Access to Land. Land Reform and Commons Preservation In

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Access to Land. Land Reform and Commons Preservation In Donald Winch Access to land: land reform and commons preservation in nineteenth- century England A presentation given at the 75th Anniversary Conference of the Economic History Society in Glasgow as part of the sessions on ‘Morality, Markets and Policy’, Saturday, March 31, 2001 I My starting point in making some observations on an impossibly large topic will have to be a simple assertion. If one could conduct a canvas of opinion during the second half of the nineteenth-century on the deprivations and injustices associated with industrialization and urbanization, loss of access to land for purposes of work or leisure would come high on the lists of a large segment of the British public. There are also good grounds for thinking that the canvas would reveal this sentiment to have become more strident during the last two decades of the century. To students of the history of land reform agitation in England during this period, these assertions will appear commonplace; they underlie the activities of what can now be seen as a linked sequence of pressure groups dedicated to the removal of the actual and perceived deficiencies of the English system of land tenure. Instead of linked sequence one could also speak of a relay race combined with some features of the game of leap-frog – a mixed image that may provide a clue both as to momentum and to the failure to reach the finishing line in good order. While abolition of primogeniture and entail had remained staple elements on the agenda of reformers since the late eighteenth century, by the end of the nineteenth the campaign reached much further into the sanctum of private property in land. Radicals of the Cobden- Bright variety who espoused the cause of ‘free trade’ in land saw themselves as carrying the crusade against landed monopoly and aristocratic privilege to its logical conclusion by making the regulations surrounding the transfer of land conform to the priorities of a middle-class world of unrestricted commerce. From the late 1860s onward they found themselves being overtaken on their left by organisations such as the Land Tenure Reform 1 Association, the Land Nationalisation Society, and the various Land Restoration Leagues formed in the wake of Henry George’s speaking tours and his book on Progress and Poverty (1880). These associations were variously dedicated to the creation of peasant proprietorships and the curtailment of private landownership, wholly or in part, through nationalisation, municipalisation, and/or taxes based on the legitimacy of communal appropriation of the ‘unearned increment’ in rental incomes and urban site values. Weaving between these competing groups were the activities of the Commons Preservation Society designed to prevent urban landowners from infringing rights of access to common land in and around cities. Some of these ideas found their way into Joseph Chamberlain’s ‘unauthorised programme’ in 1885, and into the manifestos of the Liberal and Labour parties during the decades that span the turn of the century. From a party political perspective they can be seen as attempts to address the perceived needs of the new electorate created by the Second and Third Reform Acts, which added urban and rural working-class males to the middle-class electorate originally addressed by Cobdenites. In any written version of this communication a footnote would now be inserted directing attention to a distinguished body of secondary literature on this topic.1 Taking this literature as read, how does it relate to the theme of these sessions on ‘Morality, Markets and Policy’, bearing in mind the article on ‘Moral Choice and Economic Change’ that our organiser, Barry Supple, has given us as a starting point? The conviction that one of the most important, even tragic, consequences of economic change was rural depopulation and the progressive exclusion of the working classes from the benefits of landownership might appear to be part of a familiar lament based on a form of Virgilian nostalgia to which the British have been held to be peculiarly prone. Oliver Goldsmith’s ‘Deserted Village’ in the eighteenth century and William Wordsworth passim in the nineteenth were merely the leading poetic spokesmen for this mood. Some aspects of land reform are undoubtedly susceptible to such 1 For general treatments, in addition to the specific works cited in later footnotes, see M. Beer, A History of British Socialism, G Bell, London, 1929, Vol. II, pp. 237-45; H M. Lynd, England in the 1880s, New York, 1945; R. Harrison, Before the Socialists; Studies in Labour and Politics, 1861-1881, Routledge, London, 1965; D. E. Martin, ‘Land Reform’ in P. Hollis (ed), Pressure from Without in Early Victorian England, 1974; and R. Douglas, Land, People and Politics; A History of the Land Question in the United Kingdom, 1878-1952, 1976. 2 ‘pastoral’ or ‘romantic’ interpretations. But the feature on which I shall be focussing concerns the way in which the movement obtained leadership and support from a couple of generations of members of the professional middle classes, many of them priding themselves on being serious students of Britain’s economic history -- the kind of men who were accustomed to analysing contemporary institutions and policies in the languages of political economy.2 Plural usage here is required, first, to take account of the way in which the secular and deductive approach of emerging orthodoxy, chiefly associated with Ricardo and his followers, never established complete hegemony in public debate, even during its heyday.3 And secondly, because orthodox methods of analysis increasingly came under attack from historicists and inductivists from the 1860s onwards, despite the continued authoritative status of John Stuart Mill’s Principles of Political Economy (1848-71). Especially when confronting the problems raised by land tenure, agrarian economic history, the new form of evolutionary historical jurisprudence associated with Henry Maine, and comparative studies of land tenure furnished evidence that could be used to support or deny conclusions derived from a narrower form of economic analysis.4 Without suggesting that political economy in its increasingly mixed forms during the third quarter of the century was univocal, especially when it came to framing policies, one thing can be taken for granted: its exponents cannot be accused, as many of the spokesmen for radical, Chartist, and romantic agrarian alternatives can, of being hostile towards the self- interest principle, competition, and private property in general. Moreover, since support for 2 I have spoken of men because all those with whom I shall be concerned here were men. But there were some prominent women involved, notably John Stuart Mill’s step-daughter, Helen Taylor, Millicent Garrett Fawcett, and Octavia Hill, with Hill’s interest emerging as a byproduct of her concern with the urban housing problem; see Octavia Hill, Homes of the London Poor, 1875, Cass reprint, 1970. 3 For Christian versions of political economy see Boyd Hilton, The Age of Atonement: The Influence of Evangelicalism on Social and Economic Thought, 1785-1865, Oxford, 1988; and for the Malthusian variant D. Winch, Riches and Poverty; An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750-1834, Cambridge, 1996. Part III. For a persistent conservative and protectionist challenge to orthodoxy see Anna Gambles. Protection and Politics; Conservative Economic Discourse, 1815-52, Royal Historical Society, The Boydell Press, 1999. 4 On the ways in which Maine and his Continental sources, chiefly von Maurer and Nasse, became embroiled in land reform politics see J. W. Burrow, ‘”The Village Community” and the Uses of History in Late Nineteenth-Century England’ in N. McKendrick (ed), Historical Perspectives; Studies in English Thought and Society in honour of J. H. Plumb, London: Europa Publications, 1974, pp. 255-84. See also C. Dewey, ‘Images of the Village Community: A Study in Anglo-Indian Ideology’, Modern Asian Studies, 6, 3, 1972, 291-328; ‘Particular Polities: Political Economy and the Historical Method’ in S. Collini, D. Winch, and J. Burrow, That Noble Science of Politics , Cambridge, 1983. [[/ 247-75; and A. Diamond (ed), The Victorian Achievment of Sir Henry Maine, Cambridge, 1991. 3 free trade was an issue on which most economists, if not economic historians, were univocal, their views on land reform had to recognize the global economic implications of any policy solutions they advocated. That such exponents of land reform could come to the conclusion that improving access to land was a practical goal worth pursuing through legislation and state intervention raises issues that go beyond rural preservation and conservation, the kinds of things we associate with the founding of bodies like the National Trust in 1895. Again, while my cast of land reformers was not entirely immune to such ideas, and has been found seriously wanting in qualities of hard-headedness on other grounds, what distinguished them was an obligation to show that their objectives conformed with political, economic, and administrative realities. To this one could add the fact that use of the state as an instrumentality was not the first recourse for a generation or two that had learned from domestic and foreign example the dangers of bureaucratic inefficiency, corruption, and special interest pleading. Any solutions proposed had to bear in mind such experience and be economically viable as well as desirable on other grounds. To avoid another kind of confusion, it has to be added that hard-headedness does not imply moral neutrality. Quite the reverse in fact, though a modicum of professional distance came with the academicization of economics and economic history at the end of the century. Campaigns against the English system of land ownership on whatever economic grounds were permeated by those powerful moral and political undercurrents which were fed by the well-known successes of the territorial aristocracy in retaining its position in local and national affairs, despite repeal of the Corn Laws and the passage of three reform bills.
Recommended publications
  • 'Viability' in Redistributive Land Reform: Perspectives from Southern Africa
    Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Working Paper 15 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Working paper for Livelihoods after Land Reform Project Ben Cousins1 and Ian Scoones2 June 2009 1 Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies (PLAAS), University of the Western Cape. 2 Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex. PLAAS Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies 1 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Contents Introduction 3 Modernisation and agricultural development in southern Africa: past and present 5 Framing viability: frameworks for assessing land and agrarian reform 9 Viability in redistributive land reform in southern Africa 21 Rethinking viability in southern African land reform 31 Conclusion 34 References 35 2 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Introduction ‘Viability’ is a key term in debates about land reform in southern African and beyond, and is used in relation to both individual projects and programmes. ‘Viability’ connotes ‘success- ful’ and ‘sustainable’ - but what is meant by viability in relation to land reform, and how have particular conceptions of viability informed state policies and planning approaches? More broadly, how have different notions of viability influenced the politics of land in re- cent years? This paper interrogates this influential but under-examined notion, reflecting on debates about the viability of land reform – and in particular about the relevance of small- scale, farming-based livelihoods – in southern Africa and more broadly3. These questions are not merely of academic interest.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalist Dynamics from Above and Below in China
    Forthcoming July 2015 with the special issue "AGRARIAN CHANGE IN CONTEMPORARY CHINA" of Journal of Agrarian Change Agrarian Capitalization without Capitalism?: Capitalist Dynamics from Above and Below in China Hairong Yan and Yiyuan Chen Abstract: Cooperatives, family farms, and dragon-head enterprises are emerging as new subjects of agriculture in China and are being promoted by the Chinese government as engines of agricultural development. The current dynamics of increasing capitalization of agriculture in China has been characterized by scholar Philip Huang as ‘capitalization without proletarianization’. Through case studies, we examine the dynamics of accumulation in Chinese agriculture, as well as the government's agriculture policy shift. We argue that capitalist dynamics exist in Chinese agricultural production and they come from above and below. We also argue that Chinese government’s policy shift toward de-peasantization began in the early years of the rural reform. Keywords: capital accumulation, agrarian capitalism, agrarian populism, Chayanov, China INTRODUCTION: CONTEXT AND DEBATES Thirty some years of market reform has significantly transformed China’s agrarian society and agricultural production. The official political discourse in China disavows Chinese capitalism in general. The Chinese government avows upholding socialism and making markets play ‘a decisive role’ at the same breath (China Daily 2013). It is reported that the private sector already employs 85 per cent of the national labour force, owns 60 per cent of the enterprise capital (Lu 2013) and produced more than 60 per cent GDP in 2013 (Xinhuawang 2014). Reform is underway to open the remaining public sector for private investors. With regard to agricultural sector, the latest national policy asserts ‘socialist market economy’, but strengthens a market-determined pricing system and promotes new subjects (agents) of agriculture that include agribusiness, cooperatives and family farms.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Common Rights' - What Are They?
    'Common Rights' - What are they? An investigation into rights of passage and rights of land use (or rights of common) Alan Shelley PG Dissertation in Landscape Architecture Cheltenham & Gloucester College of Higher Education April2000 Abstract There is a level of confusion relating to the expression 'common' when describing 'common rights'. What is 'common'? Common is a word which describes sharing or 'that affecting all alike'. Our 'common humanity' may be a term used to describe people in general. When we refer to something 'common' we are often saying, or implying, it is 'ordinary' or as normal. Mankind, in its earliest civilisation formed societies, usually of a family tribe, that expanded. Society is principled on community. What are 'rights'? Rights are generally agreed practices. Most often they are considered ethically, to be moral, just, correct and true. They may even be perceived, in some cases, to include duty. The evolution of mankind and society has its origins in the land. Generally speaking common rights have come from land-lore (the use of land). Conflicts have evolved between customs and the statutory rights of common people (the people of the commons). This has been influenced by Church (Canonical) law, from Roman formation, statutory enclosures of land and the corporation of local government. Privilege, has allowed 'freemen', by various customs, certain advantages over the general populace, or 'common people'. Unfortunately, the term no longer describes a relationship of such people with the land, but to their nationhood. Contents Page Common Rights - What are they?................................................................................ 1 Rights of Common ...................................................................................................... 4 Woods and wood pasture ............................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Back to the Basics: Lessons from U.S. Property Law for Land Reform
    Denver Law Review Volume 95 Issue 1 Article 9 November 2020 Back to the Basics: Lessons from U.S. Property Law for Land Reform Shelley Cavalieri Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/dlr Recommended Citation Shelley Cavalieri, Back to the Basics: Lessons from U.S. Property Law for Land Reform, 95 Denv. L. Rev. 73 (2017). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Digital Commons @ DU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Denver Law Review by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ DU. For more information, please contact [email protected],[email protected]. BACK TO THE BASICS: LESSONS FROM U.S. PROPERTY LAW FOR LAND REFORM SHELLEY CAVALIERIt ABSTRACT Redistributive land reform programs are a central development ap- proach in nations of the global south. For proponents of land reform, land redistribution is an obvious strategy, designed to reduce hunger and pov- erty, to bolster citizens' ability to support themselves and their families, and to shape the future of burgeoning democracies worldwide. But for land reform skeptics and opponents, land reform is something of a puz- zle. While states routinely redistribute money, the choice to distribute land seems somewhat peculiar. On its face, it is not obvious why land is worthy of a separate, strange approach, when this is not how nations con- sider the allocation of many other crucial non-monetary resources. To invest money in reducing the concentration of land by purchasing from some in order to give or sell land to others seems far more complex than simply redistributing financial resources.
    [Show full text]
  • 'Viability' in Redistributive Land Reform : Perspectives from Southern Africa
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by IDS OpenDocs Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Working Paper 15 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Working paper for Livelihoods after Land Reform Project Ben Cousins1 and Ian Scoones2 June 2009 1 Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies (PLAAS), University of the Western Cape. 2 Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex. PLAAS Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies 1 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Contents Introduction 3 Modernisation and agricultural development in southern Africa: past and present 5 Framing viability: frameworks for assessing land and agrarian reform 9 Viability in redistributive land reform in southern Africa 21 Rethinking viability in southern African land reform 31 Conclusion 34 References 35 2 Contested paradigms of ‘viability’ in redistributive land reform: perspectives from southern Africa Introduction ‘Viability’ is a key term in debates about land reform in southern African and beyond, and is used in relation to both individual projects and programmes. ‘Viability’ connotes ‘success- ful’ and ‘sustainable’ - but what is meant by viability in relation to land reform, and how have particular conceptions of viability informed state policies and planning approaches? More broadly, how have different notions of viability influenced the politics of land in re- cent years? This paper interrogates this influential but under-examined notion, reflecting on debates about the viability of land reform – and in particular about the relevance of small- scale, farming-based livelihoods – in southern Africa and more broadly3.
    [Show full text]
  • The Opportunities and Challenges Presented by a Land-Based Commons Approach
    Technical Committee on “Land Tenure and Development” The opportunities and challenges presented by a land-based commons approach Societies are currently having to adapt to multiple global reflection, which was facilitated and formalised by Cirad’s issues in a context of political, economic and ecological Green research unit with support from the International crises. The ‘land-based commons’ approach places col- Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), are lective action at the heart of efforts to evaluate and resolve presented in this publication. complex problems, by addressing these issues through Part 1 identifies action situations where it would be the analysis of local contexts and the structure of different useful to consider the opportunities and challenges of- international frameworks. The aim is to facilitate the fered by a land-based commons approach. Part 2 then emergence of institutional arrangements that involve the proposes various entry points that could be used to different groups and communities of interest working to mobilize scientific, cultural and social knowledge and The opportunities tackle issues at the local level, and contribute to policies highlight the different solidarity regimes that support and that can address these questions effectively. mobilize commons. Part 3 discusses the analytical This work on land-based commons is part of much framework for this procedure, which questions some of and challenges broader transdisciplinary reflection by the French Coo- the underlying assumptions that shaped previous initia- peration ‘Land Tenure and Development’ Technical tives to address land issues. Finally, Part 4 sets out six Committee (LTDTC), which has contributed to thinking guiding principles that were developed to facilitate im- presented by a land-based about ongoing changes in land and development over plementation of the land-based commons approach and the last 20 years.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Earning Rent with Your Talent
    Earning Rent with Your Talent: Modern-Day Inequality Rests on the Power to Define, Transfer and Institutionalize Talent Jonathan J.B. Mijs Harvard University This paper is forthcoming in Educational Philosophy and Teaching Abstract In this paper I develop the point that whereas talent is the basis for desert, talent itself is not meritocratically deserved. It is produced by three processes, none of which are meritocratic: (1) talent is unequally distributed by the rigged lottery of birth, (2) talent is defined in ways that favor some traits over others, and (3) the market for talent is manipulated to maximally extract advantages by those who have more of it. To see how, we require a sociological perspective on economic rent. I argue that talent is a major means through which people seek rent in modern-day capitalism. Talent today is what inherited land was to feudal societies; an unchallenged source of symbolic and economic rewards. Whereas God sanctified the aristocracy’s wealth, contemporary privilege is legitimated by meritocracy. Drawing on the work of Gary Becker, Pierre Bourdieu and Jerome Karabel, I show how rent-seeking in modern societies has come to rely principally on rent definition and creation. Inequality is produced by the ways in which talent is defined, institutionalization, and sustained by the moral deservingness we attribute to the accomplishments of talents. Consequently, today’s inequalities are as striking as ever, yet harder to challenge than ever before. Key words: Talent; meritocracy; rent; inequality. 1 Introduction Capital makes the world go ‘round. Those who own it reap the rewards. Many of the largest companies in the world are in car manufacturing (Toyota, Volkswagen), petroleum refining (Exxon Mobil, Royal Dutch Shell), and other industries that rely on copious amounts of capital.
    [Show full text]
  • Rent Control: an Interim Report to the Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development
    Golden Gate University School of Law GGU Law Digital Commons California Assembly California Documents 9-15-1975 Rent Control: An Interim Report to the Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.ggu.edu/caldocs_assembly Part of the Housing Law Commons, and the Legislation Commons Recommended Citation Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development, "Rent Control: An Interim Report to the Assembly Committee on Housing and Community Development" (1975). California Assembly. Paper 411. http://digitalcommons.law.ggu.edu/caldocs_assembly/411 This Committee Report is brought to you for free and open access by the California Documents at GGU Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in California Assembly by an authorized administrator of GGU Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. RENT CONTROL: AN INTERIM REPORT TO THE ASSEMBLY COMMITTEE ON HOUSING AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT 9/15/75 MEMBERS PETER R. CHACON, Chairman Richard Robinson, Vice Chairman Assemblyman Willie L. Brown, Jr. Assemblyman Kenneth L. Maddy Assemblyman William Campbell Assemblyman Bruce Nestande Assemblyman Paul Carpenter Assemblyman Alfred Siegler Assemblyman Mike Cull:::::n Assemblyman William Thomas Assemblyman Terry Goggin Assemblyman John Vasconcellos Assemblyman Eugene T. Gualco COMMITTEE STAFF Renle Franken, Principal Consultant Marc Sanchez, Consultant Charlotte Ashmun, Legislative Aide Sue Jones, Committee Secretary #455 RENT CONTROL: AN INTERIM REPORT TO THE ASSEMBLY COMMITTEE ON HOUSING AND COMMUNITY DEVELOPMENT Prepared by: RENEE" FRANKEN, PRINCIPAL CONSULTANT AND CHARLOTTE ASHMUN, LEGISLATIVE AIDE SEPTEMBER, 1975 TABLE OF CONTENTS I THE HISTORY OF RENT CONTROLS: AN OVERVIEW INTRODUCTION.
    [Show full text]
  • Latin-American Land Reform: the Uses of Confiscation
    Michigan Law Review Volume 63 Issue 2 1964 Latin-American Land Reform: The Uses of Confiscation Kenneth L. Karst The Ohio State University Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr Part of the Comparative and Foreign Law Commons, Land Use Law Commons, Law and Economics Commons, Legal History Commons, Legal Remedies Commons, and the Torts Commons Recommended Citation Kenneth L. Karst, Latin-American Land Reform: The Uses of Confiscation, 63 MICH. L. REV. 327 (1964). Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr/vol63/iss2/6 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Michigan Law Review at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. LATIN-AMERICAN LAND REFORM: THE USES OF CONFISCATION Kenneth L. Karst* N Latin America, every land reform is motivated principally by I political demands for equality, for the redistribution of wealth and income. The statement is true even in those countries where the governments are hostile to the idea of redistribution. Palliatives that exploit the ambiguity of the word "reform" in such countries are aimed at appeasement of the demand for sharing the wealth. Landless peasants and landowners understand perfectly well; yet, many technicians and students of land reform continue to speak a different language, a language in which land reform means anything from agricultural rent control to the introduction of hybrid corn.1 In part, talk of this kind is the product of sophistication.
    [Show full text]
  • OBJ (Application/Pdf)
    AU ESSAY ON THE ORIGIN AND DEVELOPMENT OF THE THEORY OF RENT A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF ATLANTA UNIVERSITY IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ARTS BY LAMAR HARRIS, JR. DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ATLANTA, GEORGIA AUGUST 1961 (UUL T t ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The writer wishes to express sincere thanks and appreciation to Dr. Hugo Skala, his advisor, and Head of the Department of Economics, without whose diligent assistance and guidance this work would not have been possible; and to Dr. Edward B. Williams for his untiring efforts in assisting with the completion of.this work. I wish to thank my wife, Gloria Jean, for her assistance with this work and for her devotion and inspiration. Thanks are also due Mrs. Mary Ellen James for her patience and understanding in the final typing of this thesis. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS il INTRODUCTION 1 Chapter I. MOVEMENTS, EVENTS, AND WRITERS PRECEDING THE CLASSICISTS . 3 The Beginning of Commercial Renting . 3 The Black Deaths * 3 The Enclosure Movement U The Agricultural Revolution U Forerunners to the Classicists 7 Sir William Petty 7 The Physiocrats 9 Turgot 11 II. THE CLASSICISTS 13 Adam Smith 13 The Period Preceding Maithus and Ricardo 16 Thomas Robert Malthus 19 David Ricardo 21 III. LATER WRITINGS ON THE THEORY OF RENT 26 Henry C. Carey, Nineteenth Century - American School ... 26 Frederic Bastiat, Ninettenth Century - French Writer ... 27 John Stuart Mill, Nineteenth Century - Classical School . 28 Karl Rodbertus, Nineteenth Century - State Socialist ... 29 Richard Jones, Nineteenth Century - British Historical Critic .......
    [Show full text]
  • Land Reform in the Twenty-First Century: New Challenges, New Responses
    Seattle Journal for Social Justice Volume 4 Issue 2 Article 39 May 2006 Land Reform in the Twenty-First Century: New Challenges, New Responses Roy L. Prosterman Tim Hanstad Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj Recommended Citation Prosterman, Roy L. and Hanstad, Tim (2006) "Land Reform in the Twenty-First Century: New Challenges, New Responses," Seattle Journal for Social Justice: Vol. 4 : Iss. 2 , Article 39. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj/vol4/iss2/39 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Publications and Programs at Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Seattle Journal for Social Justice by an authorized editor of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 763 Land Reform in the Twenty-First Century: New Challenges, New Responses Roy L. Prosterman1 & Tim Hanstad2 Global poverty is largely a rural phenomenon. Of the 1.2 billion people in our world living in extreme poverty—earning less than US $1 per day— approximately three-quarters live in rural areas.3 The great majority of these poor families rely on agriculture for their sustenance and well-being. For these families, land plays a dominant role in their economic and social lives, and their relationship to the land largely defines their access to opportunity, income, economic and nutritional security, and status within the community. How to improve and secure the relationship poor families have with land persists as a crucial issue in much of the world.
    [Show full text]
  • The Essential JOHN STUART MILL the Essential DAVID HUME
    The Essential JOHN STUART MILL The Essential DAVID HUME DAVID The Essential by Sandra J. Peart Copyright © 2021 by the Fraser Institute. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical articles and reviews. The author of this publication has worked independently and opinions expressed by him are, therefore, his own, and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Fraser Institute or its supporters, directors, or staff. This publication in no way implies that the Fraser Institute, its directors, or staff are in favour of, or oppose the passage of, any bill; or that they support or oppose any particular political party or candidate. Printed and bound in Canada Cover design and artwork Bill C. Ray ISBN 978-0-88975-616-8 Contents Introduction: Who Was John Stuart Mill? / 1 1. Liberty: Why, for Whom, and How Much? / 9 2. Freedom of Expression: Learning, Bias, and Tolerance / 21 3. Utilitarianism: Happiness, Pleasure, and Public Policy / 31 4. Mill’s Feminism: Marriage, Property, and the Labour Market / 41 5. Production and Distribution / 49 6. Mill on Property / 59 7. Mill on Socialism, Capitalism, and Competition / 71 8. Mill’s Considerations on Representative Government / 81 Concluding Thoughts: Lessons from Mill’s Radical Reformism / 91 Suggestions for Further Reading / 93 Publishing information / 99 About the author / 100 Publisher’s acknowledgments / 100 Supporting the Fraser Institute / 101 Purpose, funding, and independence / 101 About the Fraser Institute / 102 Editorial Advisory Board / 103 Fraser Institute d www.fraserinstitute.org Introduction: Who Was John Stuart Mill? I have thought that in an age in which education, and its improvement, are the subject of more, if not of profounder study than at any former period of English history, it may be useful that there should be some record of an education which was unusual and remarkable.
    [Show full text]