Scan&Deliver

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Scan&Deliver ILLiad TN: 4172216 111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111 Scan&Deliver Call #: WID WIDLC HM881 .8532004 Borrower: HLS Location: HLS Lending String: HLS 8/22/2013 8:23:06 AM Shipping Address: Patron: Jones, Alison Harvard University - Widener Library Interlibrary Loan Journal Title: The Blackwell companion to social Harvard University movements /edited by David A. Snow, Sarah A. Cambridge, MA 02138 Soule, and Hanspeter Kriesi. Volume: Issue: Fax: MonthNear: 2004Pages: ? Ariel: Odyssey: 206.107.43.109 Email: 206.107.43.109 Article Author: Buechler MaxCost: Article Title: The Strange Career of Strain and Breakdown Theories of Collective Action Special Instructions: ILL Number: 4172215 111111111111111111111111111111111111111111111 THIS IS NOT AN INVOICEI NON-IFM LIBRARIES WILL RECEIVE AN INVOICE UNDER SEPARATE COVER FOR THIS TRANSACTION FROM HARVARD UNIVERSITY ACCOUNTS RECEIVABLE IN 4-6 WEEKS PLEASE DO NOT SEND PA YMENT UNTIL YOU RECEIVE AN INVOICEI RUUD KOOPMANS 41'1 . PhD d e and the Study of Politics. Amer;· f'len4lfl. l'.lultlOOO) l",ruslng Returns, at epen ene, ,.I" l'u/IlI'oJl .'K'ma RI'I'II'UI, 94, 251-67. R.lmm.trJl. '}tt~tn ,1978) Sozwle Bewegung. Frankfurt am Mam: Suhrkamp. R.... h"f1. Ih"mJ\ R. IIIIMN) Mobilizing for Peace: The Antinuclear Movements in Western t JI'''/rt' I'nn..cton. NJ: Princeton University Press. Rule. I.lme,....nJ (h.lrl~ Tilly (1972) 1830 and the Unnatural History of Revolution. Journal "I'" .. ,.dlu"",. 2ll. 49-76. ,h..ftcl. hlurJ• .And Ch.ub Tilly (1974) Strikes in France, 1830-1968. Cambridge: Cam­ l-tf..JJtr t )rllH'f,!t\ Preu. \nw!Wf. ~d J. \1%21 fhtory of Collective Behavior. New York: Free Press. 'now. n.mJ A..and RoOtn D. Brnford (1999) Alternative Types of Cross-National Diffusion 111 the' '-"\AI ",,'emfnt Arena. In Donatella della Porta, Hanspeter Kriesi, and Dieter Rt"hr 1M 1.\;,,1.11 MOl't'mt"1ftS in a Globalizing World. Houndmills: Macmillan, 23-39. '-,ul... '-tr.lh \,...... ) The D\ffusion of an Unsuccessful Innovation. Annals of the American ".~ 01 f'oiltu.J/ .",d .StlClal Science, 566, 120-31. \tr.a~. n..,tJ...oJ John W. Meyer (1993) Institutional Conditions for Diffusion. Theory and "' .....h. H. ·ur'-H I. ,",,,n«. \)"~IJ. AoJ \.auh Soule (1998) Diffusion in Organizations and Social Movements: trum t htwtd ( om til POlion Spills. Annual Review ofSociology, 24, 265-90. t.."..... ~r tl~~~) I>""o(1acy and Disorder: Protest and Politics in Italy 1965-1975. (htOfJ. (t.art'nd<m. l ...... i P, ... ·.,.., III .\tlll't'mtnt: Social Movements. Collective Action and Politics. Cam­ t>.". ("mhr~ l!nl\'t'rstty Prns. 1Ill., ( lurk, [ ,q~lI i "'"m Moblllzution to Revolution. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. l.[I" ( "..uk" It)\UW 1111v. and Roblert Tilly (1975) The Rebellious Century, 1830-1930. { .lmt>f~. \1.\ "",,\.uJ Umversity Press. ',,",ITt, Rut ,"ao, I"nh.untv Modd. 8reakdown Model, and the Boston Anti-Busing Move­ motllt "1IlIw"1.....,"'.. " .1"1(/(41 Rel'Int'. 45, 357-69. 1.>4t-.rfl.\'ntldt R. I' ....!\ MOC1\(nts of Madness. Politics and Society, 2, 183-207. 3 The Strange Career of Strain and Breakdown Theories of Collective Action STEVEN M. BUECHLER Since the 1970s, social movement theory has changed dramatically. One reason is that "the study of social movements is volatile hecause the phenomena under consideration change so rapidly" (Garner 1997: 1). In this imagery, theory changes to reflect changes in its subject matter. However, theoretical change often has less to do with faithful reflections of a changing suhject matter than with rapid shifts in assumptions, perspectives, and questions (Kuhn 1962). A hroader sociology of knowledge suggests that theories also change in response to altered sociohistorical Contexts and new generations of theorists who bring different experiences to their theoretical work and to the very definition of their subject matter. Within sociology as a whole, all these factors prompted the paradigm shifts of the post-World War II period. The functionalist orthodoxy of the 1950s gave way to several alternatives in the 1960s because social phenomena changed, social and political currents also changed, and new generations of sociologists hrought differ­ ent experiences to their work. The theoretical disputes between functionalism, conflict theory, critical theory, phenomenology, feminist theory, and other alterna­ tives defined the broader context in which paradigm shifts occurred in subfields like collective behavior and social movements. The story of social movement theory is not just a function of movements themselves, but also of the social and intellectual histories of the countries and disciplines in which the theories evolve. The major paradigm shift in social movement theory is indexed hy the inelegant but revealing nomenclature of "collective behavior/social movements"; the forward slash testifies to the conceptual confusion and disagreement that characterizes this area. It was not always so. For much of the twentieth century, there was a consensu­ ally designated subfie1d called "collective behavior," and social movements were seen as one subtype of collective behavior along with panics, crazes, crowds, rumors, and riots. During this time, a major explanation for the emergence of all kinds of 48 STEVEN M. BUECHLER . h . ds of strain and breakdown gcncrate collective collectIve behavIOr was t at peno .' II .' . behavior because the social controls and morallmperatlves that norma J l<mstr~m such behavior are weakened or absent. Strain and breakdown theones were thus tled to a whole series of assumptions about the nature of collective hehavior and the subsumption of social movements under that rubric. When those assumptiOl:s were challenged and that rubric was undermined, theorists began to emphasIze the differences between collective behavior and social movements, and to focus more exclusively on the latter as requiring a separate analysis. In so doing, strain and breakdown theories were both actively challenged and passively marginalized as part of a broader paradigm shift. As often happens, the role of strain and breakdown in precipitating collecnve behavior was probably overstated by the collective behavior paradigm and under­ stated by its critics. Tracing the strange career of strain and breakdown theories promises to restore some balance to our understanding of the role of such factors in collective action while also shedding light on how paradigms shift. This chapter is organized into four parts. First, I summarize the role of strain and breakdown theories in the earlier collective behavior paradigm. Second, I trace the demise of these theories with the decline of the collective behavior paradigm and the emer­ gence of the resource mobilization approach. Third, I document how such theories nonetheless persisted throughout the predominance of resource mobilization theory. Finally, I identify how they have returned, in a new guise and nomenclature, to a central role in the analysis of collective action. THE CLASSICAL ERA OF STRAIN AND BREAKDOWN THEORIES The concepts of strain and breakdown imply a social order whose normal condition is one of integration. If the social order remains sufficiently integrated, strain and hreakdown may be avoided altogether and collective behavior may be precluded. In this logic, all roads lead to Durkheim's overriding concern with social integration and the problematic consequences of insufficient integration in modern societies (Ourkheim [1893] 1964). Premodern societies were less problematic as the con­ science collective and mechanical solidarity underwrote social integration and min­ imized strain and breakdown. With the decline of the conscience collective and increases in dynamic density and social differentiation, modern societies became more prone to such problems. In theory, the emergent division of labor would provide the functional integration and organic solidarity to bind modern societies together. In reality, Durkheim was well aware that modern societies did not conform to the theoretical expectation. His classic analyses of anomie and egoism identified breaches in the social order that could lead to chronic strains or acute breakdowns. One indication of such problems was elevated suicide rates, but suicide was merely one example of a range of antisocial, dysfunctional behaviors that could result from strain and breakdown (Durkheim [1897] 1951). The remedy was increased social integration through more explicit normative regulation to guide conduct and srrengthened social bonds to contain excessive individualism. While Durkheim said relatively little about collective behavior as the term came to be understood in the ~entieth ~entury, his analysis provided a major foundation for subsequent theones of stram and breakdown as explanations of such behavior. STRAIN AND BREAKDOWN THEORIES 49 A more direct link between social breakdown and collective behavior was forged by European theorists of crowd behavior who were Durkheim's contemporaries. In their view, "The cause of civil violence ... was the breakdown of rational con­ trol over human behavior through the spread of what one might call 'crowd mentality'" (Rule 1988: 83). Crowds were theorized to act under the sway of intense emotional states generated by physical proximity; such behavior was in marked contrast to the rational and orderly behavior that prevailed in conventional social settings. It was Robert Park (Park and Burgess 1921; Park 1972) who introduced this tradition into US sociology by positing a fundamental distinction between social integration
Recommended publications
  • Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norm Internalization Sergey Gavriletsa,B,C,1 and Peter J
    Collective action and the evolution of social norm internalization Sergey Gavriletsa,b,c,1 and Peter J. Richersond aDepartment of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996; bDepartment of Mathematics, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996; cNational Institute for Mathematical and Biological Synthesis, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996; and dDepartment of Environmental Science and Policy, University of California, Davis, CA 95616 Edited by Simon A. Levin, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, and approved May 4, 2017 (received for review March 7, 2017) Human behavior is strongly affected by culturally transmitted processing, and decision making (11) and the costs of monitor- norms and values. Certain norms are internalized (i.e., acting ing, punishments, or conditional rewards that would otherwise be according to a norm becomes an end in itself rather than merely necessary to ensure cooperation (9, 14). Internalization of norms a tool in achieving certain goals or avoiding social sanctions). allows individuals and groups to adjust their utility functions Humans’ capacity to internalize norms likely evolved in our ances- in situations with a rapidly changing environment when genetic tors to simplify solving certain challenges—including social ones. mechanisms would be too slow to react (9). A society’s values are Here we study theoretically the evolutionary origins of the capac- transmitted through the internalization of norms (15), with some ity to internalize norms. In our models, individuals can choose societies being more successful than others due to their norms to participate in collective actions as well as punish free rid- and institutions (16). The presence of both costs and benefits of ers.
    [Show full text]
  • Transient Solidarities: Commitment and Collective Action in Post-Industrial Societies Charles Heckscher and John Mccarthy
    bs_bs_banner British Journal of Industrial Relations doi: 10.1111/bjir.12084 52:4 December 2014 0007–1080 pp. 627–657 Transient Solidarities: Commitment and Collective Action in Post-Industrial Societies Charles Heckscher and John McCarthy Abstract Solidarity has long been considered essential to labour, but many fear that it has declined. There has been relatively little scholarly investigation of it because of both theoretical and empirical difficulties. This article argues that solidarity has not declined but has changed in form, which has an impact on what kinds of mobilization are effective. We first develop a theory of solidarity general enough to compare different forms. We then trace the evolution of solidarity through craft and industrial versions, to the emergence of collaborative solidarity from the increasingly fluid ‘friending’ relations of recent decades. Finally, we examine the question of whether these new solidarities can be mobilized into effective collective action, and suggest mechanisms, rather different from tra- ditional union mobilizations, that have shown some power in drawing on friending relations: the development of member platforms, the use of purposive campaigns and the co-ordination of ‘swarming’ actions. In the best cases, these can create collective actions that make a virtue of diversity, openness and participative engagement, by co-ordinating groups with different foci and skills. 1. Introduction In the last 30 years, there is every evidence that labour solidarity has weak- ened across the industrialized world. Strikes have widely declined, while the most effective recent movements have been fundamentalist and restrictive — turning back to traditional values and texts, narrowing the range of inclusion.
    [Show full text]
  • The Neighborhood As a Social Structure for Collective Action
    THE NEIGHBORHOOD AS A SOCIAL STRUCTURE FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION: THE ROLE OF BONDING SOCIAL CAPITAL, CIVIC ENGAGEMENT, AND NEIGHBORHOOD RACIAL HOMOGENEITY By Charles Collins A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Psychology – Doctor of Philosophy 2013 ABSTRACT THE NEIGHBORHOOD AS A SOCIAL STRUCTURE FOR COLLECTIVE ACTION: THE ROLE OF BONDING SOCIAL CAPITAL, CIVIC ENGAGEMENT, AND NEIGHBORHOOD RACIAL HOMOGENEITY By Charles Collins Collective action is a process by which individuals linked by a common goal engage in cooperative activities in order to affect socio-political change. Collective action takes a variety of forms including protests, sit-ins, and marches, and can address a wide swath of social justice issues. However, research on the mechanisms by which collective action takes place is still developing. Utilizing a national sample of urban neighborhood residents within seven cities, this dissertation is comprised of two related studies investigating the role that civic engagement, bonding social capital, and neighborhood homogeneity play in influencing collective action. Using path analysis, Study 1 investigates the mediating role of bonding social capital in the relationship between civic engagement and collective action. Study 2 utilized multilevel modeling (MLM) and includes a neighborhood level indicator – neighborhood racial homogeneity – to understand the relationship between individual level bonding social capital and collective action. Overall, the results reveal a complex relationship between civic engagement, bonding social capital, and neighborhood homogeneity on the outcome variable of collective action. Study 1 found that collective action was directly related to both bonding social capital and civic engagement, but that bonding social capital partially mediated the relationship between civic engagement and collective action.
    [Show full text]
  • Collective Political Action a Research Program and Some of Its Results*
    Analyse & Kritik 23/2001 (©Lucius & Lucius, Stuttgart) S. 1-20 Karl-Dieter Opp Collective Political Action A Research Program and Some of Its Results* Abstract: This paper describes a research program that focuses on the explanation of political protest and its causes. The starting point is Mancur Olson's theory of collective action. This theory is modified, extended and applied to explain political protest. In particular, it is argued that only a wide version of Rational Choice theory that includes 'soft' incentives as well as misperception is capable of providing valid ex­ planations of protest behavior. Another part of the research program is the utilization of survey research to test the predictions about protest behavior that are generated from the wide version of Rational Choice theory. The research program further aims at (a) comparing empirically Rational Choice and alternative propositions, (b) providing micro-macro explanatory models, (c) dynamic theoretical models, and (d) explaining preferences and beliefs which are usually treated as exogenous variables. The paper further reports, some results of the research program. 1. Introduction Mancur Olson's theory of collective action advanced in his book The Logic of Collective Action (1965) is among the few testable theories with high explana­ tory power in the social sciences that has generated a vast number of empirical as well as theoretical research over decades. Although the theory is still debated the following general assessment will be shared by many social scientists: " ... since the publication of Man cur Olson's book there has been a whole series of advances in our understanding of collective action, a cumulative progress rare in the social • I gratefully acknowledge support 'Of the research reported in this paper by the two major German institutions devoted to advancement of scientific research.
    [Show full text]
  • 7 the Theory of Action Reclaimed
    7 The Theory of Action Reclaimed Quid leges sine moribus vanae proficient? [Of what use are laws without morals?] Horace C: If you could converse with Talcott Parsons today, what would you say? HG: I would explain succinctly his only serious mis- take and suggest a way to correct this mistake. C: Would he agree? HG: In my dreams. Choreographer interview The analytical core for sociological theory proposed in the previous chap- ter includes a rational actor model inspired by Talcott Parsons’ voluntaristic theory of action (1937). My elaboration of this model, however, followed a differentpath from that taken by Parsons in his later work, which wandered away from the microfoundations of human behavior into the dusty realm of structural-functionalism. Big mistake. This chapter explains where and speculates why Parsons went wrong. Briefly, between writing The Structure of Social Action in 1937 and the publication of The Social System and Toward a General Theory of Action in 1951, Parsons abandoned the stress on individual efficacy of his early work (e.g., in his critique of positivism and behaviorism) in favor of treating the individual as the effect of socialization that when successful produces social order, and when unsuccessful produces social pathology. In The Structure of Social Action, Parsons mentions the term “socialization” only once, writing (pp. 400–401): Ultimate values of the individualmembers of the same commu- nity must be, to a significant degree, integrated into a system common to these members...not only moral attitudes but even the logical thought on which morality depends only develop as an aspect of the process of socialization of the child.
    [Show full text]
  • GROUP SIZE and COLLECTIVE ACTION by Arun Agrawal Dept. Of
    GROUP SIZE AND COLLECTIVE ACTION by Arun Agrawal Dept. of Political Science, Yale University 124 Prospect Street, New Haven CT 06520 Email: [email protected] and Sanjeev Goyal Econometric Institute, Erasmus University 3000 DR Rotterdam, Netherlands Email: [email protected] © 1997 by authors Paper to be presented at the conference on "Local Institutions for Forest Management: How Can Research Make a Difference," Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR), Bogo, Indonesia, November 19-21, 1997. ABSTRACT This paper examines the Olsonian thesis that group size is inversely related to successful collective action. We start with an empirical analysis based on primary data. This data gives information on a set of 21 villages in the Indian Himalayas that collectively monitor to protect and conserve community forests. This empirical analysis reveals that small and large villages fare relatively poorly, while medium size villages are much more successful, in the provision of monitoring. This finding goes against the general consensus that group size is inversely related to the likelihood of successful collective action. We identify two features of the collective good that appear critical. Both features are standard in the literature on public goods. The first feature is that the monitoring technology displays lumpiness, and must be above a certain minimum size to be worthwhile. The second feature is that the collective good is only imperfectly excludible and that this excludibility is decreasing in the size of the group. We formulate a theoretical model which incorporates these two features and develop a set of sufficient conditions on the monitoring technology under which the sustainable levels of collective good match the empirically observed patterns.
    [Show full text]
  • Collective Action and the Mobilization of Institutions
    Collective Action and the Mobilization of Institutions David Lowery University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Virginia Gray University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Jennifer Anderson University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill Adam J. Newmark Wake Forest University Bias in the composition of interest communities is often explained by reference to variations in the collective action constraint facing voluntary and nonvoluntary organizations. But with the excep- tion of literature on PAC formation, studies of direct institutional mobilization are rare. More often than not, their mobilization advantages vis-à-vis problems of collective action are simply assumed. This paper fills this gap by testing the collective action hypothesis on direct institutional mobiliza- tion. We argue that the PAC studies are flawed as tests of this hypothesis; they study the wrong mode of political activity and use selective samples and limited research designs. We develop a new test using state data on seven types of institutions to solve these problems. We also compare the collec- tive action problem facing institutions to the related problems facing voluntary organizations. We find strong evidence of collective action problems in institutional mobilization, problems that make inter- est populations of nonvoluntary and voluntary organizations appear far more similar than commonly thought. The literature on organized interests has long noted that interest systems are often biased in their composition. Using a common measure of bias of the inter- est system by examining the distribution of participants minimally active in various stages of the policy process, a number of scholars have noted that the dis- tribution of interests before government reflects only poorly the distribution of interests in society (Baumgartner and Leech 2001; Berry 1999, 20; Caldeira and Wright 1990; Golden 1998; Salisbury 1984; Schattschneider 1960; Schlozman 1984; Schlozman and Tierney 1986; Walker 1991, 59).
    [Show full text]
  • Social Networks and the Economics of Information in Collective Action and Conflict Andrew Gianou IAE (CSIC) Motivation
    Social networks and the economics of information in collective action and conflict Andrew Gianou IAE (CSIC) Motivation • Underlying motivation: why individuals and groups want to engage in conflict and what are structural features that make it more likely to occur • Popular motivation: Arab Spring protests • “…the U.S. needs to take serious note when networks of family and friends align — increasingly through digital media —on a set of grievances that political elites simply cannot or will not address.” ‐ Philip N. Howard in Digital Media and the Arab Spring from Reuters (Feb. 16 2011) Social and Economic Networks • Informal: a group of individuals/agents and a social structure that represents interdependencies between them • Graph theory forms the analytical framework for networks • Formal: a collection of N nodes and a listing of all pairs of nodes that are thought to be connected • can be represented by an NxN matrix whose elements are 0 in ijth entry if nodes iand jare not connected and 1 if iand jare connected • connection between agents can have many interpretations: suggest communication, kinship, sharing of knowledge, geographic proximity • Other issues: Static random graphs, measures of connectedness, endogenous network formation Motivating Literature • No one coherent thread in below literature: comprise a few avenues of potential research as it relates to network analysis and information economics generally • The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups by Mancur Olson • The inevitability of future revolutionary
    [Show full text]
  • Masses, Crowds, Communities, Movements: Collective Action in the Internet Age
    Social Movement Studies Journal of Social, Cultural and Political Protest ISSN: 1474-2837 (Print) 1474-2829 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/csms20 Masses, Crowds, Communities, Movements: Collective Action in the Internet Age Ulrich Dolata & Jan-Felix Schrape To cite this article: Ulrich Dolata & Jan-Felix Schrape (2016) Masses, Crowds, Communities, Movements: Collective Action in the Internet Age, Social Movement Studies, 15:1, 1-18, DOI: 10.1080/14742837.2015.1055722 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14742837.2015.1055722 Published online: 09 Jul 2015. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 999 View related articles View Crossmark data Citing articles: 2 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=csms20 Download by: [University of Liverpool] Date: 12 October 2016, At: 07:37 Social Movement Studies, 2016 Vol. 15, No. 1, 1–18, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14742837.2015.1055722 Masses, Crowds, Communities, Movements: Collective Action in the Internet Age ULRICH DOLATA & JAN-FELIX SCHRAPE Department for Organizational Sociology and Innovation Studies, Institute for Social Sciences, University of Stuttgart, Seidenstr. 36, D-70174 Stuttgart, Germany ABSTRACT This article investigates two questions: One, how might the very differently structured social collectives on the Internet – masses, crowds, communities and movements – be classified and distinguished? And two, what influence do the technological infrastructures in which they operate have on their formation, structure, and activities? For this, we differentiate between two main types of social collectives: non-organized collectives, which exhibit loosely coupled collective behavior, and collective actors with a separate identity and strategic capability.
    [Show full text]
  • Protest Or Riot?: Interpreting Collective Action in Contemporary France John P
    French Faculty Publications French Fall 2011 Protest or Riot?: Interpreting Collective Action in Contemporary France John P. Murphy Gettysburg College Follow this and additional works at: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/frenchfac Part of the International and Area Studies Commons, and the Social and Cultural Anthropology Commons Share feedback about the accessibility of this item. Murphy, J. P. (2011). Protest or Riot?: Interpreting Collective Action in Contemporary France. Anthropological Quarterly, 84:4, 977. This is the publisher's version of the work. This publication appears in Gettysburg College's institutional repository by permission of the copyright owner for personal use, not for redistribution. Cupola permanent link: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/frenchfac/1 This open access article is brought to you by The uC pola: Scholarship at Gettysburg College. It has been accepted for inclusion by an authorized administrator of The uC pola. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Protest or Riot?: Interpreting Collective Action in Contemporary France Abstract Although both events were fundamentally acts of contestation led by different segments of France’s youth, the fall 2005 riots and the spring 2006 CPE protests received very different treatment in French public opinion. Whereas the riots were overwhelmingly condemned, the protests were not only tolerated but also often celebrated. By examining dominant interpretations of these events circulated in the news media alongside those of young people collected during a year of fieldwork in the public housing projects of a medium-sized French city, this paper shines light on fundamental French values and beliefs about how society ought to work while also contributing to ongoing debates about the cultural identity of such youth.
    [Show full text]
  • Theoretical Foundations of Social Norms
    THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS OF SOCIAL NORMS: The Co-Evolution of Social Norms, Intrinsic Motivation, Markets, and the Institutions of Complex Societies Jean Ensminger HSS 228-77 California Institute of Technology Pasadena, CA 91125 [email protected] Joseph Henrich Departments of Economics and Psychology University of British Columbia Vancouver, B.C. VT6 1Z4 Canada [email protected] Draft Date: April, 2008 Early Draft: Please do not quote, cite, or circulate Chapter 2 (from): Experimenting with Social Norms: Fairness and Punishment in Cross-Cultural Perspective Jean Ensminger and Joseph Henrich, Editors 2 Chapter 2 THEORETICAL FOUNDATIONS OF SOCIAL NORMS The Co-evolution of Social Norms, Intrinsic Motivation, Markets, and the Institutions of Complex Societies Jean Ensminger and Joseph Henrich Though it seems surprising on its face, classical scholars long ago proposed a positive relationship between developed market economies and pro-social or fair-minded motivations.1 One of the first and best known scholars to write in this vein was none other than Adam Smith (1997 [1759]), whose position is quite consistent with the findings of our cross-cultural sample (Chapter 4). Even before Smith, Montesquieu (1900:316-317 [1749]) was explicit on this subject: Commerce has everywhere diffused a knowledge of the manners of all nations: these are compared one with another, and from this comparison arise the greatest advantages. Commerce is a cure for the destructive prejudices, for it is almost a general rule, that wherever we find agreeable manners, there commerce flourishes; and that wherever there is commerce, there we meet with agreeable manners. Let us not be astonished, then if our manners are now less savage than formerly.
    [Show full text]
  • Collective Action & Contentious Politics Outline
    COLLECTIVE ACTION & CONTENTIOUS POLITICS OUTLINE Tommaso Pavone ([email protected]) Spring 2015 CROWD THEORY • Crowds are transformative, suppressing individual rationality and engendering a collective “mental unity” forged by linking every participants unconscious mind • Crowd behavior diffuses via a sort of collective hypnosis, and crowd members are capable of acts of both barbarism and heroism Gustave LeBon, The Crowd: A Study of the Popular Mind (1895) 1. The mental unity of crowds a. Crowds vs. groups: a crowd is distinguished from an agglomeration of individuals by virtue of its transformative character and its accordance with the “law of the mental unity of crowds:” “Whoever be the individuals that compose it, however like or unlike be their mode of life...the fact that they have been transformed into a crowd puts them in possession of a sort of collective mind which makes them feel, think, and act in a manner quite different from that in which each individual of them would… in a state of isolation” b. The irrationality and hypnosis crowds: Individuals within crowds cease to behave rationally (as they do in isolation, where they exhibit diverse natural intellectual endowments), and fall under a state of collective hypnosis: their common, primitive unconscious urges take over, perhaps because of the “magnetic influence of the crowd,” as the unconscious mind becomes “collective property,” and every “sentiment and act is contagious,” or under the control of the hypnotizer (perhaps a group leader) c. The barbarism or heroism of crowds: As the primitive unconscious homogenizes what would otherwise be a diverse collection of individuals, individuals begin to garner a sense of “invincibility” out of the sheer size of the crowd and yield to “instincts which they would have to restrain” if they were acting alone.
    [Show full text]