Administrative Thinkers

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Administrative Thinkers ADMINISTRATIVE THINKERS Material prepared according to the Textbook and Reference Books given in the Syllabus Subject Code : 18MPA23C Prepared by : Dr. C. Esther Buvana, Asst. Professor & Head Department : PG & Research Department of Public Administration Contact No. : 9840881638 E-mail ID : [email protected] Year Subject Title Sem. Sub Code 2018 - 19 Core 6 : Administrative Thinkers II 18MPA23C Onwards Objective The purpose of this paper is to enable the students to understand the views of the Administrative Thinkers during classical, Neo classical and modern period which will make them to analyse further the various aspects of administration. UNIT – I: INTRODUCTION Kautilya – Thiruvalluvar - Woodrow Wilson. UNIT – II: CLASSICAL SCHOOL F. W. Taylor – Henri Fayol -Luther Gulick- Max Weber UNIT – III: NEO _ CLASSICAL SCHOOL Elton Mayo- Mary Parker Follet – C. I. Barnard UNIT – IV: BEHAVIOURAL SCHOOL Herbert. A. Simon- Rensis Likert- Riggs UNIT – V: SOCIO-PSYCHOLOGICAL SCHOOL Abraham Maslow -McGregor- Herzberg Textbook 1. Ravindra Prasad and Sathyanarayanan - Administrative Thinkers, sterling publishers New Delhi 2004 Reference Books 1. Anthony Tillet, Thomas Kemper & Gordon Willey – Management Thinkers, Penguin Books 1970. 2. Ramesh K Arora – Perspective in Administrative Theory, Associated Publishing House, New Delhi, 1979. 3. Sapru R.K.-Administrative Theories & management Thought, Prentice Hall, New Delhi 2000. 4. Singh R N – Management Thinkers, Sultan Chand Publishers, New Delhi. HERBERT ALEXANDER SIMON Herbert Alexander Simon was born in Milwaukee, Wisconsin on June 15, 1916. Simon's father, Arthur Simon, was a Jewish electrical engineer who came to the United States from Germany in 1903 after earning his engineering degree at Technische Hochschule Darmstadt. An inventor, Arthur also was an independent patent attorney. Simon attended Milwaukee Public Schools, where he developed an interest in science and established himself as an atheist. While attending middle school, Simon wrote a letter to "the editor of the Milwaukee Journal defending the civil liberties of atheists". Unlike most children, Simon's family introduced him to the idea that human behavior could be studied scientifically; his mother's younger brother, Harold Merkel (1892-1922), who studied economics at the University of Wisconsin–Madison under John R. Commons, became one of his earliest influences. Through Harold's books on economics and psychology, Simon discovered social science. Among his earliest influences, Simon cited Norman Angell for his book The Great Illusion and Henry George for his book Progress and Poverty. While attending high school, Simon joined the debate team, where he argued "from conviction, rather than cussedness" in favor of George's single tax. In 1933, Simon entered the University of Chicago, and, following his early influences, decided to study social science and mathematics. Simon was interested in studying biology but chose not to pursue the field because of his "color-blindness and awkwardness in the laboratory". At an early age, Simon learned he was color blind and discovered the external world is not the same as the perceived world. While in college, Simon focused on political science and economics. Simon's most important mentor was Henry Schultz, an econometrician and mathematical economist. Simon received both his B.A. (1936) and his Ph.D. (1943) in political science from the University of Chicago, where he studied under Harold Lasswell, Nicolas Rashevsky, Rudolf Carnap, Henry Schultz, and Charles Edward Merriam. After enrolling in a course on "Measuring Municipal Governments," Simon became a research assistant for Clarence Ridley, and the two co-authored Measuring Municipal Activities: A Survey of Suggested Criteria for Appraising Administration in 1938. Simon's studies led him to the field of organizational decision-making, which became the subject of his doctoral dissertation. Simon’s Decision Making Theory Introduction Herbert Simon is also a great contributor of administrative theory and is regarded as the first Behaviourist. The human relations were considered as the first Behaviourists but it was not fully developed and it was not recognised as such. According to Simon administration/management requires an enquiry into how decisions are made and tasks performed and was the essential process of organisational action. In his book ‘Administrative Behaviour’ he argued that ‘making a decision is really making a choice between alternative courses of action or even between action and non-action’. His theory has directed the scholars to study the importance of decisions and how they are made. He states that there can never be a ‘one best course of action or decision’ as stated by Classical Theorists as in reality an administrator can never have all the complete information and knowledge to do so and there will always be a better course of action which he is not aware of. And so he takes a decision based on principles of bounded rationality or limitations of human capacity in solving complex problems. Such limitations arise from internal or psychological facts of stress or motivations on one hand or external, environmental factors on the other hand. And thus, the decision taken by an administrative man is ‘satisficing’ that is satisfying and sufficing rather than maximising for the situation and ‘best choice’ as per his knowledge. STAGES IN DECISION MAKING: Intelligence Activity Stage: This stage identifies the problems of an organisation and the head of the organisation has to analyse and understand the organisational environment to proceed to a resolution. Design Activity Stage: After problem identification, the organisation head starts to look for various suitable courses or strategies or alternatives and identifies the merits and demerits of each. Choice Activity Stage: Once alternatives have been developed, the administration begins the choice activity stage. It critically evaluates the different consequences of all alternatives available and a decision is taken after examining the abovementioned alternatives’ merits and demerits and the most suitable course of action is selected. This stage requires skills such as judgement, creativity, quantitative analysis and experience in the decision making process. VALUES AND FACTS IN DECISION MAKING – SIMON: Simon opined that every decision comes with 2 components associated with it: Value component: Refers to such preferences which decision maker may be seen pursuing as an ethical statement and which cant be evaluated as true or false. Fact component: Refers to such verifiable premises where propositions can be tested to determine that whether they are true or false. Science as per Simon is concerned with facts and not values. Choosing of correct and factual aspects is what Simon advocates. But decision making is always clouded with values. Simon opines that administrative man should avoid values in decision making as much as possible to find rationalism. However he did not completely rule out values and suggested that values can be incorporated in decisions relating to fixation of end goals while factual judgements shall be seen pre- dominant in the implementation of such goals. PROGRAMMED AND NON-PROGRAMMED DECISION MAKING: In regard to organisational decision making Simon identified two types of decision making: Programmed decisions: Decisions having repetitive components and where pre established examples are present. Non Programmed decisions: Non repetitive in nature and directed towards solving problems in new environments and new variables. Simon advocated delegating to sub-units programmed decisions whereas non- programmed decisions should be retained with the upper level strategic management. RATIONAL DECISION MAKING – SIMON: Simon says that rationality in organisational decisions could be improved using the following tools: Promoting high degree of specialisation. Applying Scientific tools in the process of Decision Making. Promoting operations on the basis of market mechanism. Promoting knowledge of political institutions. Creating a wider base of knowledge so that rationality could be improved in problem solving. Bounded Rationality Herbert A. Simon proposed bounded rationality as an alternative basis for the mathematical modeling of decision-making, as used in economics, political science, and related disciplines. It complements "rationality as optimization", which views decision-making as a fully rational process of finding an optimal choice given the information available. Simon used the analogy of a pair of scissors, where one blade represents "cognitive limitations" of actual humans and the other the "structures of the environment", illustrating how minds compensate for limited resources by exploiting known structural regularity in the environment. Many economics models assume that agents are on average rational, and can in large enough quantities be approximated to act according to their preferences in order to maximise utility. With bounded rationality, Simon's goal was "to replace the global rationality of economic man with a kind of rational behavior that is compatible with the access to information and the computational capacities that are actually possessed by organisms, including man, in the kinds of environments in which such organisms exist." In short, the concept of bounded rationality revises notions of "perfect" rationality to account for the fact that perfectly rational decisions are often not feasible in practice
Recommended publications
  • The Agrarian Tradition and Its Meaning for Today
    Mr. Fite, who grew up on a South Dakota farm, is research professor of history at the University of Oklahoma and one of the country's leading agricultural historians. This essay was delivered as the McKnight lecture at the 118th annual meeting of the Minnesota Historical Society. The AGRARIAN TRADITION and Its Meaning for Today GILBERT C. FITE ONE of the most notable developments in today. Although wealthy former Senator American history during the last hundred Robert S. Kerr of Oklahoma used to picture years has been the rapid decline in the eco­ the log cabin of his birth and distribute jugs nomic, political, and social position of of good old country sorghum during cam­ American farmers. Not many years ago, the paign forays, neither Averell Harriman nor most idealized man in American life was the Nelson Rockefeller — both multimillion­ hard-working, independent son of the land. aires— found it necessary to have his pic­ He was viewed as the prototype of every­ ture taken hauling hay or milking cows thing good and worthwhile. As Thomas Jef­ during the 1958 election in New York. ferson proclaimed, farmers were "the chosen So great has been the impact of industrial­ people of God, if ever he had a chosen peo­ ization upon our culture that Christ's par­ ple." 1 But history has a way of being fickle, able of the sower is in danger of losing its and in her unfaithfulness Clio has produced meaning to modern young urbanites, who a new national idol far different from the neither sow nor reap, but who spend a life­ self-reliant yeoman of earlier generations.
    [Show full text]
  • Agrarianism: an Ideology of the National FFA Organization
    Journal of Agricultural Education Volume 54, Number 3, pp. 28 – 40 DOI: 10.5032/jae.2013.03028 Agrarianism: An Ideology of the National FFA Organization Michael J. Martin Colorado State University Tracy Kitchel University of Missouri The traditions of the National FFA Organization (FFA) are grounded in agrarianism. This ideology fo- cuses on the ability of farming and nature to develop citizens and integrity within people. Agrarianism has been an important thread of American rhetoric since the founding of country. The ideology has mor- phed over the last two centuries as the country developed from a nation of farmers to an industrial world power. The agrarian ideology that resonated in rural America during the formation of the FFA was southern agrarianism. Southern agrarian ideology argued for self-reliance and adherence to past tradi- tions. These concepts appear in the FFA traditions of the creed, opening ceremony, motto, and awards. The historical growth and success of the FFA within rural communities demonstrates the ability of the southern agrarian ideology to connect with contemporary rural values. However, the southern agrarian ideology may not connect with the culture of diverse, urban, or suburban students. Advisers of diverse, urban, or suburban FFA chapters may need to reconceptualize the FFA traditions to accommodate their students. Keywords: National FFA Organization; philosophy; ideology; agrarianism The theme Beyond Diversity to Cultural LaVergne, Larke, Elbert, & Jones, 2011). One Proficiency resonated at the 2011 American As- study highlighted how some non-FFA members sociation for Agricultural Education (AAAE) viewed FFA members as hicks (Phelps, Henry, conference. Fittingly, AAAE invited James & Bird, 2012).
    [Show full text]
  • Agrarian Anarchism and Authoritarian Populism: Towards a More (State-)Critical ‘Critical Agrarian Studies’
    The Journal of Peasant Studies ISSN: 0306-6150 (Print) 1743-9361 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/fjps20 Agrarian anarchism and authoritarian populism: towards a more (state-)critical ‘critical agrarian studies’ Antonio Roman-Alcalá To cite this article: Antonio Roman-Alcalá (2020): Agrarian anarchism and authoritarian populism: towards a more (state-)critical ‘critical agrarian studies’, The Journal of Peasant Studies, DOI: 10.1080/03066150.2020.1755840 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/03066150.2020.1755840 © 2020 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group Published online: 20 May 2020. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 3209 View related articles View Crossmark data Citing articles: 4 View citing articles Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at https://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=fjps20 THE JOURNAL OF PEASANT STUDIES https://doi.org/10.1080/03066150.2020.1755840 FORUM ON AUTHORITARIAN POPULISM AND THE RURAL WORLD Agrarian anarchism and authoritarian populism: towards a more (state-)critical ‘critical agrarian studies’* Antonio Roman-Alcalá International Institute of Social Studies, The Hague, Netherlands ABSTRACT KEYWORDS This paper applies an anarchist lens to agrarian politics, seeking to Anarchism; authoritarian expand and enhance inquiry in critical agrarian studies. populism; critical agrarian Anarchism’s relevance to agrarian processes is found in three studies; state theory; social general areas: (1) explicitly anarchist movements, both historical movements; populism; United States of America; and contemporary; (2) theories that emerge from and shape these moral economy movements; and (3) implicit anarchism found in values, ethics, everyday practices, and in forms of social organization – or ‘anarchistic’ elements of human social life.
    [Show full text]
  • Plains Indian Agrariaism and Class Conflict
    University of Nebraska - Lincoln DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln Great Plains Quarterly Great Plains Studies, Center for 1987 Plains Indian Agrariaism and Class Conflict Russel Lawrence Barsh University of Washington Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/greatplainsquarterly Part of the Other International and Area Studies Commons Barsh, Russel Lawrence, "Plains Indian Agrariaism and Class Conflict" (1987). Great Plains Quarterly. 315. https://digitalcommons.unl.edu/greatplainsquarterly/315 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Great Plains Studies, Center for at DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. It has been accepted for inclusion in Great Plains Quarterly by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@University of Nebraska - Lincoln. PLAINS INDIAN AGRARIANISM AND CLASS CONFLICT RUSSEL LAWRENCE BARSH Relatively little has been done to trace the landless bureaucratic class emerged, and their political structures of American Indians competition for political influence has domi­ through the years 1890 to 1940, when reserva­ nated reservation life ever since. As in many tion economics were undergoing their most developing countries, modernization was ac­ dramatic changes. That failure has left the false companied by a conflict between small-scale impression of a fifty-vear institutional vacuum. agrarian capitalism and central planning. In fact, the middle years were times of complex If valid, this thesis requires reversing some reJisrrihutions of power ;md the emergence of well-entrenched historical judgments, i.c., that indigellous socioeconomic classes. It was also the Ceneral Allotment Act was bad because it perhaps the earliest period in which Plains reduced the Indians' aggregate landholdings, Indians enjoyed anything like an American­ and that the Indian New Deal was good style, decentralized elective democracy.
    [Show full text]
  • Existentialistic Perspective in the Select Novels of Joan Didion
    © 2019 JETIR February 2019, Volume 6, Issue 2 www.jetir.org (ISSN-2349-5162) Existentialistic Perspective in the Select Novels of Joan Didion Dr. S. ADINARAYANAN, M.A., M. Phil., Ph. d., Head of the Department, Department of English SWAMI VIVEKANANADA ARTS & SCIENCE COLLEGE, VILLUPURAM, TAMILNADU, THIRUVALLUVAR UNIVERSITY E-mail: [email protected] ABSTRACT Joan Didion, a contemporary American author who demands consideration both as a non- fiction author and as a fiction author, is regarded a novelist, an essayist, and a New Journalist. An empirical approach to Didion’s works shows a progressive change in her perception of the connection of literature to life. The present research explores the impact of existentialist doctrines - both technically and thematically - throughout four major novels of Didion, and it is the critical study to suggest existentialism as granting a logical method by which to perceive the whole canon - focusing particularly on the existential experiences of the female protagonists in the novels. The study analyses Run River (1963) and A Book of Common Prayer (1977) which graphically reveal the existential experience of an individual entangled in Bad Faith. The writings of Didion present a comprehensive detail about the Existentialist struggle in America. America could have been regarded as an “Existential” nation from the angle that it acquired several features that would have led Sartre or Camus to experience several classic symptoms connected with the ideology. Alienation, angst, nausea, ennui and a swarm of similarly dreary physical and mental conditions could have easily been found within the nation. In conjunction with the increasing refinement of her fiction, there remains a core value consistent with the existential perspective Didion explores in each novel.
    [Show full text]
  • University of Birmingham Revisiting Samuelson's Foundations of Economic Analysis
    University of Birmingham Revisiting Samuelson's Foundations of Economic Analysis Backhouse, Roger DOI: 10.1257/jel.53.2.326 License: None: All rights reserved Document Version Publisher's PDF, also known as Version of record Citation for published version (Harvard): Backhouse, R 2015, 'Revisiting Samuelson's Foundations of Economic Analysis' Journal of Economic Literature, vol 53, no. 2, pp. 326-350. DOI: 10.1257/jel.53.2.326 Link to publication on Research at Birmingham portal General rights When referring to this publication, please cite the published version. Copyright and associated moral rights for publications accessible in the public portal are retained by the authors and/or other copyright owners. It is a condition of accessing this publication that users abide by the legal requirements associated with these rights. • You may freely distribute the URL that is used to identify this publication. • Users may download and print one copy of the publication from the public portal for the purpose of private study or non-commercial research. • If a Creative Commons licence is associated with this publication, please consult the terms and conditions cited therein. • Unless otherwise stated, you may not further distribute the material nor use it for the purposes of commercial gain. Take down policy If you believe that this document infringes copyright please contact [email protected] providing details and we will remove access to the work immediately and investigate. Download date: 16. May. 2017 Journal of Economic Literature 2015, 53(2), 326–350 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.2.326 Revisiting Samuelson’s Foundations of Economic Analysis† Roger E.
    [Show full text]
  • Institutional Economics
    INSTITUTIONAL ECONOMICS AT COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY Malcolm Rutherford University of Victoria (This Draft: March 2001) This paper draws on archival work using the James Bonbright Papers, J. M. Clark Papers, Joseph Dorfman Papers, Carter Goodrich Papers, Robert Hale Papers, and Wesley Mitchell Papers, all at the Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Columbia University, the Arthur F. Burns Papers at the Eisenhower Library, Abilene, Kansas, and the John R. Commons Papers at the State Historical Society of Wisconsin. My thanks to Lowell Harriss, Aaron Warner, Eli Ginzberg, Donald Dewey, Mark Perlman, Daniel Fusfeld, Mark Blaug, and Walter Neale for sharing their recollections of Columbia. Thanks also to my research assistant Cristobal Young. Any errors are my responsibility. This research has been supported by a Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada research grant (project # 410-99-0465). 1 1. Introduction In a number of recent papers I have attempted to outline the nature of the institutionalist movement in American economics in the interwar period (Rutherford 2000a, 2000b, 2000c). At that time institutionalism was a very significant part of American economics. In terms of research output and the production of graduate students, the main centers for institutionalism were the university of Chicago (until 1926 and the departure of J. M. Clark), the University of Wisconsin, the Robert Brookings Graduate School (which existed only briefly between 1923 and 1928), and, after the arrival of Wesley Mitchell in 1913, and J. M. Clark in 1926, Columbia University. Columbia University became the academic home of a large concentration of economists of institutionalist leaning, and other Schools and Departments in the University, particularly Business, Law, Sociology, and Philosophy, also contained many people of similar or related persuasion.
    [Show full text]
  • Agrarianism Paper
    Agrarian Environmentalism and the Nature of the State Jake P. Greear Introduction The most straightforward case of a violent, post-colonial eco-revolution in the world is probably the three-decade-old conflict on the Island of Bougainville, some 900 miles northeast of Australia. Dubbed the “Coconut Revolution," this conflict began when dispossessed native Bougainvilleans over-ran and shut down Panguna Mine, which at the time was the world’s largest copper mine, operated by Rio Tinto Zinc. Its significant profits enriched Western stockholders and was the main source of funding for the government of Papua New Guinea, !1 which encompassed Bougainville Island. A small proportion of the profits were used for local “development”—providing rudimentary housing for native Bougainvillean workers and substandard educational facilities for their children. These benefits and the meagre wages paid to workers came to be seen as an insult added to the broader injuries of colonization and the ecological devastation of the island traditionally called “Mekamui.” After their demand for $10 billion in reparations was denied, the indigenous rebel faction expelled the foreign mine operators and defeated the Papua New Guinea Defense Forces, despite their being aided by the Australian Military and industry-backed private military contractors. The war took on the character of a civil war to some degree, and it was very bloody. Today, thirty years later, the fighting has stopped, but the struggle is still unresolved. The mine remains closed, with roads blocked by rebel hold-outs who still carry guns, but even some Bougainvilleans who took part in the struggle want to see the mine re-opened.
    [Show full text]
  • Tolstoy and the Structures of Agrarian-Buddhist Utopianism in Taisho¯ Japan
    religions Article Future Perfect: Tolstoy and the Structures of Agrarian-Buddhist Utopianism in Taisho¯ Japan James Mark Shields ID Comparative Humanities Program, Bucknell University, Lewisburg, PA 17837, USA; [email protected] Received: 22 April 2018; Accepted: 13 May 2018; Published: 16 May 2018 Abstract: This study focuses on the role played by the work of Leo Tolstoy (1828–1910) in shaping socialism and agrarian-Buddhist utopianism in Japan. As Japanese translations of Tolstoy’s fiction and philosophy, and accounts of his life became more available at the end of the 19th century, his ideas on the individual, religion, society, and politics had a tremendous impact on the generation coming of age in the 1900s and his popularity grew among young intellectuals. One important legacy of Tolstoy in Japan is his particular concern with the peasantry and agricultural reform. Among those inspired by Tolstoy and the narodniki lifestyle, three individuals, Tokutomi Roka, Eto Tekirei, and Mushakoji¯ Saneatsu illustrate how prominent writers and thinkers adopted the master’s lifestyle and attempted to put his ideas into practice. In the spirit of the New Buddhists of late Meiji, they envisioned a comprehensive lifestyle structure. As Eto Tekirei moved to the village of Takaido with the assistance of Tokutomi Roka, he called his new home Hyakusho¯ Aidoj¯ o¯ (literally, Farmers Love Training Ground). He and his family endeavored to follow a Tolstoyan life, which included labor, philosophy, art, religion, society, and politics, a grand project that he saw as a “non-religious religion.” As such, Tekirei’s utopian vision might be conceived as an experiment in “alter-modernity.” Keywords: violence; nonviolence; Leo Tolstoy (1828–1910); utopianism; Japanese Buddhism; Tokutomi Roka (1868–1927); Eto Tekirei (1880–1944); Mushakoji¯ Saneatsu (1885–1976); nonresistance; agrarian way of life 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tolstoyan Episode in American Social Thought 49
    the tolstoyan episode in american social thought harry walsh Throughout a long and creative life Leo Tolstoy trod unstintingly the path of systematic philosophical inquiry. By examining every con­ tending system and by subjecting every body of thought to intense scrutiny, he was able at last to integrate his ideas into a very personal doctrine called tolstovstvo in Russian and referred to in these pages as Tolstoyism. Between Tolstoy's literary debut in 1852 and the late 1880's, when he first became known in America, Tolstoy's philosophical evolution took him through a welter of often contradictory beliefs. Taken as a stadial development, his works form a logical progression toward an ideal, but if they are to be viewed all at once, then their overall design is obscured. In nineteenth-century Russia the observant reader was able to plot the course by which Tolstoy's tireless mind moved successively from one idea to another. Thus the perceptive critic Mikhailovsky was able to predict with some accuracy the future direc­ tion of Tolstoy's literary efforts after reading Part Seven of Anna Karenina, wherein is described the shattering revelation that transformed Tolstoy's life and work. The author of The Cossacks and War and Peace came to be disowned by the man who wrote Confession and The Death of Ivan Ilyich. The American readership, however, received the young Tolstoy with the old. Whereas in 1885 only a single translation of The Cossacks was available to the American reader, by 1890 there were 34 titles in print, and a twenty-volume set of Tolstoy's collected works would soon appear.1 By reading only two of these works one might en­ counter both a defender of Orthodoxy and an apostate, an aristocrat and a muzhik, a pacifist and a militant nationalist, an advocate of family happiness and a preacher of celibacy and sexual continence, an objective observer of human behavior and an apostle.
    [Show full text]
  • Econometrics, Practice Questions, ECO54 Udayan Roy These Questions Are Based on Chapter 11 of the Ordinary Business of Life by R
    Econometrics, Practice Questions, ECO54 Udayan Roy These questions are based on chapter 11 of The Ordinary Business of Life by Roger Backhouse and Chapter 16 of History of Economic Thought, Fourth Edition, by Harry Landreth and David Colander. The latter item was distributed as a handout in class. If you do not have it, please pick up your copy from the economics department’s offices. 1. On the issue of using observed facts to test economic theories, which of the following is correct? a. Most economists believe that their theories of how the economy works must be tested against real-world events and data. However, there is more disagreement on the proper procedure for the use of data to test theories. b. Few economists believe that their theories of how the economy works must be tested against real-world events and data. However, most economists agree on the proper procedure for the use of data to test theories, if such testing is done. c. As economists generally cannot do controlled experiments to test their theories, most economists believe that it is futile to try to use real-world data to test their theories. d. Most economists believe that their theories of how the economy works must be tested against real-world events and data. Most economists agree that the only proper procedure for such testing is to run controlled experiments. 2. According to Ragnar Frisch, a Norwegian economist who became a pioneer of the subject, econometrics a. Is the expression of economic theory in mathematical terms b. Refers to the collection of data to describe an economy quantitatively c.
    [Show full text]
  • Aggregation Problem in Demand Analysis, 1930S-1950S
    Aggregation Problem in Demand Analysis, 1930s-1950s Hugo Chu∗ Abstract This article examines the emergence of the representative agent as the outcome of trans- formations that occurred in microeconomics in the 1930s-1950s years, especially in the subfield of demand theory. To tell this story, I begin with a particular historical inter- pretation of this subfield, propounded by Wade Hands and Philip Mirowski in the 1990s, known as the Hotelling-Schultz Impasse. Although this impasse was abandoned by the end of the 1930s, the testing of the Symmetry Restrictions and the validity of the Integra- bility Conditions continued to draw the attention of different research centers. The Cowles Commission, represented by its research director, Tjalling Koopmans, played an impor- tant role during this stage and, more to the point, in the subsequent emergence of the representative agent in microeconomics through their approach to aggregation problem. The significance of Paul Samuelson's introduction of homothetic preferences into General Equilibrium Theory and its connection to Koopmans's writings during the 1950s is also emphasized. Keywords: Representative Agent, Aggregation Problem, Tjalling Koopmans Resumo O presente artigo examina a emerg^enciado agente representativo como resultado da trans- forma¸c~aoque ocorreu na economia nos anos de 1930 a 1950, especialmente no subcampo da teoria da demanda. Para contar essa hist´oria,eu come¸cocom uma interpreta¸c~aohist´orica particular proposta por Wade Hands e Philip Mirowski nos anos de 1990 conhecido como o Impasse de Hotelling-Schultz. Embora esse impasse tenha sido abandonado ao final da d´ecadade 1930, o teste da Restri¸c~aode Simetria e a validade das Condi¸c~oesde Integrabil- idade continuou a chamar aten¸c~aode diferentes centros de pesquisas.
    [Show full text]