No 18/2016 Olav Bjerkholt

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

No 18/2016 Olav Bjerkholt MEMORANDUM No 18/2016 Wassily Leontief and the discovery of the input-output approach Olav Bjerkholt ISSN: 0809 -8786 Department of Economics University of Oslo This series is published by the In co-operation with University of Oslo The Frisch Centre for Economic Department of Economics Research P. O.Box 1095 Blindern Gaustadalleén 21 N-0317 OSLO Norway N-0371 OSLO Norway Telephone: + 47 22855127 Telephone: +47 22 95 88 20 Fax: + 47 22855035 Fax: +47 22 95 88 25 Internet: http://www.sv.uio.no/econ Internet: http://www.frisch.uio.no e-mail: [email protected] e-mail: [email protected] Last 10 Memoranda Øystein Kravdal No 17/16 New Evidence about effects of reproductive variables on child mortality in sub-Saharan Africa Moti Michaeli and Daniel Spiro No 16/16 The dynamics of revolutions Geir B. Asheim, Mark Voorneveld and Jörgen W. Weibull No 15/16 Epistemically robust strategy subsets Torbjørn Hanson No 14/16 Estimating output mix effectiveness: A scenario approach Halvor Mehlum and Kalle Moene No 13/16 Unequal power and the dynamics of rivalry Halvor Mehlum No 12/16 Another model of sales. Price discrimination in a horizontally differentiated duopoly market Vladimir W. Krivonozhko, Finn R. Førsund and Andrey V. Lychev No 11/16 Smoothing the frontier in the DEA models Finn R. Førsund No 10/16 Pollution Modelling and Multiple-Output Production Theory* Frikk Nesje and Geir B. Asheim No 09/16 Intergenerational altruism: A solution to the climate problem?* Michael Hoel No 08/16 Optimal control theory with applications to resource and environmental economics Previous issues of the memo-series are available in a PDF® format at: http://www.sv.uio.no/econ/english/research/unpublished-works/working-papers/ Rev-2, Dec. 19, 2016 Wassily Leontief and the discovery of the input-output approach By Olav Bjerkholt Abstract The paper is about Wassily Leontief’s path towards the discovery of input-output economics, as reflected in his 1936 and 1937 articles in the Review of Economic Statistics and in the 1941 monograph The Structure of American Economy, 1919-1929. The paper sets out an account of Leontief’s life from his childhood and early youth in St. Petersburg. Then followed study years in St. Petersburg and Berlin, work as research associate at the Institute of World Economics in Kiel, an adventurous trip to China, and a further year in Germany during which circumstances and luck brought him to the United States in 1931 and to Harvard shortly afterwards. The aim has more specifically been to consider and how Leontief’s discovery of an input-output approach was influenced by his earlier studies and research experience and by exchanges with Joseph Schumpeter, Ragnar Frisch, his Kieler colleagues and others. Keywords: Leontief, input-output JEL: D57, B31 1 Contents Introduction The St. Petersburg heritage Berlin 1925-1927 The Kiel years 1928-1931 NBER as stepping stone to the United States Enchanted at Harvard Concluding remarks Acknowledgement References Introduction “Whoever thinks of Wassily Leontief thinks of input-output, and vice versa” (Dorfman 1973, p.431). The statement sounds like a truism. Dorfman added, however, that Leontief cannot be summed up in a single accomplishment but a dominant theme running through Leontief’s professional work, providing an important clue for the discovery of input-output economics, was in Dorfman’s view that economics is an empirical and applied science. Fancy theoretical apparatus may sometimes seduce students into intriguing and sterile bypaths but the only valid test of economic research is its empirical and its practical significance. The paper is about Wassily Leontief’s path towards the discovery of input-output economics, which was marked by two articles in Review of Economic Statistics in 1936 and 1937, followed in 1941 by the monograph The Structure of American Economy, 1919-1929. The organization of the paper is largely biographical covering Leontief’s life from his childhood and early youth in St. Petersburg, followed by a relatively documentary account of his study years in St. Petersburg and Berlin and his work as research associate at the Institute of World Economics in Kiel. His adventurous trip to China in 1929 is mentioned while his last year and a half in Germany in 1930-31 is set out in some detail including his exchanges with Joseph Schumpeter, Mordecai Ezekiel and others who advised or 2 influenced him. It was circumstantial luck which brought him to the United States in 1931 and to Harvard shortly afterwards. An attempt is made in the paper to look for clues of how Leontief arrived at his discovery. The question could be put whether there on Leontief’s career path was an “input-output moment” at which the cumulated insight was brought to fruition and the input-output approach was discovered. It can be foreshadowed that such a eureka point could not be clearly identified. Perhaps this attempt was a too simplistic way of looking at the discovery process. Others have touched upon the question of when and where Leontief arrived at his input-output approach. The account of Ann Carter, a close associate of Leontief over many years from the late 1940s is the following: “When Wassily Leontief first came to the United States, he spent a year or so in New York working at the National Bureau for Economic Research. He was developing a new system, later to be called input- output analysis. One day he received an invitation to join the Harvard faculty. He replied with qualified interest: he would be pleased to come, but he required a grant of $1500 to cover the cost of a research assistant to help him with the implementation of his fundamental new study. They reviewed his project with considerable skepticism. What he proposed to do was probably impossible and certainly very strange. Still, they seemed to want him. The $1500 was granted on condition that he agreed ‘to report his failure in writing’ at the end of the year.” (Carter 1976, p.57). Another long-time Leontief associate, Karen Polenske, placed the “input-output moment” further back in time: “Leontief indicated that his development of the input-output model of an economy was influenced by Quesnay and Walras, not Marx, and that he conceived of the input-output structure in 1927 at the Institute for World Economics in Kiel” (Polenske 2004, p.11). Others have pointed to Leontief’s doctoral dissertation Die Wirtschaft als Kreislauf as the origin of his input-output approach. In the autobiographical note provided for his Nobel award in 1973 Leontief gave a brief account of the scientific logic in the path he followed: “Having come to the conclusion that so-called partial analysis cannot provide a sufficiently broad basis for fundamental understanding of the structure and operation of economic systems, I set out in 1931 to formulate a general equilibrium theory capable of empirical implementation.” (Leontief 2015). The paper thus aims at following Leontief’s tracks from his early life in St. Petersburg via Berlin, Kiel, New York to Harvard and in that biographical context look at how it 3 happened that he arrived at his input-output formulation with no pretense of offering a comprehensive biography. Leontief spoke often and entertainingly about his early. In later years he gave interviews with fascinating details about his experiences. While always prepared to speak on his scholarly work and contribute his view on a wide range of current issues Leontief was reticent about being placed on a pedestal as an important personality in the field of economics, rather than remaining the active and curious scholar he always had been. Invited in 1988 to contribute a chapter on his “life philosophy” to an anthology with contributions from highly prominent economists Leontief declined without hesitation: “Unlike some of my professional colleagues, I would find it practically impossible to describe ‘My Life Philosophy’ on twenty, a hundred or even five hundred pages. I am not as self-conscious as they seem to be.”1 Later in the same year Leontief was asked by Samuelson whether he was willing to write an autobiographical piece. Leontief waved it away: “I do not feel self-important enough and I have more interesting things to do than to write about myself.”2 As Leontief was an eminently interesting personality whose reflections and biographical notes would have been of great interest, his reticence was unfortunate. It is surely true that Leontief always, even at very high age, focused on interesting tasks ahead and seldom, if ever, looked back and reflected self-indulgently on what he had done in earlier periods of his life. Hence, on this background it is perhaps not surprising that Leontief wrote next to nothing on the origin of input-output economics as it happened in his own life experience. Several of his key co-workers and many students of input-output economics have taken a natural interest in this issue. Some asked him and got answers but not sufficient to trace his steps. This has provided motivation to look a bit closer into the issue.3 But to Leontief in his characteristic forward-looking view the importance of the “input-output moment” was the opening up of large fields that needed tilling and cultivating, tasks that would take years or even decades to complete. The origin of input-output analysis is, however, in the literature discussed also in a different meaning, namely as referring to scholarly work by pioneers of linear models with 1 Leontief to Michael Szenberg, 31 March 1988. The volume was published as Szenberg (1993) with contributions by Paul A. Samuelson, Kenneth J.
Recommended publications
  • From Grossman Translations Template
    go to editpoint editpoint go to editpoint editpoint Introduction to Henryk Grossman ‘The value-price transformation in Marx and the problem of crisis’ Rick Kuhn The transformation of values into prices of production, in volume 3 of Capital, was a vital step in Marx‘s exposure of the anatomy of capitalism and the laws of capital accumulation. In ‗The value- price transformation in Marx and the problem of crisis‘, Henryk Grossman dealt with the fundamental context and significance of the transformation and its implications for theories of economic crisis. While the issue at stake has been the coherence of Marx‘s entire analysis of capitalism, almost all of the controversy over the transformation has been preoccupied with the narrower questio of the theoretical adequacy of his mathematics. This was the case both before Grossman‘s essay, as he pointed out, and over the subsequent eighty years.1 The starting point in Grossman‘s discussion was the method that underpinned the structure of Capital and the procedure of successive approximation [Annäherungsverfahren]. After dealing with capitalism‘s most basic features at a very abstract level, achieved by means of a series of simplifying assumptions, Marx progressively lifted them to explain further aspects of concrete reality. Grossman had dealt with this procedure in a series of earlier works, paying particular attention to its implications for Marx‘s account of how crises, arising from the growing organic composition of capital were intrinsic to capitalism production, and the division of surplus value into its phenomenal forms.2 In this essay, he focussed on the place of the reproduction schemas in 1 Kliman 2007 provides a valuable account of the debate and a persuasive response to the ‗transformation problem‘.
    [Show full text]
  • Exploring a Database of “Notable People”
    Discussion paper 2016-03 A BRIEF HISTORY OF HUMAN TIME: Exploring a database of “notable people” Olivier Gergaud Morgane Louenan Etienne Wasmer Sciences Po Economics Discussion Papers ABriefHistoryofHuman Time Exploring a database of “notable people” (3000BCE-2015AD) Version 1.0.1⇤ Olivier Gergaud,† Morgane Laouenan,‡ Etienne Wasmer§ February 8, 2016 Abstract This paper describes a database of 1,243,776 notable people and 7,184,575 locations (Geolinks) associated with them throughout human history (3000BCE-2015AD). We first describe in details the various approaches and procedures adopted to extract the relevant information from their Wikipedia biographies and then analyze the database. Ten main facts emerge. 1. There has been an exponential growth over time of the database, with more than 60% of notable people still living in 2015, with the exception of a relative decline of the cohort born in the XVIIth century and a local minimum between 1645 and 1655. 2. The average lifespan has increased by 20 years, from 60 to 80 years, between the cohort born in 1400AD and the one born in 1900AD. 3. The share of women in the database follows a U-shape pattern, with a minimum in the XVIIth century and a maximum at 25% for the most recent cohorts. 4. The fraction of notable people in governance occupations has decreased while the fraction in occupations such as arts, literature/media and sports has increased over the centuries; sports caught up to arts and literature for cohorts born in 1870 but remained at the same level until the 1950s cohorts; and eventually sports came to dominate the database after 1950.
    [Show full text]
  • H-Diplo ROUNDTABLE XXII-24
    H-Diplo ROUNDTABLE XXII-24 Alan Bollard. Economists at War: How a Handful of Economists Helped Win and Lose the World Wars. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2020. ISBN: 9780198846000 (hardcover, $25.00). 1 February 2021 | https://hdiplo.org/to/RT22-24 Editor: Diane Labrosse | Production Editor: George Fujii Contents Introduction by Paul Poast, University of Chicago ........................................................................................................................... 2 Review by Laura Hein, Northwestern University .............................................................................................................................. 5 Review by Annalisa Rosselli, University of Rome Tor Vergata, Italy ............................................................................................ 8 Response by Alan Bollard, Victoria University of Wellington .....................................................................................................11 H-Diplo Roundtable XXII-24 Introduction by Paul Poast, University of Chicago ive me a one-handed economist. All my economists say, “on the one hand… on the other hand”.’ That phrase, reputedly uttered by President Harry Truman, captures the core of economics as a discipline and practice. Call it ‘G cost-benefit analysis, decision making in recognition of tradeoffs, or an ability to think ‘on the margin.’ While such practices are of value during times of peace, their importance heightens during the exigencies of war. War exacerbates the scarcity which marks everyday
    [Show full text]
  • Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall
    Tendency of the rate of profit to fall en.wikipedia.org /wiki/Tendency_of_the_rate_of_profit_to_fall The tendency of the rate of profit to fall (TRPF) is a hypothesis in economics and political economy, most famously expounded by Karl Marx in chapter 13 of Capital, Volume III.[1] Although not accepted in 20th century mainstream economics, the existence of such a tendency was widely noted throughout the 19th century.[2] Economists as diverse as Adam Smith,[3] John Stuart Mill,[4] David Ricardo[5] and Stanley Jevons[6] referred explicitly to the TRPF as an empirical phenomenon that needed to be explained. They differed in the reasons they gave for why the TRPF might necessarily occur.[7] In his 1857 Grundrisse manuscript, Karl Marx called the tendency of the rate of profit to fall "the most important law of political economy" and sought to give a causal explanation for it, in terms of his theory of capital accumulation.[8] The tendency is already foreshadowed in chapter 25 of Capital, Volume I (on the "general law of capital accumulation"), but in Part 3 of the draft manuscript of Marx's Capital, Volume III, edited posthumously for publication by Friedrich Engels, an extensive analysis is provided of the tendency. [9] Marx regarded the TRPF as proof that capitalist production could not be an everlasting form of production, since, in the end, the profit principle itself would suffer a breakdown.[10] However, because Marx never published any finished manuscript on the TRPF himself, because the tendency is hard to prove or disprove theoretically, and because it is hard to test and measure the rate of profit, Marx's TRPF theory has been a topic of controversy for more than a century.
    [Show full text]
  • Radical Political Economy
    RADICAL POLITICAL ECONOMY For too long radical political economy has suffered for lack of a coherent alternative to formal Marxian economic theory. People have had to choose between (1) continuing to use a formal model based on the labor theory of value as Marx developed in Capital to justify and retain one’s opposition to capitalism, or (2) abandoning the formal Marxian framework as outdated, and risk losing a critical evaluation of capitalism. Radical Political Economy: Sraffa Versus Marx provides readers with a third choice. A point-by-point comparison of Sraffian and Marxian treatments of prices, profits, technological change, economic crises, environmental sus- tainability, and the moral case against capitalism, are presented in six core chapters. They explain how the Sraffian treatment surpasses the formal Marxian treatment in every case. Both Marxian and Sraffian theories are presented in a highly accessible way, while large professional literatures are thoroughly referenced throughout. Marx was not the first, but remains the greatest, critic of capitalism, and richly deserves his place in history. However it is time to use intellectual tools unavailable to Marx in the nineteenth century to improve upon his formal analysis. This book is of great importance to those who study Sraffa and Marx, as well as academics and students who are interested in political economy, the history of economic thought, and economic and philosophical theory. Robin Hahnel is Professor Emeritus at the Department of Economics, American University Washington DC, USA. He is also the Co-Director of Economics for Equity and the Environment and has published widely in the fields of radical political economy and environmental economics.
    [Show full text]
  • Emil J. Gumbel's Last Course on the “Statistical Theory of Extreme Values
    Extremes (2018) 21:97–113 DOI 10.1007/s10687-017-0299-z Emil J. Gumbel’s last course on the “Statistical theory of extreme values”: a conversation with Tuncel M. Yegulalp Lexuri Fernandez´ 1 · Matthias Scherer1 Received: 31 March 2017 / Revised: 31 May 2017 / Accepted: 14 June 2017/ Published online: 27 June 2017 © The Author(s) 2017. This article is an open access publication Abstract GUMBEL. Eponym in mathematical statistics for the first type extreme value distribution and the copula that is both of extreme value and Archimedean kind. Hydrologists appreciate Emil J. Gumbel as a pioneer in promoting non-normal distributions in their field. Historians rank him among the most influential German intellectuals of the Weimar Republic. He disclosed secret societies that destabilized the Weimar Republic and used statistical methods to document political murders and to reveal a biased legal system. He was the first professor who lost his position for his political ideals and his stand against the national socialistic party, his books were banned and burned. Stripped of his nationality in 1933 he immigrated to France. In 1940 he escaped to the USA and settled in New York, where he was appointed Adjunct Professor at Columbia University, Department of Industrial Engineering, in 1953. We spoke with Tuncel M. Yegulalp –Professor emeritus of Mining Engineer- ing at Columbia University– about Emil J. Gumbel’s last course on the “Statistical Theory of Extreme Values” back in 1964. Keywords Emil J. Gumbel · Extreme value theory · History of statistics AMS 2000 Subject Classifications 01A60 · 01A70 · 60G70 Matthias Scherer [email protected] Lexuri Fernandez´ [email protected] 1 Lehrstuhl fur¨ Finanzmathematik, Technische Universitat¨ Munchen,¨ Parkring 11-13, 85748 Garching bei Munchen,¨ Germany 98 L.
    [Show full text]
  • A Brief History of Human Time
    LIEPP Working Paper February 2016, nº46 A Brief History of Human Time Exploring a database of “notable people” Olivier Gergaud KEDGE Business School and LIEPP, Sciences Po [email protected] Morgane Laouenan CNRS, Centre d’économie de la Sorbonne, U. Paris 1 and LIEPP, Sciences Po [email protected] Etienne Wasmer Sciences Po, LIEPP and Department of Economics, [email protected] www.sciencespo.fr/liepp © 2016 by the authors. All rights reserved. ABriefHistoryofHuman Time Exploring a database of “notable people” (3000BCE-2015AD) Version 1.0.1⇤ Olivier Gergaud,† Morgane Laouenan,‡ Etienne Wasmer§ February 8, 2016 Abstract This paper describes a database of 1,243,776 notable people and 7,184,575 locations (Geolinks) associated with them throughout human history (3000BCE-2015AD). We first describe in details the various approaches and procedures adopted to extract the relevant information from their Wikipedia biographies and then analyze the database. Ten main facts emerge. 1. There has been an exponential growth over time of the database, with more than 60% of notable people still living in 2015, with the exception of a relative decline of the cohort born in the XVIIth century and a local minimum between 1645 and 1655. 2. The average lifespan has increased by 20 years, from 60 to 80 years, between the cohort born in 1400AD and the one born in 1900AD. 3. The share of women in the database follows a U-shape pattern, with a minimum in the XVIIth century and a maximum at 25% for the most recent cohorts. 4. The fraction of notable people in governance occupations has decreased while the fraction in occupations such as arts, literature/media and sports has increased over the centuries; sports caught up to arts and literature for cohorts born in 1870 but remained at the same level until the 1950s cohorts; and eventually sports came to dominate the database after 1950.
    [Show full text]
  • Research Question Description of Project a Timeline of the Debate
    The “Transformation Problem” and the Labor Theory of Value Michael McCormack with Professor Deepankar Basu UMass Economics Undergraduate Research Assistantship The Transformation Problem, by Cyann Brolfe http://fixingtheeconomists.files.wordpress.com/2 013/08/labour_creates_all_wealth.gif Research Question A Timeline of the Debate and Project Conclusions/Implications The transformation problem and the What is the significance of the labor theory of value continue to be transformation of values into 1894 – the most contested aspects of Marxian economics. Based on the research this prices of production in Marxian original semester, the debate is of great economics and the economic sciences formulation of the importance for the theoretical vigor of more generally? the Marxian method. transformation 1896 – Eugene Bohm-Bawerk problem in criticizes Marx's labor theory What remains to be seen is a comprehensive solution to the problem. Capital Volume of value and refutes With so many contesting opinions III, chapter 9 transformation of values to stemming from the Sraffian critique of Description of Project prices Marx, many interpretations do not The literature around the debate provide a resolution to the debate. spanning from Capital Volume III They do, however, attest to how (1894) to the development of the advanced economic theory can be Temporal Single System integrated with Marx's landmark Interpretation of the critique of capital, suggesting a new frontier for political economy and transformation problem (1980s) was heterodox economic theory. surveyed to track the qualitative and quantitative changes that have occurred since Marx's original transformation of values into prices of production.Methods 1907, 1942 – Ladislaus Bortkiewicz makes adjustments to Marx's original algorithm 1971 – Michio Morishima (converting constant and variable capital mathematically expands • The methodology of this from values into prices, not just output the transformation, Role of Student values).
    [Show full text]
  • The Circulation of Economic Ideas Vladimir S
    Russian Journal of Economics 7 (2021) 1–8 DOI 10.32609/j.ruje.7.66257 Publication date: 31 March 2021 www.rujec.org Introduction West–Russia–West: The circulation of economic ideas Vladimir S. Avtonomov a,b,* a HSE University, Moscow, Russia b Primakov National Research Institute of World Economy and International Relations, Russian Academy of Sciences, Moscow, Russia Abstract The paper serves as an introduction to the RuJE special issue on the circulation of economic ideas between Russia and the West. This circulation is a contentious issue, especially among Russian economists. In this article a specific pattern of West–Russia–West transfer is investigated. The pattern suggests that experiencing strong influence from the West, leading Russian economists developed and modified Western economic theories, adapt- ing them to specific Russian political, ideological and cultural circumstances. As a result, they exerted a certain influence over the next generations of Western economists. Among these circumstances the paper mentions moral and religious factors, the peasant question, the special influence of Marxism, the development of mathematics and statistics in Russia in the 1890s–1920s, and the unique experience of building a planned economy. Keywords: history of Russian economic thought, Karl Marx, Marxism, Russian peasant question, planned economy. JEL classification: B12, B14, B15, B30, B31 1. General historical relations of Russia and the West: A brief introduction The general relations between the West (or Western Europe, because the USA began to be considered as a Russian counterpart fairly recently) and Russia has long been a fundamental question of self-identification for Russian society. We can only broach this controversial issue superficially.1 It reflects Russia’s pre- dicament as a country with significant specificity determined by its history and * E-mail address: [email protected] 1 Among innumerable sources we can mention: Billington (1966), Hedlund (2003), Pipes (1995).
    [Show full text]
  • Tesis Joaquín Farina
    Universidad de Castilla-La Mancha Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales DOCTORADO EN ECONOMIBA Y EMPRESA TESIS DOCTORAL LA TASA DE EXPLOTACIÓN COMO MEDIDA DE DESIGUALDAD GLOBAL (1973-2012) D. Joaquín Farina Dirigido por: Dr. D. Eladio Febrero Paños Dr. D. Matías Gámez Martínez Albacete, 2017 Agradecimientos Especialmente a mis directores Eladio Febrero Paños, Matías Gámez Martínez y sus familias A mi familia que fueron un respaldo indispensable. A Luca cuya sonrisa permanente despierta la creatividad del más oscuro ratón de biblioteca. Inicialmente esta dedicatoria decía "A mi hijo Luca ("el bebé que no llora") y a su madre.". Pero ahora llora. A mis padres especialmente, los prestamistas de última instancia en tan costosa empresa. Anticipadamente a los jurados evaluadores por los comentarios que seguramente enriquecerán mi trabajo. A pesar de nuestros enfrentamientos teóricos no siempre en los mejores términos a Juan Ignacio Palacio Morena por sus comentarios iniciales a mi protoproyecto de tesis. A Diego Guerrero Jiménez (UCM) quien fue el primero en impulsarme en este método de medición. Gonzalo Ralón fue tal vez el mejor alumno que pisó mis aulas. Bien vale el plural porque cursó varias asignaturas a mi cargo obteniendo siempre la máxima calificación. Pero el premiado fui yo, ya que hoy cuento con su amistad incondicional. Fue coautor en varios de los trabajos que son insumo de esta tesis. Sus comentarios contribuyeron a mejorar este trabajo sobre todo en lo metodológico y me mejoraron en lo personal. Los aportes de Marín Trombetta, mi econometrista de cabecera, son imposible de mensurar, al menos cuantitativamente como a él le hubiera gustado.
    [Show full text]
  • CLAVEY-DISSERTATION-2019.Pdf
    Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950 The Harvard community has made this article openly available. Please share how this access benefits you. Your story matters Citation Clavey, Charles H. 2019. Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University, Graduate School of Arts & Sciences. Citable link http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:42029484 Terms of Use This article was downloaded from Harvard University’s DASH repository, and is made available under the terms and conditions applicable to Other Posted Material, as set forth at http:// nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:dash.current.terms-of- use#LAA Experiments in Theory: The Transatlantic Development of Social Science and Critical Theory, 1930-1950 A dissertation presented by Charles H. Clavey to The Department of History in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in the subject of History Harvard University Cambridge, Massachusetts April 2019 © 2019 Charles H. Clavey All Rights Reserved. Dissertation Advisor: Professor Peter E. Gordon Charles H. Clavey EXPERIMENTS IN THEORY: THE TRANSATLANTIC DEVELOPMENT OF SOCIAL SCIENCE & CRITICAL THEORY, 1930-1950 ABSTRACT From its foundation in 1923, the Institute for Social Research conducted empirical studies of the social forms, cultural products, and psychological effects of advanced capitalism. Adapting methods from social- and human-scientific fields as diverse as experimental psychology and industrial sociology, Institute affiliates fashioned a research methodology they termed “experiments in theory.” In this dissertation, I recover the history of these experiments. To do so, I reconstruct the debates that led to the creation of the method and document its application in a variety of projects between 1930 and 1950.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Beyond Random Causes: Harmonic Analysis Of
    BEYOND RANDOM CAUSES: HARMONIC ANALYSIS OF BUSINESS CYCLES AT THE MOSCOW CONJUNCTURE INSTITUTE BY MARCO P. VIANNA FRANCO*, LEONARDO COSTA RIBEIRO**, AND EDUARDO DA MOTTA E ALBUQUERQUE*** Abstract This article proposes a historical assessment of harmonic analysis of business cycles and its ability to both decompose and build cycles, as received at the Moscow Conjuncture Institute. It traces how the Fourier transform arrived at the Institute, mediated by Henry L. Moore, in the works and actions of Albert Vainshtein, Nikolai Chetverikov, and Nikolai Kondratiev, ultimately leading to Eugen Slutsky’s well-known 1927 article The Summation of Random Causes as the Source of Cyclic Processes. Although the evidence does not warrant the assumption that there was an orchestrated effort at the Institute to push forward a research agenda on harmonic analysis of business cycles, it certainly unfolded as more than the summation of random events and individual incursions. Moreover, the Institute as a whole could have produced much more on this matter if it had escaped Stalinist oppression for at least a few more years. * Konrad Lorenz Institute for Evolution and Cognition Research. Email: [email protected] ** Cedeplar, Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Email: [email protected] *** Cedeplar, Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais Email: [email protected] This “preprint” is the peer-reviewed and accepted typescript of an article that is forthcoming in revised form, after minor editorial changes, in the Journal of the History of Economic Thought (ISSN: 1053-8372), issue TBA. Copyright to the journal’s articles is held by the History of Economics Society (HES), whose exclusive licensee and publisher for the journal is Cambridge University Press.
    [Show full text]