.
    [Show full text]
  • Saudi Neomercantilism in the Oil Price
    The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at: https://www.emerald.com/insight/2631-3561.htm REPS 5,1 Saudi neomercantilism in the oil price war Ahmed Samir Mahdi Department of Political Science, Faculty of Business Administration, 2 Economics and Political Science, The British University in Egypt, Cairo, Egypt Received 10 October 2019 Accepted 10 October 2019 Abstract Purpose – The so-called “oil price war” of 2014-2016 took place between several main global oil producers; OPEC (led by Saudi Arabia), Russia and the newcomer; American tight oil or fracking oil. These oil producers were competing against each other over market shares in the global oil market, by maintaining their high oil production rates, even if this led to a decline in oil prices and a reduction in revenues from oil sales. As energy politics need more coverage in International Political Economy (IPE) theory, this paper aims to argue that Saudi Arabia’s policies during the oil price war of 2014-2016 reflected a policy of neomercantilism, which is the IPE equivalent of the school of realism in International Relations (IR). Design/methodology/approach – This paper tests for neomercantilism by testing three of its main definitional components. The first definitional component is that the state, as the political authority, intervenes in the economic decisions. The second component is the primacy of the state interests over business corporate profits, or the primacy of political and security considerations over short-term economic and corporate profit considerations. The third is the zero-sum or relative gains nature of dealings between states.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy and Public Policy
    POLITICAL ECONOMY AND PUBLIC POLICY Deepak Lal TIIE INTERNAI'IONAI. CETrER FOR ECONOMic GiRo\vIi is a non-profit research institute founded in 1985 to stimulate international discussions on eco­ nomic policy, economic growth. and human welfare. The Center sponsors research, pxiblic'ations. and conferences in cooperation with an international network of correspondent institututes. which distribute publications ofboth the Center and other network members to I)olif'y audiences around the world. The Center's research and publications program is organized aroulnd five series: Sector Studies: Country Studies: Studies in I llman evelopment and Social Wellare: Occasional Papers; and a Reprint Series. The Center is affiliated with tihe Institute for Conteniporarv Studies, and has headquarters in Panama and a home office in San Francisco, California. Publication signifies that the Center believes a work to be a competent treatment worthy of public consideration. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions of a vork are entirely those of the author and should not be attributed to ICEG. its affiliated organizations, its board of overseers, or organizations thai support ICEG. For further inlonnation, please conta('t the International Center for Economic Growth, 243 Kearny Street, San Francisco, Califbrnia. 94108, USA. Phone (415) 981-5353: Fax (415) 986-4878. ICEG Board of Overseers Y. Seyvid Abdulai Woo-Choong Kim OPEC Fund Ibr International Daeiwoo Corp., Korea I'velopment, Austria Adalbert Krieger Vasena Abdalatif AI-I laniad Argentina Arab FAnd.fbr Economic and Pedro Pablo Kuczynski Social Developmenit. KutVait USA Nicolils Ardito-Barletta Agustin Legorreta Chairman.Panama InverlatS.A., Mexico Roy Ash Sol Linowitz Ash Capital Partnership.USA CoudertBros., USA Raymond Barre Jorge Mejia Salazar France Colombia Roberto Campos Saburo Okita NationalSenator,Brazil Institute for Domestic and Inter- Carlos Manuel Castillo nationalPoliciesStudies.Japan CosiaRica Tonfis Pastoriza A.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. Introduction: the Fall of the Soviet Union and the Resurgence of Russia
    1. Introduction: The Fall of the Soviet Union and the Resurgence of Russia Kristi Elaine Govella1 University of California, Berkeley Vinod K. Aggarwal University of California, Berkeley 1.1 Introduction Much has happened in the two decades since the end of the Cold War. In the immediate aftermath of the fall of the Soviet Union, Russia went through a period of dramatic domestic political change and uncertainty in the foreign policy arena. A country that was once a superpower in a bipolar world began to doubt its place in the international system—and not without reason: the collapse of the USSR left Russia in a state of economic, political, and social turmoil, marked by declining economic output and increasing inflation, foreign debt, and budget deficits. Other problems included lack of law and order, loss of central control over the periphery, conflicts in Chechnya, rampant corruption, chronic political instability, and a severe financial crisis. At the start of Vladimir Putin’s presidency, the country’s share of world GDP had fallen to just 1.5 percent, in 1 The authors would like to thank Sarah Garding, Maria Vassilieva, and Theocharis Grigoriadis for their helpful comments and feedback. Kathy Bowen, Peter Volberding, and Robert Nelson provided valuable research assistance. contrast to the 21 percent share held by the United States.2 Moreover, Russia’s economic and political transition during the 1990s was fraught with complications and disappointments. The last decade, however, has witnessed Russia’s reemergence onto the international scene, as well as a recentralization of power under former president Vladimir Putin, the current prime minister of Russia.
    [Show full text]
  • (Trade) War: Examining the Relationship Between The
    The Art of (Trade) War: Examining the Relationship Between the Political Economies of the U.S. and China Through the Lens of Previous Machiavellian Moments A Honors Political Science Thesis by Hunter D. Snowden Presented to the Department of Political Science in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree with honors of Bachelor of Arts Trinity College Duke University March 2019 1 Contents Acknowledgments…………………………………………………………………3 1. Abstract…………………………………………………………………………….4 2. Introduction………………………………………………………………………...5-9 2.1. Machiavellian Moment 2.2. Hegemonic Stability Theory 3. Research Question………………………………………………………………….9 4. Literature Review………………………………………………………………….10-22 4.1. Mercantilism 4.2. Chinese System of Political Economy 4.3. U.S. System of Political Economy 4.4. U.S. – Chinese Relations 4.5. Gaps in Previous Research 5. Results……………………………………………………………………………...22-35 5.1. England vs. The Netherlands 5.2. US vs. China 5.3. China & England 5.4. US & The Netherlands 6. Conclusion………………………………………………………………………….35-41 7. Bibliography………………………………………………………………………..41-45 2 Acknowledgements First, I would like to thank Professor Edmund Malesky for all of the advice and supervision he provided to me throughout the writing of this paper. Without his suggestions and revisions, I would not have been able to get to this point. I would also like to thank my friends and family who were willing to put up with me sending them countless versions to read over and revise. Finally, I would like to thank Duke University and the political science department for this opportunity. I have learned a great deal not only about this topic and how to write a thesis but about myself and what I can achieve.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Political Economy: Understanding the International
    Global Political Economy Global Political Economy UNDERSTANDING THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ORDER Robert Gilpin WITH THE ASSISTANCE OF Jean M. Gilpin PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD Copyright 2001 by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 3 Market Place, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1SY All Rights Reserved Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Gilpin, Robert. Global political economy : understanding the international economic order / Robert Gilpin with the assistance of Jean M. Gilpin. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-691-08676-1 (alk. paper) — ISBN 0-691-08677-X (pbk.) 1. International economic relations. 2. Free trade. 3. International finance. 4. Technological innovations—Economic aspects. 5. Economic development. I. Gilpin, Jean M. II. Title. HF1359 .G5516 2001 337—dc21 00-051684 This book has been composed in Sabon. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (R 1997) (Permanence of Paper) www.pup.princeton.edu Printed in the United States of America by Princeton University Press, Princeton & Oxford 10987654321 10987654321 (Pbk.) Contents List of Abbreviations and Acronyms ix Preface xi ONE. The New Global Economic Order 3 Changes in the World Economy 5 Intellectual Perspectives 13 My Perspective: State-centric Realism 15 Purpose of Economic Activity 23 Conclusion 24 TWO. The Nature of Political Economy 25 What You Seek Is What You Find 31 The Nature of an Economy 38 Embeddedness of the Economy 41 Conclusion 45 THREE. The Neoclassical Conception of the Economy 46 The Discipline of Neoclassical Economics 46 Nature of a Market 54 Method of Comparative Statics 57 Intellectual Limitations 60 Economists and Public Policy 69 Comparison of Economics and Political Economy 74 Conclusion 76 FOUR.
    [Show full text]
  • Prof. Dimitar Hadjinikolov, Dsc Interventionist Theories 1
    Prof. Dimitar Hadjinikolov, DSc www.hadjinikolov.pro Interventionist Theories 1. International trade in the global political economy – overview 2. Mercantilism 3. Neomercantilism 3. International trade and balance of payment statistics Under p. 1 Mercantilism vs liberalism? Q: Who is the winner? A: Nobody yet. 2 The role of the State in the Economy Intervention Strategy Matrix 3 Interventionism in contemporary economic policy Interventionism in contemporary economic policy is also: - dirigisme, - Dirigisme, an approach to economic development emphasizing the positive role of state intervention. The term dirigisme is derived from the French word diriger (“to direct”), which signifies the control of economic activity by the state. Preventing market failure was the basic rationale of this approach. Dirigisme was introduced in France following World War II to promote industrialization and protect against foreign competition, and it was subsequently mimicked in East Asia. Dirigiste policies often include centralized economic planning, directing investment, controlling wages and prices, and supervising labour markets. Q: Are there some positive examples of dirigisme? What about China? - functionalism, socialism, sustainable development 4 Economic liberalism More about liberal international trade theories – in the next lectures! We are leaving in a time of a transition from markets with national regulations to a global market with supranational regulations 5 2. Mercantilism The underlying principles of mercantilism included Jean-Baptiste Colbert
    [Show full text]