<<

Strategic Journal Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) Published online EarlyView 15 July 2016 in Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) DOI: 10.1002/smj.2540 Received 12 May 2015; Final revision received 22 April 2016

PRODUCT VARIETY AND VERTICAL INTEGRATION YUE MAGGIE ZHOU1,* and XIANG WAN2 1 Department of Strategy, Stephen M. Ross School of , University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, Michigan, U.S.A. 2 Department of and Logistics, Fisher College of Business, Ohio State University, Columbus, Ohio, U.S.A.

Research summary: In vertical relationships, the potential for scale economy in often calls for specialization and . Specialization, however, depends critically on the stability of the task and contractual environment. In a highly uncertain environment, the need for frequent mutual adjustments favors integration instead of outsourcing. To evaluate vertical relationships in chains where one stage competes on product variety under great uncertainty and the other stage competes on scale, we compare operations data at about 300 centers within a major soft-drink bottler before and after it was integrated into an upstream concentrate producer. We find that vertical integration improved coordination for the integrated firm by aligning incentives and reducing strategic information asymmetry, butit worsened coordination for upstream rivals that shared the same downstream facilities. Managerial summary: Managers make frequent decisions about outsourcing versus integration. This article helps to crystalize the costs and benefits of integration by pointing to two important factors: the potential for and the need for coordination under uncertainty. It studies an where one stage of the value chain competes on product variety under great uncertainty and the other stage competes on scale. Based on operations data at about 300 distribution centers within a major soft-drink bottler before and after it was integrated into an upstream concentrate producer, we find that vertical integration improved coordination for the integrated firm (by reducing both stockouts and inventory, and improving forecasts), butit worsened coordination for upstream rivals that shared the same downstream facilities. Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

INTRODUCTION mutual adaptation along the value chain (Helfat and Campo-Rembado, 2016; Helfat and Raubitschek, Repeated exchange relationships along the value 2000), thereby accommodating product variety and chain are vulnerable to coordination problems differentiation (Argyres and Bigelow, 2010). From when an upstream firm competes on product vari- the downstream firm’s perspective, contracting ety, with the products manufactured and distributed enables gains to specialization by allowing the by a downstream firm that competes on scale. downstream firm to pool contacts from multiple From the upstream firm’s perspective, vertical customers to achieve economies of scale and integration helps to coordinate product sequencing learning (Jacobides and Hitt, 2005). Uncertainty and successive that require frequent aggravates these incentive conflicts and makes contracting costly (Klein, 2000; Teece, 1996; Williamson, 1975). Should the two stages verti- Keywords: vertical integration; coordination; product variety; information asymmetry; stockout cally integrate to pursue product differentiation *Correspondence to: Yue Maggie Zhou. 701 Tappan Street, despite the higher production cost, or should they R4446, Ann Arbor, MI 48109. Phone: (734) 763-1436. E-mail: continue to contract for scale and compromise [email protected]

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1135 product variety? In this article, we investigate the (Financial Times, 2009a). To overcome the burden mechanisms by which contracting solution gives of increased coordination, both Coca-Cola and way to vertical integration when demand uncer- Pepsi restructured their largest bottlers from minor- tainty with respect to product variety increases, ity shareholdings to fully-owned subsidiaries—a and upstream competitors are affected when one of change that makes it possible for us to compare them vertically integrates the downstream facilities. multiple operations variables before and after the We propose that the downstream firm pro- full integration. ducing for multiple upstream firms exacerbates Our analyses are based on operations data at the vertical coordination challenges and jeopardizes product (stock-keeping unit, or SKU) level across the upstream firm’s product variety strategy. In hundreds of distribution centers (DCs) within a particular, sharing downstream capacity among major bottling company (the Bottler) for one dom- multiple upstream firms creates problems of strate- inant CP between 2008 and 2011, during which gic information asymmetry. On the one hand, a time the Bottler was fully acquired by the CP. downstream firm seeking to maximize its profits Our focus is a key measure of coordination perfor- may under-forecast sales for one upstream firm mance along the value chain: stockouts. Stockouts so that it produces less for this firm, but more happen when customer orders are not completely for another (Yehezkel, 2008). On the other hand, fulfilled. Frequent stockouts result in customer dis- an upstream firm may not fully share strategic satisfaction, and ultimately, hurt sales, profitabil- information down the value chain (Novak and ity, and future demand (Anderson, Fitzsimons, and Eppinger, 2001). For instance, even though pro- Simester, 2006a; Musalem et al., 2010; Wan, Evers, viding incomplete or untimely information makes and Dresner, 2012). It is therefore an important per- the downstream firm’s sales forecasts noisy, the formance measure in the product variety literature. upstream firm may still keep or new We first examined about 1,200 SKUs that were product launch plans in secrecy until shortly before produced and distributed by the Bottler for the the actual event because it fears the information parent CP both before and after full integration. being leaked to competing upstream firms that We found that despite the Bottler’s significantly share the same downstream facilities. If one of the increased product offerings in the NonCSD cat- upstream firms integrates the downstream firm, egory after integration, the stockout rate for an the coordination between these two firms can average DC–SKU pair in our sample dropped by be enhanced by aligning incentives and sharing two percent (from a pre-integration sample average information, albeit at a cost to the other upstream of 26%), and that the reduction was significantly firms that still share the downstream facilities. more for NonCSDs than for CSDs. We test these in the soft-drink industry, where We then explored the mechanisms of incentive the two dominant concentrate producers (CPs), and information that could influence stockouts. A Coca-Cola and Pepsi, compete fiercely on product downstream firm wants to lower its production variety and on-time store delivery. For decades, the and distribution costs, mainly through producing CPs have been taking advantage of their market and delivering a single category of products with power and securing supply through exclusive large volumes and avoiding products with rela- contracts with the bottlers. The large CPs also tively low and uncertain demand as well as through allow their bottlers to produce for other smaller minimizing excess inventory. Because NonCSDs CPs. This sharing arrangement maximizes scale, have smaller and less certain demand, and produc- but creates obstacles along other dimensions, ing them requires bottlers to frequently adjust their such as making it more difficult to introduce process away from producing CSDs, bottlers have and coordinate new products. These difficulties less incentive to carry NonCSDs, notwithstanding became more pronounced over the last decade as the greater strategic value of NonCSDs for the CPs. the CPs faced increasing pressure to diversify their A full integration reduces incentive conflicts; we product categories from traditional carbonated therefore expected our analysis to show DCs car- soft drinks (CSDs) to healthier, noncarbonated rying higher inventories after integration, particu- soft drinks (NonCSDs). However, bottlers have larly among NonCSDs. However, to our surprise, strongly opposed this change as their existing we found that the inventory of NonCSDs decreased capital-intensive production process relies heav- (relative to both actual and forecasted sales) after ily on economies of scale from CSD products integration. The reduction in both stockouts and

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1136 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan inventory suggests that integration created an over- upstream firms is consistent with the hypothesis that all improvement in coordination efficiency. firms’ horizontal and vertical scopes could also be We next examined if the improved efficiency substitutive due to constraints in a firm’s total coor- was consistent with an improvement in informa- dination capacity (Zhou, 2011). tion sharing along the value chain. We compared Second, for the literature on product variety, DCs’ sales forecasts before and after integration. our focus on coordination problems echoes prior We found that DCs adjusted their sales forecasts research on the operational risk of product variety upward, especially if they were located close to the despite its strategic value (Barnett and Freeman, CP, where integration could enable closer monitor- 2001; Cottrell and Nault, 2004; Sorenson, 2000). ing by the CP. We also found that DCs reduced While the operations issues that arise with product the noise (standard deviation) in their sales fore- variety in stockouts, inventory, and forecasting error casts. This reduction was greater for DCs located far have been studied in the from the CP, where they could not easily observe the literature (Fisher, 1997; Fisher and Ittner, 1999; CP’s plan for product launches and promotions, and Wan and Dresner, 2015), studies about product vari- would therefore benefit more from explicit notifica- ety and organizational interactions along the supply tion from the CP after integration. We also found chain are rare (Ramdas, 2003). By focusing on verti- that DCs reduced forecasting noise more for newer cal integration, this article introduces organizational products, for which the DCs would have less experi- factors to the analyses. ence in estimating the impact of disturbance caused Finally, our analyses add to a rich body of case by promotion and other product launches. studies on vertical integration in general and the As a comparison, we examined about 300 SKUs soft-drink industry in particular (Karnani, 2010; (mostly CSDs) produced and distributed by the Klein, 2000; Muris, Scheffman, and Spiller, 1992; Bottler for its CP parent’s competitors under Yoffie and Kim, 2012). While the majority of license agreements. We find that for these products, prior cases examine transaction costs arising from stockout rates increased after integration, while relationship-specific investments, the current article both inventory and sales forecasts reduced. In focuses on a narrow time window around vertical addition, the noise in sales forecasts increased. integration, during which no significant physical This is consistent with a worsened incentive and investments were made. This allowed us a unique information problem between the upstream com- vantage from which to analyze adaptation-related petitors of the CP parent and the CP parent’s now coordination issues. fully integrated Bottler. Overall, our results suggest that, on the one hand, vertical integration enhances coordination THEORETICAL DEVELOPMENT by aligning incentives and facilitating monitoring and information sharing along the value chain. Product variety and vertical coordination On the other hand, vertical integration introduces By catering to a wider range of customer pref- a competitive disadvantage for the CP parents’ erences, product variety increases the aggregated competitors that share the same downstream demand for a firm’s products, but often reduces the facilities through contracts. demand and increases the sales volatility for indi- Our theoretical analyses and empirical findings vidual variety (e.g., Anupindi et al., 2011; Cachon have relevance for several strands of literature. First, and Terwiesch, 2012), which exacerbates coordi- they complement recent studies on the relationship nation problems along the value chain. First, it between firms’ horizontal and vertical scopes. On increases incentive conflicts between the upstream the one hand, they confirm the coordination ben- and downstream firms. For the downstream firms, efits of vertical integration for enhancing firms’ product variety increases production costs by com- adaptability across markets (Forbes and Lederman, promising economies of scale, increases equipment 2009; Novak and Stern, 2009), and the benefit of and overhead costs, and lowers worker productiv- integrative capability for seizing strategic opportu- ity. It also increases distribution costs as the down- nities in industries dominated by successive inno- stream firm has to deliver each variety in smaller vations (Helfat and Campo-Rembado, 2016; Helfat batches and keep extra inventory (wasting working and Raubitschek, 2000). On the other hand, the find- capital) to account for unexpected variation in con- ing that integration worsens coordination with rival sumer demand across varieties.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1137

In addition, product variety exacerbates informa- existing varieties. On the other hand, when the CP tion asymmetry between the upstream and down- announces a price promotion for an existing vari- stream firm. The information asymmetry can bein ety too late, the Bottler might under-forecast the both directions. On the one hand, a downstream demand for the existing variety. Therefore, secrecy firm has better information about consumers’ will- on the part of the CP about either new variety launch ingness to pay for various varieties and may not or old variety promotion against the Bottler leads to accurately share that information with the upstream forecasting noise. firm. In our context, the Bottler collects most ofthe In sum, expanding in a new product category demand information directly from the stores when increases sales volatility as well as production and its truck drivers make deliveries or when its sales distribution costs. If the strategic value of prod- representatives conduct routine inspections of store uct variety outweighs these additional costs, then shelves. The downstream firm may under-forecast the jointly optimal decision along the value chain demand so that (1) the upstream firm extracts less should be to increase variety. However, contract- value (e.g., in the form of franchise or license fees); ing between the upstream and downstream firms (2) the downstream firm produces less of the vari- to achieve a jointly optimal outcome is not easy. ety that does not maximize its profit; or (3) the Increasing product variety increases the number of downstream firm has more freedom to manufacture contingencies that need to be covered, monitored, other varieties (Yehezkel, 2008), including varieties and enforced under a contract. In addition, to the for other upstream firms. Sharing markets, facili- extent that different product varieties are interde- ties, and production processes across multiple prod- pendent in their needs for resources and adjust- uct varieties makes it difficult for the upstream firm ments, the contract may get overly complex or even to separate the demand, costs, and performance of infeasible. Because of these contracting problems, individual varieties for evaluation, compensation, we expect the Bottler to have a higher stockout rate and therefore, contracting. for NonCSDs than for CSDs before integration. On the other hand, an upstream firm might hesi- tate to share proprietary information down the value chain, especially if the downstream firm also man- Vertical integration and coordination ufactures for other upstream firms. The upstream firm’s proprietary knowledge about technological Vertical integration can improve coordination in and product design, as well as its plans several ways. First, it aligns incentives by providing for promotions and new product launches, can be both transacting parties ownership over residual more readily leaked to competitors with whom they claims (Hart and Moore, 2005; Williamson, 1985). share production or distribution facilities. Strate- It subjects organizational units to more compat- gic information withholding by upstream firms due ible profit objectives that facilitate an integrated to concerns over leakage in the is response to changes in global circumstances prevalent in many contexts with differentiated prod- (Gulati, Lawrence, and Puranam, 2005; Lawrence ucts (Anand and Goyal, 2009). These concerns and Lorsch, 1967), such as rapidly evolving may cause the upstream firm to restrict its down- technology and consumer demand (Weigelt and stream firm’s access to strategic information, even Sarkar, 2012). Second, vertical integration enables if such restrictions hinder coordination (Novak and closer monitoring of employee effort (Hart, 1995; Stern, 2009). In private conversations with us, the Williamson, 1975). Similar to arguments made by Bottler’s forecasting staff often complained about Joskow (2008), employees within a subsidiary have how, before integration, the CP waited until the last more incentive (e.g., avoiding termination for false minute to give it accurate information about promo- reporting) and obligation to reveal information tion and launch plans, leaving the Bottler too little to the parent company than employees within time to refine its sales forecasts and plan produc- a less closely affiliated contractor; the parent tion. When the CP launches a new variety without company also has more authority and means (e.g., giving the Bottler sufficient lead time, the Bottler internal auditing) to collect information from its will not be able to adequately account for the sub- own subsidiary than from a less closely affiliated stitution effect between the demand for the new contractor. Finally, vertical integration facilitates variety and the demand for the existing varieties; information sharing by weakening the incentives it will therefore over-forecast the demand for the for knowledge appropriation and better protecting

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1138 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan propriety information (Nickerson and Zenger, costs of bottling facilities and distribution networks 2004; Novak and Stern, 2009). by carrying products for its smaller rivals under In our context, after integration, the Bottler has license agreements. In fact, bottlers for Coca-Cola greater incentive to carry more NonCSDs; there- and Pepsi each manufacture and distribute about fore, it will be more likely to increase inventory. one-third of Dr. Pepper’s products. Given that this The Bottler will also have more incentive and obli- sharing arrangement mainly results from concerns gation to share information with the CP, and the about economies of scale, it might create constraints CP will have more authority to visit the stores to along other dimensions (e.g., production introduc- assess demand and evaluate sales forecasts directly. tions and coordination). Finally, the Bottler will have greater incentive and We do not conceptualize our particular context as obligation to protect the CP’s proprietary informa- a world where firms play strategic games with full tion, so that the CP will share its promotion and rationality and foresight. Rather, we view the firms product launch plans with the Bottler in a timelier as following an evolutionary process in adapting manner, thereby enabling the Bottler to make more their product-introduction and vertical-integration accurate adjustments to its forecasts and production decisions. The old arrangement in which Coca-Cola schedule. We therefore expect the Bottler to have a and Pepsi owned a minority share (<40%) in their lower stockout rate for the products of its CP parent downstream facilities and share the facilities with after integration, particularly among NonCSDs. smaller CPs through contracts discouraged (but did not totally prohibit) new product introductions. As new product introductions became more important Vertical integration and competition due to the exogenous shift in consumer demand Vertical integration offers competitive advantages toward healthier NonCSDs, the disadvantage of in oligopolistic industries. Mainly, the integrated the contractual arrangements became more and firm can foreclose either sources of supply or chan- more constraining. One way to overcome these nels of distribution to prevent their non-integrated disadvantages is vertical integration. rivals from accessing these sources or channels Therefore, we examine a more subtle form of (Chipty, 2001; Hart et al., 1990). In the soft-drink “foreclosure” that happens not through a total denial industry, the upstream segment is occupied by a of the competitors’ access to production resources small number of CPs, while the downstream seg- or distribution channels, but through a substitu- ment is populated by a large number of bottling tion of coordination along the value chain. More plants and distribution centers owned by a few specifically, vertical integration can align incentives dozen “bottlers.” This gives the large upstream and the flow of information between an upstream CPs more bargaining power over the bottlers. The firm and its downstream subsidiary, while atthe large CPs’ bargaining power is further enhanced same time magnifying incentive and information by the bottler’s need for large contracts to achieve problems between the subsidiary and the upstream economies of scale to improve their thin profit mar- parent’s competitors that also source from the sub- gin. Under such conditions, the large upstream firms sidiary. The subsidiary may now maximize its par- can use exclusive contracts to secure supply. ent’s market share at a cost to the parent’s rivals. The However, even with business from the major subsidiary may reduce its inventory holding and upstream firms, some downstream firms may not demand forecasts for rival products. The rivals may have enough volume to maximize economies of also feel less comfortable sharing strategic informa- scale. This makes it advantageous for them to con- tion with the subsidiary, leading to noisier demand tract with smaller upstream firms that need to source forecasts for their products1. Even when an inte- downstream production plants and distribution net- grated company does not intentionally foreclose its works, but lack the volume to justify an exclusive contract. In such cases, the large upstream firm 1 Of course, foreseeing that coordination problems could lead to can share its downstream facilities with smaller a loss of revenue from other upstream firms after integration, upstream firms, provided that the downstream firm the downstream firm’s current shareholders may demand an does not carry rival products that are in direct com- acquisition from the acquiring parent. However, if the strategic value of integration is greater than the potential loss petition with products of the large upstream firm. of revenue from the competitors, the parent and the downstream For example, in our context, Coca-Cola and Pepsi shareholders will be able to reach an agreement to split the net each allow its bottlers to defray the high capital gain from integration.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1139 rivals, the increase in internal coordination demands were publicly traded. After the integration, both CPs between the subsidiary and its upstream parent after established wholly owned subsidiaries that bought integration might crowd out coordination for rival out all the shares in the bottlers2. Both CPs claimed products. Because of this substitution in coordina- that the change would give them greater flexibility tion, we expect the Bottler to have a greater stockout to adapt to consumer tastes, more direct control over rate for upstream rivals’ products after integration. investments in the bottling processes, and the abil- ity to coordinate. According to Indra Nooyi, CEO of Pepsi, “The fully integrated beverage business will THE SOFT-DRINK INDUSTRY AND THE enable us to bring innovative products and pack- BOTTLING COMPANY ages to market faster, streamline our manufacturing and distribution systems and react more quickly to The soft-drink industry is dominated by two CPs, changes in the marketplace, … Ultimately it will Coca-Cola and Pepsi. Most bottlers used to be put us in a much better position to compete and to independently owned, but had exclusive long-term grow both now and in the years ahead” (Pepsi Press partnerships with a CP. Bottlers purchase con- Release, 2009). Muhtar Kent, CEO of Coca Cola, centrate from the CP, add carbonated water and gave similar comments: “The market and industry high-fructose corn syrup, bottle the resulting bev- have changed dramatically. … With this transac- erage, and deliver it to customers. Coca-Cola and tion, we are converting passive capital into active Pepsi bottlers provide direct store delivery, where capital, giving us direct control over our investment the bottlers’ sales or delivery staff routinely visit in North America to accelerate growth and drive the stores to survey sales, check product display, long-term profitability”(Coca Cola Press Release, stock the shelves, and place orders for replenish- 2010). ment (Cokesolutions, 2015). The bottling process is Our data come from the largest anchor bottler capital-intensive and relies on high-speed produc- for one of the two dominant CPs. The Bottler owns tion lines; changing between products of different dozens of bottling plants and hundreds of distribu- type or sizes is difficult. In contrast, the distribu- tion centers (DCs), accounting for more than half tion process is largely influenced by “drop size” of the beverages its CP sold in North America. (size of each delivery). As a result, bottlers pre- Like most of its competitors, the Bottler employs a fer to distribute standard products with steady and make-to-stock (as opposed to make-to-order) inven- high demand. To achieve greater scale economy, tory system. Products are produced and stocked anchor bottlers for Coca-Cola and Pepsi also pro- at a stable pace according to a forecast of future duce and distribute for their CP partner’s rivals, pro- sales, that is, before customers place actual orders. vided these products do not compete directly with Orders are placed based on the CPs’ product lists, their CP partner’s products. national advertisements, and promotion deals with- Over the last decade, major soft-drink companies out knowledge of the DCs’ actual inventory. have been under increasing pressure to expand The Bottler delivers its products on trucks to their product lines because consumers are shifting retailer stores both large (e.g., supermarkets) and to healthier, NonCSD drinks. For example, while small (e.g., convenience stores). Stockouts occur U.S. soda consumption slid for the tenth straight when a DC cannot deliver an entire order to a given year in 2014, the U.S. bottled-water consumption outlet. Unfilled demand is not backordered. jumped by 7.3 percent (Wall Street Journal, 2015). New orders are placed based on the retail store’s According to a recent Gallup survey, more than current inventory levels. Demand is forecasted for 60 percent of Americans now avoid soda (Beverage eight, four, and two weeks in the future, and updated Daily, 2015). This has shifted both Coca-Cola and every week on a rolling-horizon basis. Production Pepsi’s strategic focus toward NonCSDs. In response to the pressing need from the market 2 Because of the big difference between the CP’s and the bottler’s to expand their product lines, and the lack of incen- business models and profit margins, partial ownership does not tive for bottlers to cooperate with that expansion, in sufficiently solve the incentive or information problems between 2009–2010, both Coca-Cola and Pepsi fully inte- the two parties. Vertical integration fully aligns the two entities’ incentives, thereby improving coordination. Empirically, study- grated their largest bottlers. Before the integration, ing a transition from partial ownership (as opposed to from an each CP had owned a 30–40 percent shareholding arms-length relationship) to integration implies that our estima- stake in its anchor bottlers; the rest of the shares tion of the integration impact is more conservative.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1140 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan plans are based on the four-week-advance forecasts To compare operations before and after integra- and the current inventory level. The Bottler tries to tion, we limited our sample to those SKUs that the retain four weeks of forecasted demand in inven- 264 DCs carried at the time of integration, includ- tory at the beginning of every four-week period, ing about 1,200 SKUs owned by the CP parent and though actual inventory varies both across product 300 SKUs delivered to other upstream CPs under categories and over time. license agreements. Our final sample contains about two million DC–SKU–period observations.

EMPIRICAL DESIGN Variables The exogenous shock in the demand for NonCSDs We first examined Stockoutsit, a dummy variable became especially salient toward the end of the that takes the value of 1 if SKU s experiences at least last decade. The upstream CPs responded with one stockout at DC i in period t, and is 0 otherwise. an increased rate of product introductions in the We then examined a few other operations variables NonCSD category. The newness of these prod- in order to explain any change we observed in ucts implies more information asymmetry: The stockouts. Among them, Inventorysit, is inventory upstream firm will have greater uncertainty about (in days of sales) of SKU s carried by DC i in consumers’ willingness to pay, while the down- period t. Sales forecasts_levelsit is the ratio between stream firm will find it more difficult to predict actual and forecasted sales. It is also called AF the upstream firm’s product promotion and launch ratio, a standard measure of forecasting accuracy in plans. This is therefore a valuable period of time to operations management. It reflects the bias in sales carry out our empirical investigation. forecasts. Sales forecasts_noisesit is the standard deviation in weekly AF ratios. It reflects the noise in sales forecasts. Data and sample Our main independent variables include We obtained operations data for all of the Bottler’s Integrationt, a dummy variable that indicates the U.S. DCs from the beginning of 2008 to the second time periods after the integration, NonCSDs,a month of 2011. Together, these 264 DCs delivered dummy variable that indicates whether the SKU thousands of SKUs over the sample period, includ- is a NonCSD product, and the interaction term ing SKUs owned by the CP parent and SKUs deliv- between Integrationt and NonCSDs. We also ered for other companies under license agreements. included several control variables. Among them, A SKU is defined as a unique combination of , Salessit is the quantity (in standardized cases) of flavor, weight, container material, container size, SKU s sold by DC i in period t, log transformed. and package size. It is a commonly used measure Sales volatilitysit is measured using the coefficient of product variety (Fosfuri and Giarratana, 2009). of variation in sales, or the standard deviation of Our data is weekly except for inventory, which sales normalized by its mean. is only available at the period level. Each period Table 1 provides sample descriptive statistics contains four weeks. In order to accommodate the and correlation matrix for the combined sample of frequency of the inventory data and to save com- own and rival products. An average SKU had a putation time, we aggregated the data to the period 25 percent chance of stockouts at a DC in every level. period. Forty-two percent of the observations were We first examined some summary statistics at the for NonCSDs. An average SKU was sold in 154 DC level. We found that on average about 37 percent (exp(5.04)) cases per period per DC. The volatility of the SKUs and 20 percent of the sales carried by a in weekly sales for an average DC–SKU–period DC were for NonCSDs. In addition, there was a sig- was 0.17. The average inventory was about 31 days nificant increase in both the number of SKUs and of actual sales. The average AF ratio was 1.01. That total sales at the DC level after integration, espe- is, on average, sales forecasted by DCs were about cially for NonCSDs. The number of NonCSD SKUs 99 percent of actual sales. The standard deviation in increased by 27 percent, NonCSD sales per DC forecasts was 0.14. increased by 15 percent, and the share of NonCSD Table 2 compares mean values before and sales increased by two percent. after integration, for own CSDs, own NonCSDs,

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1141

Table 1. Summary statistics and correlation matrix

Variable Mean SD (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

(1) Stockout (1,0) 0.25 0.44 1.00 (2) Integration (1,0) 0.37 0.48 −0.001 1.00 (3) NonCSD (1,0) 0.42 0.49 0.01 −0.002 1.00 (4) Sales 5.04 1.68 0.15 −0.05 −0.31 1.00 (5) Sales volatility 0.17 0.16 0.01 0.03 0.08 −0.54 1.00 (6) Inventory (in days of sales) 31 32 −0.10 −0.01 0.20 −0.45 0.36 1.00 (7) Sales forecasts_level (AF ratio) 1.01 0.34 0.12 0.03 −0.05 0.18 −0.07 −0.31 1.00 (8) Sales forecasts_noise 0.14 0.10 −0.03 −0.004 0.06 −0.25 0.35 0.11 −0.03 1.00

and rival , respectively3.Afewkey (e.g., Anupindi et al., 2011; Cachon and Terwiesch, differences can be observed from the table. First, 2012). We included DC–SKU and seasonal fixed before integration DCs sold far more own CSDs effects and an annual trend in all main specifica- (exp(5.58) = 265 cases per DC-SKU-period) and tions. For linear regression models, we also clus- rival CSDs (exp(5.39) = 219 cases) than own tered robust standard errors at the DC level to NonCSDs ((exp(4.47) = 89 cases). Second, there account for correlation among SKUs carried by the was no significant change in stockout rates for own same DC. CSDs after integration. In comparison, there was Our main regression estimated the probability of a significant reduction in stockout rates for own SKU s experiencing a stockout at DC i in period t: NonCSDs (p-value = 0.040) and an increase in stockout rates for rival products (p-value = 0.080). E[Stockoutsit]=DCSKUsi + Seasont Third, there was a reduction in sales per SKU and 𝛼 𝛼 + 0Annualtrendt + 1Integrationt an increase in sales volatility across the board, 𝛼 𝛾 most likely due to increased product variety. + 2Integrationt ∗ NonCSDs + Xsit , Fourth, DCs kept more inventory for NonCSDs (1) than for both own and rival CSDs, reflecting the extra buffer needed to satisfy uncertain and more where DCSKUsi and Seasont are DC-SKU pair volatile NonCSD sales. After integration, inventory and season fixed effects, respectively. Assuming increased for own CSDs and rival products, but sales follow a normal distribution, the probability decreased for own NonCSDs (p-values < 0.0001). of stockouts can be illustrated as the probability of Finally, DCs’ sales forecasts became less noisy the actual demand being greater than the available inventory; such probability depends on sales quan- for own products, but more noisy for rival prod- tity and volatility. We therefore included them as ucts (p-values < 0.0001). Of course, these mean control variables in X . comparisons do not control for any factor that sit We then compared a few operations variables that might influence these variables, such as time trend, might have contributed to the change in stockouts. seasonal fluctuation, or unobservable heterogeneity To do that, we estimated the following specification: at the DC–SKU level. We consider these factors in our econometric analyses. 𝛼 DVsit = DCSKUsi + Seasont + 0Annualtrendt Specifications 𝛼 𝛼 + 1Integrationt + 2Integrationt ∗ NonCSDs We designed most of our specifications based 𝛾 𝜀 + Xsit + sit,(2) on standard textbooks of operations management

where DV sit represents different operations vari- 3 The majority (95%) of rival products were CSDs; we therefore ables such as inventory and sales forecasts (both did not separately examine rival NonCSD products. Even though level and noise), as defined before. the Bottler carried mostly CSD products for the upstream rivals, Finally, we replicated Equations 1 and 2 on the upstream rivals could still learn from the Bottler Coca-Cola and Pepsi’s plans for NonCSDs and use this information to the subsample of rival products to identify any develop their own NonCSD products bottled by themselves or difference between the own and rival products in other plants. changes after integration.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1142 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan

Table 2. Mean comparison

Own CSDs Pre-integration Post-integration Difference (p-value)

Stockout (1,0) 0.26 0.26 0 (0.907) Sales 5.58 5.50 −0.08 (0.000) Sales volatility 0.15 0.16 0.01 (0.000) Inventory (in days of sales) 24.90 25.21 0.31 (0.000) Sales forecasts_level (AF ratio) 1.01 1.03 0.02 (0.000) Sales forecasts_noise 0.140 0.137 −0.003 (0.000)

Own nonCSDs Pre-integration Post-integration Difference (p-value)

Stockout (1,0) 0.26 0.25 −0.01 (0.040) Sales 4.49 4.30 −0.19 (0.000) Sales volatility 0.18 0.19 0.01 (0.000) Inventory (in days of sales) 38.69 36.85 −1.84 (0.000) Sales forecasts_ level (AF ratio) 0.98 1.01 0.03(0.210) Sales forecasts_noise 0.152 0.15 −0.002 (0.000)

Rival products (mostly CSDs) Pre-integration Post-integration Difference (p-value)

Stockout (1,0) 0.24 0.25 0.01 (0.080) Sales 5.39 5.13 −0.26 (0.090) Sales volatility 0.16 0.17 0.01 (0.000) Inventory (in days of sales) 25.75 26.77 1.01 (0.000) Sales forecasts_level (AF ratio) 1.07 1.04 −0.03 (0.340) Sales forecasts_noise 0.14 0.15 0.01 (0.000)

RESULTS two years before integration but experienced a stockout during the last period before integration. Pre-integration coordination (own products) A marginal effect calculation based on the coef- ficient (keeping all other variables at their mean Table 3 compares operations variables for CSDs values) shows that NonCSDs were three percent and NonCSDs owned by the CP parent before inte- (p-value < 0.001) more likely to experience an gration. The coefficients in Columns (1)–(4) are increasing stockout rate before integration. consistent with our expectation. NonCSDs had a higher rate of stockouts. A marginal effect calcula- tion (keeping all other variables at their mean val- ues) shows that NonCSDs were six percent more Post-integration coordination (own products) likely to experience a stockout than CSDs. This was Table 4 estimates the probability of stockouts for despite the fact that NonCSDs had five more days of the CP’s own products. A marginal effect calcu- buffer inventory. DCs also tended to under-forecast lation based on Column (1) suggests that stockout sales more for NonCSDs, and the standard devia- rate fell by two percent age points (p-value < 0.001) tion in sales forecasts for NonCSDs tended to be after integration, from a pre-integration stock- higher than that for CSDs. The p-values were less out rate of 26 percent. The change is sizable than 0.001 for all these coefficients. given that it happened during the period Column (5) investigates any time trend in stock- of one year after integration. Interviews with outs before integration. For each DC–SKU pair, we the Bottler’s management confirmed that there compared the stockouts two years before the inte- had not been any significant adjustments in the gration and the stockouts for the last period before Bottler’s operations, such as investments in phys- integration. The dependent variable, pre-integration ical assets and equipment or a reallocation of increase in stockouts, assumed the value of 1 if sourcing relationships, that would have reduced the DC–SKU pair did not experience a stockout stockouts.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1143

Table 3. Coordination challenges for own products before integration

Inventory (in days Sales Sales Pre-integration increase Dependent Stockout (1,0) of sales) forecasts_level (AF) forecasts_noise in stockouts (0,1) Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

NonCSD (1,0) 0.324 5.353 0.011 0.003 0.196 [0.005] [0.333] [0.002] [0.001] [0.018] Sales 0.362 −6.868 0.045 −0.004 0.278 [0.002] [0.236] [0.001] [0.000] [0.005] Sales volatility 2.002 34.506 0.147 0.200 2.659 [0.016] [0.903] [0.010] [0.004] [0.055] Season dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 1,297,634 1,297,634 1,297,634 1,297,634 100,672 Log-likelihood −711,038 −6.19E + 06 −408,500 1.27E + 06 −45,197 Pseudo R2 0.036 0.243 0.041 0.135 0.045

Logit estimation is used for columns (1) and (5), and ordinary least square linear regressions are used for columns (2)–(4). The dependent variable in column (5) is the probability that a DC-SKU did not experience a stockout in the two years before integration, but experienced a stockout in the last four-week period before integration. Standard errors for columns (1) and (5) and robust standard errors clustered at DC level for columns (2)–(4) are included in square brackets. p-Values for all point estimates are less than 0.001. All tests are two-tailed.

Table 4. Vertical integration and stockout rate for own products

DV = stockout (1,0) (1) ALL (2) ALL (3) ALL (4) CSD (5) NonCSD

Integration −0.049 −0.040 −0.054 −0.019a −0.153 [0.007] [0.008] [0.008] [0.009] [0.010] NonCSD_X_Integration −0.017b −0.015c [0.008] [0.008] Sales 0.490 0.415 0.567 [0.004] [0.006] [0.006] Sales volatility 2.568 2.702 2.439 [0.016] [0.024] [0.023] Annual trend Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Season dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes DC-SKU pair fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 2,016,158 2,016,158 2,016,158 1,048,436 967,772 Log-likelihood −817,743 −817,741 −801,719 −416,493 −384,569 Pseudo R2 0.021 0.021 0.021 0.019 0.025 a p-Value = 0.050, b p-Value = 0.035, c p-Value = 0.079. Fixed logit estimation is used for all columns. Standard errors are included in square brackets. p-Values for all point estimates are less than 0.001 unless noted otherwise. All tests are two-tailed.

Columns (2) and (3) show a negative coeffi- for CSDs. In addition, we estimated stockouts sep- cient to the interaction between integration and arately for CSDs and NonCSDs in Columns (4) NonCSD dummies (p-values are 0.035 and 0.079, and (5). Results showed a highly significant reduc- respectively). The significance of the interaction tion in stockouts for NonCSDs after integration term in logit models may not be read directly from (p-value < 0.001), and a less significant reduction the coefficients (Hoetker, 2007; Norton, Wang, and in stockouts for CSDs (p-value = 0.050). A Wald’s Ai, 2004; Wiersema and Bowen, 2009). To prop- test confirmed that the difference in the integra- erly interpret the interaction term, we first exam- tion coefficients across the two groups is statis- ined the odds ratios (Buis, 2010). Our calcula- tically significant (p-value < 0.001)4. These addi- tion based on Column (3) suggests that the odds tional tests supported our expectation that stockouts of a stockout was five percent lower after inte- gration, and the odds of a stockout after integra- 4 To account for potential difference in residual variations across tion for NonCSDs was 0.98 percent of the odds the two groups, we also followed Hoetker (2006) and calculated

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1144 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan decreased more for NonCSDs than for CSDs after stockouts. Factors such as this could drive a spu- integration. rious relationship between integration and stock- outs. Unfortunately, we did not have price or profit information at the product level to control for this. Alternative explanations Instead, we took a few steps to mitigate this con- Integration can bring about multiple benefits other cern. First, if DCs carried more NonCSDs because than improving coordination between the CP and they became more profitable, these products should the Bottler (Financial Times, 2009b; Wall Street have experienced an increase in sales. Therefore, we Journal, 2010). Some of these benefits are alter- controlled for sales quantity and time trend in all of native explanations for the integration decision, our regressions. Second, as a robustness check we although they will not necessarily reduce stock- performed a test that corrects for selection at the DC outs. For example, integration helps introduce more level. We exploited the fact that a number of states innovative products, but this will not reduce stock- had imposed and credibly threatened a penalty for 5 outs in our sample, which includes only products soda consumption during our sample period . Based that the Bottler was already carrying at the time of on this information, we first estimated the likeli- the integration. If anything, increasing product vari- hood that a DC had more than 20 percent of sales ety increases rather than reduces stockouts (Ander- from NonCSDs during our sample period; we called son, Fitzsimons, and Simester, 2006b; Musalem these DCs diversified DCs. Our results show that et al., 2010; Wan et al., 2012). Integration bene- DCs in states with a soda penalty were more likely fits that are unrelated to stockouts would make our to be diversified. In the second stage, we estimated estimation less endogenous, and integration bene- the likelihood that a DC reduced stockouts after fits that are positively related to stockouts would integration, correcting for self-selection using an make our estimation more conservative. In addi- Inverse Mills Ratio calculated from the first stage. tion to product innovation, integration might cre- Our results are included in on-line Appendix S1. ate opportunities for process innovation that could They confirm that, after correcting for selection, potentially reduce stockouts. Because a large num- diversified DCs were still more likely to see a reduc- ber of own and rival products share the same facili- tion in their average stockout rate after integration, ties and processes (which drives scale economy for which is consistent with our main results in Table 4. the Bottler in the first place), we estimated sepa- In sum, while multiple expected benefits can rately the change in stockouts for own and rival explain the CP’s motivation to vertically integrate, products after integration. Column (1) in Table 7 not all of them can explain the reduction in stock- suggests that stockouts for rival products increased outs that we observe in Table 4. The next subsection rather than decreased after integration, refuting the examines a few operations variables to shed light process-innovation story. Our interviews with com- on the exact mechanisms through which stockouts pany staff also confirmed that no significant process reduced after integration. changes had been made during the short duration of our sample period. Inventory and sales forecasts An alternative explanation for the reduction in stockouts is unobserved factors (omitted variables). Table 5 explores a few mechanisms that could For example, the CP could have decided to integrate reduce stockouts. The most obvious one is to because the change in consumer preferences had increase inventory. While before integration the made bottling NonCSD products more profitable DCs might not be willing to hold too much inven- tory at the cost of working capital, after inte- than before. At the same time, if NonCSD products gration they should have more incentive to do became more profitable for a DC, it would have so. Table 5 first compares inventory before and also carried more NonCSDs, and thereby, reduced

5 For example, Washington imposed a $0.02 per ounce tax on the difference in a ratio of two coefficients, for example, coeffi- CSDs in 2010 (Seattle Times, 2010) and New York proposed a cients for integration and log(sales quantity) (or sales volatility). $0.01 per ounce tax on soft drinks in its 2009 state budget (New These calculations confirmed that the negative effect of integra- York Times, 2010). Virginia imposed a state excise tax on soda in tion (relative to the effect of sales quantity or volatility) was both addition to a sales tax. A number of other states, such as Maryland, economically and statistically more significant for NonCSDs than levy sales taxes on soda, but not on other grocery food (Pinho, for CSDs. 2012).

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1145 after integration. Coefficients in Column (1) sug- include the age of the product (number of periods gest that, as expected, inventory of own CSDs since its initial launch). Older products have more increased by close to a day of sales after integra- sales information to reduce forecasting bias and tion (p-value < 0.001). However, to our surprise, should benefit less from integration. This coefficient inventory of own NonCSDs decreased by three days is supportive but not statistically significant. (p-value < 0.001). This implies that if inventory for Columns (4) and (5) compare the noise in sales NonCSDs had not been reduced after integration, forecasts. Results suggest that DCs reduced the the stockout rate for NonCSDs would have fallen noise in their sales forecasts after integration, even more. and the reduction was greater for NonCSDs One potential explanation for the reduction in (p-value < 0.001) and DCs far away from the CP both stockouts and inventory is that within each (p-value = 0.001). Even before the integration, DCs four-week period the fluctuation in inventory more close to the CP would be able to partially observe closely matched that in sales; as a result, stockouts some “hint” that the CP will initiate a new product fell despite less period-average inventory relative launch or promotion, whereas DCs faraway would to sales. Unfortunately, we did not have daily or have to wait for the CP’s explicit notification. DCs weekly inventory data to test this idea, even though faraway therefore experienced greater information we noticed that the standard deviation of inventory disadvantage before integration and would benefit in days of sales during the post-integration period more from integration. Column 5 also confirms that was two days less than before integration. forecasts of newer products benefited more from One of the most important ways to better match integration (p-value < 0.001). inventory to sales is through more accurate sales Overall, results in Table 5 suggest that the joint forecasting. After all, real-time inventory (in days reduction in both stockout rates and inventory after of sales) is determined based on forecasted quantity, integration was due to an overall improvement in adjusted with the lagged actual-to-forecast (AF) coordination efficiency, most likely reduced infor- ratio and forecasting noise (standard deviation in mation asymmetry in both directions. While the AF ratio) (e.g., Anupindi et al., 2011; Cachon and reduction in the Bottler’s information misrepresen- Terwiesch, 2012). More accurate sales forecasts tation (i.e., the increase in sales forecasts) after inte- will not only better match inventory and sales gration can explain the reduction in inventory in to reduce stockouts, but also will give DCs the days of forecasted sales, it cannot not explain the confidence to hold less “buffer” inventory. Column (2) compares sales forecasts. It suggests reduction in inventory in days of actual sales. We that DCs increased their sales forecasts (reduced AF think the inventory reduction may also be caused ratio) from about 99 percent to 100 percent of actual by DCs reducing buffer inventory as they became sales after integration (p-value = 0.004). We argue more confident in less noisy sales forecasts. Ina in the theory section that improved sales forecasting supplementary analysis, we did find that inventory could be caused by better monitoring by the CP and was positively associated with both the downward more information sharing between the CP and the forecasting bias and forecasting noise in the previ- Bottler. To test this mechanism, column (3) adds ous period. a dummy to capture if the DC is in the same or In order to see if inventory and sales forecasts a neighboring state of the CP parent. A number explain the reduction in stockouts, in Table 6, of scholars have found that the integration benefit we re-estimated stockouts with the additional vari- of better monitoring is more prevalent for units ables of inventory and sales forecasts. The results that are geographically near headquarters than for first confirm that stockouts were negatively related units that are far away (Brickley and Dark, 1987; to inventory and positively correlated with AF Kalnins and Lafontaine, 2013; Rubin, 1978). This ratio and noise in sales forecasts. In addition, is because monitoring often requires managers from columns (1) and (2) confirm that after controlling headquarters to visit the units routinely, which can for the changes in inventory, stockouts increased for be costly for units in remote locations. Consistent CSDs (p-value = 0.069) and reduced even more) for with this line of logic, the coefficients in column (3) NonCSDs (p-value < 0.001). Columns (3) and (4) confirm that the upward correction in sales forecasts confirm that after controlling for the improvement was mostly experienced by DCs that were located in sales forecasts, the change in stockouts became near the CP (p-value = 0.011). Column (3) also smaller. Wald’s tests of these coefficients across

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1146 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan

Table 5. Alternative mechanisms for stockout reduction: inventory and sales forecasts

Inventory (in days of sales) Sales forecasts_level (AF) Sales forecasts_noise Dependent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Integration 0.808 −0.010a −0.015b −0.007 −0.051 [0.210] [0.003] [0.014] [0.001] [0.003] NonCSD_X_Integration −3.843 0.001c 0.002d −0.002 0.0001e [0.227] [0.003] [0.003] [0.0004] [0.0005] Sales −20.351 0.333 0.333 0.020 0.020 [0.243] [0.005] [0.005] [0.0005] [0.0005] Sales volatility 7.739 0.047 0.048 0.177 0.177 [0.738] [0.007] [0.007] [0.003] [0.003] DC near CP (1,0)_X_Integration −0.016f 0.003 [0.006] [0.001] Product age_X_Integration 0.002g 0.010 [0.003] [0.0006] Annual trend Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Season dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes DC-SKU pair fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 2,016,158 2,016,158 2,016,158 2,016,158 2,016,158 Log-likelihood −8.94E + 06 −287854 −595,322 2.24E + 06 2.17E + 06 Adjusted R2 0.593 0.303 0.308 0.308 0.308 a p-Value = 0.004. b p-Value = 0.278. c p-Value = 0.587. d p-Value = 0.446. e p-Value = 0.855. f p-Value = 0.011. g p-Value = 0.489. Fixed effects linear regressions are used for all columns. Robust standard errors clustered at DC level are included in square brackets for all columns. p-Values for all point estimates are less than 0.001 unless noted otherwise. All tests are two-tailed. models suggested that their differences are statisti- In addition to the main results in Tables 3–7, cally significantly. we ran a host of robustness checks. For example, to reduce potential simultaneity we lagged all independent variables. To avoid any estimation Vertical integration and rival products bias due to some dependent variables being To facilitate a comparison with the CPs’ own prod- left-censored, we re-estimated these variables using ucts, Table 7 estimates the changes in stockouts, their log-transformed values and Tobit models, inventory, and sales forecasts for the products of respectively. Our main results were robust to these rival CPs. The coefficients show that the stockout alternative specifications. rate and forecasting noise increased while inven- tory and sales forecasts reduced after integration (p-value < 0.001), consistent with our expectation. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS In sum, the results in Tables 4–6 imply that, despite the increased sales volatility that accom- This article studies how product variety creates panies a greater level of variety in the NonCSD coordination problems along the value chain, and category, DCs were able to reduce both stockouts how vertical integration helps to solve these prob- and inventory for own NonCSDs after integration. lems through incentive alignment and information This is consistent with DCs having more incen- sharing. In particular, we examine challenges tive to increase sales forecasts and having better between a concentrate producer (CP) and its anchor information to reduce forecasting noise. In con- Bottler in coordinating product introductions, trast, Table 7 suggests that there was a deterio- manufacturing, and distribution. We show that, ration in DCs’ operational performance for rival in this particular case, vertical integration had products. a positive impact on coordination (in terms of

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1147

Table 6. Impact of inventory and sales forecasts on stockouts

DV = stockout (1,0) (1) CSD (2) NonCSD (3) CSD (4) NonCSD

Integration 0.017a −0.175 −0.011b −0.121 [0.010] [0.010] [0.010] [0.010] Sales 0.105 0.156 0.004c 0.046 [0.006] [0.007] [0.006] [0.008] Sales volatility 2.763 2.491 1.809 1.749 [0.024] [0.023] [0.032] [0.033] Inventory (in days of sales) −0.019 −0.019 −0.017 −0.017 [0.001] [0.006] [0.0002] [0.0001] Sales forecasts_level (AF) 0.669 0.550 [0.011] [0.012] Sales forecasts_noise 1.860 1.362 [0.042] [0.045] Annual trend Yes Yes Yes Yes Season dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes DC-SKU pair fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 1,048,436 967,772 1,048,436 967,772 Log-likelihood −408,828 −373,511 −393,025 −360,260 Adjusted R2 0.037 0.053 0.054 0.067 a p-value = 0.069. b p-value = 0.245. c p-value = 0.523. Inventory and sales forecasts are measured at the beginning of each period. Fixed effects linear regressions are used for all columns. Robust standard errors clustered at DC level are included in square brackets for all columns. p-Values for all point estimates are less than 0.001 unless noted otherwise. All tests are two-tailed. Table 7. Integration and rival products

Stockout (1,0) Inventory (in days of sales) Forecasts_level (AF) Forecasts_noise Dependent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)

Integration 0.055 −2.332 0.085 0.004 [0.017] [0.293] [0.004] [0.001] Sales 0.526 −17.177 0.307 0.015 [0.010] [0.430] [0.008] [0.001] Sales volatility 2.822 9.082 0.078 0.216 [0.042] [1.021] [0.015] [0.005] Annual trend Yes Yes Yes Yes Season dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes DC-SKU pair fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Observations 315,870 315,870 315,870 315,870 Log-likelihood −124828 −1.37E + 06 −62280 354696 Pseudo/Adjusted R2 0.026 0.576 0.259 0.317

Fixed effects logit estimation is used for column 1, and fixed effects ordinary least square linear regressions are used for columns (2)–(4). Standard errors for column (1) and robust standard errors clustered at DC level in columns (2)–(4) are included in square brackets. p-Values for all point estimates are less than 0.001. All tests are two-tailed. stockouts, inventory, and sales forecasts) for the along the value chain and examines the coordina- CP’s own products, but a negative impact on coor- tion benefits and trade-offs of vertical integration. dination for products the bottler carried for the CP’s It complements recent studies on the coordination rivals. challenges firms face when they pursue economies The key theoretical contribution of the article is of scope, and studies on the coordination benefits of to marry two primarily unrelated streams of prior vertical integration for enhancing firms’ adaptabil- work on product variety and vertical scope. It relates ity. Finally, by highlighting how an integrated firm product scope extension to coordination challenges improves coordination at the cost of its upstream

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1148 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan rivals, the article implies an intricate mechanism of repeatedly integrated and disintegrated their bot- nonprice discrimination. tlers. The recentness of this particular integration A second theoretical contribution of the arti- event prevents us from investigating whether the cle is to bridge existing work on product vari- integration benefits are sustainable given the wors- ety in operations management and strategy. Even ening for rival CPs’ products and the poten- though there is a large body of mathematical models tial burden of coordinating the integrated firm. On about variety-related problems in operations man- the one hand, integration provides incentives for agement, these models are usually built at the level more information sharing. On the other hand, inte- of a single plant or production line. Studies about gration removes the boundary that used to insulate variety and the interaction between organizational the upstream and downstream firms from each other units along the supply chain are rare. This article and imposes more complex relationships between fills this gap. At the same time, while there isalarge the two. Only a few years after acquiring their body of literature on the benefits of vertical inte- bottlers, both CPs announced that they intended gration in strategy, the empirical investigation has to refranchise their distribution networks (Bever- been limited to aggregate, firm-level performance age Daily, 2013; Coca-Cola Company Press, 2016). under different governance modes or to a single Future studies may examine the CPs’ performance performance measure at the transaction level. By in the now more mature NonCSD segment after incorporating basic models from operations man- franchising. agement on stockouts, inventory, and sales fore- Studying hundreds of organization units and casts, this article paints a more complete picture of thousands of product varieties within a single com- the mechanisms behind coordination and vertical pany allowed us to eliminate unobserved firm het- integration. erogeneity and extract detailed operations data The article has a few limitations that create about key elements of coordination. However, we opportunities for future research. Because this is a did not have a control group that could help us case study of one company, it cannot answer the to identify the causal effect of integration more general question of whether an increase in prod- sharply. While we cannot fully solve this endo- uct variety should be accompanied by an increase geneity issue, we tried to mitigate it by (1) ruling or a reduction in vertical scope. On the one hand, out alternative explanations, (2) adding a strict set product scope and vertical scopes may be comple- of control variables and fixed effects, (3) adopt- mentary because vertical integration allows firms to ing a selection model and other robustness checks, exercise stronger control over resources and pro- (4) comparing post-integration changes in multi- cesses that are shared across related markets (Forbes ple operations variables to construct a cohesive and Lederman, 2009; Novak and Stern, 2009). On story, (5) exploiting pre- and post-integration dif- the other hand, because firms are constrained in ferences across various product categories (CSDs their total coordination capacity, their product and versus NonCSDs, own versus rival, new versus vertical scopes may be substitutive (Zhou, 2011). old) and distribution centers (those close to ver- Our study presents one scenario where vertical inte- sus those far away from the CP headquarters, those gration improves product-level efficiency for the diversified versus those never significantly diversi- integrated company, to the disadvantage of its rivals. fied), and (6) using rival products as a “placebo” This is consistent with both the coordination-benefit or “falsification” test that further removes some and coordination-capacity-constraint arguments. time-varying DC characteristics. By using this com- Firm scope is a dynamic phenomenon that shifts parative approach, the article aims to identify the with the relative magnitude of transaction and inte- exact mechanisms that could explain the change in gration costs. Integration is justified when benefits coordination. of a coordinated response to environmental changes In conclusion, this article highlights the intricate outweigh the potential organization and production and important challenges facing firms that pursue costs that can be saved through outsourcing. In the product variety. It shows that vertical integration context of this study, the CPs integrated their bot- plays a positive role in coordination by align- tlers, in spite of low profit margins in the bottling ing incentives and facilitating information sharing business, in order to achieve a coordinated response along the value chain. At the same time, integration at a time when consumer demand for NonCSDs has the potential to crowd out coordination for rival was evolving rapidly. Historically, the CPs have products.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj Product Variety and Vertical Integration 1149

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Cokesolutions. 2015. Direct store delivery: optimizing the road to success. The authors gratefully acknowledge the thought- Cottrell T, Nault BR. 2004. Product variety and firm sur- vival in the microcomputer . Strategic ful suggestions provided by Gautam Ahuja, Management Journal 25(10): 1005–1025. Ravi Anupindi, Seth Carnahan, Sendil Ethiraj, Financial Times. 2009a. PepsiCo takes control of its largest Wally Hopp, Aseem Kaul, Jun Li, Xiaoyang Li, bottlers. (accessed 5 August 2009). Gabriel Natividad, Amy Nguyen-Chyng, Catherine Financial Times. 2009b. PepsiCo pays up. (accessed 5 Thomas, James Westphal, Editor Connie Helfat, August 2009). and two reviewers. We appreciate the questions Fisher ML. 1997. What is the right supply chain for your product? Harvard Business Review 75: 105–117. and comments raised by participants at University Fisher ML, Ittner CD. 1999. The impact of product variety of Maryland and University of Michigan strategy on automobile assembly operations: empirical evidence seminars, the Academy of Management Meetings, and simulation analysis. Management Science 45(6): Midwest Strategy Meetings, NYU Econ Strategy 771–786. Workshop, Strategy Management Society Meet- Forbes SJ, Lederman M. 2009. Adaptation and vertical ings, Strategic Research Forum, and the Tuck integration in the airline industry. American Economic Strategy Summer Camp. All errors remain ours. Review 99(5): 1831–1849. Fosfuri A, Giarratana MS. 2009. Masters of war: rivals’ product innovation and new in mature prod- uct markets. Management Science 55(2): 181–191. REFERENCES Gulati R, Lawrence PR, Puranam P. 2005. Adaptation in vertical relationships: beyond incentive conflict. Strate- Anand KS, Goyal M. 2009. Strategic information man- gic Management Journal 26(5): 415–440. agement under leakage in a supply chain. Management Hart O. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Science 55(3): 438–452. Clarendon Press: Oxford, UK. Anderson ET, Fitzsimons GJ, Simester D. 2006a. Measur- Hart OD, Moore J. 2005. On the design of hierarchies: ing and mitigating the costs of stockouts. Management Coordination versus specialization. Journal of Political Science 52(11): 1751–1763. Economy 113(4): 675–702. Anderson ET, Fitzsimons GJ, Simester D. 2006b. Measur- Hart O, Tirole J, Carlton DW, Williamson OE. 1990. ing and mitigating the costs of stockouts. Management Vertical integration and market foreclosure comments Science 52(11): 1751–1763. and discussion. Brookings papers on economic activity. Anupindi R, Chopra S, Deshmukh SD, Mieghem JAV, 1990 (1990): 205–286. Zemel E. 2011. Managing Business Process Flows (3rd Helfat CE, Campo-Rembado MA. 2016. Integrative capa- edn). Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ. bilities, vertical integration, and innovation over suc- Argyres N, Bigelow L. 2010. Innovation, modularity, and cessive technology lifecycles. Organization Science vertical deintegration: evidence from the early U.S. auto (Forthcoming): 249–264. industry. Organization Science 21(4): 842–853. Helfat CE, Raubitschek RS. 2000. Product sequencing: Barnett WP, Freeman J. 2001. Too much of a good co-evolution of knowledge, capabilities and products. thing? Product proliferation and organizational failure. Journal 21(10–11): 961–979. Organization Science 12(5): 539–558. Hoetker G. 2006. Do modular products lead to modular Beverage Daily. 2013. and Pepsi shifting bottling organizations? Strategic Management Journal 27(6): assets to build brands in 2013: Rabobank analyst. 501–518. Beverage Daily. 2015. More than 60% of Americans now Hoetker G. 2007. The use of logit and probit models in avoid soda: Gallup. strategic management research: critical issues. Strategic Brickley JA, Dark FH. 1987. The choice of organizational Management Journal 28(4): 331–343. form the case of franchising. Journal of Financial Economics 18(2): 401–420. Jacobides MG, Hitt LM. 2005. Losing sight of the forest Buis ML. 2010. Stata tip 87: interpretation of interactions for the trees? Productive capabilities and gains from in nonlinear models. Stata Journal 10(2): 305–308. trade as drivers of vertical scope. Strategic Management Cachon G, Terwiesch C. 2012. Matching Supply with Journal 26(13): 1209–1227. Demand: An Introduction to Operations Management. Joskow PL. 2008. Vertical integration. In Handbook of New McGraw-Hill/Irwin: New York. Institutional Economics, Menard C, Shirle M (eds). Chipty T. 2001. Vertical integration, market foreclosure, Dordrecht, Springer: 319–348. and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. Kalnins A, Lafontaine F. 2013. Too far away? The effect American Economic Review 91(3): 428–453. of distance to headquarters on business establishment Coca-Cola Company Press. 2016. The Coca-Cola Com- performance. American Economic Journal: Microeco- pany announces plans to significantly accelerate bottler nomics 5(3): 157–179. refranchising. Karnani A. 2010. PepsiCo & Coca-Cola Company: Coca Cola Press Release. 2010. The Coca-Cola Company vertical integration. William Davidson Institute Case finalizes transaction with Coca-Cola enterprises. 1-428-939.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj 1150 Y. M. Zhou and X. Wan

Klein B. 2000. Fisher-General Motors and the Nature Wall Street Journal. 2010. Corporate News: Coca-Cola of the Firm. Journal of Law and Economics 43(1): deal is U.S. strategy shift—pact with big bottler likely 105–141. will change how beverages are distributed to stores and Lawrence PR, Lorsch JW. 1967. Differentiation and inte- consumers: (accessed 25 February 2010). gration in complex organizations. Administrative Sci- Wall Street Journal. 2015. Soft drinks hit 10th year of ence Quarterly 12: 1–47. decline: (accessed 26 March 2015). Muris TJ, Scheffman DT, Spiller PT. 1992. Strategy and Wan X, Dresner ME. 2015. Closing the loop: an transaction costs: The organization of distribution in the empirical analysis of the dynamic decisions affect- carbonated soft drink industry. Journal of Economics ing product variety. Decision Sciences 46(6): and Management Strategy 1(1): 83–128. 1141–1164. Musalem A, Olivares M, Bradlow ET, Terwiesch Wan X, Evers PT, Dresner ME. 2012. Too much of a good C, Corsten D. 2010. Structural estimation of the thing: the impact of product variety on operations and effect of out-of-stocks. Management Science 56(7): sales performance. Journal of Operations Management 1180–1197. 30(4): 316–324. New York Times. 2010. Soda Tax in N.Y. a victim of Weigelt C, Sarkar M. 2012. Performance implications of industry campaign. (accessed July 2, 2010). outsourcing for technological innovations: managing Nickerson JA, Zenger TR. 2004. A knowledge-based the efficiency and adaptability trade-off. Strategic Man- theory of the firm—the problem-solving perspective. agement Journal 33(2): 189–216. Organization Science 15(6): 617–632. Wiersema MF, Bowen HP. 2009. The use of limited Norton E, Wang H, Ai C. 2004. Computing interaction dependent variable techniques in strategy research: effects and standards errors in logit and probit models. issues and methods. Strategic Management Journal Stata Journal 4(2): 154–167. 30(6): 679–692. Novak S, Eppinger SD. 2001. Sourcing by design: product Williamson OE. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis complexity and the supply chain. Management Science and Antitrust Implications. The Free Press: New York, 47(1): 189–204. NY. Novak S, Stern S. 2009. Complementarity among ver- Williamson OE. 1985. The Limits of Firms: Incentive tical integration decisions: evidence from automo- and Bureaucratic Features. Economic Institutions of bile product development. Management Science 55(2): Capitalism. 311–332. Yehezkel Y. 2008. Retailers’ choice of product variety and Pepsi Press Release. 2009. PepsiCo reaches merger agree- exclusive dealing under asymmetric information. Rand ments with Pepsi Bottling Group and PepsiAmericas. Journal of Economics 39(1): 115–143. Pinho R. 2012. Taxes on soft drink or candy. OLR Yoffie DB, Kim R. 2012. Coca-Cola in 2011: in search Research Report: (accessed 7 November 2012). of a new model. Harvard Business School Case: 9- Ramdas K. 2003. Managing product variety: an integrative 711-504. review and research directions. Production and Opera- Zhou YM. 2011. Synergy, coordination costs, and diversi- tions Management 12(1): 79–101. fication choices. Strategic Management Journal 32(6): Rubin PH. 1978. The theory of the firm and the struc- 624–639. ture of the franchise contract. Journal of Law and Economics 21 (1): 223–233. Seattle Times. 2010. Voters reject state income tax, SUPPORTING INFORMATION candy-soda tax: (accessed 2 November 2010). Sorenson O. 2000. Letting the market work for you: an evolutionary perspective on product strategy. Strategic Additional supporting information may be found Management Journal 21(5): 577–592. in the online version of this article: Teece DJ. 1996. Firm organization, industrial structure, and technological innovation. Journal of Economic Appendix S1. Correcting for selection into Behavior and Organization 31(2): 193–224. Non-CSD varieties at the DC level.

Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strat. Mgmt. J., 38: 1134–1150 (2017) DOI: 10.1002/smj