Bertil Gotthard Ohlin

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Bertil Gotthard Ohlin PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 20 BERTIL GOTTHARD OHLIN BERTIL GOTTHARD OHLIN doc. Ing. Anetta Čaplánová, PhD. Bertil Gothard Ohlin was born on 23rd rent economic development. In 1931 he April 1899 in Klippan, the village in the prepared a report on the World Depres- East of Sweden, in the middle-class sion for the League of Nations and in family. In 1917 he graduated from the 1934 an analysis of the unemployment Lund University, where he studied mat- situation for the Swedish government. hematics, statistics and economics. Between 1937 – 1947 he studied for Later he studied economics at Stock- some period at recognized world uni- holm School of Economics under Eli versities, at the University in Berkley, at Heckscher and Gustav Cassel, who con- Columbia and Oxford University. ducted research in the theory of in- Ohlin belongs, due to his economic ternational trade. This inspired ideas developed between the world Ohlin’s interest in this area. Ohlin wor- wars, which had formed in discussions ked on the theory of international trade in his docto- with his colleagues – other economists in Stock- ral thesis from 1924 entitled Handelns teori (Trade holm, E. Lindahl, G. Myrdal, E. Lundberg, to the theory). Between 1925 – 1930 he held a chair at the Stockholm School, a group, which is in many res- Copenhagen University. In 1931 he returned back to pects considered to be a parallel and independent Sweden, where he succeeded Heckscher at the developer of the theory of the economy with unused Stockholm School of Economics. Already during this resources, which became the essence of Keynes‘ period he paid attention to the analysis of the cur- General Theory. At the end of 30-ties Ohlin became a member of the beginning and towards the end of his professio- the Swedish parliament „Riksdag”, with which the nal career, since his long-lasting political activities long period of his active participation in the political did not allow him to allocate more time to his acade- life of Sweden began.Between 1944 – 1967 he wasmic work. a chairman of the Liberal Party.During the 2nd World In 1977 he was awarded, together with James War he served as the Minister of Trade in the Swe- Meade, the Nobel price for economics for his contri- dish government.He was an MP until 1970. bution to the development of the monetary theory For many years Ohlin contributed to Swedish and the theory of economic expansion and for the newspapers.He wrote articles related to current eco- analysis of theoretical and practical problems of nomic events and economic policy.Similarly to hisinternational trade and movements of capital.Bertil academic work most of these articles were written at Ohlin died on 3rd August 1979 in Stockholm. Ohlin’s contribution to economic theory maintain its macroeconomic equilibrium. In differen- ce to Keynes, Ohlin emphasized that if proper mone- Monetary Theory tary and fiscal policies were formulated and fixed In 1929 for the first time Ohlin attracted attention of exchange rate regime applied, the increase of taxes a wider audience of economists and gained recogni- required by the need to accumulate resources to pay tion in his polemics with J. M. Keynes on the mecha- reparations, would bring about the decrease of the nism of capital transfers applied to the concrete purchasing power in Germany and the increased example of reparations, which was Germany assig- demand in England and France. This would find cor- ned to pay after the 1st World War. In this discussion responding response in the trade balance of these Ohlin took the position that even in the situation of a countries. Germany would create export surplus and large international monetary transfer a country can England and France import surpluses. BIATEC, Volume XII, 7/2004 PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS BERTIL GOTTHARD OHLIN 21 Similarly to other representatives of Stockholm operations as a tool of monetary policy was limited in School, Ohlin frequently used the ex-ante and ex-post Sweden. Ohlin criticized it and requested to use chan- approach in his analysis. He emphasized the impor- ges in the interest rate and subsequently in the volu- tance of time-lags and with respect to the analysis of me of credits as the main tool of the monetary policy the monetary policy he pointed out that changes in of this period. psychological reactions of individuals could influence Ohlin also dealt with the issue of the optimal level of the economic development to a larger degree than the interest rates, which he considered to be at 3-3.5 per- monetary policy itself. The ex-ante and ex-post app- cent. He arrived at this estimate on the basis of the roach did not allow him to consider the interest rate as analysis of the dynamics on the Swedish market of an equilibrating variable. Regardless from its value, ex long-term credits in 1930. He concluded that the inter- post investment will be always equal to savings. So in est rate at 3 percent represented a critical lower mar- the first place he considered the interest rate as the gin, since there existed psychological barriers, which price of credit and only in this respect able to influen- did not allow it to decrease below this level. However, ce to some extent the size of investment. in 1938 interest rates in Sweden fell even below 3 per- Ohlin’s monetary theory is in a wider sense closely cent. Ohlin attributed it to the fact that the recession in related to his business cycle theory. If the central bank the industry created suitable psychological preconditi- aims to influence the real sector of the economy then ons for their decrease. the interest rate will play a key role. Ohlin also analy- According to Ohlin, the aim of the interest rate regu- zed possibilities for endogenous changes in the lation should be the price stabilization and the desi- money supply and credit, but questioned whether rable economic development. He criticized the ban- these changes are sufficient to influence aggregate king system that during the war it was not able to expenditures. Ohlin’s paper „Till fragan om penningte- maintain the flexibility and did not issue bonds with oriens uppläggning“ (On the Formulation of Monetary short periods of maturity. Ohlin did not emphasize the Theory) from 1933 is considered by several econo- role of money in the economy. If the ex ante - ex post mists as a parallel formulation of the theory, which approach is applied, not the quantity of money in cir- Keynes came with in his General Theory. However, in culation is important for changes in price level, but the difference to Keynes a primary concern of Ohlin’s conditions, which exist on the capital market. He cal- insterest in this article is the analysis of changes in the led for attention of economists to an individual, whose price level and the fluctuations of output are treated psychological reactions to the liquidity and interest only as secondary ones. On the other hand, it is rates, he considered to be more important as money necessary to emphasize that Ohlin did not specify the and its circulation if aiming to influence the economic role of changes in output as an equilibrating variable development. as Keynes did. As stated above, Ohlin analyzed changes in the Ohlin’s theory of interest rates can be considered as price level and also factors, which lead to the price his monetary theory in the narrower sense. This theo- changes. His explanation of changes in the price level ry was presented in his papers in the „Economic Jour- elaborates on the Wicksell’s idea according to which nal“ (1937) and further elaborated in the monograph the inevitable and sufficient condition for the increase Kapitalmarknad och räntepolitik (The Capital Market in prices is the increase of the sum of the consumpti- and Interest Rate Policy) (1941). The main aim of the on and investment demands compared to the change later one was to formulate a capital market theory and in output. Thus, the price increase can be initiated eit- to criticize credit policy in Sweden during the first two her from the side of investment or from the side of years of the war. He also analyzed factors, which consumption. If trying to explain changes in prices determine the level of interest rates. He considered then we have to concentrate on the identification of one of the most important factors in this respect factors, which influence the demand and the supply of expectations of economic agents. Prices on the secu- consumption and investment goods. rities market are formed in the mutual interaction of In his paper from 1934 Ohlin pointed to the interest the demand and supply. He called for the diversifica- rate as a factor, which has impact on the size of the tion of this market in general and in Sweden of those demand and the supply. The decrease of the interest days in particular. In Sweden up to 1935 securities rate leads to the increase of planned investment. The with the maturity period between 30 – 80 years were impact of the increase of investment on output and issued. Only in 1935 securities with the maturity peri- price level depends upon the elasticity of supply deter- od of 12 years were issued, however this step was not mined by the existence of unused resources in the met positively by investors. Because of the situation economy. If the supply is perfectly elastic, i.e. there during this period the possibility to use open market exist spare resources in the economy, the increase of BIATEC, Volume XII, 7/2004 PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 22 BERTIL GOTTHARD OHLIN investment will lead to the corresponding increase and se for the discussions among several economists on will not increase the price level.
Recommended publications
  • The Life and Times of Gordon Tullock
    Public Choice (2012) 152:3–27 DOI 10.1007/s11127-011-9899-3 The life and times of Gordon Tullock Charles K. Rowley · Daniel Houser Received: 24 October 2011 / Accepted: 25 October 2011 / Published online: 10 November 2011 © Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011 Abstract Gordon Tullock is a founding father of public choice. In an academic career that has spanned 50 years, he forged much of the research agenda of the public choice program and he founded and edited Public Choice, the key journal of public choice scholarship. Tullock, however did much more than this. This Special Issue of Public Choice honors Gordon Tullock in precisely the manner that he most values: the creation of new ideas across the vast range of his own scholarly interests. Keywords Gordon Tullock · Tullock’s life · Tullock’s times Si monumentum requiris, circumspice 1 Innocence of youth Gordon Tullock was born in Rockford, Illinois on February 13, 1922. His father, George Tullock, was a hardy Midwesterner of Scottish ancestry. His mother, Helen, nee Crumb, was of equally hardy Pennsylvania-Dutch stock. His father’s elder brother, Tom, and his two children, also lived in Rockford, but some distance away. So Gordon had no close and continuing relationship with them. Both of Gordon’s grandfathers died before he was old enough to remember them. Both of his grandmothers ‘lived with us for some time, but fortunately not at the same time’ (Tullock 2009:1) Rockford, often referred to as the ‘Forest City’, was a mid-sized city with a 64,000 pop- ulation in 1922, when Gordon Tullock was born.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mont Pelerin Society: a MANDATE RENEWED
    1 The Mont Pelerin Society: A MANDATE RENEWED By Deepak Lal Ladies and Gentlemen, Welcome to this special meeting of the MPS. In this address I would like to explain why it has been called at such short notice and how I hope it provides a renewal of the mandate our founders set for the society.1 After being anointed with the Presidency of this august body in Tokyo (in early September), my wife and I went on to a lecture tour in China. We were in Shanghai on a tour of the magnificent Suzhou industrial estate outside Shanghai, with MPS member Steven Cheung. On the afternoon of the 15th September Steve received a call on his Blackberry that Lehman Brothers had gone into bankruptcy. Steve opined that this marked the end of American capitalism. I thought this somewhat hyperbolic. But, on getting back to London at the end of September, as I was tending my roses, my neighbor, a Thatcherite heart surgeon, said over the hedge that, given the recent events in the capital markets, did I still stand by the views I had expressed in my last book on "Reviving the Invisible Hand".2 I replied that even a severe trade cycle downturn would not undermine the well tested classical liberal principles I had espoused. Though, Gordon Brown might be in trouble having repeatedly congratulated himself for having abolished boom and bust. Two subsequent events shattered this complacency. I had been following a political betting site called Betfair on which some youngsters at the Tokyo MPS meeting were placing bets on a McCain victory.
    [Show full text]
  • David R. Henderson: Why Everyone Read Samuelson - WSJ 8/17/15, 11:06 AM
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Calhoun, Institutional Archive of the Naval Postgraduate School Calhoun: The NPS Institutional Archive Faculty and Researcher Publications Faculty and Researcher Publications 2009-12 Why Everyone Read Samuelson Henderson, David R. The Wall Street Journal http://hdl.handle.net/10945/46117 David R. Henderson: Why Everyone Read Samuelson - WSJ 8/17/15, 11:06 AM This copy is for your personal, non-commercial use only. To order presentation-ready copies for distribution to your colleagues, clients or customers visit http://www.djreprints.com. http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052748704869304574595823818190240 COMMENTARY Why Everyone Read Samuelson The late Nobel laureate's mathematical approach to economics has been a mixed blessing. By DAVID R. HENDERSON Updated Dec. 14, 2009 7:10 p.m. ET Three years after World War II drew to a close, a young professor at MIT published "Foundations of Economic Analysis." Its mathematical approach to economics would revolutionize the profession. And its author, Paul Samuelson, would go on to earn many awards and honors, culminating in 1970, when he won the Nobel Prize in economics—the second year it was awarded. Samuelson died on Sunday at the age of 94. His influence has been profound, but the mathematization of economics has been a mixed blessing. The downside is that the math hurdle in leading U.S. economics programs is now so high that people who grasp the power of economic concepts to explain human behavior are losing out in the competition to mathematicians. The upside is that Samuelson sometimes used math to resolve issues that had not been resolved at a theoretical level for decades.
    [Show full text]
  • ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography
    Τεύχος 53, Οκτώβριος-Δεκέμβριος 2019 | Issue 53, October-December 2019 ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη Nobel Prize in Economics Τα τεύχη δημοσιεύονται στον ιστοχώρο της All issues are published online at the Bank’s website Τράπεζας: address: https://www.bankofgreece.gr/trapeza/kepoe https://www.bankofgreece.gr/en/the- t/h-vivliothhkh-ths-tte/e-ekdoseis-kai- bank/culture/library/e-publications-and- anakoinwseis announcements Τράπεζα της Ελλάδος. Κέντρο Πολιτισμού, Bank of Greece. Centre for Culture, Research and Έρευνας και Τεκμηρίωσης, Τμήμα Documentation, Library Section Βιβλιοθήκης Ελ. Βενιζέλου 21, 102 50 Αθήνα, 21 El. Venizelos Ave., 102 50 Athens, [email protected] Τηλ. 210-3202446, [email protected], Tel. +30-210-3202446, 3202396, 3203129 3202396, 3203129 Βιβλιογραφία, τεύχος 53, Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019, Bibliography, issue 53, Oct.-Dec. 2019, Nobel Prize Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη in Economics Συντελεστές: Α. Ναδάλη, Ε. Σεμερτζάκη, Γ. Contributors: A. Nadali, E. Semertzaki, G. Tsouri Τσούρη Βιβλιογραφία, αρ.53 (Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019), Βραβείο Nobel στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη 1 Bibliography, no. 53, (Oct.-Dec. 2019), Nobel Prize in Economics Πίνακας περιεχομένων Εισαγωγή / Introduction 6 2019: Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo and Michael Kremer 7 Μονογραφίες / Monographs ................................................................................................... 7 Δοκίμια Εργασίας / Working papers ......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Heckscher-Ohlin Model
    CAVE.6607.cp06.p095-120 6/5/06 7:12 PM Page 95 CHAPTER 6 Factor Endowments and Trade II: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model theory of international trade that highlights the variations among countries of supplies of broad categories of productive factors (labor, capital, and land, none Aof which may be specific to any one sector) was developed by two Swedish econ- omists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin.1 Their model subsequently has been extended in scores of articles and treatises. Some of the new results were startling: Two countries that share the same general technology but differ in their endowments of the basic fac- tors of production may nonetheless find that free trade in commodities forces wage rates in the two countries into absolute equality. Advocates of protection have found support in another proposition: Even a broad-based factor such as labor may unam- biguously gain by the imposition of tariffs. Most of these propositions were carefully proven and adequately qualified in a simple form of the theory—the 2 3 2 model, so called because it analyzed an economy producing two commodities with the use of only two productive factors.This model has proved to be immensely popular not only in the area of international trade but also in fields such as public finance and economic growth. We initially follow Heckscher and Ohlin in assuming that countries share the same technological knowledge, an assump- tion made to highlight a cause for trade (different relative factor endowments) that is distinct from the technological asymmetries emphasized in the Ricardian model.
    [Show full text]
  • Eli Heckscher,Sweden,Liberalism
    Discuss this article at Journaltalk: http://journaltalk.net/articles/5902 ECON JOURNAL WATCH 13(1) January 2016: 75–99 Eli Heckscher’s Ideological Migration Toward Market Liberalism Benny Carlson1 LINK TO ABSTRACT Sweden is a country that is often misunderstood by outsiders, and even by Swedes themselves. From the latter part of the nineteenth century, Sweden’s eco- nomic policies were quite liberal, and for 100 years, say from 1870 to 1970, the economy grew rapidly (see Schön 2011; Bergh 2014). During this period Sweden enjoyed relatively high-quality public debate—a tradition in which Sweden still remains quite exceptional. Leading economists took active part and influenced opinion; they were genuine leaders in public discourse. Five titans stand out: Knut Wicksell, Gustav Cassel, Eli Heckscher, Bertil Ohlin, and Gunnar Myrdal.2 The first three were highly liberal. Ohlin began as liberal, like his mentor Heckscher, but moved to a position of social liberalism, or moderate welfare-statism, and became a leading politician (Berggren 2013). Myrdal represents Sweden’s turn toward social democracy (Carlson 2013). Here I tell of Eli Heckscher (1879–1952), and in particular of his ideological development. For most of his life Heckscher was the most firmly principled eco- nomic liberal Sweden had. He fought against state-socialist tendencies, Keynesian crisis policy, and economic planning, and had only one real rival, Gustav Cassel, 1. Lund University School of Economics and Management, 221 00 Lund, Sweden. I thank MIT Press for their permission to incorporate in this article some material that was previously published in a chapter of Eli Heckscher, International Trade, and Economic History, edited by Ronald Findlay, Rolf G.
    [Show full text]
  • Bertil Ohlin [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 532-536
    Bertil Ohlin [Ideological Profiles of the Economics Laureates] Niclas Berggren Econ Journal Watch 10(3), September 2013: 532-536 Abstract Bertil Ohlin is among the 71 individuals who were awarded the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel between 1969 and 2012. This ideological profile is part of the project called “The Ideological Migration of the Economics Laureates,” which fills the September 2013 issue of Econ Journal Watch. Keywords Classical liberalism, economists, Nobel Prize in economics, ideology, ideological migration, intellectual biography. JEL classification A11, A13, B2, B3 Link to this document http://econjwatch.org/file_download/757/OhlinIPEL.pdf ECON JOURNAL WATCH North, Douglass C. 2009. Interview by Karen Ilse Horn. In Roads to Wisdom: Conversations with Ten Nobel Laureates in Economics by Horn, 153-172. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. North, Douglass C., and Robert P. Thomas. 1973. The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. North, Douglass C., John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R. Weingast. 2009. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Bertil Ohlin by Niclas Berggren Bertil Ohlin (1899–1979), professor of economics and Nobel laureate in 1977, developed a social consciousness early on, both because of his mother’s involvement in assisting the poor and because of his going to school with less well- to-do children. In the 1920s—also Ohlin’s twenties—he argued that the best method for helping the less fortunate was to increase economic growth: only by creating and sustaining conditions for higher production levels could living standards rise over the long term.
    [Show full text]
  • Reacting to Samuelson: Early Development Economics and the Factor-Price Equalization Theorem
    1 Reacting to Samuelson: Early Development Economics and the Factor-Price Equalization Theorem Mauro Boianovsky (Universidade de Brasilia) [email protected] Abstract. Paul Samuelson’s famous 1948 “factor price equalization theorem” was his main contribution to international trade theory. He demonstrated conditions under which trade in goods only would lead to full equalization of the remuneration of productive factors across countries. In practice, general factor-price equalization has not been a feature of the international economy, as Samuelson acknowledged. His theorem came out when development economics was starting to emerge as a new field of research and policy, largely based on the observed international income asymmetries between poor and rich countries. The paper investigates how development economists reacted mostly (but not always) critically to that theorem, with attention to the methodological issues involved and to Samuelson’s own perception of the theorem’s relevance. Key words. Samuelson, factor-price equalization, development economics, trade theory JEL codes. B20, B27, B30 Resumo. O famoso teorema de 1948 da “equalização dos preços dos fatores” de Paul Samuelson foi sua principal contribuição à teoria do comércio internacional. Ele demonstrou condições sob as quais o comércio de bens iria conduzir à plena equalização das remunerações dos fatores entre os países. Na prática, a equalização dos preços dos fatores não tem ocorrido em geral, como Samuelson reconheceu. O seu teorema veio à tona quando a economia do desenvolvimento estava começando a emergir como nova área de pesquisa e política, baseada largamente nas assimetrias internacionais de renda observadas. O trabalho investiga como economistas do desenvolvimento reagiram em geral (mas não sempre) de forma crítica àquele teorema, com atenção às questões metodológicas envolvidas e à própria percepção de Samuelson da relevância do seu teorema.
    [Show full text]
  • Course Information
    ECON 452: Senior Seminar Sweet Briar College, Fall 2012 Sherry Forbes Gray 317 T/R 1030-1200 434.381.6177 [email protected] j j j Course Information Description The original will of Alfred Nobel (1895) established Nobel Prizes in only five fields - physics, chemistry, medicine or physiology, literature, and peace - and the Prize continues to be considered one of the most prestigious awards for advances in those fields today. But in 1968, the Sveriges Riksbank established a Nobel Prize in the field of Economic Sciences, establishing an award for economists who "have during the previous year rendered the greatest service to mankind." But why economics? Nobel Prizes were not originally established for any field in the social sciences, so why was economics the only one to get a Nobel Prize? What is this "service" that economists provide, and what is the relevance of this "science of economics" for today’s problems? These are the questions we are going to address in this seminar as we study the contributions of the Nobel laureates. Specifically, we are going to examine 1.) the development of modern economics through the contributions of the Nobel Prize winners in economics, and 2.) how those ideas influenced (and continue to influence) every day life and how we think about the "big ideas" of today. Economics is not a "settled" discipline - the development of economic ideas and of economics as a science has not been neat, organized, or even at times very coherent. Why is there so much controversy? Much of the debate, of course, revolves around the appropriate role for government and how much we should rely on free markets or government intervention to solve society’sproblems.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Wigforss Connection': the Stockholm School Vs. Keynes
    This article was downloaded by: [University of Stockholm] On: 09 January 2013, At: 06:04 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rejh20 The ‘Wigforss Connection’: the Stockholm School vs. Keynes debate revisited Martin Kragh Version of record first published: 09 Nov 2012. To cite this article: Martin Kragh (2012): The ‘Wigforss Connection’: the Stockholm School vs. Keynes debate revisited, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, DOI:10.1080/09672567.2012.708770 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2012.708770 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms- and-conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub- licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
    [Show full text]
  • Lucas, Keynes, and the Crisis
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Lucas, Keynes, and the crisis Research Report, No. 2009-2 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2009) : Lucas, Keynes, and the crisis, Research Report, No. 2009-2, The University of Western Ontario, Department of Economics, London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70391 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Lucas, Keynes, and the Crisis by David Laidler Research Report # 2009-2 July 2009 Department of Economics Research Report Series Department of Economics Social Science Centre The University of Western Ontario London, Ontario, N6A 5C2 Canada This research report is available as a downloadable pdf file on our website http://economics.uwo.ca/econref/WorkingPapers/departmentresearchreports.html.
    [Show full text]
  • OHLIN on the GREAT DEPRESSION the Popular Message in the Daily Press
    OHLIN ON THE GREAT DEPRESSION The popular message in the daily press Benny Carlson and Lars Jonung* February 2001 $EVWUDFWThis paper traces the development of Bertil Ohlin's views on issues such as the causes of the depression of the 1930's, policies against the depression, the use of fiscal and monetary policies, and tariffs and public works to stabilize the business cycle. We examine about 80 of his articles on the depression of the 1930’s, published in 6WRFNKROPV7LGQLQJHQ, a Stockholm daily, between 1926 and 1935. This is a small sample of Ohlin's total output of more than 2 300 contributions to the daily press – a number that makes him the most prolific economic journalist of all Swedish professors of economics in the 20th century Our basic result is that Ohlin was an eager but cautious commentator on current affairs. Initially, he was quite optimistic, underestimating the depth of the depression. Later, as the depression worsened, he proposed bolder measures such as increased public works and public investments as well as an expansionary monetary policy to fight unemployment. By 1932, Ohlin had adopted a multiplier approach. He was strongly opposed to cuts in nominal wages and public expenditures during the depression. Summarizing his views on the depression in 1934, Ohlin concluded that it was not the result of any inherent weakness of capitalism. Turning to the perennial debate on the originality of the Stockholm School: Do Ohlin´s daily articles show him as a pioneer or as an orthodox in macroeconomic thinking in the 1930's? We conclude that support for either interpretation can be heralded.
    [Show full text]