Consumer Theory
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
Quasilinear Approximations
Quasilinear approximations Marek Weretka ∗ August 2, 2018 Abstract This paper demonstrates that the canonical stochastic infinite horizon framework from both the macro and finance literature, with sufficiently patient consumers, is in- distinguishable in ordinal terms from a simple quasilinear economy. In particular, with a discount factor approaching one, the framework converges to a quasilinear limit in its preferences, allocation, prices, and ordinal welfare. Consequently, income effects associated with economic policies vanish, and equivalent and compensating variations coincide and become approximately additive for a set of temporary policies. This ordi- nal convergence holds for a large class of potentially heterogenous preferences that are in Gorman polar form. The paper thus formalizes the Marshallian conjecture, whereby quasilinear approximation is justified in those settings in which agents consume many commodities (here, referring to consumption in many periods), and unifies the general and partial equilibrium schools of thought that were previously seen as distinct. We also provide a consumption-based foundation for normative analysis based on social surplus. Key words: JEL classification numbers: D43, D53, G11, G12, L13 1 Introduction One of the most prevalent premises in economics is the ongoing notion that consumers be- have rationally. The types of rational preferences studied in the literature, however, vary considerably across many fields. The macro, financial and labor literature typically adopt consumption-based preferences within a general equilibrium framework, while in Industrial Organization, Auction Theory, Public Finance and other fields, the partial equilibrium ap- proach using quasilinear preferences is much more popular. ∗University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Economics, 1180 Observatory Drive, Madison, WI 53706. -
Theory of Consumer Behaviour
Theory of Consumer Behaviour Public Economy 1 What is Consumer Behaviour? • Suppose you earn 12,000 yen additionally – How many lunch with 1,000 yen (x1) and how many movie with 2,000 yen (x2) you enjoy? (x1, x2) = (10,1), (6,3), (3,4), (2,5), … – Suppose the price of movie is 1,500 yen? – Suppose the additional bonus is 10,000 yen? Public Economy 2 Consumer Behaviour • Feature of Consumer Behaviour • Consumption set (Budget constraint) • Preference • Utility • Choice • Demand • Revealed preference Public Economy 3 Feature of Consumer Behaviour Economic Entity Firm(企業), Consumer (家計), Government (経済主体) Household’s income Capital(資本), Labor(労働),Stock(株式) Consumer Firm Hire(賃料), Wage(賃金), Divided(配当) Goods Market (財・サービス市場) Price Demand Supply Quantity Consumer = price taker (価格受容者) Public Economy 4 Budget Set (1) • Constraint faced by consumer Possible to convert – Budget Constraint (income is limited) into monetary unit – Time Constraint (time is limited) under the given wage rate – Allocation Constraint Combine to Budget Constraint Generally, only the budget constraint is considered Public Economy 5 Budget Set (2) Budget Constraint Budget Constraint (without allocation constraint) (with allocation constraint) n pi xi I x2 i1 x2 Income Price Demand x1 x1 Budget Set (消費可能集合) B B 0 x1 0 x1 n n n n B x R x 0, pi xi I B x R x 0, pi xi I, x1 x1 i1 i1 Public Economy 6 Preference (1) • What is preference? A B A is (strictly) preferred to B (A is always chosen between A and B) A B A is preferred to B, or indifferent between two (B is never chosen between A and B) A ~ B A and B is indifferent (No difference between A and B) Public Economy 7 Preference (2) • Assumption regarding to preference 1. -
CONSUMER CHOICE 1.1. Unit of Analysis and Preferences. The
CONSUMER CHOICE 1. THE CONSUMER CHOICE PROBLEM 1.1. Unit of analysis and preferences. The fundamental unit of analysis in economics is the economic agent. Typically this agent is an individual consumer or a firm. The agent might also be the manager of a public utility, the stockholders of a corporation, a government policymaker and so on. The underlying assumption in economic analysis is that all economic agents possess a preference ordering which allows them to rank alternative states of the world. The behavioral assumption in economics is that all agents make choices consistent with these underlying preferences. 1.2. Definition of a competitive agent. A buyer or seller (agent) is said to be competitive if the agent assumes or believes that the market price of a product is given and that the agent’s actions do not influence the market price or opportunities for exchange. 1.3. Commodities. Commodities are the objects of choice available to an individual in the economic sys- tem. Assume that these are the various products and services available for purchase in the market. Assume that the number of products is finite and equal to L ( =1, ..., L). A product vector is a list of the amounts of the various products: ⎡ ⎤ x1 ⎢ ⎥ ⎢x2 ⎥ x = ⎢ . ⎥ ⎣ . ⎦ xL The product bundle x can be viewed as a point in RL. 1.4. Consumption sets. The consumption set is a subset of the product space RL, denoted by XL ⊂ RL, whose elements are the consumption bundles that the individual can conceivably consume given the phys- L ical constraints imposed by the environment. -
Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions
Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions Theodoros Diasakos and Georgios Gerasimou School of Economics and Finance School of Economics and Finance Discussion Paper No. 1708 Online Discussion Paper Series 14 Mar 2017 (revised 23 Aug 2019) issn 2055-303X http://ideas.repec.org/s/san/wpecon.html JEL Classification: info: [email protected] Keywords: 1 / 31 Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions∗ Theodoros M. Diasakos Georgios Gerasimou University of Stirling University of St Andrews August 23, 2019 Abstract It is frequently assumed in several domains of economics that demand functions are invertible in prices. At the primitive level of preferences, however, the characterization of such demand func- tions remains elusive. We identify conditions on a utility-maximizing consumer’s preferences that are necessary and sufficient for her demand function to be continuous and invertible in prices: strict convexity, strict monotonicity and differentiability in the sense of Rubinstein (2012). We show that preferences are Rubinstein-differentiable if and only if the corresponding indifference sets are smooth. As we demonstrate by example, these notions relax Debreu’s (1972) preference smoothness. ∗We are grateful to Hugo Sonnenschein and Phil Reny for very useful conversations and comments. Any errors are our own. 2 / 31 1 Introduction Invertibility of demand is frequently assumed in several domains of economic inquiry that include con- sumer and revealed preference theory (Afriat, 2014; Matzkin and Ricther, 1991; Chiappori and Rochet, 1987; Cheng, 1985), non-separable and non-parametric demand systems (Berry et al., 2013), portfolio choice (Kubler¨ and Polemarchakis, 2017), general equilibrium theory (Hildenbrand, 1994), industrial or- ganization (Amir et al., 2017), and the estimation of discrete or continuous demand systems. -
Slutsky Equation the Basic Consumer Model Is Max U(X), Which Is Solved by the Marshallian X:Px≤Y Demand Function X(P, Y)
Slutsky equation The basic consumer model is max U(x), which is solved by the Marshallian x:px≤y demand function X(p; y). The value of this primal problem is the indirect utility function V (p; y) = U(X(p; y)). The dual problem is minx fp · x j U(x) = ug, which is solved by the Hicksian demand function h(p; u). The value of the dual problem is the expenditure or cost function e(p; u) = p · H(p; u). First show that the Hicksian demand function is the derivative of the expen- diture function. e (p; u) = p · h(p; u) ≤p · h(p + ∆p; u) e (p + ∆p; u) = (p + ∆p) · h(p + ∆p; u) ≤ (p + ∆p) · h(p; u) (p + ∆p) · ∆h ≤ 0 ≤ p · ∆h ∆e = (p + ∆p) · h(p + ∆p; u) − p · h(p; u) ∆p · h(p + ∆p; u) ≤ ∆e ≤ ∆p · h(p; u) For a positive change in a single price pi this gives ∆e hi(p + ∆p; u) ≤ ≤ hi(p; u) ∆pi In the limit, this shows that the derivative of the expenditure function is the Hicksian demand function (and Shephard’s Lemma is the exact same result, for cost minimization by the firm). Also ∆p · h(p + ∆p; u) − ∆p · h(p; u) = ∆p · ∆h ≤ 0 meaning that the substitution effect is negative. Also, the expenditure function lies everywhere below its tangent with respect to p: that is, it is concave in p: e(p + ∆p; u) ≤ (p + ∆p) · h(p; u) = e(p; u) + ∆p · h(p; u) The usual analysis assumes that the consumer starts with no physical en- dowment, just money. -
Chapter 5 Online Appendix: the Calculus of Demand
Chapter 5 Online Appendix: The Calculus of Demand The chapter uses the graphical model of consumer choice to derive the demand for a good by changing the price of the good and the slope of the budget constraint and then plotting the relationship between the prices and the optimal quantities as the demand curve. Figure 5.7 shows this process for three different prices, three budget constraints, and three points on the demand curve. You can see that this graphical approach works well if you need to plot a few points on a demand curve; however, getting the quantity demanded at every price requires us to apply the calculus of utility maximization. Before we do the calculus, let’s review what we know about the demand curve. The chapter defines the demand curve as “the relationship between the quantity of a good that consumers demand and the good’s price, holding all other factors constant.” In the appendix to Chapter 4, we always Figure 5.7 Building an Individual’s Demand Curve (a) (b) Mountain Dew Mountain Dew P = 4 (2 liter bottles) (2 liter bottles) G PG = 1 Income = $20 P = 2 10 10 G PG = $1 PMD = $2 4 3 3 U U 1 2 U U 1 3 2 0 14 20 0 3105 8 14 20 Quantity of grape juice Quantity of grape juice (1 liter bottles) (1 liter bottles) Price of Price of grape juice grape juice ($/bottle) ($/bottle) Caroline’s $4 demand for 2 grape juice $1 1 0 0 14 3 8 14 Quantity of grape juice Quantity of grape juice (1 liter bottles) (1 liter bottles) (a) At her optimal consumption bundle, Caroline purchases (b) A completed demand curve consists of many of these 14 bottles of grape juice when the price per bottle is $1 and quantity-price points. -
APEC 5152 - Handout 1
APEC 5152 - Handout 1 February 16, 2017 Micro-Preliminaries Contents 1 Consumer preferences 2 1.1 The indirect utility function . 4 1.2 The expenditure function . 6 1.3 Aggregation . 7 2 Production technologies 8 2.1 The cost function . 9 2.2 The value-added function . 11 2.3 Aggregation . 13 2.3.1 The aggregate cost function and value added function . 13 2.3.2 The aggregate gross national product function . 15 3 Appendix 16 3.1 The Primal-Dual Problem (Envelope Theorem) . 16 3.2 Elasticities and homogenous functions . 18 1 Introduction - microeconomic foundations Throughout these notes, the following notation denotes factor endowments, factor rental rates and output prices. Sectors are indexed by j 2 f1; 2; 3g ; and denote the quantity of sector-j's output by 3 the scalar Yj: Corresponding output prices are denoted p = (p1; p2; p3) 2 R++, with the scalar pj representing the per-unit price of sector-j output. We consider three factor endowments: labor, L; capital, K; and land Z. The corresponding factor rental rates are: w is the wage rate, r is the rate of return to capital, and τ is the unit land rental rate. Represent the vector of factor rental rates by w = (w; r; τ) : 1 Consumer preferences The economy is composed of a large number of atomistic households. Each household faces the η η η η 3 same vector of prices p and the same vector of factor rental rates w. Let υ = (L ;K ;Z ) 2 R++ denote the level of factor endowments held by household-η; with Lη;Kη and Zη representing the η 3 household's endowment of labor, capital and land. -
Public Economics Lecture Notes
Public Economics Lecture Notes Matteo Paradisi 1 Contents 1 Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elas- ticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply 4 1.1 Uncompensated Elasticity and the Utility Maximization Problem . 4 1.2 Substitution Elasticity and the Expenditure Minimization Problem . 6 1.3 Relating Walrasian and Hicksian Demand: The Slutsky Equation . 6 1.4 StaticLaborSupplyChoice .................................. 7 1.5 Dynamic Labor Supply . 10 2 Section 2: Introduction to Optimal Income Taxa- tion 12 2.1 TheIncomeTaxationProblem ................................ 12 2.2 Taxation in a Model With No Behavioral Responses . 12 2.3 TowardstheMirrleesOptimalIncomeTaxModel . 13 2.4 Optimal Linear Tax Rate . 13 2.5 OptimalTopIncomeTaxation ................................ 15 3 Section 3-4: Mirrlees Taxation 17 3.1 TheModelSetup........................................ 17 3.2 OptimalIncomeTax ...................................... 19 3.3 Diamond ABC Formula . 20 3.4 Optimal Taxes With Income Effects ............................. 21 3.5 Pareto Efficient Taxes . 23 3.6 A Test of the Pareto Optimality of the Tax Schedule . 23 4 Section 5: Optimal Taxation with Income Effects and Bunching 28 4.1 Optimal Taxes with Income Effects.............................. 28 4.2 Bunching Estimator . 31 5 Section 6: Optimal Income Transfers 34 5.1 OptimalIncomeTransfersinaFormalModel . 34 5.2 Optimal Tax/Transfer with Extensive Margin Only . 35 5.3 Optimal Tax/Transfer with Intensive Margin Responses . 36 5.4 Optimal Tax/Transfer with Intensive and Extensive Margin Responses . 37 6 Section 7: Optimal Top Income Taxation 38 6.1 TrickleDown: AModelWithEndogenousWages . 38 6.2 Taxation in the Roy Model and Rent-Seeking . 39 6.3 Wage Bargaining and Tax Avoidance . 40 7 Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduc- tion to Capital Taxation 44 7.1 Optimal Minimum Wage . -
Arrow-Debreu Model Versus Kornai-Critique
Athens Journal of Business & Economics - Volume 3, Issue 2 – Pages 143-170 Arrow-Debreu Model versus Kornai-critique By József Móczár More than forty-five years have passed since János Kornai published his book entitled „Anti-equilibrium” (Kornai, 1971). This was the first scientific work in the international literature that provided a comprehensive critique on the general equilibrium theory as described in Debreu’s theory of price and the Arrow-Debreu model and opened a debate on the validity of the mainstream neoclassical model. Frank Hahn’s response was the most severe to the critique. Kornai, insisting on his original critique, reflected on Hahn’s response in his own autobiography (Kornai, 2008). In this paper, we review the Arrow-Debreu model and its background, reconstruct the major points of the Kornai vs. Hahn debate, including its historical preliminaries, and examine the validity of criticisms and rebuttals. As we will see, the recent theories have not always verified Hahn’s objections and some Nobel Prize lectures in economics recently showed that both the neoclassical theory and the general equilibrium theory in the sense of Arrow-Debreu model was wrong on either empirical or theoretical grounds (Offer and Söderberg, 2016). We also show Kornai’s newest results towards an alternative model of detailed resource allocation, DRSE contrary to the general equilibrium (Kornai, 2014). Keywords: general equilibrium theory, Arrow-Debreu model, Anti-Equilibrium, Kornai vs. Hahn debate, Walrasian equilibrium, Kornai’s new equilibrium states, ex post and ex ante models, DRSE model, ergodic dynamic system. Introduction Although the axiomatic analysis of modern equilibrium theory, i.e., Gerard Debreu‟s book entitled “Theory of Value” does not explicitly discuss the Walras-model, the author, as a member of Bourbaki, does take the equilibrium theory developed from Walras‟ work into consideration with rigorous mathematical scrutiny (Debreu, 1959). -
General Equilibrium
Hart Notes Matthew Basilico April, 2013 Part I General Equilibrium Chapter 15 - General Equilibrium Theory: Examples • Pure exchange economy with Edgeworth Box • Production with One-Firm, One-Consumer • [Small Open Economy] 15B. Pure Exchange: The Edgeworth Box Denitions and Set Up Pure Exchange Economy • An economy in which there are no production opportunities. Agents possess endowments, eco- nomic activity consists of trading and consumption Edgeworth Box Economy • Preliminaries Assume consumers act as price takers Two consumers i = 1; 2; Two commodities l = 1; 2 • Consumption and Endowment 0 Consumer i s consumption vector is xi = (x1i; x2i) Consumer 0s consumption set is 2 ∗ i R+ Consumer has preference relation over consumption vectors in this set ∗ i %i 0 Consumer i s endowment vector is !i = (!1i;!2i) ∗ Total endowment of good l is !¯l = !l1 + !l2 • Allocation 1 An allocation 4 is an assignment of a nonnegative consumption vector to each con- x 2 R+ sumer ∗ x = (x1; x2) = ((x11; x21) ; (x12; x22)) A feasible allocation is ∗ xl1 + xl2 ≤ !¯l for l = 1; 2 A nonwasteful allocation is ∗ xl1 + xl2 =! ¯l for l = 1; 2 ∗ These can be depicted in Edgeworth Box • Wealth and Budget Sets Wealth: Not given exogenously, only endowments are given. Wealth is determined by by prices. ∗ p · !i = p1!1i + p2!2i Budget Set: Given endowment, budget set is a function of prices 2 ∗ Bi (p) = xi 2 R+ : p · xi ≤ p · !i ∗ Graphically, draw budget line [slope = − p1 ]. Consumer 1's budget set consists of p2 all nonnegative vectors below and to the left; consumer 2's is above and to the right • Graph: Axes: horizontal is good 1, vertial is good 2 Origins: consumer 1 in SW corner (as usual), consumer 2 in NE corner (unique to Edgeworth boxes) • Oer Curve = Demand (as a function of p) (A depiction of preferences of each consumer) %i ∗ Asume strictly convex, continuous, strongly monotone 2 As p varies, budget line pivots around !. -
ECON2001 Microeconomics Lecture Notes Budget Constraint
ECON2001 Lecture Notes ECON2001 Microeconomics Lecture Notes Term 1 Ian Preston Budget constraint Consumers purchase goods q from within a budget set B of affordable bun- dles. In the standard model, prices p are constant and total spending has to remain within budget p0q ≤ y where y is total budget. Maximum affordable quantity of any commodity is y/pi and slope ∂qi/∂qj|B = −pj/pi is constant and independent of total budget. In practical applications budget constraints are frequently kinked or discon- tinuous as a consequence for example of taxation or non-linear pricing. If the price of a good rises with the quantity purchased (say because of taxation above a threshold) then the budget set is convex whereas if it falls (say because of a bulk buying discount) then the budget set is not convex. Marshallian demands The consumer’s chosen quantities written as a function of y and p are the Marshallian or uncompensated demands q = f(y, p) Consider the effects of changes in y and p on demand for, say, the ith good: • total budget y – the path traced out by demands as y increases is called the income expansion path whereas the graph of fi(y, p) as a function of y is called the Engel curve – we can summarise dependence in the total budget elasticity y ∂qi ∂ ln qi i = = qi ∂y ∂ ln y – if demand for a good rises with total budget, i > 0, then we say it is a normal good and if it falls, i < 0, we say it is an inferior good – if budget share of a good, wi = piqi/y, rises with total budget, i > 1, then we say it is a luxury or income elastic and if it -
Advanced Microeconomics Comparative Statics and Duality Theory
Advanced Microeconomics Comparative statics and duality theory Harald Wiese University of Leipzig Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 1 / 62 Part B. Household theory and theory of the …rm 1 The household optimum 2 Comparative statics and duality theory 3 Production theory 4 Cost minimization and pro…t maximization Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 2 / 62 Comparative statics and duality theory Overview 1 The duality approach 2 Shephard’slemma 3 The Hicksian law of demand 4 Slutsky equations 5 Compensating and equivalent variations Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 3 / 62 Maximization and minimization problem Maximization problem: Minimization problem: Find the bundle that Find the bundle that maximizes the utility for a minimizes the expenditure given budget line. needed to achieve a given utility level. x2 indifference curve with utility level U A C B budget line with income level m x1 Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 4 / 62 The expenditure function and the Hicksian demand function I Expenditure function: e : R` R R, ! (p, U¯ ) e (p, U¯ ) := min px 7! x with U (x ) U¯ The solution to the minimization problem is called the Hicksian demand function: χ : R` R R` , ! + (p, U¯ ) χ (p, U¯ ) := arg min px 7! x with U (x ) U¯ Harald Wiese (University of Leipzig) Advanced Microeconomics 5 / 62 The expenditure function and the Hicksian demand function II Problem Express e in terms of χ and V in terms of the household optima! Lemma For any α > 0: χ (αp, U¯ ) = χ (p, U¯ ) and e (αp, U¯ ) = αe (p, U¯ ) .