General Equilibrium

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

General Equilibrium Hart Notes Matthew Basilico April, 2013 Part I General Equilibrium Chapter 15 - General Equilibrium Theory: Examples • Pure exchange economy with Edgeworth Box • Production with One-Firm, One-Consumer • [Small Open Economy] 15B. Pure Exchange: The Edgeworth Box Denitions and Set Up Pure Exchange Economy • An economy in which there are no production opportunities. Agents possess endowments, eco- nomic activity consists of trading and consumption Edgeworth Box Economy • Preliminaries Assume consumers act as price takers Two consumers i = 1; 2; Two commodities l = 1; 2 • Consumption and Endowment 0 Consumer i s consumption vector is xi = (x1i; x2i) Consumer 0s consumption set is 2 ∗ i R+ Consumer has preference relation over consumption vectors in this set ∗ i %i 0 Consumer i s endowment vector is !i = (!1i;!2i) ∗ Total endowment of good l is !¯l = !l1 + !l2 • Allocation 1 An allocation 4 is an assignment of a nonnegative consumption vector to each con- x 2 R+ sumer ∗ x = (x1; x2) = ((x11; x21) ; (x12; x22)) A feasible allocation is ∗ xl1 + xl2 ≤ !¯l for l = 1; 2 A nonwasteful allocation is ∗ xl1 + xl2 =! ¯l for l = 1; 2 ∗ These can be depicted in Edgeworth Box • Wealth and Budget Sets Wealth: Not given exogenously, only endowments are given. Wealth is determined by by prices. ∗ p · !i = p1!1i + p2!2i Budget Set: Given endowment, budget set is a function of prices 2 ∗ Bi (p) = xi 2 R+ : p · xi ≤ p · !i ∗ Graphically, draw budget line [slope = − p1 ]. Consumer 1's budget set consists of p2 all nonnegative vectors below and to the left; consumer 2's is above and to the right • Graph: Axes: horizontal is good 1, vertial is good 2 Origins: consumer 1 in SW corner (as usual), consumer 2 in NE corner (unique to Edgeworth boxes) • Oer Curve = Demand (as a function of p) (A depiction of preferences of each consumer) %i ∗ Asume strictly convex, continuous, strongly monotone 2 As p varies, budget line pivots around !. Given this line, consumer demands most preferred point in B (p). This set of demanded consumptions makes up oer curve ∗ Just like demand function: x1 (p; p · !1) ∗ Curve passes through the endowment point. Also, since at each point endowment is aordable, every point on oer curve must be at least as good as !i. • Walrasian Equilibrium (a.k.a. Competitive Equilibrium), for an Edgeworth Box: Denition: Price vector ∗ and an allocation ∗ ∗ ∗ in the Edgeworth box such that p x = (x1; x2) for i = 1; 2 ∗ for all 0 ∗ ∗ xi %i xi xi 2 Bi (p ) At equilibrium, the oer curves of the two consumers intersect ∗ Any intersection of the oer curves outside of ! corresponds to a WE p∗ Only relative prices 1 are determined in equilibrium, since each consumer's demand is p2∗ homogenous of degree zero ∗ ∗ ∗ is a WE ∗ ∗ ∗ is a WE ∗ p = (p1; p2) =) αp = (αp1; αp2) • Solving for WE strategy: 1. Optimization: Max utility, using budget constraint to reduce number of variables 2. Demand: Solve for Demand (OC) as a function of price xli (p) 3. Market Clearing: Set total demand for a good equal to endowment: xl1 + xl2 = !l (a) AKA solve for excess demand function zl (p) = xl1 + xl2 − !l, and then set it equal to 0. ∗ p1 4. Solve for price ratio ∗ p2 (a) To determine p∗, only need to nd that for which one market clears. Other will neces- sarily clear at these prices. See PS1 Q6 3 • Multple WE Can certainly have multiple WE, as you will have a WE any time the Oer Curves intersect more than once ∗ i.e. quasilinear utility with respect to dierent numeraires (doctored a bit, MWG 521) • Non-existance of WE Two classic examples 1. Non-monotonic Preferences (a) Endowment on the boundary (b) Consumer 2 only desires good 1 and has all good 1. (c) Price of good 2 is zero. Consumer 2 strictly prefers receiving more of good 1 (but won't). But also prefers to receive more of good 2 at price 0. (d) No p∗ at which demands are compatible i. [Since Consumer 1's demand for good 2 is innite at p2 = 0] ii. Can also say: there is an 0 ∗ 0 ∗ , hence not a WE x1 1 x1; x1 2 B (p ) 2. Nonconvex Preferences (a) In example, consumer 1's oer curve is disconnected, so it does not intersect consumer 2's 4 • Pareto Optimum Denition: An allocation x in the EWB is Pareto Optimal if there is no other allocation x0 in the Edgeworth box with 0 and and 0 for some . xi %i xi i = 1; 2 xi i xi i ∗ An economic outcome is Pareto optimal if there is no alternative feasible outcome at which every individual in the economy is at least as well o, and some individual is strictly better o. Interior solution: consumers' indierence curves through x must be tangent Corner solution: tangency need not hold • Pareto Set Set of all Pareto Optimal allocations • Contract Curve The part of the Pareto Set where both consumers do at least as well as at their initial endowments • 1st Welfare Theorem Any Walrasian equilibirum allocation x∗ necessarily belongs to the Pareto Set • 2nd Welfare Theorem Verbally: Under convexity assumptions (not required for 1st WT), a planner can achieve any desired Pareto optimal allocation by appropriately redistributing wealth in a lump-sum fashion and then letting the market work Denition: An allocation x∗ in the EWB is supportable as an equilibrium with transfers if ∗ there is a price system p and wealth transfers T1 and T2 satisfying T1 + T2 = 0 such that for each consumer we have: ∗ 0 0 2 such that ∗ 0 ∗ i xi % xi 8xi 2 R+ p · xi ≤ p · !i + Ti ∗ Note that p∗ doesn't change; it is essentially the endowment ! that is moved by the transfers to get to the new x∗ Failures ∗ Nonconvexities: May fail when preferences aren't convex (given budget line, consumer with nonconvex preference may prefer dierent point to intended x∗) ∗ Monotonicity: (Figure 10(a) above). ! is PO, but cannot be supported as an equilib- rium with transfers 5 15C: The One-Consumer, One-Producer Economy • Set up Single producer, single rm; both are price taking. x1 = leisure (and labor = z = L¯ − x1); x2 = good produced by rm Endowment: L¯ of leisure, 0 of x2 (although consumer owns rm and gets prots, which are positive) Continuous, convex and strongly monotone dened over and % x1 (leisure) x2 • Production max pf (z) − wz z≥0 Given prices (p; w),[p is price of x2, w is wage] rm has optimal labor demand z (p; w), output q (p; w) and π (p; w) • Consumption max u (x1; x2) 2 (x1;x2)2R+ s.t. px2 ≤ w L¯ − x1 + π (p; w) Budget constraint is from wage earning and prot from rm • Walrasian Equilibrium Price vector (p∗; w∗) at which consumption and labor markets clear: ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ x2 (p ; w ) = q (p ; w ) ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ L¯ − x1 (p ; w ) = z (p ; w ) 6 Graphically: 15.C.1(b) is not an equilibrium; 15.C.2 is A particular consumption-leisure combination is an WE () it maximizes the consumer's utility subject to the economy's technological and endowment constraints • Graph Of (producer's origin) in SE corner; takes x−axis as −z Oc (consumer's origin) in SW corner as usual Budget constraint line has slope w and intercept π(p;w) . This is the isoprot line of the − p p rm's prot maximization problem: (−z; q): pq − wz = π (p; w) 16: Equilibrium and Its Basic Welfare Properties Basic Model Denitions • I consumers, J consumers, L goods Consumer consumption set L • i Xi ⊂ R Preferences dened on , rational (complete & transitive) • %i Xi Endowment vector L • !¯ = (!1;:::;!L) 2 R Firm production set (or technology) L. Every (nonempty), closed. • Yj ⊂ R Yj 6= ; Basic data on preferences, technologies and resources for this economy are summarized by I J f(Xi; %i)gi=1 ; fYjgj=1 ; !¯ Feasible Allocation (x; y) • Denition: A feasible allocation is a vector (x1; : : : ; xI ; y1; : : : ; yI ) s.t. 1. xi 2 Xi 8i 7 2. yj 2 Yj 8j 3. P P i xi =! ¯ + j yj n o The set of feasible allocations is denoted by P P A = (x; y) 2 X1 × · · · × XI × Y1 × · · · × YI : i xi =! ¯ + j yj ⊂ RL(I+J) Pareto Optimum Denition: A feasible allocation is Pareto Optimal if 0 0 s.t. 0 • (x; y) 2 A @ (x ; y ) 2 A xi %i xi 8i and 0 for some . xi xi i Private Ownership Economies Endowment: Each consumer has initial endowment L • i !i 2 R • Shareholding: Each consumer i has shareholding θij in rm j θij 2 [0; 1] 8i; j P i θij = 1 8j Data on preferences, technology, resources and ownership are summarized by I J I f(Xi; %i)gi=1 ; fYjgj=1 ; f!i; θi1; : : : θiJ gi=1 Walrasian Equilibrium n o Given a private ownership economy specied by I J I , f(Xi; %i)gi=1 ; fYjgj=1 ; (!i; θi1; : : : ; θiJ )i=1 ∗ ∗ An allocation (x ; y ) and a price vector p = (p1; : : : pL) constitute a Walrasian (or competitive) Equilibrium if: 1. ∗ p · yj ≤ p · yj 8yj 2 Yj (a) [ max: That is, for every ∗ maximizes prots in ] π j; yj yj n o 2. For every , ∗ is maximal for in the budget set P ∗ i xi %i xi 2 Xi : p · xi ≤ p · !i + j θijp · yj (a) [Hence ∗ ∗ ∗ P ∗] xi i xi =) p xi > p !i + j θijp · yj (b) [Consumers maximize utility subject to budet constraint, and anything strictly better is unattainable] 3.
Recommended publications
  • Planning Board June 15, 2021 Page 1 Page 1 of 27 Meeting of The
    Planning Board June 15, 2021 Page 1 Meeting of the Planning Board of the Town of Lewisboro held via the videoconferencing application Zoom (Meeting ID: 957 4529 2964). The audio recording of this meeting is Lewisboro Planning Board 06-15-21.mp3 and the YouTube link is https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=bD5fYuufYoA (video starts at 2:11 of audio). Present: Janet Andersen, Chair Jerome Kerner Charlene Indelicato Greg La Sorsa Maureen Maguire Judson Siebert, Esq., Keane & Beane P.C., Planning Board Counsel Jan Johannessen, AICP, Kellard Sessions Consulting, Town Planner/Wetland Consultant Ciorsdan Conran, Planning Board Administrator Mary Shah, Conservation Advisory Council Approximately 14 participants were logged into the Zoom meeting and 2 viewers on YouTube. Ms. Andersen called the meeting to order at 7:30 p.m. Janet Andersen: Hi, I’m Janet Andersen and I’m calling to order the Town of Lewisboro Planning Board meeting for Tuesday, June 15, 2021, at 7:30 pm. This meeting is happening via Zoom, with live streaming to YouTube on the LewisboroTV channel and it's being recorded. The public can view the meeting via Zoom or YouTube, and we have confirmed that the feed is active and working, I think. Ciorsdan Conran: Almost working on YouTube. Janet Andersen: Almost up on YouTube. We will check that. In accordance with the governor's executive orders, no one is at our usual meeting location at 79 Bouton. Ciorsdan Conran, our planning board administrator, has confirmed that the meeting has been duly noticed and legal notice requirements have been fulfilled. Joining me on this Zoom conference from the town of Lewisboro are members of the planning board: Charlene Indelicato, Jerome Kerner, Greg La Sorsa, and Maureen Maguire.
    [Show full text]
  • Quasilinear Approximations
    Quasilinear approximations Marek Weretka ∗ August 2, 2018 Abstract This paper demonstrates that the canonical stochastic infinite horizon framework from both the macro and finance literature, with sufficiently patient consumers, is in- distinguishable in ordinal terms from a simple quasilinear economy. In particular, with a discount factor approaching one, the framework converges to a quasilinear limit in its preferences, allocation, prices, and ordinal welfare. Consequently, income effects associated with economic policies vanish, and equivalent and compensating variations coincide and become approximately additive for a set of temporary policies. This ordi- nal convergence holds for a large class of potentially heterogenous preferences that are in Gorman polar form. The paper thus formalizes the Marshallian conjecture, whereby quasilinear approximation is justified in those settings in which agents consume many commodities (here, referring to consumption in many periods), and unifies the general and partial equilibrium schools of thought that were previously seen as distinct. We also provide a consumption-based foundation for normative analysis based on social surplus. Key words: JEL classification numbers: D43, D53, G11, G12, L13 1 Introduction One of the most prevalent premises in economics is the ongoing notion that consumers be- have rationally. The types of rational preferences studied in the literature, however, vary considerably across many fields. The macro, financial and labor literature typically adopt consumption-based preferences within a general equilibrium framework, while in Industrial Organization, Auction Theory, Public Finance and other fields, the partial equilibrium ap- proach using quasilinear preferences is much more popular. ∗University of Wisconsin-Madison, Department of Economics, 1180 Observatory Drive, Madison, WI 53706.
    [Show full text]
  • Special Edition Band Songlist
    (revised for January 2021) POP/DANCE 24-Karat Magic Bruno Mars Ain't It Fun Paramore Ain't Nobody Chaka Khan All About The Bass Meghan Trainor Attention Charlie Puth Bad Romance Lady Gaga Bang Bang Ariana Grande/Nicki Minaj Bidi Bidi Bom Bom Selena Gomez Big Time Peter Gabriel Billie Jean Michael Jackson Blurred Lines Robin Thicke Boogie Oogie Oogie Taste Of Honey California Gurls Katy Perry Can't Stop the Feelin' Justin Timberlake Celebration Kool & The Gang Cheap Thrills Sia Cheerleader Felix Jaehn Chunky Bruno Mars Conga Gloria Estefan and The Miami Sound Machine Crazy In Love Beyoncé Dancing Queen Abba Donna Summer Medley Donna Summer Don't Cha Pussycat Dolls Don't Stop The Music Rhianna Drag Me Down One Direction Ex's and Oh's Elle King Faith George Michael Family Affair Mary J Blige Fancy Iggy Azalea feat. Charli XCX Feel It Still Portugal, The Man Finesse Bruno Mars/Cardi B Footloose Kenny Loggins Funkytown Lipps, Inc. Girls Just Wanna Have Fun Cyndi Lauper Give Me Everything Pitbull Good Kisser Usher Groove is in The Heart Deee-Lite Happy Pharrell Williams Havana Camilla Cabello Hella Good No Doubt I Feel For You Chaka Khan I Gotta Feelin' Black Eyed Peas I Wanna Dance With Somebody Whitney Houston I Will Survive Gloria Gaynor Intentions Justin Bieber I'm Like A Bird Nelly Furtado Jealous Nick Jonas Just Dance Lady Gaga Kiss Prince Lady Marmalade LaBelle/Shakira Last Dance Donna Summer Leave Your Hat On Joe Cocker Let's Go Crazy Prince Let's Groove Tonight Earth, Wind and Fire Locked Out Of Heaven Bruno Mars Love on Top Beyoncé
    [Show full text]
  • Smith V. Bull Jesse W
    Golden Gate University School of Law GGU Law Digital Commons Jesse Carter Opinions The eJ sse Carter Collection 5-16-1958 Smith v. Bull Jesse W. Carter Supreme Court of California Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.ggu.edu/carter_opinions Part of the Business Organizations Law Commons Recommended Citation Carter, Jesse W., "Smith v. Bull" (1958). Jesse Carter Opinions. Paper 14. http://digitalcommons.law.ggu.edu/carter_opinions/14 This Opinion is brought to you for free and open access by the The eJ sse Carter Collection at GGU Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Jesse Carter Opinions by an authorized administrator of GGU Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 294 SMITE: v' BULL [50 C.2d A. No. 24510. In Bank. May 16, 1958.] BERTILLE B. SMITH, as Administratrix With Will An­ nexed, etc., Respondent, v. FRANK BULL, Appellant. [1] Partnership-Dissolution-Proof.-Evidence that on February 5 of a certain year defendant wrote plaintiff's husband, with whom he was associated in an advertising agency partnership, that he was dissatisfied with the partnership and believed it should be "liquidated," that on February 20 defendant signed a lease on new premises and certified that he was conducting an advertising agency at the new premises under a new name, that on the same day he was notified by a finance company having a major account in the partnership that its account would be transferred to him, that on February 23 defendant notified plaintiff's husband of
    [Show full text]
  • Approximate Nash Equilibria in Large Nonconvex Aggregative Games
    Approximate Nash equilibria in large nonconvex aggregative games Kang Liu,∗ Nadia Oudjane,† Cheng Wan‡ November 26, 2020 Abstract 1 This paper shows the existence of O( nγ )-Nash equilibria in n-player noncooperative aggregative games where the players' cost functions depend only on their own action and the average of all the players' actions, and is lower semicontinuous in the former while γ-H¨oldercontinuous in the latter. Neither the action sets nor the cost functions need to be convex. For an important class of aggregative games which includes con- gestion games with γ being 1, a proximal best-reply algorithm is used to construct an 1 3 O( n )-Nash equilibria with at most O(n ) iterations. These results are applied in a nu- merical example of demand-side management of the electricity system. The asymptotic performance of the algorithm is illustrated when n tends to infinity. Keywords. Shapley-Folkman lemma, aggregative games, nonconvex game, large finite game, -Nash equilibrium, proximal best-reply algorithm, congestion game MSC Class Primary: 91A06; secondary: 90C26 1 Introduction In this paper, players minimize their costs so that the definition of equilibria and equilibrium conditions are in the opposite sense of the usual usage where players maximize their payoffs. Players have actions in Euclidean spaces. If it is not precised, then \Nash equilibrium" means a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. This paper studies the approximation of pure-strategy Nash equilibria (PNE for short) in a specific class of finite-player noncooperative games, referred to as large nonconvex aggregative games. Recall that the cost functions of players in an aggregative game depend on their own action (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 4 " Theory of Choice and Individual Demand
    Lecture 4 - Theory of Choice and Individual Demand David Autor 14.03 Fall 2004 Agenda 1. Utility maximization 2. Indirect Utility function 3. Application: Gift giving –Waldfogel paper 4. Expenditure function 5. Relationship between Expenditure function and Indirect utility function 6. Demand functions 7. Application: Food stamps –Whitmore paper 8. Income and substitution e¤ects 9. Normal and inferior goods 10. Compensated and uncompensated demand (Hicksian, Marshallian) 11. Application: Gi¤en goods –Jensen and Miller paper Roadmap: 1 Axioms of consumer preference Primal Dual Max U(x,y) Min pxx+ pyy s.t. pxx+ pyy < I s.t. U(x,y) > U Indirect Utility function Expenditure function E*= E(p , p , U) U*= V(px, py, I) x y Marshallian demand Hicksian demand X = d (p , p , I) = x x y X = hx(px, py, U) = (by Roy’s identity) (by Shepard’s lemma) ¶V / ¶p ¶ E - x - ¶V / ¶I Slutsky equation ¶p x 1 Theory of consumer choice 1.1 Utility maximization subject to budget constraint Ingredients: Utility function (preferences) Budget constraint Price vector Consumer’sproblem Maximize utility subjet to budget constraint Characteristics of solution: Budget exhaustion (non-satiation) For most solutions: psychic tradeo¤ = monetary payo¤ Psychic tradeo¤ is MRS Monetary tradeo¤ is the price ratio 2 From a visual point of view utility maximization corresponds to the following point: (Note that the slope of the budget set is equal to px ) py Graph 35 y IC3 IC2 IC1 B C A D x What’swrong with some of these points? We can see that A P B, A I D, C P A.
    [Show full text]
  • A Stated Preference Case Study on Traffic Noise in Lisbon
    The Valuation of Environmental Externalities: A stated preference case study on traffic noise in Lisbon by Elisabete M. M. Arsenio Submitted in accordance with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy University of Leeds Institute for Transport Studies August 2002 The candidate confirms that the work submitted is his own and that appropriate credit has been given where reference has been made to the work of others. Acknowledgments To pursue a PhD under a part-time scheme is only possible through a strong will and effective support. I thank my supervisors at the ITS, Dr. Abigail Bristow and Dr. Mark Wardman for all the support and useful comments throughout this challenging topic. I would also like to thank the ITS Directors during my research study Prof. Chris Nash and Prof A. D. May for having supported my attendance in useful Courses and Conferences. I would like to thank Mr. Stephen Clark for the invaluable help on the computer survey, as well as to Dr. John Preston for the earlier research motivation. I would like to thank Dr. Hazel Briggs, Ms Anna Kruk, Ms Julie Whitham, Mr. F. Saremi, Mr. T. Horrobin and Dr. R. Batley for the facilities’ support. Thanks also due to Prof. P. Mackie, Prof. P. Bonsall, Mr. F. Montgomery, Ms. Frances Hodgson and Dr. J. Toner. Thanks for all joy and friendship to Bill Lythgoe, Eric Moreno, Jiao Wang, Shojiro and Mauricio. Special thanks are also due to Dr. Paul Firmin for the friendship and precious comments towards the presentation of this thesis. Without Dr.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture Notes General Equilibrium Theory: Ss205
    LECTURE NOTES GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM THEORY: SS205 FEDERICO ECHENIQUE CALTECH 1 2 Contents 0. Disclaimer 4 1. Preliminary definitions 5 1.1. Binary relations 5 1.2. Preferences in Euclidean space 5 2. Consumer Theory 6 2.1. Digression: upper hemi continuity 7 2.2. Properties of demand 7 3. Economies 8 3.1. Exchange economies 8 3.2. Economies with production 11 4. Welfare Theorems 13 4.1. First Welfare Theorem 13 4.2. Second Welfare Theorem 14 5. Scitovsky Contours and cost-benefit analysis 20 6. Excess demand functions 22 6.1. Notation 22 6.2. Aggregate excess demand in an exchange economy 22 6.3. Aggregate excess demand 25 7. Existence of competitive equilibria 26 7.1. The Negishi approach 28 8. Uniqueness 32 9. Representative Consumer 34 9.1. Samuelsonian Aggregation 37 9.2. Eisenberg's Theorem 39 10. Determinacy 39 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM THEORY 3 10.1. Digression: Implicit Function Theorem 40 10.2. Regular and Critical Economies 41 10.3. Digression: Measure Zero Sets and Transversality 44 10.4. Genericity of regular economies 45 11. Observable Consequences of Competitive Equilibrium 46 11.1. Digression on Afriat's Theorem 46 11.2. Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu Theorem: Anything goes 47 11.3. Brown and Matzkin: Testable Restrictions On Competitve Equilibrium 48 12. The Core 49 12.1. Pareto Optimality, The Core and Walrasian Equiilbria 51 12.2. Debreu-Scarf Core Convergence Theorem 51 13. Partial equilibrium 58 13.1. Aggregate demand and welfare 60 13.2. Production 61 13.3. Public goods 62 13.4. Lindahl equilibrium 63 14.
    [Show full text]
  • Preview Guide
    ContentsNOT FOR SALE Preface xiii CHAPTER 3 The Behavior of Consumers 45 3.1 Tastes 45 CHAPTER 1 Indifference Curves 45 Supply, Demand, Marginal Values 48 and Equilibrium 1 More on Indifference Curves 53 1.1 Demand 1 3.2 The Budget Line and the Demand versus Quantity Consumer’s Choice 53 Demanded 1 The Budget Line 54 Demand Curves 2 The Consumer’s Choice 56 Changes in Demand 3 Market Demand 7 3.3 Applications of Indifference The Shape of the Demand Curve 7 Curves 59 The Wide Scope of Economics 10 Standards of Living 59 The Least Bad Tax 64 1.2 Supply 10 Summary 69 Supply versus Quantity Supplied 10 Author Commentary 69 1.3 Equilibrium 13 Review Questions 70 The Equilibrium Point 13 Numerical Exercises 70 Changes in the Equilibrium Point 15 Problem Set 71 Summary 23 Appendix to Chapter 3 77 Author Commentary 24 Cardinal Utility 77 Review Questions 25 The Consumer’s Optimum 79 Numerical Exercises 25 Problem Set 26 CHAPTER 4 Consumers in the Marketplace 81 CHAPTER 2 4.1 Changes in Income 81 Prices, Costs, and the Gains Changes in Income and Changes in the from Trade 31 Budget Line 81 Changes in Income and Changes in the 2.1 Prices 31 Optimum Point 82 Absolute versus Relative Prices 32 The Engel Curve 84 Some Applications 34 4.2 Changes in Price 85 2.2 Costs, Efficiency, and Gains from Changes in Price and Changes in the Trade 35 Budget Line 85 Costs and Efficiency 35 Changes in Price and Changes in the Optimum Point 86 Specialization and the Gains from Trade 37 The Demand Curve 88 Why People Trade 39 4.3 Income and Substitution Summary 41
    [Show full text]
  • Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited
    Seattle Journal for Social Justice Volume 5 Issue 2 Article 28 May 2007 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj Recommended Citation Nadal, Alejandro (2007) "Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited," Seattle Journal for Social Justice: Vol. 5 : Iss. 2 , Article 28. Available at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/sjsj/vol5/iss2/28 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Student Publications and Programs at Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Seattle Journal for Social Justice by an authorized editor of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 569 Coasean Fictions: Law and Economics Revisited Alejandro Nadal1 After the 1960s, a strong academic movement developed in the United States around the idea that the study of the law, as well as legal practice, could be strengthened through economic analysis.2 This trend was started through the works of R.H. Coase and Guido Calabresi, and grew with later developments introduced by Richard Posner and Robert D. Cooter, as well as Gary Becker.3 Law and Economics (L&E) is the name given to the application of modern economics to legal analysis and practice. Proponents of L&E have portrayed the movement as improving clarity and logic in legal analysis, and even as a tool to modify the conceptual categories used by lawyers and courts to think about
    [Show full text]
  • Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions
    Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions Theodoros Diasakos and Georgios Gerasimou School of Economics and Finance School of Economics and Finance Discussion Paper No. 1708 Online Discussion Paper Series 14 Mar 2017 (revised 23 Aug 2019) issn 2055-303X http://ideas.repec.org/s/san/wpecon.html JEL Classification: info: [email protected] Keywords: 1 / 31 Preference Conditions for Invertible Demand Functions∗ Theodoros M. Diasakos Georgios Gerasimou University of Stirling University of St Andrews August 23, 2019 Abstract It is frequently assumed in several domains of economics that demand functions are invertible in prices. At the primitive level of preferences, however, the characterization of such demand func- tions remains elusive. We identify conditions on a utility-maximizing consumer’s preferences that are necessary and sufficient for her demand function to be continuous and invertible in prices: strict convexity, strict monotonicity and differentiability in the sense of Rubinstein (2012). We show that preferences are Rubinstein-differentiable if and only if the corresponding indifference sets are smooth. As we demonstrate by example, these notions relax Debreu’s (1972) preference smoothness. ∗We are grateful to Hugo Sonnenschein and Phil Reny for very useful conversations and comments. Any errors are our own. 2 / 31 1 Introduction Invertibility of demand is frequently assumed in several domains of economic inquiry that include con- sumer and revealed preference theory (Afriat, 2014; Matzkin and Ricther, 1991; Chiappori and Rochet, 1987; Cheng, 1985), non-separable and non-parametric demand systems (Berry et al., 2013), portfolio choice (Kubler¨ and Polemarchakis, 2017), general equilibrium theory (Hildenbrand, 1994), industrial or- ganization (Amir et al., 2017), and the estimation of discrete or continuous demand systems.
    [Show full text]
  • 2. Budget Constraint.Pdf
    Engineering Economic Analysis 2019 SPRING Prof. D. J. LEE, SNU Chap. 2 BUDGET CONSTRAINT Consumption Choice Sets . A consumption choice set, X, is the collection of all consumption choices available to the consumer. n X = R+ . A consumption bundle, x, containing x1 units of commodity 1, x2 units of commodity 2 and so on up to xn units of commodity n is denoted by the vector xx =(1 ,..., xn ) ∈ X n . Commodity price vector pp =(1 ,..., pn ) ∈R+ 1 Budget Constraints . Q: When is a bundle (x1, … , xn) affordable at prices p1, … , pn? • A: When p1x1 + … + pnxn ≤ m where m is the consumer’s (disposable) income. The consumer’s budget set is the set of all affordable bundles; B(p1, … , pn, m) = { (x1, … , xn) | x1 ≥ 0, … , xn ≥ 0 and p1x1 + … + pnxn ≤ m } . The budget constraint is the upper boundary of the budget set. p1x1 + … + pnxn = m 2 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x2 Budget constraint is m /p2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m. m /p1 x1 3 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x2 Budget constraint is m /p2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m. the collection of all affordable bundles. Budget p1x1 + p2x2 ≤ m. Set m /p1 x1 4 Budget Constraint for Three Commodities • If n = 3 x2 p1x1 + p2x2 + p3x3 = m m /p2 m /p3 x3 m /p1 x1 5 Budget Set for Three Commodities x 2 { (x1,x2,x3) | x1 ≥ 0, x2 ≥ 0, x3 ≥ 0 and m /p2 p1x1 + p2x2 + p3x3 ≤ m} m /p3 x3 m /p1 x1 6 Opportunity cost in Budget Constraints x2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m Slope is -p1/p2 a2 Opp.
    [Show full text]