CLAVEY-DISSERTATION-2019.Pdf

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

CLAVEY-DISSERTATION-2019.Pdf Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950 The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Clavey, Charles H. 2019. Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, Graduate School of Arts & Sciences. Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:42029484 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950 A dissertation presented by Charles H. Clavey to The Department of History in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of History Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2019 © 2019 Charles H. Clavey All Rights Reserved. Dissertation Advisor: Professor Peter E. Gordon Charles H. Clavey EXPERIMENTS IN THEORY: THE TRANSATLANTIC DEVELOPMENT OF SOCIAL SCIENCE & CRITICAL THEORY, 1930-1950 ABSTRACT From its foundation in 1923, the Institute for Social Research conducted empirical studies of the social forms, cultural products, and psychological effects of advanced capitalism. Adapting methods from social- and human-scientific fields as diverse as experimental psychology and industrial sociology, Institute affiliates fashioned a research methodology they termed “experiments in theory.” In this dissertation, I recover the history of these experiments. To do so, I reconstruct the debates that led to the creation of the method and document its application in a variety of projects between 1930 and 1950. I argue that the Institute’s empirical social research formed a necessary corollary to its critical social theory. The Institute is well known for its deep critiques of empirical techniques and paradigms. In the postwar era, its most prominent members identified empirical research as a means of maintaining the “social totality” inimical to human freedom. I complicate this disciplinary memory and the historical narratives it subtends. Between the First and Second World Wars, Institute affiliates subjected existing methods of empirical research to incisive critique, arguing that these approaches simultaneously promoted ideas of “individuality” and effaced subjectivity. At the same time, Institute members forged methods and conducted studies they believed capable of unmasking this ideology and its consequences. Concepts central to the Institute’s critical theory—from alienation to authoritarianism—emerged in and through these empirical projects. In the first chapters of the dissertation, I trace the origins of the Institute’s method to pioneering social-psychological studies conducted by a cohort of Austrian-Marxist researchers. iii Through the studies they conducted as Institute consultants, these researchers played an outsized role in shaping the organization’s nascent program of empirical social research. In the middle chapters of the dissertation, I focus on the Institute’s exile in the United States and explore its members’ critical dialogue with American and émigré researchers. I argue that the Institute conceived its experiments-in-theory method through the assertion of a conceptual disjunction between the “European” and “American” approaches to social research. Further, I demonstrate that the Institute refined this method through empirical studies of class consciousness and prejudice in an American context. In the final chapter, I reconstruct the Institute’s study of authoritarianism and argue that this project both brought to its conclusion the development of the experiments-in-theory method and returned the Institute to the problem of “individuality.” Confronted with the realization that empirical research must assume the existence of individuals in order to critique the ideology of individuality, Institute researchers developed the dialectical argument that empirical studies must assume their own impossibility. Across the dissertation, I call attention to the institutional and political forces that motivated the Institute’s development of its program of empirical research. By tracing the movement of social scientists around Europe and across the Atlantic, I suggest several new contexts in which to understand the Institute’s origins and development. I further reconsider the Institute’s relationship with the social- and human-scientific disciplines its members encountered in the United States: behavioral psychology, cultural anthropology, market research, and public- opinion polling. One result of this reframing is that I call attention to the voices of social scientists whose contributions to the Institute and its critical theory have long been neglected. More broadly, I aim to return attention to the Institute’s experiments in theory. Recovering these studies will enrich both historical understandings and contemporary practices of critical theory. iv CONTENTS Abstract / iii Contents / v Figures and Tables / vii Acknowledgments / viii Introduction Between Empirical Social Science and Critical Social Theory / 1 Experiments in Theory / 1 Histories of Critical Theory and Social Science / 9 Argument and Structure / 28 Chapter 1 Resiliency or Resignation: the Psychology of Unemployment, 1919-1933 / 42 The Prison without Bars / 42 Making the “New People” / 46 Socialist and Social Scientist / 55 Psychological Breakdown / 66 Capitalist Crises and Socialist Dilemmas / 78 Conclusion: A Style of Thinking / 85 Chapter 2 From Authority to Authoritarianism: Studying the Family, 1934-1936 / 90 A Publication Worse than Unscientific / 90 Authority between Culture and Family / 94 Authoritarian Mind and Authoritarian Society / 108 The Origins of Concepts / 127 The Proliferation of Types / 141 Conclusion / 151 Chapter 3 How to Ask “Why?”: Empirical Research Across the Atlantic, 1934-1941 / 155 This Role of Specialist / 155 Lazarsfeld’s Critique of American Research / 160 The Task of Substruction / 174 Concrete Evidence and Discerning Interpretations / 194 Conclusion / 213 v Chapter 4 Experimenting with Theory: the Princeton Radio Research Project, 1938-1941 / 219 Extraordinary Possibilities and a Large Potential Audience / 219 An Opportunity for Relatively Free Experimentation / 224 Hunting for the European Approach / 236 Adorno’s Most Dangerous Thesis / 246 Individual as Mere Ideology / 267 Studying the New Type of Human Being / 281 Conclusion / 292 Chapter 5 A Highly Promising Method: Critical Theory and Empirical Research, 1941-1945 / 294 Methods European and American / 294 The Peril of Anti-Semitism & the Promise of Social Research / 298 The Stereotype Takes Care of Everything / 305 Outflanking the Research Racket / 323 Almost-Monadological Psychology / 331 Conclusion / 336 Chapter 6 European Concepts and American Methods: Studies of Authoritarianism, 1943-1950 / 342 Guided by a Theoretical Orientation / 342 Insights and Hunches / 346 Uncovering the Fascist Personality / 366 Psychology Presupposing its Own End / 395 Conclusion / 409 Conclusion Experiments in Theory / 413 Arguments and Interventions / 413 Contributions and Limitations / 419 Striking Affinities and Unlikely Connections / 427 Into the Cold War / 435 Works Cited / 442 Archival Sources & Oral Histories / 442 Newspapers, Periodicals, & Journals / 443 Published Primary Sources / 444 Secondary Literature / 459 vi FIGURES AND TABLES Figure 2.1: Sale- and Consumption-Barometer / 130 Figure 2.2: Process of the Economic Satisfaction of Needs / 132 Figure 2.3: The “Orgnanon” Theory of Language /138 Figure 3.1: Procedure of Market Research / 169 Figure 3.2: Structure of Action / 170 Figure 3.3: Typology of a Marriage / 179 Figure 3.4: Conceptual Possibilities for the Exercise of Authority / 184 Figure 3.5: Conceptual Possibilities of the Acceptance of Authority / 184 Figure 3.6: Multidimensional Attribute Space of Authority / 184 Figure 3.7: Concepts of Authority Reduced from Typologies / 184 Figure 3.8: Outline of the Process of Interpretation / 187 Figure 4.1: Models of Communication Before and After the Radio / 232 Figure 4.2: Sample Data Produced by the Lazarsfeld-Stanton Program Analyzer / 252 Figure 6.1: TAT Image 12 F / 356 Figure 6.2: Reorganization of the Institute's Research into Anti-Semitism / 369 Figure 6.3: Ongoing Research Projects of the SRD, 1945 / 370 Figure 7.1: Participation according to Statistical Groups and the Seven Main Themes / 440 Table 6.1: Variables, Items, and Areas Tested by the F-Scale Questionnaire / 382 Table 6.2: Typology of “Stereopaths” / 392 vii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Over the past three years, I have been fortunate to receive generous institutional funding, expert guidance from mentors, insightful critiques from peers, and unceasing encouragement from friends and family. Without this support, I could not have developed, researched, or written this dissertation. It is my pleasure to acknowledge and thank these institutions and individuals. First and foremost, my deepest thanks go to Peter E. Gordon. As an advisor, Peter was an expert guide through circuitous paths of graduate education. As a historian, Peter taught me how to be attentive to textual detail and sensitive to historical context while remaining open to philosophical questions.
Recommended publications
  • 7: MARX's THEORY of ETHICS Svetozar Stojanovic
    7: MARX'S THEORY OF ETHICS Svetozar Stojanovic I In the history of Marxism and Marxology two kinds of interpretation of Marx can be easily distinguished. One might be called nonethical and the other ethical. I shall argue in the spirit of the latter, namely that Marx's writings have considerable ethical content that could be used as a starting point to work out a Marxist normative ethics. How­ ever at present there exists no such ethics, at least none satisfactory and worthy of Marx's name. Why? Several reasons are usually cited and from them I can accept a poli­ tical one, namely Stalinism which prevented work on the develop­ ment of the true Marxist ethics. However the root, in my opinion, goes much deeper and can be found within Marx's own writings. I shall try to show that unless some theoretical obstacles contained in these writings are removed, the efforts to create a Marxist evaluative ethics will not succeed. II In attempting to develop this thesis it is necessary to consider two questions: what has served as a basis for a completely nonethical interpretation of Marx and what are the reasons usually given by those who claim that Marx's writings have no ethical content, indeed that they could not have such content? First of all it is a fact that Marx himself wrote that he had tran­ scended the domain of philosophy and entered the field of a “ real, positive science." Consequently he thought that he was the founder of scientific socialism in contrast to a utopian one.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Jerry Shang 5/9/2018 History 310 Austro-Marxism: Finding
    1 Jerry Shang 5/9/2018 History 310 Austro-Marxism: Finding Socialism in Modernity Introduction In Otto Bauer’s What is Austro-Marxism? (1927), he stated that Austro-Marxism was first coined by an American socialist, L. Boudin, to describe a collection of Marxist thinkers including Max Adler, Karl Renner, Rudolf Hilferding, Otto Bauer and others who grew up in the socialist student movement of fin-de-siècle Vienna. Despite these thinkers’ common background, Austro- Marxism as a school of thought lacked the unity L. Boudin conferred to it through its name. Even Otto Bauer himself noted that this group of scholars “were united not so much by a specific political orientation.”1 These thinkers cited above all had interests in different areas, for example, Max Adler took on a theoretical approach and tried to apply a neo-Kantian emphasis on subjectivity and human volitions to the Marxist concept of historical progression; Karl Renner focused more on the law and its ability to support the capitalist system; Rudolf Hilferding was known for his discussion on finance capital and his extension upon Marxist economic theories; Otto Bauer focused on the question of nationality and its incorporation into Marxist thoughts. Though this was not to say that there were no communications and references between these thinkers, the various focuses and interests made it hard to characterize Austro-Marxism as a unified movement. In a sense, Otto Bauer’s question posed by his title remained unanswered. Current historiography on Austro-Marxism has also shied away from this question by focusing on individual thinkers.
    [Show full text]
  • From Grossman Translations Template
    go to editpoint editpoint go to editpoint editpoint Introduction to Henryk Grossman ‘The value-price transformation in Marx and the problem of crisis’ Rick Kuhn The transformation of values into prices of production, in volume 3 of Capital, was a vital step in Marx‘s exposure of the anatomy of capitalism and the laws of capital accumulation. In ‗The value- price transformation in Marx and the problem of crisis‘, Henryk Grossman dealt with the fundamental context and significance of the transformation and its implications for theories of economic crisis. While the issue at stake has been the coherence of Marx‘s entire analysis of capitalism, almost all of the controversy over the transformation has been preoccupied with the narrower questio of the theoretical adequacy of his mathematics. This was the case both before Grossman‘s essay, as he pointed out, and over the subsequent eighty years.1 The starting point in Grossman‘s discussion was the method that underpinned the structure of Capital and the procedure of successive approximation [Annäherungsverfahren]. After dealing with capitalism‘s most basic features at a very abstract level, achieved by means of a series of simplifying assumptions, Marx progressively lifted them to explain further aspects of concrete reality. Grossman had dealt with this procedure in a series of earlier works, paying particular attention to its implications for Marx‘s account of how crises, arising from the growing organic composition of capital were intrinsic to capitalism production, and the division of surplus value into its phenomenal forms.2 In this essay, he focussed on the place of the reproduction schemas in 1 Kliman 2007 provides a valuable account of the debate and a persuasive response to the ‗transformation problem‘.
    [Show full text]
  • Dialectic of Solidarity Studies in Critical Social Sciences
    Dialectic of Solidarity Studies in Critical Social Sciences Series Editor DAVID FASENFEST Wayne State University Editorial Board JOAN ACKER, Department of Sociology, University of Oregon ROSE BREWER, Afro-American and African Studies, University of Minnesota VAL BURRIS, Department of Sociology, University of Oregon CHRIS CHASE-DUNN, Department of Sociology, University of California-Riverside G. WILLIAM DOMHOFF, Department of Sociology, University of California-Santa Cruz COLETTE FAGAN, Department of Sociology, Manchester University MATHA GIMENEZ, Department of Sociology, University of Colorado, Boulder HEIDI GOTTFRIED, Department of Sociology, Wayne State University KARIN GOTTSCHALL, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, University of Bremen BOB JESSOP, Department of Sociology, Lancaster University RHONDA LEVINE, Department of Sociology, Colgate University JACQUELINE O’REILLY, Department of Sociology, University of Sussex MARY ROMERO, School of Justice Studies, Arizona State University CHIZUKO URNO, Department of Sociology, University of Tokyo VOLUME 11 Dialectic of Solidarity Labor, Antisemitism, and the Frankfurt School By Mark P. Worrell LEIDEN • BOSTON 2008 Cover design: Wim Goedhart This book is printed on acid-free paper. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Worrell, Mark. Dialectic of solidarity : labor, antisemitism, and the Frankfurt School / by Mark Worrell. p. cm. — (Studies in critical social sciences) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-90-04-16886-2 (hbk. : alk. paper) 1. Working class—United States— Attitudes. 2. Antisemitism—United States. 3. Frankfurt school of sociology. I. Title. II. Series. HD8072.W83 2008 301.01—dc22 2008011351 ISSN: 1573-4234 ISBN: 978 90 04 16886 2 Copyright 2008 by Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden, The Netherlands. Koninklijke Brill NV incorporates the imprints Brill, Hotei Publishing, IDC Publishers, Martinus Nijhoff Publishers and VSP.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring a Database of “Notable People”
    Discussion paper 2016-03 A BRIEF HISTORY OF HUMAN TIME: Exploring a database of “notable people” Olivier Gergaud Morgane Louenan Etienne Wasmer Sciences Po Economics Discussion Papers ABriefHistoryofHuman Time Exploring a database of “notable people” (3000BCE-2015AD) Version 1.0.1⇤ Olivier Gergaud,† Morgane Laouenan,‡ Etienne Wasmer§ February 8, 2016 Abstract This paper describes a database of 1,243,776 notable people and 7,184,575 locations (Geolinks) associated with them throughout human history (3000BCE-2015AD). We first describe in details the various approaches and procedures adopted to extract the relevant information from their Wikipedia biographies and then analyze the database. Ten main facts emerge. 1. There has been an exponential growth over time of the database, with more than 60% of notable people still living in 2015, with the exception of a relative decline of the cohort born in the XVIIth century and a local minimum between 1645 and 1655. 2. The average lifespan has increased by 20 years, from 60 to 80 years, between the cohort born in 1400AD and the one born in 1900AD. 3. The share of women in the database follows a U-shape pattern, with a minimum in the XVIIth century and a maximum at 25% for the most recent cohorts. 4. The fraction of notable people in governance occupations has decreased while the fraction in occupations such as arts, literature/media and sports has increased over the centuries; sports caught up to arts and literature for cohorts born in 1870 but remained at the same level until the 1950s cohorts; and eventually sports came to dominate the database after 1950.
    [Show full text]
  • No 18/2016 Olav Bjerkholt
    MEMORANDUM No 18/2016 Wassily Leontief and the discovery of the input-output approach Olav Bjerkholt ISSN: 0809 -8786 Department of Economics University of Oslo This series is published by the In co-operation with University of Oslo The Frisch Centre for Economic Department of Economics Research P. O.Box 1095 Blindern Gaustadalleén 21 N-0317 OSLO Norway N-0371 OSLO Norway Telephone: + 47 22855127 Telephone: +47 22 95 88 20 Fax: + 47 22855035 Fax: +47 22 95 88 25 Internet: http://www.sv.uio.no/econ Internet: http://www.frisch.uio.no e-mail: [email protected] e-mail: [email protected] Last 10 Memoranda Øystein Kravdal No 17/16 New Evidence about effects of reproductive variables on child mortality in sub-Saharan Africa Moti Michaeli and Daniel Spiro No 16/16 The dynamics of revolutions Geir B. Asheim, Mark Voorneveld and Jörgen W. Weibull No 15/16 Epistemically robust strategy subsets Torbjørn Hanson No 14/16 Estimating output mix effectiveness: A scenario approach Halvor Mehlum and Kalle Moene No 13/16 Unequal power and the dynamics of rivalry Halvor Mehlum No 12/16 Another model of sales. Price discrimination in a horizontally differentiated duopoly market Vladimir W. Krivonozhko, Finn R. Førsund and Andrey V. Lychev No 11/16 Smoothing the frontier in the DEA models Finn R. Førsund No 10/16 Pollution Modelling and Multiple-Output Production Theory* Frikk Nesje and Geir B. Asheim No 09/16 Intergenerational altruism: A solution to the climate problem?* Michael Hoel No 08/16 Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Previous issues of the memo-series are available in a PDF® format at: http://www.sv.uio.no/econ/english/research/unpublished-works/working-papers/ Rev-2, Dec.
    [Show full text]
  • Save Pdf (0.06
    IRSH (), pp. – © Internationaal Instituut voor Sociale Geschiedenis BOOK REVIEWS Austro-Marxism: The Ideology of Unity. Vol. Austro-Marxist Theory and Strategy. Ed. by Mark E. Blum and William Smaldone. [Historical Materialism, .] Brill, Leiden . xix, pp. € .;$.. (E-book: € .;$.). Austro-Marxism: The Ideology of Unity. Vol. Changing the World: The Politics of Austro-Marxism. Ed. by Mark E. Blum and William Smaldone. [Historical Materialism, .] Brill, Leiden . xi, pp. € .; $.. (E-book: € .;$.). In the history of Marxism, even during its classical age, there were rarely periods when genu- ine research and intellectual discovery flourished. The rather short summer of Austro- Marxism must be regarded as the most important exception to this rule. Not much of the extremely rich and variegated Austro-Marxist literature has been available in English until now, although a few major works, including Otto Bauer’s seminal book Die Nationalitätenfrage und die Sozialdemokratie, Rudolf Hilferding’s great study Das Finanzkapital, and Karl Renner’s pioneering study Rechtsinstitute des Privatrechts und ihre soziale Funktion, have been translated, albeit belatedly. Otto Bauer’s crucial work on the Austrian Revolution (Die österreichische Revolution, first published in ), was translated in an abridged version in the s. A new translation of this key contribution to Marxist political theory is in the making; the first English translation of Bauer’s last major book Zwischen zwei Weltkriegen? Die Krise der Weltwirtschaft, der Demokratie und des Sozialismus will be published shortly. Regarding the enormous literature that the leading Austro-Marxist theoreticians pro- duced in a relatively short span of time and their many contributions to Marxist sociology, historiography, political science, political economy, and philosophy, it is quite remarkable that there has been only one major collection in English until now, the volume Austro-Marxism, translated and edited by Tom Bottomore and Patrick Goode in .
    [Show full text]
  • The University of Chicago Experimental Futures And
    THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO EXPERIMENTAL FUTURES AND IMPOSSIBLE PROFESSIONS: PSYCHOANALYSIS, EDUCATION, AND POLITICS IN INTERWAR VIENNA, 1918-1938 A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO THE FACULTY OF THE DIVISION OF THE SOCIAL SCIENCES IN CANDIDACY FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY DEPARTMENT OF HISTORY BY PHILLIP J. HENRY CHICAGO, ILLINOIS AUGUST 2018 TABLE OF CONTENTS DISSERTATION ABSTRACT v ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS x INTRODUCTION 1 Red Vienna 6 Interwar Psychoanalysis 20 Psychoanalysis, Education, and Politics in Interwar Vienna 35 CHAPTER ONE Between Seduction and Sublimation: The Emergence of a Psychoanalytic Theory of Education, 1896-1914 44 Unstable Foundations 45 Verführung and its Vicissitudes 50 Erziehung zur Realität 65 The Possibilities for Prophylaxis and the Elusiveness of Sublimation 78 Psychoanalysis and the New Education 91 CHAPTER TWO Recasting Bourgeois Psychoanalysis: Education, Authority, and the Politics of Analytic Therapy in the Freudian Revision of 1918 99 Out of the Wilderness, Into the Wasteland 104 Suggestion and its Discontents 110 Forming a Class Body for Psychoanalysis 119 The Ways and Means of Psychoanalysis 123 Beyond the Classical Paradigm 135 ii CHAPTER THREE Fashioning a New Psychoanalysis: Exceptional States and the Crisis of Authority in Analytic Practice, 1919-1925 139 States of Exception 146 Analysis for the Masses 157 Ego Politics and the Pedagogy of Reconstruction 167 Psychoanalytisches Neuland 177 The Limits of Analytic Therapy 184 CHAPTER FOUR The Mass Psychology of Education: Freudian Experiments in Collective
    [Show full text]
  • 15 THERE a Marhi5t 50[Iol06y?
    lU[IEn IiOlDmAnn 15 THERE A mARHI5T 50[IOl06Y? Translated and IntradlHed bV Ion mrthall When Lucien Goldmann' s essay , Is There a Marxist the socially relevant, like so many practitioners of the Sociology?' first appeared in Les Temps Modernes in 1957, 'sociology of literature'. it made an important contribution to the revival of a serious consideration of the Marxist method. The scientistic MoreoVer, since Goldmann's active political commitment deformation of Marxism, emanating from Moscow, was beginning was limited to taking stands on particular issues, he did not to wear thin, and had been proving an ideal Aunt Sally for a suffer from inhibitions of the later Lukacs, and was able to horde of hack scholars determined to 'refute' Marxism. At make useful analyses of such 'modernist' literary trends as the same time, in both Eastern and Western Europe, various the French nouveau roman. versions of 'ethical' and 'humanistic' Marxisms were being developed by those who wanted to break with the brutalities Goldmann's Philosophy and Human Sciences is still a of the Stalin era without having, to find a scientific valuable counter-manual for anyone exposed to bourgeois explanation of why they happened. Goldmann' s stress on the social science. Yet Go1dmann, for all his concern with concept of 'totality' as central to dialectical thinking cuts , totali ty', does not follow Lukacs in what was the fundamental through the false dichotomies of fact and value, science and proposi tion of History and Class Consciousness: "For when ethics, ends and means, etc. confronted by the overwhelming resources of knowledge, culture and routine which the bourgeoisie undoubtedly possesses and Goldmann, whose premature death at the age of fifty-seven will continue to possess as long as it remains the ruling in 1970 was a serious loss to Marxist scholarship, will be class, the only effective superiority of the proletariat, its remembered for two things.
    [Show full text]
  • Ontology and Politics As Foundations of Herbert Marcuse's Dialectical
    ARTÍCULOS DE INVESTIGACIÓN Towards a theory of action: ontology and politics as foundations of Herbert Marcuse’s dialectical phenomenology* Juliano Bonamigo Ferreira de Souza Université catholique de Louvain, Lovaina, Bélgica E-mail: [email protected] Recibido: 5 de noviembre de 2019 | Aprobado: 3 de marzo de 2020 https://doi.org/10.17533/udea.ef.n62a06 Abstract: This article seeks to analyze the modes of composition of the so-called dialectical phenomenology, proposed by Herbert Marcuse in 1928. It is one of his first writings, in which the author seeks to think of a theory of action whose starting point are the historical analyses derived from the historical materialism of Marx and Engels, orchestrated with the existential analytic provided by Being and time, by Heidegger. In order to interpret this pioneering philosophical architecture, (1) we will first show how Marcusean method establishes the understanding of a historical situation. (2) In the second section, we analyze how Marcuse interprets, in a very original way, the ontologi- cal aspects of Dasein. (3) In the last part, it is about showing how Marcuse operates a junction of both analyses in order to argue the need for a transforming action on the unveiled social alienation. Together, these three movements seek to emphasize the social concern that has always occupied Herbert Marcuse’s philosophical reflections. Keywords: dialectics, Herbert Marcuse, historical materialism, ontology, politics * This article is part of a research developed with financial support from the Fonds de la Recherche Scientifique de Belgique (F.R.S.– FNRS) under the Research Project (PDR) “Gouverner par l’environnement : mésopolitique et bureaucratie au XXe siècle”.
    [Show full text]
  • H-Diplo ROUNDTABLE XXII-24
    H-Diplo ROUNDTABLE XXII-24 Alan Bollard. Economists at War: How a Handful of Economists Helped Win and Lose the World Wars. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2020. ISBN: 9780198846000 (hardcover, $25.00). 1 February 2021 | https://hdiplo.org/to/RT22-24 Editor: Diane Labrosse | Production Editor: George Fujii Contents Introduction by Paul Poast, University of Chicago ........................................................................................................................... 2 Review by Laura Hein, Northwestern University .............................................................................................................................. 5 Review by Annalisa Rosselli, University of Rome Tor Vergata, Italy ............................................................................................ 8 Response by Alan Bollard, Victoria University of Wellington .....................................................................................................11 H-Diplo Roundtable XXII-24 Introduction by Paul Poast, University of Chicago ive me a one-handed economist. All my economists say, “on the one hand… on the other hand”.’ That phrase, reputedly uttered by President Harry Truman, captures the core of economics as a discipline and practice. Call it ‘G cost-benefit analysis, decision making in recognition of tradeoffs, or an ability to think ‘on the margin.’ While such practices are of value during times of peace, their importance heightens during the exigencies of war. War exacerbates the scarcity which marks everyday
    [Show full text]
  • Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall
    Tendency of the rate of profit to fall en.wikipedia.org /wiki/Tendency_of_the_rate_of_profit_to_fall The tendency of the rate of profit to fall (TRPF) is a hypothesis in economics and political economy, most famously expounded by Karl Marx in chapter 13 of Capital, Volume III.[1] Although not accepted in 20th century mainstream economics, the existence of such a tendency was widely noted throughout the 19th century.[2] Economists as diverse as Adam Smith,[3] John Stuart Mill,[4] David Ricardo[5] and Stanley Jevons[6] referred explicitly to the TRPF as an empirical phenomenon that needed to be explained. They differed in the reasons they gave for why the TRPF might necessarily occur.[7] In his 1857 Grundrisse manuscript, Karl Marx called the tendency of the rate of profit to fall "the most important law of political economy" and sought to give a causal explanation for it, in terms of his theory of capital accumulation.[8] The tendency is already foreshadowed in chapter 25 of Capital, Volume I (on the "general law of capital accumulation"), but in Part 3 of the draft manuscript of Marx's Capital, Volume III, edited posthumously for publication by Friedrich Engels, an extensive analysis is provided of the tendency. [9] Marx regarded the TRPF as proof that capitalist production could not be an everlasting form of production, since, in the end, the profit principle itself would suffer a breakdown.[10] However, because Marx never published any finished manuscript on the TRPF himself, because the tendency is hard to prove or disprove theoretically, and because it is hard to test and measure the rate of profit, Marx's TRPF theory has been a topic of controversy for more than a century.
    [Show full text]