COMPETITION, CONTRACT, and VERTICAL INTEGRATION FRIEDRICH Kesslert RICHARD H

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

COMPETITION, CONTRACT, and VERTICAL INTEGRATION FRIEDRICH Kesslert RICHARD H THE YALE LAW JOURNAL VOLUM E 69 NOVEMBER 1959 NUMBER 1 COMPETITION, CONTRACT, AND VERTICAL INTEGRATION FRIEDRICH KESSLERt RICHARD H. STEHH VERTICAL integration, the coordination of successive stages of production or distribution,' has received considerable attention in recent years. This at- tention, however, has been confined largely to integration by stock or asset acquisition--ownership integration. Contract integration-vertical contractual arrangements such as requirement, output, exclusive dealing, franchise, con- signment, and agency agreements 2 --has just begun to be treated as a form of vertical integration 3 although it is widely used to achieve industrial coordina- tJustus S. Hotchkiss Professor of Law, Yale Law School. tTrial Attorney, Antitrust Division, U.S. Department of Justice. This Article was prepared prior to Mr. Stern's entering government service; the views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the Department of Justice. The authors wish to thank Mrs. Jonathan Fine of the Massachusetts Bar for valuable assistance in research; our greatest debt is to Ward S. Bowman, Jr., Professor of Law and Economics at the Yale Law School, who gave us the benefit of his great learning and creative perception with unsurpassed generosity and cordiality of spirit. 1. Cole defines "vertical integration" as "that type of organization that comes into existence when two or more successive stages of production and/or distribution are com- bined under the same control." Cole, General Discussion of Vertical Integration, in VERTICAL INTEGRATION IN IRLUUETING 9, 99 (Bureau Econ. & Bus. Research, U. Ill., No. 74, 1952). According to Adelman, "a firm is called vertically integrated when it transmits from one of its departments to another a good or service which could, without major adaptation, be sold in the market." Adelman, Integration and Antitrust Policy, 63 HARv. L. REv. 27 (1949); Bork adopts this definition in Vertical Integration and the Sherman Act: The Legal History of an Economic Misconception, 22 U. Cni. L. REv. 157 n.1 (1954). For Frank, "[Vlertical Integration may be described as the functional co-ordination of one or more units in each of the several successive stages of production, so that they are all operated as a single, unified industrial process." Frank, The Signili- ance of Industrial Integration, 33 J. PoL. EcoN. 179 (1925). See also Buans, TnE DE- CLINE OF CoETrmoI 421 (1936) (salability of intermediate products). 2. The vertical joint-venture agreement might be added to this list of contractual coordination devices. Joint venture is a hybrid integration device which combines owner- ship and contract. Typically, a supplier and his customer set up a jointly owned subsidiary in order to transact their business. See note 14 infra. 3. See McLaren, Related Problems of "RequiremnentI' Contracts and Acquisitions in Vertical Integratim Under the Anfi-Trust Laws, 45 Iu. L REv. 141 (1950); Adelman, Corporate Integration, in How To CO=PLY WrrE TEE ANTITRUST LAws 290, 303-04 (Van Cise & Dunn ed. 1954); Rostow, Over All Size, in id. 311, 323; Hia & HA.E, HeinOnline -- 69 Yale L.J. 1 1959-1960 THE YALE LAW JOURNAL [Vol, 69:1 tion and even control. Nor have informal understandings which are ancillary to formal contracts and which aim at coordination 4 been included in an overall concept of integration. As a result, the functional similarities or differences between these alter- native methods of integration have been underemphasized or ignored. Con- tractual arrangements aimed at coordinating the supply of materials or dis- posal of output frequently affect the contracting firms, as well as the rest of the industry, in much the same way as ownership of suppliers or outlets does. But important differences may attend the two devices-differences in business effectiveness and in legal consequences. With an eye toward possible differences between ownership and contract, part I of this Article will deal with the industrial and economic aspects of vertical integration. The remain- ing parts are devoted to legal problems: part II examines the effect of the antitrust laws on integration systems and part III considers the impact of pricing regulations. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION IN ITS BUSINESS SETTING THE IMPACT ON THE FIRM Cost reduction is the principal technological justification for vertical in- tegration.5 "Cost reduction," however, is a broad term which requires further MARKET POWER: SIZE AND SHAPE UNDER THE SHERMAN AcT 204 (1958) ("vertical control"). Compare id. n.12 (§ 3 of the Clayton Act not applicable) ; Levi, The DuPont Case and § 7, 3 ANTITRUST BULL. 1, 10 (1958). However, the courts have been aware that contractual arrangements may serve as alternatives to ownership integration. See Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 319 (1949) (dissenting opinion of Douglas, J.) ; cf. Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal Sugar Co., 334 (I.S. 219, 243-44 (1948); Gulf Ref. Co. v. Fox, 297 U.S. 381 (1936). Contractual arrangements aiming at vertical integration extend over a wide range, verging at one extreme on the permanence and control of ownership integration, and at the other approaching the impermanence and lack of control of the spot-market transaction. 4. For example, manufacturers frequently have an understanding of exclusive dealing with their dealers, although exclusive dealing is not required by the formal sales contract. This is particularly common when the manufacturer leases the premises to the dealer. Loans or extension of credit may assure an outlet or secure a source of supply, and thus serve as devices of vertical industrial coordination. See International Shoe Co., TRADE REG. REP. (1957-1958 FTC Cas.) U 26611 (1957), consent order entered, id. Ui 27074; Hearings Before the Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly of the Senate Coln- inittee on the Judiciary, 84th Cong., 1st Sess., Ser. 3, pt. 6, at 2598-99 (1955) [hereinafter cited as 1955 Sen. Hearings]; id. pt. 7, at 2665-66, 2668; Bus. Week, May 19, 1951, p. 26 (General Motors lends to steel companies to secure their output) ; United Stateg v. National City Lines, 186 F.2d 562 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 341 U.S. 916 (1951). 5. Adelman, Integration and Antitrust Policy, 63 HARv. L. Rxv. 27, 48 (1949) ("Ste- cessful integration . consists in the saving of overhead, and results in doing a given job more cheaply."). Of course, vertical integration may occur without any rational justification. Historical accident and mere chance may cause a vertical integration pattern in an industry where there are no economies or diseconomies of scale. Adelman, Concept and Statstiual HeinOnline -- 69 Yale L.J. 2 1959-1960 1959] VERTICAL INTEGRATION analysis, for it encompasses a multitude of reasons for adopting integration." Perhaps the most important of these is the increased stability of operations that coordination affords. Consumer outlets, sources of supply, and uniform- ity of quality are made more secure, thus increasing the feasibility of long- range planning.7 Facilities can be fully utilized, overtime production or idle plant minimized, s and inventory reduced.9 foreover, vertical integration eliminates many costs incurred in the transfer of goods from one control to another. The most obvious of these are marketing expenses.10 Also, when goods are manufactured for general salability rather than for a specific known function, many all-purpose features unnecessary to each individual buyer are incorporated, thereby raising the cost of production in order to increase market appeal." Such "functional cross-hauling" costs can be eliminated by integration. Measuremet of Vertical Integration, in BusINESS CONCENTRATION AND PRICE POLICY 281, 320 (1955). For a discussion of underwriters' profits as a motivation for ownership integration, see Thorp, The Persistence of the Merger Movement, 21 Am. EcoN. REV. 77, 85-86 (Supp. 1931). And psychological factors such as power and prestige should not be ignored. See 2 DEvING, FINANCIAL POLICY OF CoRroRATioNs 812 (5th ed. 1053): Adelman, supra note 5, at 34; JmVIES, ORDA. BY PLANNING 29, 30 (1948). 6. For example, to the extent that vertical integration lessens human wear and tear attendant to the constant making of sales contracts, it is a cost reduction factor. See Llewellyn's excellent discussion of this point in Book Review, 52 HAnv. L. REv. 700, 701 (1939), referring to the human economies of standardized contracts. 7. See DEAN, MANAGERIAL EcoNoMics 117 (1951) ; Girdner, Inlegrated Marketing Institutions, 209 ANNALS 55 (1940). In Goodyear Tire & Rubber Co., 22 F.T.C. 232. 287 (1936), respondent defended itself against a charge of violation of § 2 of the Clayton Act by asserting that the large assured volume obtained from its requirements contract integration with Sears, Roebuck served to "remove hazards and insure stability by avoiding the fluctuation of profit inevitable in respondent's other business... :' See note 526 infra. See also KImDALL & KIMBALL, PRINCIPLES OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATIO.N 61 (6th ed. 1947) ("danger of having production slowed up because of lack of supplies greatly reduced") ; FoLTs, INTRODUCTION TO INDUSTRIAL MANAGEMENT 169-70 (1938). 8. This factor is most significant when overhead costs are large. See DAVIS, VFsRT- CAL INTEGRATION IN THE TEXTnE INDUSTRIES 3 (1938). 9. KIMALL & KIMBALL, op. cit. supra note 7, at 61; Frank, The Significance of Industrlal Integration, 33 J. POL. ECON. 179, 190-91 (1925); see NEvi.s, Foro: Tnn TimEs, THE MAN, THE COM PANY 336 (1954). But see DE CuAzEAv & KAs, I.TEG;rATh'. IN THE OIL INDUSTRY 454 (1959). 10. CON-VERSE & HUEGY, ELEMENTS OF MARKETING 199 (3d ed. 1947) (savings on "salesmen, advertising, sales promotion, sales managers, buyers"). See also Girdner. supra note 7; Frank, supra note 9, at 179, 190-91. These expenses also include handling. transportation (geographical cross-hauling), and credit losses. 11. A familiar example of this is the "Swiss Army" knife, wfith saw, file, curkscrew, awl, bottle opener, screwdriver, can opener, and scissors, in one package.
Recommended publications
  • Make and Buy: Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Cost Reduction∗
    Make and Buy: Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Cost Reduction∗ Simon Loertscher† Michael H. Riordan‡ University of Melbourne Columbia University November 16, 2017 Abstract Globalization reshaped supply chains and the boundaries of firms in favor of outsourcing. Now, even vertically integrated firms procure substantially from ex- ternal suppliers. To study procurement and the structure of firms in this reshaped economy, we analyze a model in which integration grants a downstream customer the option to source internally. Integration is advantageous because it allows the customer sometimes to avoid paying markups, but disadvantageous because it dis- courages investments in cost reduction by independent suppliers. The investment- discouragement effect more likely outweighs the markup-avoidance effect if the upstream market is more competitive, as is so in a more global economy. Keywords: outsourcing, vertical integration, make and buy. JEL-Classification: C72, L13, L22, L24 ∗We are grateful to the editor (John Asker) and three anonymous referees for comments and sugges- tions that have improved the paper considerably. The paper has also benefitted from comments by Malin Arve, Patrick Bolton, Roberto Burguet, Jacques Cr´emer, Jean de Bettignies, Yassine Lefouili, Hans- Theo Normann, Eric Rasmusen, Patrick Rey, Antonio Rosato, Yossi Spiegel and workshop participants at the 2011 Industrial Economics Conference at Zhejiang University, at the 2013 Kick-off Workshop of the D¨usseldorf Institute for Competition Economics, at Ecole Polyt´echnique in Paris, at Indiana Uni- versity, at the Organizational Economics Workshop at the University of Sydney 2012, the Workshop of Public Private Collaboration 2013 at IESE Business School in Barcelona, the 2013 Canadian Economics Association Meetings in Montreal, the 2014 Australasian Economic Theory Workshop in Canberra, the 2014 Searle Conference on Antitrust Economics in Chicago, and the Conference in honour of Jacques Cr´emer on Advances in the Economics of Organizations and the New Economy in Toulouse in 2016.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Vertical Integration
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Impact of Vertical Integration H. Luke, Erin The University of Wisconsin-Whitewater 7 March 2021 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/106490/ MPRA Paper No. 106490, posted 08 Mar 2021 07:37 UTC 1 Impact of Vertical Integration Erin H. Luke The University of Wisconsin-Whitewater 2021 Abstract Vertical integration is a powerful, and complex business strategy that when used under the right conditions can positively impact an organization. A company’s strategists need to understand what dimensions of integration to use, and the best time to use it. De Beers is a company with a controversial history of being an anti-competitive monopoly. By strategizing into a vertical integrated company De beers has added value to its company by not only targeting the retail, and industrial market, but also the I.T. industry. Forward and backward integration has helped organizations like De Beers maintain control over its inputs and outputs. Rather than just buying all diamond mines, and stock piling the material in order to control the prices, De Beers has embraced change by focusing on new emerging industries. Through vertical strategy and new ownership De Beers is turning its company around in a very competitive luxury industry. Organizations should be aware of the costs of vertical integration when exploring its potential. Bureaucratic costs, and companies becoming too large and inflexible under certain environments can become a problem. Vertical integration is a powerful strategy, but it must always be under scrutiny, and redesigned when the external and internal environment deems change necessary. 2 2 Table of Contents What is Vertical Integration? .......................................................................................................3 De Beers Summary ........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Market Structure by Timothy F
    This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH SIEPR Discussion Paper No. 11-010 Vertical Integration and Market Structure by Timothy F. Bresnahan Jonathan D. Levin Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305 (650) 725-1874 The Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research at Stanford University supports research bearing on economic and public policy issues. The SIEPR Discussion Paper Series reports on research and policy analysis conducted by researchers affiliated with the Institute. Working papers in this series reflect the views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research or Stanford University. Vertical Integration and Market Structure Timothy Bresnahan and Jonathan Levin* Stanford University March 2012 Abstract. Contractual theories of vertical integration derive firm boundaries as an efficient response to market transaction costs. These theories predict a relationship between underlying features of transactions and observed integration decisions. There has been some progress in testing these predictions, but less progress in quantifying their importance. One difficulty is that empirical applications often must consider firm structure together with industry structure. Research in industrial organization frequently has adopted this perspective, emphasizing how scale and scope economies, and strategic considerations, influence patterns of industry integration. But this research has paid less attention to contractual or organizational details, so that these two major lines of research on vertical integration have proceeded in parallel with only rare intersection. We discuss the value of combining different viewpoints from organizational economics and industrial organization. JEL classification numbers: D23, L14, L22.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: the Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Todorova, Tamara Article — Manuscript Version (Preprint) Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: The Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry Journal of Advanced Research in Management Suggested Citation: Todorova, Tamara (2010) : Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: The Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry, Journal of Advanced Research in Management, ISSN 2068-7532, ASERS Publishing, Craiova, Vol. 1, Iss. 2 (Winter), pp. 127-138 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/172498 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration in the Luxury Sector
    Vertical Integration in the their economic model– and the consequen - ces it has had on the way the luxury sector Luxury Sector: Objectives, functions. A company is considered to be vertically Methods, Effects integrated when it is present at a number of Franck Delpal successive stages of the production process. However, a number of studies have outlined the various methods of integration, that go well beyond the simple full ownership of two successive production phases. Harrigan thus defines the different degrees of integra - tion implemented by companies, from complete control to total dis-integration via intermediary levels that concern only a selection of the production process or forms of control that are alternative to ownership (quasi-integration, vertical restrictions…). This analytical table corresponds more to The luxury market has grown impressively the diversity of the practices observed. over the past three decades. The figures Schematically, in the case of luxury fashion, supplied by Bain & Company testify to this we can outline four distinct phases in the fact: sales of luxury products went from 72 making of a product: billion Euros in 1994 to 168 billion Euros in 2010, which makes an annual growth rate – Design; average of 5%. Fashion items (ready-to- – The production of intermediary goods wear, shoes, leather goods) still retain a (fabrics, leathers…); considerable market share as they represent – Manufacturing the finished product; half of this figure. In addition to its econo - – Distribution, wholesale then retail. mic weight, the luxury fashion sector merits We are aware that this level of simplification analysis due to the evolution in its structure forces us to set aside numerous essential (number, size and organisation of compa - divisions in a company (quality control, nies) over the past few years.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Vertical Integration on Competing Input Suppliers
    The Effects of Vertical Integration on Competing Input Suppliers by R. Preston McAfee* Department of Economics University of Texas Austin, TX 78712 Wednesday, March 03, 1999 Prepared for The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Abstract: When a downstream firm buys an input supplier, the downstream firm can reduce its costs of using that input. Other input suppliers typically respond by pricing more aggressively, given the demand reduction, which tends to lower input supply costs to other firms. Thus a vertical merger may lower rival's costs, rather than raise them. * I have benefited from the comments of Joe Haubrich and William Thompson. Vertical integration is a booming phenomenon in many US industries. The massive consolidation of the defense industry has resulted in three or four platform developers1 that produce many of the components used in military platforms. Banking is consolidating at a rapid pace, with integration of related financial services (insurance, credit cards) along with input services (check clearing, payments, electronic funds transfer) into the parent companies. Telecommunications firms are merging, combining cable, wireless, local wireline and long distance services. Simultaneously, other firms are concentrating on their "core competency" and selling off related lines of business. Automobile manufacturers, for instance, are increasing their dependence on independent or semi-independent parts suppliers. What are the effects of vertical integration? There is a large literature that might reasonably be described as disjointed. Much of the focus has been on providing a rationale for opposing vertical mergers on antitrust grounds. When a firm F buys an input supplier (upstream firm) U that also supplies F's (downstream) competitor, the firm can raise the price of the input to its downstream competitor, thereby providing an advantage in the downstream market.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry John M
    Paper to be presented at the 35th DRUID Celebration Conference 2013, Barcelona, Spain, June 17-19 Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry John M. de Figueiredo Duke University School of Law [email protected] Brian S. Silverman University of Toronto Rotman School of Management [email protected] Abstract An important unanswered question in strategy research is: how does vertical integration affect industry evolution? Foreclosure and efficiency theory both predict that vertical integration by one firm can increase the exit rate of non-integrated rivals, but offer competing predictions for the cause of this increase. A related question is how upstream markets for technology affect downstream firm and industry performance ? i.e., to what extent does a thick upstream market for key technological inputs reduce foreclosure and reduce the efficiency benefits of integration? This paper attempts to answer these questions by a developing a series of predictions regarding the effect of vertical integration patterns and upstream markets for technology on downstream pricing, entry rates, and exit rates. We test these predictions empirically with unusually detailed data on the U.S. laser printer and laser engine industries between 1984 and 1996. We exploit both cross-section and time-series variation in governance of laser engine procurement among laser printer firms to explore the effects of vertical integration on entry, exit, and pricing dynamics in each segment of the industry. Jelcodes:L10,L63 Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry Abstract An important unanswered question in strategy research is: how does vertical integration affects industry evolution? Foreclosure and efficiency theory both predict that vertical integration by one firm can increase the exit rate of non-integrated rivals, but offer competing predictions for the cause of this increase.
    [Show full text]
  • Formulating Vertical Integration Strategies^ KATHRYN RUDIE HARRIGAN Columbia University
    Hevkn 1994, Vbt 9. Na 4. 63&4SS2. Formulating Vertical Integration Strategies^ KATHRYN RUDIE HARRIGAN Columbia University A framework is proposed that develops the dimensions of vertical integra- tion strated and proposes key factors that might augment their uses within various scenarios. These represent new hypotheses and conjectures about make-or-buy decisions that require empirical testing. If the framework is valid, strategists could formulate better hybrid vertical integration strategies by recogniang the hypothesized effects of these forces on the industries that might be linked. Managers need a ready supply of raw matoials and tbey have not recognized how to make this a more services, as wdl as a ready market for their firms' durable and keen competitive weapon. Because suc- outputs. The business arratigements tbat are used to cessful vertical integration strategies require the control tbese risks are forms of vertical integration. cooperation of several strategic business units Tbey tnay include vertical acquisitions, or intemal (SBUs), the formulation of such strategies is in the devdo{«ient of supplying or distributing units, or province of the chief executive officer (CEO). In otber means of extending firms' control over out- some cases, effective vertical integration may even siders. require temporary subsidization of one business unit at the expense of another. Decisions regarding sucb The Phenomenon of Vertical Integration SBU coordination (and resource allocations among Vertical integration is a corporate strategy tbat has them) must be made by the chief strategists. Tbus been misunderstood. It has lotig been a key force in effective vertical integration strategies need to refiect tbe development of bigb productivity and managerial botb business unit and corporate level strategy scqibistication in U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers Hilda Jordan Arline Walden University
    Walden University ScholarWorks Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Collection 2016 Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers Hilda Jordan Arline Walden University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.waldenu.edu/dissertations Part of the Advertising and Promotion Management Commons, and the Marketing Commons This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Collection at ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Walden University College of Management and Technology This is to certify that the doctoral study by Hilda Arline has been found to be complete and satisfactory in all respects, and that any and all revisions required by the review committee have been made. Review Committee Dr. Annie Brown, Committee Chairperson, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Dr. Lisa Kangas, Committee Member, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Dr. Patsy Kasen, University Reviewer, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Chief Academic Officer Eric Riedel, Ph.D. Walden University 2016 Abstract Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers by Hilda Jordan Arline MBA, Strayer University, 2010 BS, Elizabeth City State University, 1995 Doctoral Study Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Business Administration Walden University August 2016 Abstract Franchised small businesses will not survive their first 5 years if they cannot implement marketing strategies that appeal to their customers. The purpose of this multiple case study was to explore the marketing strategies that successful franchise small business leaders used to retain customers.
    [Show full text]
  • Linking Up: Vertical Integration Makes a Comeback
    Linking up: Vertical integration makes a comeback Transactions up and down the supply chain become more appealing to acquirers As horizontal deals become more challenging due to consolidation, dealmakers increasingly consider opportunities to go vertical. Vertical mergers have been stealing some conglomerate with a network of retail Will the trend of vertical transactions of the thunder from horizontal deals of locations, it could result in health continue in the coming months and late. As horizontal targets become harder insurance and other medical services at years despite these headwinds? In which to come by, some acquirers are focusing lower prices to consumers. types of situations are vertical deals most on companies up or down the supply appealing, and when do they not make chain from them—presenting both new Before these combinations can be sense? In order to answer these and opportunities for expansion and a new consummated, however, they must be other pressing questions on the subject, set of challenges. approved by antitrust authorities. Vertical we spoke with four leading experts. mergers have recently drawn greater Some of the most significant vertical scrutiny by the government, causing integrations penned recently also have would-be acquirers to second-guess the power to transform whole industries. their intentions as court actions play out. Contents Take the US$69bn tie-up between M&A advisors may also be hamstrung in pharmacy operator CVS Health and their ability to counsel clients regarding The upside of verticality 2 insurance giant Aetna, announced the types of cases the U.S. Justice in December 2017. By creating a Department elects to challenge.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Internet Strategies in the Apparel Industry1
    VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND INTERNET STRATEGIES IN THE APPAREL INDUSTRY1 Robert H. Gertner, University of Chicago and NBER Robert S. Stillman, Lexecon (Draft: November 16, 2000) Abstract Is greater vertical scope an impediment to change (inertia of large organizations) or a facilitator of change (avoidance of contract inflexibility)? There is little empirical evidence on this issue. This paper attempts to help fill this void by studying how firms in the apparel industry have adapted to the Internet. We focus on the apparel industry because apparel is one of the leading categories of on-line sales and because of the variance in organizational form that exists within the apparel industry. Some firms such as The Gap are vertically integrated. Many other brands are owned by vendors and sold primarily through department stores and other third-party retailers. Based on research that included interviews with apparel industry executives, we identify transaction-cost reasons why non-integrated firms in the apparel industry may have been at a relative disadvantage in their ability and incentive to adapt to the Internet. We examine the accuracy of our hypothesis using data from a sample of 30 firms in the apparel industry. Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that vertically integrated specialty retailers tended to start on-line sales sooner, even after controlling for other factors such as whether a firm had pre-existing catalog operations. This systematic pattern is inconsistent with the null hypothesis that the timing of on-line sales is the product of firm-specific factors that are unrelated to organizational form. We also find that the products of vertically integrated specialty retailers and catalog companies are more available on-line than the products of non-integrated vendors.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Product Differentiation1
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Repository@Nottingham Vertical integration and product di¤erentiation1 Piercarlo Zanchettin 2 and Arijit Mukherjee 3 Version: July 24, 2017 We study a new channel of downstream rent extraction through vertical integration: competition for integration. Innovative downstream …rms create value and pro…t oppor- tunities through product di¤erentiation, which however a¤ects an upstream monopolist’s incentive to vertically integrate. By playing the downstream …rms against each other for integration, the upstream …rm can extract even more than the additional pro…ts generated by the downstream …rms’di¤erentiation activities. To preempt rent extraction, the down- stream …rms may then reduce di¤erentiation, which reduces social welfare. We show that this social cost of vertical integration is more likely to arise in innovative and competitive industries, and that the competition for integration channel of downstream rent extraction is robust to upstream competition. Key Words: Vertical integration; product di¤erentiation; rent extraction; product innovation, market segmentation. JEL Codes: D43, L13, 034 1 We thank, without implicating, Carl Davidson, Gianni De Fraja, Vincenzo Denicoló, Simona Mateut, Claudio Mezzetti, and Daniel Seidmann for useful comments. We are also grateful to seminar audiences in Nottingham, Leicester, and Vienna. The usual disclaimer applies. 2 Corresponding author: Department of Economics, University of Leicester, University Road, Leicester, LE1 7RH, UK. Tel.: +44-116-2525319, Fax: +44-116-2522908, E-mail: [email protected]. 3 Nottingham University Business School, UK; CESifo and INFER, Germany; GRU, City Uni- versity of Hong Kong, Hong Kong.
    [Show full text]