The Formula of Trumponomics the U.S

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Formula of Trumponomics the U.S The Formula of Trumponomics The u.S. Reverts to Neomercantilism and Protectionism to Gather Strength for a New Breakthrough Alexander V. Losev Abstract This article examines the global problem of the ongoing transformation of the U.S. policy from globalization to neomercantilism and protectionism—in par- ticular, the reasons why one of the results of deep structural changes in the world economy is the erosion of the U.S. hegemony and the rise of political competition in the world. The author analyzes this change in the context of the transfer of management functions from the state to corporations and central banks in the post-indus- trial economies. The article attempts to answer two key questions: 1. Is Donald Trump right in pursuing a tough economic policy, or is there a real alternative to ‘Trumponomics’ that could strengthen the U.S. position in the growing global competition? 2. What economic policy is preferable for GDP growth and citizens’ welfare: monetary or fiscal? The author comes to the conclusion that Trump’s rise to power was not a domes- tic political irregularity or the result of foreign influence on American democra- Alexander V. Losev is CEO of Sputnik Assets Management, JSC. e-mail: [email protected] Sputnik Assets Management, JSC Floor 10, BTs Pollars, Bldg. B, Derbenevskaya Naberezhnaya 11, Moscow 115114, Russia E-mail: [email protected] This article is greatly expanded and revised version of the paper written for the Valdai Inter- national Discussion Club. The original copy is available at: http://ru.valdaiclub.com/a/valdai- papers/valdayskaya-zapiska-87/?sphrase_id=57934 DOI: 10.31278/1810-6374-2018-16-3-66-88 66 RUSSIA IN GLOBAL AFFAIRS The Formula of Trumponomics cy institutions, but a historical inevitability in the face of the global challenges facing the United States. Prospects of the U.S. losing economic leadership are discussed, together with domestic and foreign policies aimed to prevent that. The study was based on the analysis of macroeconomic data of the United States and major regions of the world, as well as on the analysis of monetary and economic cycles. The dynamics of GDP growth and its nominal values, as well as the dynamics of industrial production in the United States and in the macro-regions of the world were considered with GDP and GNP compared on a component basis. Keywords: Trumponomics, neomercantilism, globalization, soft power, hard power, national interests. rumponomics’ is a popular term coined to describe the economic policy of the donald Trump administration, based on fiscal reflation and rigid neomercantilism, aimed at ‘Tdeveloping industry and infrastructure, and supported by the return of corporate capital and an active “peace through strength” foreign policy. THE “GOLDEN AGE” OF GLOBALIZATION AND ITS COMPLETION BY 2016 With the establishment of the united States’ absolute leadership in the early 1990s, globalization became the main idea of ​​the american elites. an integration process was launched to transform the structure of national economies and political relations between countries into geo-economy. The world, with few exceptions, did not challenge the u.S. leader- ship and took for granted the american rules of the game and the sys- tem of global labor specialization. It agreed to a reduction of national sovereignty in favor of u.S.-controlled international organizations and institutions such as the Imf, the World Bank, the WTo, and the exchange Stabilization fund, to the transnationalization of financial markets, to the role of the u.S. federal Reserve as the issuer of a world reserve currency, the dollar, to the rules of international trade, and unequal distribution of revenues. VOL. 16 • No. 3 • JULY – SEPTEMBER • 2018 67 Alexander V. Losev each country that played by these rules derived benefits from global- ization. It was globalization that ensured fast economic growth for most regions of the world and their accelerated technological devel- opment. The united States, as befits the leader, became the main ben- eficiary. The decades-long expansion of international trade earned it an additional one trillion dollars a year (hufbauer and Jung, 2016). however, the absence of serious political challenges to the u.S. leadership, economic globalization and the financialization of markets have resulted in geopolitics degenerating into geo-economics. Central banks have begun to influence economic processes, including the lives and incomes of citizens, corporations, budgets and economic cycles in their own and other countries, much more than democratically elect- ed politicians and parliaments do, as stated in The Economist under the headline “The Wars of Independence” (anon, 2017). Whereas ten years ago the u.S. and the eu were the main contrib- utors to global GdP, jointly accounting for 54 percent of it, now this figure has decreased to 45 percent. Simultaneously, the asian mega- region (South and Southeast asia) is ahead of the u.S. by 5.7 percent and ahead of the eu by 8.3 percent in terms of nominal GdP. The share of the Indo-Pacific region in global GdP is 30 percent, while that of the eu and the united States is 46 percent. at the same time, China’s nominal GdP increased from $3.5 trillion to $12.3 trillion be- tween 2007 and 2017, that is, 3.5 times over ten years. Statistics show that the breakthrough occurred in 2016, when east asian countries, in particular China, “the world’s factory,” became a new beneficiary of globalization (The World Bank, 2017). The united States suddenly realized that a time was coming when a continuation of current geo-economic processes would weaken american leader- ship and lead to a further growth of the asia-Pacific region. The u.S. faced a growing trade deficit ($566 billion in 2017) and an increase in public debt to $21 trillion. THE EROSION OF SOFT POWER The soft power of the u.S. and the attractiveness of democratic val- ues ​​in the world have been devalued by the liberalism of world trade, 68 RUSSIA IN GLOBAL AFFAIRS The Formula of Trumponomics the transnationalism of financial elites, and the emergence of groups of supranational actors from among major corporations, investment funds and banks, as well as by changes in the direction of capital and resource flows. The ultra-high concentration of world production and labor resources in Southeast asia and the accumulation of material values, technologies and financial reserves there have allowed China to claim full participation in the management of the global economy and globalization processes. The hitherto unshakable Paxa mericana has begun to erode. as Im- manuel Wallerstein wrote in his analysis of world systems and the situ- ation in the contemporary world, “The period from 1990 to 2025/2050 will most likely be short on peace, short on stability, and short on legiti- macy. In part, this is because of the decline of the united States as the hegemonic power of the world-system” (Wallerstein, 1995). COMPONENTS OF NEOMERCANTILISM China is one of the most important actors in the new rivalry for world leadership. Therefore, it would be appropriate to quote the famous Chinese treatise The Art of War by Sun Tzu: “disorder arises from order, cowardice arises from courage, weakness arises from strength. order and disorder are a matter of organization, courage and coward- ice are a matter of momentum, strength and weakness are a matter of formation” (Sun Tzu, 1991). In the current geo-economic processes, three components of the formula of “the great matter of the state”—quantity, power, and form— will determine the final result. Quantity is an emphasis on the growth of national welfare, the return of capital and its concentration in the home country, as well as the development of the domestic market to the detriment of allies and trading partners. Power is military/political, financial and technological domina- tion. Form is the structure of the national economy, borders and barri- ers established around it, as well as a system of incentives, and expan- sion to foreign markets. VOL. 16 • No. 3 • JULY – SEPTEMBER • 2018 69 Alexander V. Losev all strategies of the united States and its competitors—major powers or state associations—will inevitably be built along these three lines, formulated by the great strategist of ancient China. DONALD TRUMP AS A RESPONSE TO THE DEMAND FOR A NEW ECONOMIC POLICY By the time of the 2016 presidential election, it had become clear that the u.S. would soon have to scale down its soft power policy and reduce the funding of allies due to a growing budget deficit, and that the promotion of democracy had led to the so-called “Imperial overstretch” (Imperiale Überdehnung) (münkler, 2005). Washington needs to place emphasis on hard power, with elements of military pressure, and on protectionism in order to slow down globalization, which helps China grow, and restore the manageability of geo-eco- nomic processes. economist dani Rodrik in 1999 introduced the notion of the ‘Glo- balization Paradox’ and argued that there is a conflict between democ- racy, economic globalization, and national sovereignty. Rodrik insists that these three political goals cannot coexist at the level of nation state (Rodrik, 2011). he argues that we cannot have “deep economic integration” (he uses the term ‘hyper-globalization’), national sover- eignty (nation state), and democratic politics all at once (Rodrik, 2011: 200–201). We can have at most two out of three. Since democracy can- not be compromised, and he rejects the “global governance” option, he proposes a return to national sovereignty. he considers that global standards and regulations are not just impractical; they are undesir- able. The democratic legitimacy constraint ensures that global gov- ernance will result in the lowest common denominator, a regime of weak and ineffectual rules (Rodrik, 2011: 204).
Recommended publications
  • Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: the Role of Economic Factors
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Crossref Hindawi Publishing Corporation ISRN Economics Volume 2013, Article ID 954071, 14 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/954071 Research Article Explaining Protectionism Support: The Role of Economic Factors Natalia Melgar,1 Juliette Milgram-Baleix,2 and Máximo Rossi1 1 Department of Economics, University of the Republic, Constituyente 1502, 11200 Montevideo, Uruguay 2 Department of Economic eory and History, University of Granada, Campus Cartuja, 18071 Granada, Spain Correspondence should be addressed to Natalia Melgar; [email protected] Received 8 November 2012; Accepted 26 November 2012 Academic Editors: T. M. Dall and D. Mitra Copyright © 2013 Natalia Melgar et al. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. We �nd that individuals’ opinions concerning protectionist policies match with how their revenue could be affected in the medium or long term by trade liberalisation in line with predictions of the comparative advantage models. An adverse macroeconomic context (large increase in the unemployment rate or in�ation rate) increases protectionist attitudes, thus re�ecting that people do not trust that free trade will lead to lower prices or create jobs despite trade theory optimism. People share a mercantilist view of trade since more imports increase protectionism support, while people positively value exports, especially in small countries. Regarding policy measures, while protectionist measures do not in�uence protectionism support in general, easy access to exports reduces people’s support for protectionism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Food Insecurity in East Asia
    Rice, politics and power: the political economy of food insecurity in East Asia Paul Belesky Master of International Studies (International Relations) The University of Queensland A thesis submitted for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy The University of Queensland, 2016 School of Political Science and International Studies School of Social Science Abstract This thesis has three main objectives: (1) to provide a critical political economy study of the complex interplay between rice, politics and power in East Asia; (2) to make a contribution to understanding the evolution of the regional and global food system through an historically-contextualised exploration of the political economy of rice in the East Asian region; and (3) to make a contribution towards an alternative analytical framework for the political economy of food insecurity in the region. This study focuses on the agricultural commodity of rice as a prism through which to examine and explore the complex and multidimensional nature of food insecurity in the region, with rice providing a lens through which to explore social relations and relations of power that underpin the political economy of food and agriculture. This study has identified a gap in literature in relation to a contemporary analysis of the political economy of rice, with a second gap appearing in relation to the evolution of the global food system from an East Asian perspective. This thesis aims to make a contribution towards addressing these gaps in literature. With these objectives in mind, this thesis responds
    [Show full text]
  • On the Crisis of the “Liberalization Policy” in the Economics of Interdependence
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Lorenz, Detlef Article — Digitized Version On the crisis of the “liberalization policy” in the economics of interdependence Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Lorenz, Detlef (1978) : On the crisis of the “liberalization policy” in the economics of interdependence, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Verlag Weltarchiv, Hamburg, Vol. 13, Iss. 7/8, pp. 169-173, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02929188 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/139551 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu WORLD TRADE On the Crisis of the "Liberalization Policy" in the Economics of Interdependence by Detlef Lorenz, Berlin* In spite of all protestations and exhortations it is a fact that trade liberalization, the modern version of free trade, is caught in a crisis.
    [Show full text]
  • 9. Information Technology in the Learning Economy: Challenges for Developing Countries Dieter Ernst and Bengt-Åke Lundvall
    9. Information technology in the learning economy: challenges for developing countries Dieter Ernst and Bengt-Åke Lundvall The engine of growth should be technological change, with international trade serving as a lubricating oil and not as fuel. (Lewis 1978, p. 74) Both the pace and the acceleration of innovation are startling; nay terrify- ing...No one can predict the ...range of skills which will need to be amassed to create and take advantage of the next revolution but one. (And thinking about the next but one is what everyone is doing. The game is already over for the next.) (Anderson 1997) Research in industrialized countries has shown that the ability to learn determines the economic success not only of firms and industries but also of whole regions (industrial districts) and countries (OECD 1996a, 1996b, 1996c). This has given rise to the concept of the learning economy, which is based on the following propositions (Lundvall and Johnson 1994; Lundvall 1994, 1996): learning is an interactive, socially embedded process; its efficiency depends on the institutional setup, the national innovation system. The content of the knowledge generated through learning is criti- cal: tacit knowledge is essential for adjusting to change (flexibility) and for implementing change (innovation). This chapter inquires how the concept of the learning economy can be applied to the requirements of developing countries (DCs). Its main purpose is to develop an analytical framework for understanding how learning and capability formation can foster industrial upgrading, with special emphasis on the spread of information technology (IT). Under what conditions can DCs use this set of generic technologies to improve their learning capabilities? As a growing amount of knowledge becomes accessible through worldwide information networks, the establishment of national IT capabilities should help to accelerate knowledge creation and diffusion.
    [Show full text]
  • Policy Response to the Great Depression of the 1930S: Turkish Neomercantilism in the Balkan Context
    Turkish Studies ISSN: 1468-3849 (Print) 1743-9663 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/ftur20 Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context Adnan Türegün To cite this article: Adnan Türegün (2016) Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context, Turkish Studies, 17:4, 666-690, DOI: 10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 Published online: 01 Sep 2016. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 234 View related articles View Crossmark data Citing articles: 1 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=ftur20 Download by: [Cankaya Universitesi] Date: 22 September 2017, At: 06:32 TURKISH STUDIES, 2016 VOL. 17, NO. 4, 666–690 http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14683849.2016.1227684 Policy response to the Great Depression of the 1930s: Turkish neomercantilism in the Balkan context Adnan Türegün Department of Sociology and Anthropology, Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada ABSTRACT In examining the Turkish response to the crisis of the 1930s, this paper contributes to existing literature at three levels: economic policy conception, comparative case selection, and mode of explanation. First, it takes a holistic approach to economic policy (neomercantilism) by looking at its foreign trade and finance (autarkic), microeconomic (etatist), and macroeconomic (neoclassical orthodox) dimensions. Second, it locates the Turkish response in the Balkan context, where other small states responded to comparable stimuli. Third, while viewing the macroeconomic conservatism of Turkish neomercantilism as a situational necessity, it explains the autarkic dimension by the shared German metropolitan linkages of the Balkans as a region, and the etatist dimension by the Kemalist bureaucracy’s larger room for maneuver in a context of wider gap between political modernization and economic backwardness.
    [Show full text]
  • Neomercantilism and Great-Power Energy Competition in Central Asia and the Caspian
    University of Louisville ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository Faculty Scholarship Summer 2014 Neomercantilism and great-power energy competition in Central Asia and the Caspian. Charles E. Ziegler University of Louisville, [email protected] Rajan Menon Follow this and additional works at: https://ir.library.louisville.edu/faculty Part of the Asian Studies Commons, Comparative Politics Commons, International Relations Commons, and the Soviet and Post-Soviet Studies Commons Original Publication Information This article was originally published in Strategic Studies Quarterly, volume 38, issue 4, in Summer 2014. This Article is brought to you for free and open access by ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of ThinkIR: The University of Louisville's Institutional Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Neomercantilism and Great-Power Energy Competition in Central Asia and the Caspian Charles E. Ziegler Rajan Menon Russia, China, and the United States are vying for political influence and control of natural resources in Central Asia in what has been labeled a twenty-first-century Great Game.1 Among the conditions drawing these major powers to the region are its location at the heart of the Eur- asian landmass and its bountiful natural resources. China and Russia are driven in roughly equal measure by political and economic consider- ations. They have adopted neomercantilist policies (i.e., state-directed efforts aimed at making asymmetric economic gains at the expense of competitors, a concept we discuss at length below) to realize their goals in the region.
    [Show full text]
  • Saudi Neomercantilism in the Oil Price
    The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available on Emerald Insight at: https://www.emerald.com/insight/2631-3561.htm REPS 5,1 Saudi neomercantilism in the oil price war Ahmed Samir Mahdi Department of Political Science, Faculty of Business Administration, 2 Economics and Political Science, The British University in Egypt, Cairo, Egypt Received 10 October 2019 Accepted 10 October 2019 Abstract Purpose – The so-called “oil price war” of 2014-2016 took place between several main global oil producers; OPEC (led by Saudi Arabia), Russia and the newcomer; American tight oil or fracking oil. These oil producers were competing against each other over market shares in the global oil market, by maintaining their high oil production rates, even if this led to a decline in oil prices and a reduction in revenues from oil sales. As energy politics need more coverage in International Political Economy (IPE) theory, this paper aims to argue that Saudi Arabia’s policies during the oil price war of 2014-2016 reflected a policy of neomercantilism, which is the IPE equivalent of the school of realism in International Relations (IR). Design/methodology/approach – This paper tests for neomercantilism by testing three of its main definitional components. The first definitional component is that the state, as the political authority, intervenes in the economic decisions. The second component is the primacy of the state interests over business corporate profits, or the primacy of political and security considerations over short-term economic and corporate profit considerations. The third is the zero-sum or relative gains nature of dealings between states.
    [Show full text]
  • Political Economy and Public Policy
    POLITICAL ECONOMY AND PUBLIC POLICY Deepak Lal TIIE INTERNAI'IONAI. CETrER FOR ECONOMic GiRo\vIi is a non-profit research institute founded in 1985 to stimulate international discussions on eco­ nomic policy, economic growth. and human welfare. The Center sponsors research, pxiblic'ations. and conferences in cooperation with an international network of correspondent institututes. which distribute publications ofboth the Center and other network members to I)olif'y audiences around the world. The Center's research and publications program is organized aroulnd five series: Sector Studies: Country Studies: Studies in I llman evelopment and Social Wellare: Occasional Papers; and a Reprint Series. The Center is affiliated with tihe Institute for Conteniporarv Studies, and has headquarters in Panama and a home office in San Francisco, California. Publication signifies that the Center believes a work to be a competent treatment worthy of public consideration. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions of a vork are entirely those of the author and should not be attributed to ICEG. its affiliated organizations, its board of overseers, or organizations thai support ICEG. For further inlonnation, please conta('t the International Center for Economic Growth, 243 Kearny Street, San Francisco, Califbrnia. 94108, USA. Phone (415) 981-5353: Fax (415) 986-4878. ICEG Board of Overseers Y. Seyvid Abdulai Woo-Choong Kim OPEC Fund Ibr International Daeiwoo Corp., Korea I'velopment, Austria Adalbert Krieger Vasena Abdalatif AI-I laniad Argentina Arab FAnd.fbr Economic and Pedro Pablo Kuczynski Social Developmenit. KutVait USA Nicolils Ardito-Barletta Agustin Legorreta Chairman.Panama InverlatS.A., Mexico Roy Ash Sol Linowitz Ash Capital Partnership.USA CoudertBros., USA Raymond Barre Jorge Mejia Salazar France Colombia Roberto Campos Saburo Okita NationalSenator,Brazil Institute for Domestic and Inter- Carlos Manuel Castillo nationalPoliciesStudies.Japan CosiaRica Tonfis Pastoriza A.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. Introduction: the Fall of the Soviet Union and the Resurgence of Russia
    1. Introduction: The Fall of the Soviet Union and the Resurgence of Russia Kristi Elaine Govella1 University of California, Berkeley Vinod K. Aggarwal University of California, Berkeley 1.1 Introduction Much has happened in the two decades since the end of the Cold War. In the immediate aftermath of the fall of the Soviet Union, Russia went through a period of dramatic domestic political change and uncertainty in the foreign policy arena. A country that was once a superpower in a bipolar world began to doubt its place in the international system—and not without reason: the collapse of the USSR left Russia in a state of economic, political, and social turmoil, marked by declining economic output and increasing inflation, foreign debt, and budget deficits. Other problems included lack of law and order, loss of central control over the periphery, conflicts in Chechnya, rampant corruption, chronic political instability, and a severe financial crisis. At the start of Vladimir Putin’s presidency, the country’s share of world GDP had fallen to just 1.5 percent, in 1 The authors would like to thank Sarah Garding, Maria Vassilieva, and Theocharis Grigoriadis for their helpful comments and feedback. Kathy Bowen, Peter Volberding, and Robert Nelson provided valuable research assistance. contrast to the 21 percent share held by the United States.2 Moreover, Russia’s economic and political transition during the 1990s was fraught with complications and disappointments. The last decade, however, has witnessed Russia’s reemergence onto the international scene, as well as a recentralization of power under former president Vladimir Putin, the current prime minister of Russia.
    [Show full text]
  • (Trade) War: Examining the Relationship Between The
    The Art of (Trade) War: Examining the Relationship Between the Political Economies of the U.S. and China Through the Lens of Previous Machiavellian Moments A Honors Political Science Thesis by Hunter D. Snowden Presented to the Department of Political Science in fulfillment of the requirements for the degree with honors of Bachelor of Arts Trinity College Duke University March 2019 1 Contents Acknowledgments…………………………………………………………………3 1. Abstract…………………………………………………………………………….4 2. Introduction………………………………………………………………………...5-9 2.1. Machiavellian Moment 2.2. Hegemonic Stability Theory 3. Research Question………………………………………………………………….9 4. Literature Review………………………………………………………………….10-22 4.1. Mercantilism 4.2. Chinese System of Political Economy 4.3. U.S. System of Political Economy 4.4. U.S. – Chinese Relations 4.5. Gaps in Previous Research 5. Results……………………………………………………………………………...22-35 5.1. England vs. The Netherlands 5.2. US vs. China 5.3. China & England 5.4. US & The Netherlands 6. Conclusion………………………………………………………………………….35-41 7. Bibliography………………………………………………………………………..41-45 2 Acknowledgements First, I would like to thank Professor Edmund Malesky for all of the advice and supervision he provided to me throughout the writing of this paper. Without his suggestions and revisions, I would not have been able to get to this point. I would also like to thank my friends and family who were willing to put up with me sending them countless versions to read over and revise. Finally, I would like to thank Duke University and the political science department for this opportunity. I have learned a great deal not only about this topic and how to write a thesis but about myself and what I can achieve.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Political Economy: Understanding the International
    Global Political Economy Global Political Economy UNDERSTANDING THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ORDER Robert Gilpin WITH THE ASSISTANCE OF Jean M. Gilpin PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD Copyright 2001 by Princeton University Press Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540 In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press, 3 Market Place, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1SY All Rights Reserved Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Gilpin, Robert. Global political economy : understanding the international economic order / Robert Gilpin with the assistance of Jean M. Gilpin. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-691-08676-1 (alk. paper) — ISBN 0-691-08677-X (pbk.) 1. International economic relations. 2. Free trade. 3. International finance. 4. Technological innovations—Economic aspects. 5. Economic development. I. Gilpin, Jean M. II. Title. HF1359 .G5516 2001 337—dc21 00-051684 This book has been composed in Sabon. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (R 1997) (Permanence of Paper) www.pup.princeton.edu Printed in the United States of America by Princeton University Press, Princeton & Oxford 10987654321 10987654321 (Pbk.) Contents List of Abbreviations and Acronyms ix Preface xi ONE. The New Global Economic Order 3 Changes in the World Economy 5 Intellectual Perspectives 13 My Perspective: State-centric Realism 15 Purpose of Economic Activity 23 Conclusion 24 TWO. The Nature of Political Economy 25 What You Seek Is What You Find 31 The Nature of an Economy 38 Embeddedness of the Economy 41 Conclusion 45 THREE. The Neoclassical Conception of the Economy 46 The Discipline of Neoclassical Economics 46 Nature of a Market 54 Method of Comparative Statics 57 Intellectual Limitations 60 Economists and Public Policy 69 Comparison of Economics and Political Economy 74 Conclusion 76 FOUR.
    [Show full text]
  • Prof. Dimitar Hadjinikolov, Dsc Interventionist Theories 1
    Prof. Dimitar Hadjinikolov, DSc www.hadjinikolov.pro Interventionist Theories 1. International trade in the global political economy – overview 2. Mercantilism 3. Neomercantilism 3. International trade and balance of payment statistics Under p. 1 Mercantilism vs liberalism? Q: Who is the winner? A: Nobody yet. 2 The role of the State in the Economy Intervention Strategy Matrix 3 Interventionism in contemporary economic policy Interventionism in contemporary economic policy is also: - dirigisme, - Dirigisme, an approach to economic development emphasizing the positive role of state intervention. The term dirigisme is derived from the French word diriger (“to direct”), which signifies the control of economic activity by the state. Preventing market failure was the basic rationale of this approach. Dirigisme was introduced in France following World War II to promote industrialization and protect against foreign competition, and it was subsequently mimicked in East Asia. Dirigiste policies often include centralized economic planning, directing investment, controlling wages and prices, and supervising labour markets. Q: Are there some positive examples of dirigisme? What about China? - functionalism, socialism, sustainable development 4 Economic liberalism More about liberal international trade theories – in the next lectures! We are leaving in a time of a transition from markets with national regulations to a global market with supranational regulations 5 2. Mercantilism The underlying principles of mercantilism included Jean-Baptiste Colbert
    [Show full text]