Cognitive Style, Selectivity, and Reinforcement: Toward

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Cognitive Style, Selectivity, and Reinforcement: Toward Published as: Rinke, Eike Mark, and Julia Lück. 2010. “Cognitive Style, Selectivity, and Reinforcement: Toward Clarifying the Role of Political Ideology in the Reception of Political Communication.” In Politische Kommunikation Heute: Beiträge des 5. Düsseldorfer Forums Politische Kommunikation, edited by Kathrin Mok and Michael Stahl, 219–34. Berlin, Germany: Frank & Timme. Published version available in public domain courtesy of Frank & Timme publishers. EIKE MARK RINKE & JULIA LÜCK Cognitive Style, Selectivity, and Reinforcement: Toward Clarifying the Role of Political Ideology in the Reception of Political Communication If political communication does not entail uniform effects, what is it really that conditions the consequences of political messages for their recipients? Com- munication researchers have asked this question for a long time and »political predispositions« has been a popular answer for nearly as long. It dates back at least to Lazarsfeld et al.’s familiar »People’s Choice« study (1944) and Hyman and Sheatsley’s (1947) statements that »people seek informationMaterial congenial to their attitudes« (p. 417) and »people will interpret … information in different ways, according to their prior attitudes« (p. 418). These phenomena have later been referred to as selective exposure and selective perception (Klapper, 1960). For various reasons, there has been a resurging interest in scholarship on partisan selectivity in political communication of late. The purpose of this paper is to contribute to this line of researchgeschütztes by envisaging an integration of concepts, theories and methodological instruments from the »motivated social cognition approach« (Jost et al., 2003) in political psychology. We take the first steps of this integrative enterprise: First, we outline the relevance of motivated selectivity research in the context of ongoing minimal effects debates. After that, we present readers with the current scope of research in the field of selective exposure and perception. Finally, we sketch a novel approach to research on political partisan selectivities in political communication, one that should paveurheberrechtlich the way for a better understanding of the nature of such selectivi- ties and, by extension, of the different patterns of media effects as they occur along lines of ideological difference. 1 »Minimal Effects«: The Resurgence of a Familiar Paradigm In a recent article, Bennett and Iyengar (2008) suggest that today we are facing »a new era of minimal effects« referring back to a notion developed in 1940s © Frank & Timme Verlag für wissenschaftliche Literatur 219 and early 1950s media effects research. Lazarsfeld and his colleagues (1944) proposed a substitution of the commonsensical paradigm of strong media effects with a model of »limited effects« and Klapper (1960) maintained that if there are any media effects at all they would be highly conditional and depend- ing on predispositions of the audience – thus, what media can do is reinforce existing attitudes and opinions rather than change them. According to Bennett and Iyengar (2008) as well as Stroud (2008), the major difference between the historical situations in the 1940s and the beginning twentieth century is that in the mid-twentieth century social networks (e.g., churches and parties) exerted a stronger influence on the individual predispositions of citizens compared to today’s situation in which ties to such networks have become looser, more flexible, and more temporary. At the same time, opportunities to primarily attend to information that fits existing beliefs have grown due to greater choice of media options. These complementary developments have led to a resurgent interest of scholars in the minimal effects paradigm. In Materiallight of these develop- ments Bennett and Iyengar (2008: 724) conclude: »As media audiences devolve into smaller, like-minded subsets of electorates, it becomes less likely that media messages will do any other than reinforce prior predispositions« This view suggests that sweeping effects of political communication are highly unlikely. But, as Iyengar and Simon (2000) suggest, this does in no way entail that »effects« should be discarded completely.geschütztes Rather, what we are confronted with is an increasing need to properly conceptualize media effects in order to better understand them. They propose what they call a »resonance model« of political communication effects. Such a model is meant to account for interac- tions between features of content or sources of political communication and audience characteristics in the emergence of political communication effects. Underlying this model is the recognition that even if voters might not be persuaded by any particular political message this does not mean that it has no effect at all.urheberrechtlich As has been shown by Holbert (2005), for example, viewing debates between US presidential candidates tends to reinforce voting decisions of Democrats and Republicans rather than to reverse them. However, the reinforcement hypothesis has not gone uncriticized. An illustrative case in point is a study conducted by Chaffee and Miyo (1983), who tested the hy- pothesis in a panel study of adolescents and their parents concluding that reinforcement based on political partisanship only occurs under specific circumstances (e.g., among people with less political experience) – which led them to reject a straightforward generalization of the hypothesis. However, 220 © Frank & Timme Verlag für wissenschaftliche Literatur enormous social and technological change has occurred since the 1980s which seems to warrant a reconsideration of the claims associated with the minimal effects paradigm. A common denominator of early minimal effect theories and their today equivalents is the assumption that people choose and perceive media informa- tion according to their existing predispositions. As was noted above, the two most prominent mechanisms which work to produce minimal effects under- stood as »reinforcement effects« have been those of selective exposure to and selective perception of messages received through mediated communication. Understanding the nature of minimal effects assumptions thus necessitates an understanding of selectivity in media exposure and perception. We will pro- vide a brief review of important milestones in selective exposure and percep- tion research in the following section1, before we propose to draw on the »motivated social cognition« model of ideology from political psychology as a new direction in research on reinforcement effects in politicalMaterial communication. 2 Selective Exposure and Perception: Mechanisms of Partisan Reinforcement Selective exposure research has tried togeschütztes clarify whether, why, how and under which conditions media users tend to selectively expose themselves to media information. Despite the age of the concept, the very concept of selective exposure is still disputed in academic debate (Stroud, 2008; Smith, Fabrigar, & Norris, 2008). The task before us here is to present the evidence for an assump- tion of widespread contemporary selective exposure and contrast it with evidence for the alternative rival hypothesis that giving people access to more and more information leads to them being confronted with diverse opinions and worldviewsurheberrechtlich as well as being more informed and open-minded. To this end, our first step will be to explain the concept of selective exposure before giving a brief review of traditional as well as more recent research in this field. One of the first theories where selective exposure was a central approach to explain how people choose information was Festinger’s »Theory of Cognitive Dissonance« (1957). This work has been a frequent subject of academic disputes, with some arguing for its validity (e.g., D’Alessio & Allen, 2002) and ............................................ 1 For a more extended recent review of selective exposure research, see Smith, Fabrigar, & Norris (2008). © Frank & Timme Verlag für wissenschaftliche Literatur 221 others arguing against its empirical evidence (e.g., Donsbach, 1991). Notwith- standing these disputes, its heavy influence on selective exposure research is beyond question. Festinger argued that an urge to avoid cognitive dissonance is a universal human trait and that there is a universal need for cognitive closure in humans. This means that people avoid information that is inconsis- tent to the existing opinions and more or less ignore information that does not fit into their own worldview. Consequently, in his view, selective exposure is a key strategic action to reduce intraindividual dissonance. A decade later, Sears and Freedman (1967) published a widely regarded overview of then-available selective exposure research, in an attempt to rectify conceptual inconsistencies and clarify the empirical evidence available at the time. One of their major conclusions was that rather than looking for selectiv- ity in exposure to attitude-inconsistent information it might be more useful to investigate partisan selectivity in the perception (in their words: evaluation) of such information. In the conceptual part of their exposition,Material they distinguish three different definitions of selective exposure. These distinctions are still important to bear in mind when dealing with this concept. The first notion of selective exposure they identified was as »[a]ny systematic bias in audience composition« (Sears & Freedman, 1967: 195). Here, selective exposure
Recommended publications
  • How I Taught Law and Economics
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Australasian Journal of Economics Education Vol. 2. Numbers 1 & 2, 2005 1 HOW I TAUGHT LAW AND ECONOMICS Warren J. Samuels Professor Emeritus Michigan State University, USA EDITOR’S NOTE:∗ Introduction I taught graduate law and economics for some years at Michigan State University. Technically it was listed either under Public Finance, in which field I had taught graduate and undergraduate Public Expenditure Theory for some years, or as a free-standing course (not within a field). The actual title of the course, Economics 819, was Economic Role of Government. The catalog description of the course read: Analysis of fundamentals of economic role of government with focus on social control and social change; legal basis of economic institutions; applications to specialized problems and institutions. The specific objectives of the course were three: 1. Insight into the “fundamentals of the economic role of government” beyond spending and taxing per se. 2. Insight into the problems of studying the fundamentals of the economic role of government: sources and conceptual, ideological and substantive materials. 3. Identification and mastery of several alternative approaches to the economic role of government, or to “law and economics.” I taught the course once a year for over ten years, sometimes during the regular academic year and sometimes during the summer. After technically retiring I taught the course each Fall for several years. 1. INTRODUCTORY LECTURES The specific approaches comprising the course are (1) Neoclassical, which has two strands, Pigovian and Paretian; (2) Institutional; (3) Critical Legal Studies; and (4) Marxian; these were briefly elaborated upon.
    [Show full text]
  • Selective Perception
    SELECTIVE PERCEPTION THOMAS A. RUSSMAN Catholic University ofAmerica N THE YEARS SINCE THE PUBLICATION of Wittgenstein's Philo­ I sophical Investigations, two developments in fields not strictly philosophical have taken the momentum from positivism: discovery (1), in the history of science, the increasing realization that the scientific enterprise is largely governed by what Thomas Kuhn called "paradigms"; discovery (2), in the neurosciences, the increasing understanding of the high degree of selectivity involved in, for example, the physiological process of visual perception. The purpose of this paper is to examine some implications of these two developments and estimate to what extent they push us toward Wittgensteinian or neo-Kantian views. My contention will be that they push us in these directions less than at first might appear and that their chief thrust is in another direction entirely. Discovery (1) was a fatal blow to the Baconian conception that science begins with neutral observations, is ruled by nothing but what is given, and proceeds thence to permanent conclusions via an assured method of induction. Rather, scientific observation is guided by theory; out of the infinite possibilities of all that could be observed, a given theory makes some of these observables "in­ teresting" by predicting their connection with a larger body of knowledge about the world. Interesting observations, designed to verify the theory in hand, are the ones sought by scientists, who characteristically require elaborate and exact apparatus to conduct these observations. What is even more scandalous from the view­ point of the positivist scientific mythology, the hold of a current theory is sometimes so strong as to cause the dismissal of ex­ perimental discoveries that are vindicated later.
    [Show full text]
  • Perception.Pdf
    148 PERCEPTION: A DETERMINANT FOR EFFECTIVE COMMUNICATION By Lanre 0/aodu Amodu Through whic~ To whom? Abstract With what effe Communication may be the process whereby a source encodes a message and sends it through a medium to a receiver. It may even involve the sending of a From feedback by the receiver to the source; however, effective communication goes far communicatio1 beyond this level. It has been observed that the fact that a receiver receives the originator and actual message does not guarantee that he interprets it in the way intended by the the receiver is source. Any message received is interpreted in the light of the perception of the In an< receiver. This study therefore examines the relevance and significance of other sal ient perception to communication. It also examines what communication is, and how the Communicatio process is mediated by the perceptual process. A Perceptual Communication automatically Model is proposed in the study to explain the relationship between communication communicatior and perception. The study concludes by suggesting that communicators should correspondenc design messages in terms of their receivers' perceptual inclination rather than feedback from focusing entirely on the elements of the communication. by the source, In a fL Introduction by psych ologi ~ Gamble and Gamble (2005) describe communication as being located in the core of our communicatio1 "humanness." This can be considered to be an apt description since our lives truly depend on neither a beg i communication. Communication forms the centre of human existence because it is the means by receiver who ~ which human beings relate with their environment.
    [Show full text]
  • Selective Perceptions and Group Brainstorming: an Investigation of Auditors’ Fraud Risk Assessment
    INDIAN INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT AHMEDABAD INDIA Research and Publications Selective Perceptions and Group Brainstorming: An Investigation of Auditors’ Fraud Risk Assessment Naman Desai Vishal Gupta W.P. No.2015-03-14 March 2015 The main objective of the working paper series of the IIMA is to help faculty members, research staff and doctoral students to speedily share their research findings with professional colleagues and test their research findings at the pre-publication stage. IIMA is committed to maintain academic freedom. The opinion(s), view(s) and conclusion(s) expressed in the working paper are those of the authors and not that of IIMA. INDIAN INSTITUTE OF MANAGEMENT AHMEDABAD-380 015 INDIA IIMA INDIA Research and Publications Selective Perceptions and Group Brainstorming: An Investigation of Auditors’ Fraud Risk Assessment Naman Desai Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad [email protected] Vishal Gupta Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad [email protected] Abstract Individuals in an organizational context are routinely faced with complex problems that are not well defined and that challenge their cognitive capacities. To deal with such complex issues, decision-makers construct “belief-structures” which in turn create selective perceptions about information and events that prevent them from being overwhelmed by the amount and complexity of information. This study examines the impact of two important contextual variables; pressures and opportunities on auditors‟ selective perceptions and fraud risk assessments. Research suggests that a situation relevant concept, norm, perspective, or cognitive process that is shared by a majority of the group members, will be exaggerated in a group setting where groups are trying to accomplish a task that does not have a normatively/demonstrably correct answer.
    [Show full text]
  • Mind Perception Daniel R. Ames Malia F. Mason Columbia
    Mind Perception Daniel R. Ames Malia F. Mason Columbia University To appear in The Sage Handbook of Social Cognition, S. Fiske and N. Macrae (Eds.) Please do not cite or circulate without permission Contact: Daniel Ames Columbia Business School 707 Uris Hall 3022 Broadway New York, NY 10027 [email protected] 2 What will they think of next? The contemporary colloquial meaning of this phrase often stems from wonder over some new technological marvel, but we use it here in a wholly literal sense as our starting point. For millions of years, members of our evolving species have gazed at one another and wondered: what are they thinking right now … and what will they think of next? The interest people take in each other’s minds is more than idle curiosity. Two of the defining features of our species are our behavioral flexibility—an enormously wide repertoire of actions with an exquisitely complicated and sometimes non-obvious connection to immediate contexts— and our tendency to live together. As a result, people spend a terrific amount of time in close company with conspecifics doing potentially surprising and bewildering things. Most of us resist giving up on human society and embracing the life of a hermit. Instead, most perceivers proceed quite happily to explain and predict others’ actions by invoking invisible qualities such as beliefs, desires, intentions, and feelings and ascribing them without conclusive proof to others. People cannot read one another’s minds. And yet somehow, many times each day, most people encounter other individuals and “go mental,” as it were, adopting what is sometimes called an intentional stance, treating the individuals around them as if they were guided by unseen and unseeable mental states (Dennett, 1987).
    [Show full text]
  • Perception, Fairness, Psychological Traps, and Emotions
    CHAPTER 3 Perception, Fairness, Psychological Traps, and Emotions From JAY FOLBERG, DWIGHT GOLANN, THOMAS STIPANOWICH & LISA KLOPPENBERG, RESOLVING DISPUTES: THEORY, PRACTICE & LAW (2d ed. 2010) A. The Role of Perceptions The key to understanding and mastering negotiation is to be aware that those in conflict and who want something from one another see the situation differently. It is these differences that give root to conflict and to the need to negotiate, as well as to the possibility of agreement. We assess conflict and evaluate a case or the worth of an item differently because of differing perceptions. Our individual perceptions determine how we view ourselves, others, and the world. No two views are exactly the same. For example, we may selectively perceive or differ in our perceptions of the following: • facts • abilities • people • available resources • interests • scarcity • history • timing • fairness • costs • priorities • applicable law or rules • relative power • likely outcomes Our view of each of these elements, as well as our perceptions of other variables, shape how we see the world and how we form differences. It is because of such differences in perceptions that people bet on horse races, wage war, and pursue lawsuits. A classic Japanese story, on which the film Rashomon is based, illustrates the role of perceptions and how the truth through one person’s eyes may be very different from another’s, as seen through the prism of the individuals’ own perceptions. Through divergent narratives, the story and the film explore how perceptions distort or enhance different people’s memories of a single event, in this case, the death of a Samurai warrior.
    [Show full text]
  • It's No Longer the Economy, Stupid: Selective Perception and Attribution
    4/2/2019 It's No Longer the Economy, Stupid (VERSION 6) - Google Docs It’s No Longer the Economy, Stupid: Selective Perception and Attribution of Economic Outcomes April 2019 Sean Freeder University of California, Berkeley Abstract: Scholars of American politics have long touted retrospective economic voting as a means by which citizens capably exercise democratic accountability, despite their overall inattentiveness to politics, and susceptibility to elite manipulation. In an era of runaway polarization, this may no longer be true. Using data from the American National Election Study, General Social Survey, and original survey experiments, I present evidence that the relationship between incumbent reelection and economic performance has weakened considerably. I argue that the decline is explained by two psychological mechanisms for motivated reasoning: first, citizens are likelier to misperceive the economy if the alternative would mean acknowledging the seeming successes of the other party, or the apparent failings of their own. Second, even when citizens perceive the economy correctly, they often selectively attribute actual credit or blame for economic outcomes in a manner consistent with their partisanship. I present evidence not only that citizens regularly engage in selective perception and selective attribution, but that they trade off between the two depending on which, in a given election, requires the least cognitive effort for maintaining the perceived superiority of their own party. Both the decline of economic voting and
    [Show full text]
  • Communication Theories
    Communication Theories Athira K M • Hypodermic Needle Theory, also known as Magic Bullet Theory (hypodermic syringe model or transmission-belt model) was promulgated by Harold Lasswell in 1920s. • It was written in the book “Propaganda Technique” in the World War. • Media dependency theory, a systematic approach to the study of the effects of mass media on audiences and of the interactions between media, audiences, and social systems. • It was introduced in outline by the American communications researchers Sandra Ball-Rokeach and Melvin DeFleur in 1976. • Dependency theory conceives of dependency as a relationship in which the fulfillment of one party‟s needs and goals is reliant on the resources of another party. • A main focus of the theory is the relationship between media and audiences. • In industrialized and information-based societies, individuals tend to develop a dependency on the media to satisfy a variety of their needs, which can range from a need for information on a political candidate‟s policy positions (to help make a voting decision) to a need for relaxation and entertainment. In general, the extent of the media‟s influence is related to the degree of dependence of individuals and social systems on the media. Two of the basic propositions put forward by Ball-Rokeach and DeFleur are: (1) the greater the number of social functions performed for an audience by a medium (e.g., informing the electorate, providing entertainment), the greater the audience‟s dependency on that medium, and (2) the greater the instability of a society (e.g., in situations of social change and conflict), the greater the audience‟s dependency on the media and, therefore, the greater the potential effects of the media on the audience.
    [Show full text]
  • Rashawn Ray's CV
    Rashawn Ray Curriculum Vitae September 2020 CONTACT INFORMATION Department of Sociology University of Maryland 2112 Parren J. Mitchell Art-Sociology Building College Park, MD 20742 (301) 405-9581 [email protected] https://www.brookings.edu/experts/rashawn-ray/ EMPLOYMENT David M. Rubenstein Fellow, Governance Studies, The Brookings Institution, 2019-2021 Professor of Sociology, University of Maryland, 2020-present Director, Lab for Applied Social Science Research (LASSR), 2017-present Affiliate Faculty Member, Department of Women’s Studies, 2015-present Research Associate, Maryland Population Research Center, 2012-present Associate Professor of Sociology with tenure, University of Maryland, 2016-2020 Edward McK. Johnson, Jr. Endowed Faculty Fellow, 2016-2018 Assistant Professor, Department of Sociology, 2012-2016 Associate Research Director, Consortium on Race, Gender, and Ethnicity (CRGE), 2015 Robert Wood Johnson Foundation Health Policy Research Postdoctoral Scholar, University of California, Berkeley/UCSF, 2010-2012 Savant Outreach Coordinator, Office for Women’s Affairs, Indiana University, 2008-2010 Visiting Scholar and Lecturer, University of Mannheim-Germany, 2008 EDUCATION Ph.D., Sociology, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, 2010 Minor: Research Methods M.A., Sociology, Indiana University, Bloomington, Indiana, 2005 B.A, Sociology, University of Memphis, Memphis, TN, 2003 Minor: Women Studies Magna Cum Laude with University Honors Rashawn Ray 2 RESEARCH AND TEACHING INTERESTS Social Psychology, Race Relations, Race-Class-Gender, Family, and Health Policy PUBLICATIONS (*Denotes graduate student of Rashawn Ray; **Denotes community partner) Books Jackson, Pamela Braboy and Rashawn Ray. 2018. How Families Matter: Simply Complicated Intersections of Race, Gender, and Work. Lexington Books: Lanham, MD. Ray, Rashawn (Ed.). 2017. [2010]. Race and Ethnic Relations in the 21st Century: History, Theory, Institutions, and Policy (Revised First Edition).
    [Show full text]
  • Selective Beliefs Over Preferences∗
    Selective Beliefs over Preferences∗ Luke A. Stewart University of California, Berkeley April 29, 2009 Abstract People tend to believe what they want to believe. In this paper, I examine how people interpret others' behavior to form beliefs about others' preferences. I develop a \selective beliefs" model of social preferences in which people have intrinsic preferences over outcomes and also hold prior beliefs about the preferences of others. I propose that people attempt to selectively perceive and interpret others' behavior such that their posterior beliefs about others' preferences minimally interfere with their own self-interest. From a general model, I derive two specific models designed for the regression analysis of a semi-transparent simplified ultimatum game experiment, where I assume that the second-mover forms posterior beliefs about first-mover's preferences over the second-mover's two possible outcome choices. The inequality aversion model is designed to measure the second-mover's behavioral response to an available signal indicating that the first-mover has some degree of aversion to inequality. The income concern model measures the second-mover's behavioral response to an available signal indicating that the first-mover is either concerned or unconcerned about income. ∗I am ever grateful to my thesis adviser, Professor Botond K}oszegi,for his invaluable input and for coolly fielding an extraordinary number of questions on everything from psychology and economics to word-processing. I also thank Professor Roger Craine for his generous advice on the research process. 1 Introduction In the absence of meaningful communication, social interaction is governed by personal preferences, social convention, and the assumptions people make about the preferences of others based on incomplete information.
    [Show full text]
  • Concept of Communication Theory
    JOURNALISM & MASS COMMUNICATION JMC-07 CONCEPT OF COMMUNICATION THEORY Block 1 Concept of Communication Theory Unit-1 Importance of Communication Theory, Wwo Step Flow & Multistep Flow Theory, Individual Difference Theory, Unit-2 Selectivity & Gatekeeping Theory, Diffusion of Innovation Theory, Personal Influence Theory Unit-3 Authoritarian Theory, Libertarian Theory, Communist Media Theory, Social Responsibility Theory Unit-4 Development Media Theory, Democratic Participation Theory, Communication Convergence. 1 Expert Committee Members Prof. Mrinal Chatterjee Chairman Professor, IIMC, Dhenkanal Dr. Dipak Samantarai Member Director, NABM, Bhubaneswar Dr. Asish Kumar Dwivedy Member Asst. Professor (Communication) Studies, SoA University, Bhubaneswar Sudhir Patnaik Member Editor, Samadrusti Sujit Kumar Mohanty Member Asst. Professor (Journalism & Mass Communication) Central University of Orissa, Koraput Jyoti Prakash Mohapatra Member Convenor Academic Consultant (Journalism & Mass Communication), Odisha State Open University, Sambalpur Course Writer: Course Editor Ruby Nanda Sanjay Kumar Sahoo Media Academician Media Academician Material Production : Dr. JayantaKar Sharma Registrar Odisha State Open University, Sambalpur © OSOU, 2017. Promoting Use and Contribution of Open Education Resources is made available under a Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike 4.0 http://creativecommons.org/licences/by-sa/4.0 Printed by Sri Mandir Publication, Sahid Nagar, Bhubaneswar 2 JMC-07 Block 1 Content UNIT 1 1.0 Unit structure 05 1.1 Learning Objectives
    [Show full text]
  • Slavery and Polarization, 1819-1860
    Slavery and Polarization, 1819-1860 Investigation: Abolitionism When people disagree about something important to them, polarization can grow. Those involved choose sides and begin to see events and situations as “us” versus “them.” The driving force for polarization is emotion, which generally increases on both sides. In the period before the Civil War, people in the North and South disagreed about tariffs on imports, about how power should be divided between the state and national governments, and about slavery. Opposition to slavery in the North became the most important “trigger” of the Civil War. Simple, strong shared ideas about what’s right and fair form the “ideology” of the group holding the ideas. In the following data, identify the ideology of the groups involved. Opposition to Slavery Opposition to slavery started during the colonial period. Efforts to abolish it were led by a few religious groups who felt that slavery was morally wrong. Even in the South there had been opposition to slavery. In the 1830s more and more people began to speak out in favor of abolition—ending slavery—and it soon became a “movement” in the North. Abolitionists organized societies, gave speeches, published articles, and mailed literature throughout the country, including the South. The view of the American Anti-Slavery Society, an abolitionist group founded in 1833: We believe that no man has the right to enslave his brother, or to hold him as a piece of merchandise. No man has a right to earn wages for someone else’s work. No man has the right to deny another a chance to improve his mind, his way of life, or his morals.
    [Show full text]