Formulating Vertical Integration Strategies^ KATHRYN RUDIE HARRIGAN Columbia University

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Formulating Vertical Integration Strategies^ KATHRYN RUDIE HARRIGAN Columbia University Hevkn 1994, Vbt 9. Na 4. 63&4SS2. Formulating Vertical Integration Strategies^ KATHRYN RUDIE HARRIGAN Columbia University A framework is proposed that develops the dimensions of vertical integra- tion strated and proposes key factors that might augment their uses within various scenarios. These represent new hypotheses and conjectures about make-or-buy decisions that require empirical testing. If the framework is valid, strategists could formulate better hybrid vertical integration strategies by recogniang the hypothesized effects of these forces on the industries that might be linked. Managers need a ready supply of raw matoials and tbey have not recognized how to make this a more services, as wdl as a ready market for their firms' durable and keen competitive weapon. Because suc- outputs. The business arratigements tbat are used to cessful vertical integration strategies require the control tbese risks are forms of vertical integration. cooperation of several strategic business units Tbey tnay include vertical acquisitions, or intemal (SBUs), the formulation of such strategies is in the devdo{«ient of supplying or distributing units, or province of the chief executive officer (CEO). In otber means of extending firms' control over out- some cases, effective vertical integration may even siders. require temporary subsidization of one business unit at the expense of another. Decisions regarding sucb The Phenomenon of Vertical Integration SBU coordination (and resource allocations among Vertical integration is a corporate strategy tbat has them) must be made by the chief strategists. Tbus been misunderstood. It has lotig been a key force in effective vertical integration strategies need to refiect tbe development of bigb productivity and managerial botb business unit and corporate level strategy scqibistication in U.S. business (Cbandler, 1977). Ver- requirements. tically integrated corporations bave been key engines Tbis paper proposes a framework for developing of cbange in tbe past and bave enbanced sbarebolder effective vertical integration strategies. It was wealtb (Lubatkin, 1982). Yet earUer findings tbat developed by syntbesizing tbe tbeoretical foundations "dominant verticals" (Rumelt, 1974) and vertical establisbed by tbe industrial economics and strategic mergers were least successful as diversifications management literatures witb firms' observed behav- (Baker, Miller, & Ramsperger, 1981) may bave iors. Thus it suggests a new way to look at vertical soured mana^rs and academic researcbers on tbe integration and the forces that affect firms' cboices usefulness of tbis strategy unnecessarily. Oftentimes concerning vertical linkages. It develops normative researcbas did not recognize tbat votical integration propositions conceming wbicb generic vertical could be an effective strategy, provided it was used strategies migbt be more appropriate under different pnutently, because tbey often took an overly aggre- competitive circumstances, and it uses examples of gated view of it. Because critics bave not discemed firms' successes or failures in using vertical integra- bow tbe impOTtant dimensions of vertical integraticm tion to suggest bow traditional concepts of this be adapted over time (as industries cbange). strategy mi^t be amended to refiect effective in- dustry practices. These suggestions are new hypo- theses, which will require empirical testing. Vertical 'The research was st^iported by tbe Strategy Researcb Center, Cdurabia University. Comments and oitidsm from William H. integration is one of tbe first diversification strategies Newman, Ian MacMillan, and Donald C. Hambrick are also tbat firms embrace. Unfortunatdy, some firms seem graulaHy acknowledged. The author is indebted to Donald C. to use it in a manner that seems inappropriate for I&iabrick for suggesting the graphic configuration in Fipire 1. tbdr circumstances. Tbe issue of vertical inte^ation 638 deserves additional analysis because it bas been sified firms he bad classified in otber ways. If misunderstood in tbe past, and because tbe develop- previous studies of votical inte^ation used dassifica- ment of a more rigorous means of analyzitig this tion rules simiiar to Rumelt's, tbey also may bave strategy (and the performance it promises) cotild understated its tme activity level. For example. result in the formulation of more effective industry Federal Trade Commission data for 1948 to 1972 linkages, more rapid technological improvements, conceming large acquisitions (assets larger tban $10 stronger global strategies, and better use of vertical million) indicate tbat less than 15 percent of these integration. Table 1 summarizes many ofthe advan- were vertical mergers; and Salter and Wdnhold's tages and risks associated with vertical integration. (1979) list of $100 million or more acquisitions made The narrow case in which a firm's major diversi- during 1975-1978 indicated that only 4 percent were fication strategy has been only vertical is not the focus vertical. Thus an illusion was perpetuated that ver- of this inquiry. Instead, it considers the larger tical integrations were rare, except in the ral, mbber, universe of firms that have linked two or more SBUs basic metals, and forest products industries. But, in through vertical relationsbips and bave diversified in fact, acquisitions that are classified as bdng other- otber ways as well. Rumeh (1974) would bave found wise "related" to tbe firm's core businesses may also tbat many of tbe more diversified firms in his For- bave provided new distribution cbannds or other tune 500 sample also bad vertical transfers of goods assets that are vertically related to them. or services in-bouse, bad tbat been tbe focus of bis Acquired firms are bundles of assets rather than inquiry. Tbus Rumelt reported tbat 22 percent of tbe single business units, as Ocddental Petroleum firms in bis sample embraced a dominant vertical discovered when courting Cities Service (and as Du strategy in 1969 (up from 20 percent in 1949), but Pont learned while absorbing Conoco). Acquisitions vertical linkages also existed witbin tbe bighly diver- can offer vertical linkages as wdl as nonvertical diver- sifications. Corporate strategists must dedde whether to retain the business units acqtiired inddentally in Table 1 this fashion; and if tbey are vertically rdated, Some Advantages and Disadvantages strategists must dedde wbetber to encourage intra- of Vertical Integration firm commerce (subsidy) or demand arms-length transactions between vertical sister units. Thus, more seemingly unrelated mergers bave vertical elements Advantages Disadvantages to tbem tban is generally recognized, but oftentimes Internal benefits Internat costs strategists see no advantage to encouraging vertical Integration econoniies reduce Need for overbead to coordinate relationsbips between in-bouse units. Tbis may oc- costs by eliminating steps, re- vertical integration increased ducing duplicate overbead, costs cur because tbe opportunities for vertical competitive and cutting costs (tecbnology Burden of excess capacity from advantage bave passed in some industries. In otber dependent) unevenly balanced tninimum Iniproved coorditiation of activ- efficient scale plants (technol- cases, bowever, tbis occurs because managers did not ities reduces inventorying and ogy dependent) recognize bow to exploit tbe advantages of vertical other costs Poorly organized vertically in- Avoid time-consuming tasks, tegrated firms do not enjoy integration effectively. such as price shopping, com- sipergies tbat compensate for municating design details, or bigber costs negotiating contracts The Legacy of Vertical Integration Cortipetitive benefits Competitive dangers Avoid forecbsure to inputs, ser- Obsolete processes may be per- Vertical integration bas been an important mana- vices, or markets petuated gerial innovation and a necessary technological step Improved marketitig or techno- Creates mobility (or exit) bar- logical intelligence riers in developing certain industries, but it may not be Opportunity to create product links firm to sick adjacent busi- appropriate in tbe same form under all circum- differentiation (increased value added) Lose access to itiformation from stances. For example, ownership of ore mines, ships, Superior control of firm's eco- suppliers or distributors foundries, rolling mills, and fabricating plants was nomic environment (market Synergies created through ver- power) ' tical im^ration may be over- necessary for steel companies to lower costs and im- Create credibility for new prod- rated prove productivity in the 1890s. In its early years. ucts Managers integrated before Ford Motor Company owned and operated every Synergies could be created by tbinking tbrough the most ap- coordinatbig vertical activities propriate way to do so stage of processing from iron ore to Hnisb-and-trim skillfully operations (except tires and glass). In these early 639 years, suppliers may not have berai as willing to share on tbeories of market power and tbe ideal of perfectly Ford's gamble in persua^ng consumers to purcbase competitive industries (Addman, 1979; Blair & "horsdess carriages," so Ford bad to devdop com- Kaserman, 1978; Comanor, 1967; Dennison, 1939; ponraits to its spedfications for itsdf. Tliere were Frank, 1925; Jewkes, 1930; and Lavington, 1925). substantial economies assodated with vertical in- Tbese scholars largely have not recognized that dif- tegration once FOTd bad overcome the public's ferent motives for vertical integration—such as resistance
Recommended publications
  • Make and Buy: Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Cost Reduction∗
    Make and Buy: Outsourcing, Vertical Integration, and Cost Reduction∗ Simon Loertscher† Michael H. Riordan‡ University of Melbourne Columbia University November 16, 2017 Abstract Globalization reshaped supply chains and the boundaries of firms in favor of outsourcing. Now, even vertically integrated firms procure substantially from ex- ternal suppliers. To study procurement and the structure of firms in this reshaped economy, we analyze a model in which integration grants a downstream customer the option to source internally. Integration is advantageous because it allows the customer sometimes to avoid paying markups, but disadvantageous because it dis- courages investments in cost reduction by independent suppliers. The investment- discouragement effect more likely outweighs the markup-avoidance effect if the upstream market is more competitive, as is so in a more global economy. Keywords: outsourcing, vertical integration, make and buy. JEL-Classification: C72, L13, L22, L24 ∗We are grateful to the editor (John Asker) and three anonymous referees for comments and sugges- tions that have improved the paper considerably. The paper has also benefitted from comments by Malin Arve, Patrick Bolton, Roberto Burguet, Jacques Cr´emer, Jean de Bettignies, Yassine Lefouili, Hans- Theo Normann, Eric Rasmusen, Patrick Rey, Antonio Rosato, Yossi Spiegel and workshop participants at the 2011 Industrial Economics Conference at Zhejiang University, at the 2013 Kick-off Workshop of the D¨usseldorf Institute for Competition Economics, at Ecole Polyt´echnique in Paris, at Indiana Uni- versity, at the Organizational Economics Workshop at the University of Sydney 2012, the Workshop of Public Private Collaboration 2013 at IESE Business School in Barcelona, the 2013 Canadian Economics Association Meetings in Montreal, the 2014 Australasian Economic Theory Workshop in Canberra, the 2014 Searle Conference on Antitrust Economics in Chicago, and the Conference in honour of Jacques Cr´emer on Advances in the Economics of Organizations and the New Economy in Toulouse in 2016.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Vertical Integration
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Impact of Vertical Integration H. Luke, Erin The University of Wisconsin-Whitewater 7 March 2021 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/106490/ MPRA Paper No. 106490, posted 08 Mar 2021 07:37 UTC 1 Impact of Vertical Integration Erin H. Luke The University of Wisconsin-Whitewater 2021 Abstract Vertical integration is a powerful, and complex business strategy that when used under the right conditions can positively impact an organization. A company’s strategists need to understand what dimensions of integration to use, and the best time to use it. De Beers is a company with a controversial history of being an anti-competitive monopoly. By strategizing into a vertical integrated company De beers has added value to its company by not only targeting the retail, and industrial market, but also the I.T. industry. Forward and backward integration has helped organizations like De Beers maintain control over its inputs and outputs. Rather than just buying all diamond mines, and stock piling the material in order to control the prices, De Beers has embraced change by focusing on new emerging industries. Through vertical strategy and new ownership De Beers is turning its company around in a very competitive luxury industry. Organizations should be aware of the costs of vertical integration when exploring its potential. Bureaucratic costs, and companies becoming too large and inflexible under certain environments can become a problem. Vertical integration is a powerful strategy, but it must always be under scrutiny, and redesigned when the external and internal environment deems change necessary. 2 2 Table of Contents What is Vertical Integration? .......................................................................................................3 De Beers Summary ........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Market Structure by Timothy F
    This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH SIEPR Discussion Paper No. 11-010 Vertical Integration and Market Structure by Timothy F. Bresnahan Jonathan D. Levin Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305 (650) 725-1874 The Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research at Stanford University supports research bearing on economic and public policy issues. The SIEPR Discussion Paper Series reports on research and policy analysis conducted by researchers affiliated with the Institute. Working papers in this series reflect the views of the authors and not necessarily those of the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research or Stanford University. Vertical Integration and Market Structure Timothy Bresnahan and Jonathan Levin* Stanford University March 2012 Abstract. Contractual theories of vertical integration derive firm boundaries as an efficient response to market transaction costs. These theories predict a relationship between underlying features of transactions and observed integration decisions. There has been some progress in testing these predictions, but less progress in quantifying their importance. One difficulty is that empirical applications often must consider firm structure together with industry structure. Research in industrial organization frequently has adopted this perspective, emphasizing how scale and scope economies, and strategic considerations, influence patterns of industry integration. But this research has paid less attention to contractual or organizational details, so that these two major lines of research on vertical integration have proceeded in parallel with only rare intersection. We discuss the value of combining different viewpoints from organizational economics and industrial organization. JEL classification numbers: D23, L14, L22.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: the Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Todorova, Tamara Article — Manuscript Version (Preprint) Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: The Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry Journal of Advanced Research in Management Suggested Citation: Todorova, Tamara (2010) : Vertical Integration in High-Transaction Cost Sectors: The Case of the Bulgarian Pharmaceutical Industry, Journal of Advanced Research in Management, ISSN 2068-7532, ASERS Publishing, Craiova, Vol. 1, Iss. 2 (Winter), pp. 127-138 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/172498 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration in the Luxury Sector
    Vertical Integration in the their economic model– and the consequen - ces it has had on the way the luxury sector Luxury Sector: Objectives, functions. A company is considered to be vertically Methods, Effects integrated when it is present at a number of Franck Delpal successive stages of the production process. However, a number of studies have outlined the various methods of integration, that go well beyond the simple full ownership of two successive production phases. Harrigan thus defines the different degrees of integra - tion implemented by companies, from complete control to total dis-integration via intermediary levels that concern only a selection of the production process or forms of control that are alternative to ownership (quasi-integration, vertical restrictions…). This analytical table corresponds more to The luxury market has grown impressively the diversity of the practices observed. over the past three decades. The figures Schematically, in the case of luxury fashion, supplied by Bain & Company testify to this we can outline four distinct phases in the fact: sales of luxury products went from 72 making of a product: billion Euros in 1994 to 168 billion Euros in 2010, which makes an annual growth rate – Design; average of 5%. Fashion items (ready-to- – The production of intermediary goods wear, shoes, leather goods) still retain a (fabrics, leathers…); considerable market share as they represent – Manufacturing the finished product; half of this figure. In addition to its econo - – Distribution, wholesale then retail. mic weight, the luxury fashion sector merits We are aware that this level of simplification analysis due to the evolution in its structure forces us to set aside numerous essential (number, size and organisation of compa - divisions in a company (quality control, nies) over the past few years.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Vertical Integration on Competing Input Suppliers
    The Effects of Vertical Integration on Competing Input Suppliers by R. Preston McAfee* Department of Economics University of Texas Austin, TX 78712 Wednesday, March 03, 1999 Prepared for The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Abstract: When a downstream firm buys an input supplier, the downstream firm can reduce its costs of using that input. Other input suppliers typically respond by pricing more aggressively, given the demand reduction, which tends to lower input supply costs to other firms. Thus a vertical merger may lower rival's costs, rather than raise them. * I have benefited from the comments of Joe Haubrich and William Thompson. Vertical integration is a booming phenomenon in many US industries. The massive consolidation of the defense industry has resulted in three or four platform developers1 that produce many of the components used in military platforms. Banking is consolidating at a rapid pace, with integration of related financial services (insurance, credit cards) along with input services (check clearing, payments, electronic funds transfer) into the parent companies. Telecommunications firms are merging, combining cable, wireless, local wireline and long distance services. Simultaneously, other firms are concentrating on their "core competency" and selling off related lines of business. Automobile manufacturers, for instance, are increasing their dependence on independent or semi-independent parts suppliers. What are the effects of vertical integration? There is a large literature that might reasonably be described as disjointed. Much of the focus has been on providing a rationale for opposing vertical mergers on antitrust grounds. When a firm F buys an input supplier (upstream firm) U that also supplies F's (downstream) competitor, the firm can raise the price of the input to its downstream competitor, thereby providing an advantage in the downstream market.
    [Show full text]
  • Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry John M
    Paper to be presented at the 35th DRUID Celebration Conference 2013, Barcelona, Spain, June 17-19 Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry John M. de Figueiredo Duke University School of Law [email protected] Brian S. Silverman University of Toronto Rotman School of Management [email protected] Abstract An important unanswered question in strategy research is: how does vertical integration affect industry evolution? Foreclosure and efficiency theory both predict that vertical integration by one firm can increase the exit rate of non-integrated rivals, but offer competing predictions for the cause of this increase. A related question is how upstream markets for technology affect downstream firm and industry performance ? i.e., to what extent does a thick upstream market for key technological inputs reduce foreclosure and reduce the efficiency benefits of integration? This paper attempts to answer these questions by a developing a series of predictions regarding the effect of vertical integration patterns and upstream markets for technology on downstream pricing, entry rates, and exit rates. We test these predictions empirically with unusually detailed data on the U.S. laser printer and laser engine industries between 1984 and 1996. We exploit both cross-section and time-series variation in governance of laser engine procurement among laser printer firms to explore the effects of vertical integration on entry, exit, and pricing dynamics in each segment of the industry. Jelcodes:L10,L63 Markets for Technology, Vertical Integration, and Industry Dynamics: Efficiency and Foreclosure in the Laser Printer Industry Abstract An important unanswered question in strategy research is: how does vertical integration affects industry evolution? Foreclosure and efficiency theory both predict that vertical integration by one firm can increase the exit rate of non-integrated rivals, but offer competing predictions for the cause of this increase.
    [Show full text]
  • Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers Hilda Jordan Arline Walden University
    Walden University ScholarWorks Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Collection 2016 Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers Hilda Jordan Arline Walden University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarworks.waldenu.edu/dissertations Part of the Advertising and Promotion Management Commons, and the Marketing Commons This Dissertation is brought to you for free and open access by the Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies Collection at ScholarWorks. It has been accepted for inclusion in Walden Dissertations and Doctoral Studies by an authorized administrator of ScholarWorks. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Walden University College of Management and Technology This is to certify that the doctoral study by Hilda Arline has been found to be complete and satisfactory in all respects, and that any and all revisions required by the review committee have been made. Review Committee Dr. Annie Brown, Committee Chairperson, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Dr. Lisa Kangas, Committee Member, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Dr. Patsy Kasen, University Reviewer, Doctor of Business Administration Faculty Chief Academic Officer Eric Riedel, Ph.D. Walden University 2016 Abstract Marketing Strategies Used by Franchise Small Businesses to Retain Customers by Hilda Jordan Arline MBA, Strayer University, 2010 BS, Elizabeth City State University, 1995 Doctoral Study Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Doctor of Business Administration Walden University August 2016 Abstract Franchised small businesses will not survive their first 5 years if they cannot implement marketing strategies that appeal to their customers. The purpose of this multiple case study was to explore the marketing strategies that successful franchise small business leaders used to retain customers.
    [Show full text]
  • Linking Up: Vertical Integration Makes a Comeback
    Linking up: Vertical integration makes a comeback Transactions up and down the supply chain become more appealing to acquirers As horizontal deals become more challenging due to consolidation, dealmakers increasingly consider opportunities to go vertical. Vertical mergers have been stealing some conglomerate with a network of retail Will the trend of vertical transactions of the thunder from horizontal deals of locations, it could result in health continue in the coming months and late. As horizontal targets become harder insurance and other medical services at years despite these headwinds? In which to come by, some acquirers are focusing lower prices to consumers. types of situations are vertical deals most on companies up or down the supply appealing, and when do they not make chain from them—presenting both new Before these combinations can be sense? In order to answer these and opportunities for expansion and a new consummated, however, they must be other pressing questions on the subject, set of challenges. approved by antitrust authorities. Vertical we spoke with four leading experts. mergers have recently drawn greater Some of the most significant vertical scrutiny by the government, causing integrations penned recently also have would-be acquirers to second-guess the power to transform whole industries. their intentions as court actions play out. Contents Take the US$69bn tie-up between M&A advisors may also be hamstrung in pharmacy operator CVS Health and their ability to counsel clients regarding The upside of verticality 2 insurance giant Aetna, announced the types of cases the U.S. Justice in December 2017. By creating a Department elects to challenge.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Internet Strategies in the Apparel Industry1
    VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND INTERNET STRATEGIES IN THE APPAREL INDUSTRY1 Robert H. Gertner, University of Chicago and NBER Robert S. Stillman, Lexecon (Draft: November 16, 2000) Abstract Is greater vertical scope an impediment to change (inertia of large organizations) or a facilitator of change (avoidance of contract inflexibility)? There is little empirical evidence on this issue. This paper attempts to help fill this void by studying how firms in the apparel industry have adapted to the Internet. We focus on the apparel industry because apparel is one of the leading categories of on-line sales and because of the variance in organizational form that exists within the apparel industry. Some firms such as The Gap are vertically integrated. Many other brands are owned by vendors and sold primarily through department stores and other third-party retailers. Based on research that included interviews with apparel industry executives, we identify transaction-cost reasons why non-integrated firms in the apparel industry may have been at a relative disadvantage in their ability and incentive to adapt to the Internet. We examine the accuracy of our hypothesis using data from a sample of 30 firms in the apparel industry. Consistent with our hypothesis, we find that vertically integrated specialty retailers tended to start on-line sales sooner, even after controlling for other factors such as whether a firm had pre-existing catalog operations. This systematic pattern is inconsistent with the null hypothesis that the timing of on-line sales is the product of firm-specific factors that are unrelated to organizational form. We also find that the products of vertically integrated specialty retailers and catalog companies are more available on-line than the products of non-integrated vendors.
    [Show full text]
  • Vertical Integration and Product Differentiation1
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Repository@Nottingham Vertical integration and product di¤erentiation1 Piercarlo Zanchettin 2 and Arijit Mukherjee 3 Version: July 24, 2017 We study a new channel of downstream rent extraction through vertical integration: competition for integration. Innovative downstream …rms create value and pro…t oppor- tunities through product di¤erentiation, which however a¤ects an upstream monopolist’s incentive to vertically integrate. By playing the downstream …rms against each other for integration, the upstream …rm can extract even more than the additional pro…ts generated by the downstream …rms’di¤erentiation activities. To preempt rent extraction, the down- stream …rms may then reduce di¤erentiation, which reduces social welfare. We show that this social cost of vertical integration is more likely to arise in innovative and competitive industries, and that the competition for integration channel of downstream rent extraction is robust to upstream competition. Key Words: Vertical integration; product di¤erentiation; rent extraction; product innovation, market segmentation. JEL Codes: D43, L13, 034 1 We thank, without implicating, Carl Davidson, Gianni De Fraja, Vincenzo Denicoló, Simona Mateut, Claudio Mezzetti, and Daniel Seidmann for useful comments. We are also grateful to seminar audiences in Nottingham, Leicester, and Vienna. The usual disclaimer applies. 2 Corresponding author: Department of Economics, University of Leicester, University Road, Leicester, LE1 7RH, UK. Tel.: +44-116-2525319, Fax: +44-116-2522908, E-mail: [email protected]. 3 Nottingham University Business School, UK; CESifo and INFER, Germany; GRU, City Uni- versity of Hong Kong, Hong Kong.
    [Show full text]
  • Do Prices Determine Vertical Integration?
    Do Prices Determine Vertical Integration? The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Alfaro, Laura, Paola Conconi, Harald Fadinger, and Andrew F. Newman. "Do Prices Determine Vertical Integration?" Review of Economic Studies (forthcoming). (NBER Working Paper 16118 and CEPR Discussion Paper 7899.) Published Version http://restud.oxfordjournals.org/ Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:23779733 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Open Access Policy Articles, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#OAP Do Prices Determine Vertical Integration?∗ Laura Alfaro Harvard Business School and NBER Paola Conconi Universit´eLibre de Bruxelles (ECARES) and CEPR Harald Fadinger University of Vienna Andrew F. Newman Boston University and CEPR February 2014 Abstract What is the relationship between product prices and vertical integration? While the litera- ture has focused on how integration affects prices, this paper provides evidence that prices can affect integration. Many theories in organizational economics and industrial organi- zation posit that integration, while costly, increases productivity. It follows from firms’ maximizing behavior that higher prices induce more integration. The reason is that at low prices, increases in revenue resulting from enhanced productivity are too small to justify the cost, whereas at high prices the revenue benefit exceeds the cost. Trade policy pro- vides a source of exogenous price variation to assess the validity of this prediction: higher tariffs should lead to higher prices and therefore to more integration.
    [Show full text]