Mass Migration, Cheap Labor, and Innovation∗

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Mass Migration, Cheap Labor, and Innovation∗ Mass Migration, Cheap Labor, and Innovation∗ David Andersson† Mounir Karadja‡ Erik Prawitz§ August 2017 Please click here for the most updated version. Abstract Migration is often depicted as a major problem for struggling developing countries, as they may lose valuable workers and human capital. Yet, its effects on sending regions are ambiguous and depend crucially on local market responses and migrant selection. This paper studies the effects of migration on technological innovation in sending communities during one of the largest migration episodes in human history: the Age of Mass Migration (1850–1913). Using novel historical data on Sweden, where about a quarter of its population migrated, we find that migration caused an increase in technological patents in sending municipalities. To establish causality, we use an instrumental variable design that exploits severe local growing season frost shocks to- gether with within-country travel costs to reach an emigration port. Exploring possible mechanisms, we suggest that increased labor costs, due to low-skilled emigration, in- duced technological innovation. JEL Codes: O15, O31, O33. ∗We thank Torsten Persson, David Str¨omberg and Jakob Svensson for their guidance and support. We are grateful for comments and advice received from Philippe Aghion, Konrad Burchardi, Francisco Buera, Jon de Quidt, Nathan Lane, Andreas Madestam, Peter Nilsson, Nathan Nunn, Maria Petrova and Per Pettersson-Lidbom, as well as numerous seminar participants. †Department of Business Studies, Uppsala University. ‡Department of Economics, Uppsala University. §Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University, and Research Institute of Industrial Economics. 1 1 Introduction Migration is often depicted as a major problem for struggling developing countries. While they may lose human capital and reduce their available workforce, the effects of migration on sending regions are ambiguous and surprisingly understudied. With the number of in- ternational migrants continuing to grow rapidly worldwide, studying the consequences of migration remains highly important.1 This paper presents an empirical analysis of the short- and long-term effects of migration on technological innovation in sending communities. While the effects of immigration on innovative activity have received increasing attention in the literature (see e.g. Hunt & Gauthier-Loiselle, 2010; Borjas & Doran, 2012; Hornung, 2014; Moser, Voena & Waldinger, 2014), the effects in the regions left behind remain poorly studied. Theoretically, migration may affect innovation in sending regions for different reasons. For example, it may affect innovative activity through its effects on human capital. Emigration can lead to “brain drain” (Kwok & Leland, 1982), if migrants are high-skilled, or “brain gain”, if migrants return home with accumulated human capital (Borjas & Bratsberg, 1996; Dustmann, Fadlon & Weiss, 2011). Instead, if migrants are low-skilled, the main concern may be another. By its nature, emigration can produce a shortage of labor. Labor scarcity and increasing wages could in themselves discourage the innovation of new technologies, by reducing firm profits as well as the workforce that would use them (Ricardo, 1951; Acemoglu, 2010). On the other hand, high wages may also induce the innovation of new labor-saving technologies (Hicks, 1932; Habakkuk, 1962; Acemoglu, 2010).2 Our analysis takes a historical perspective and examines one of the largest migration episodes in human history: the Age of Mass Migration. Between 1850 and World War I, nearly 30 million Europeans left their home soil and crossed the Atlantic Sea for the United States. We focus on Sweden, where as many as a quarter of the initial population emigrated. At the onset of its transatlantic migration experience, Sweden was in many regards similar to other underdeveloped countries of today. It was primarily an agrarian society abundant in low-wage workers and its production processes were highly labor intensive. The determinants behind the Swedish, and more broadly the Scandinavian, catch-up miracle of the decades before the war have been extensively debated by economists and economic historians (e.g. Wicksell, 1882; O’Rourke & Williamson, 1995; Ljungberg, 1996). While the sources of this 1In 2015, as many as 244 million international migrants lived outside their country of origin, an increase of 41 percent, compared to 2000 (United Nations, 2015). 2Crucially, technological innovation may respond in different ways depending on if technology reduces or increases the marginal product of labor (Acemoglu, 2010). Thus, while labor scarcity increases the incentives to invent labor-saving technology, the opposite would be the case for technology that constitutes a complement to labor. 2 transformation remain disputed, it is well established that Swedish wages went from being below the West European average in the 1860s to the level of British wages in 1914. Less attention has been paid to the remarkable speed of technological progress. Described as a technological revolution, this era saw a vast increase in mechanized equipment, which arguably had the most profound effect on the nature of economic development (Heckscher, 1941). Concurrent with the mass departure of predominantly low-skilled workers, innovations surged, and at the turn of the century, after about a quarter of its initial population had left the country, the number of technological patents reached record high levels. Shedding light on the “black box” of technological progress, this paper asks if and to what extent migration may have played a role in this development. To measure the effects of migration on innovation, we use a novel and personally digitized data set covering the universe of all technological patents in Sweden between the mid 19th century and World War I. We combine it with data from church books and shipping line records covering all Swedish migrants, both emigrants and immigrants, for the relevant period, to construct a data set at the municipal level. Our main empirical framework compares long-term changes in innovative activity be- tween municipalities within the same region, but with different emigration histories. To obtain exogenous variation in cumulative migration, we employ an instrumental variable strategy making use of two sources of variation.3 First, it is well-recognized that a series of harvest failures, caused by unusually poor weather conditions, was crucial as a push factor for the first wave of large scale migration (see e.g. Sundb¨arg, 1913; Thomas, 1941; Barton, 1994; Beijbom, 1995). To capture the importance of harvest failures, we construct a mea- sure of frost incidence during growing seasons at the onset of mass migration. Second, since predominantly two ports where used in the early stages of the emigration episode (Gothen- burg and Malm¨o),we capture the travel cost of emigrating by calculating the distance to the nearest emigration port.4 Interacting these two sources of variation, the idea behind the instrument rests on the notion that a negative shock to agriculture increased migration rates and especially so if migration costs were low. Due to Swedish migration being highly path dependent (Runblom & Norman, 1976; Beijbom, 1995; Hatton, 1995), something we also document, we can strongly predict not only the first wave of migration, but emigration during the entire mass migration period. 3Our identification strategy is similar to the one employed in a companion paper by two of the authors of this paper (Karadja & Prawitz, 2016). 4It is well established in the migration literature that travel costs constitute an important part of the migration decision (see e.g. Quigley, 1972; Morten & Oliveira, 2014). Studying the effects of emigration on regional wage convergence, Enflo, Lundh & Prado(2014) use the distance to Gothenburg as an instrument for emigration. 3 Constructing our instrument as an interaction between a negative shock to agriculture and a proxy for emigration travel costs, enables us to control for the direct effects these two variables may have by themselves. Therefore, we can arguably overcome typical threats to exclusion restrictions with instruments capturing push factors of migration. In a balance test, we document that our instrument is not systematically related to baseline characteristics. And in a placebo test, we show that frost shocks during non growing seasons, constructed in the same fashion as our growing season counterparts, do not affect emigration, nor do they have an effect on other outcome variables. Our results show that in the long run, emigration caused an increase in technological innovations in origin municipalities. Our IV estimates report that a ten percent increase in the number of emigrants during the main Swedish transatlantic emigration period 1867– 1900 would have increased the number of patents by roughly 6 percent. Moreover, weighting patents by a measure of their economic value, using information on patent fees paid, we find an even stronger positive effect on innovations. Our results are robust to the inclusion of several baseline controls as well as a variety of different specifications. In the second part of our analysis, we attempt to understand the underlying mechanism of our main result. We start by studying the timing of the effects of migration. While it is possible that migration had a negative short-term impact on innovation, e.g. through “brain drain”, our estimates suggest that patents were positively affected shortly after migration
Recommended publications
  • The Old Privileges and the New Spirit of Law: Jewish Residential Areas in the Duchy of Warsaw
    Studia Judaica 23 (2020), nr 1 (45), s. 43–74 doi:10.4467/24500100STJ.20.002.12916 Aleksandra Oniszczuk https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5562-9058 The Old Privileges and the New Spirit of Law: Jewish Residential Areas in the Duchy of Warsaw Abstract: Among the most important aspects of government policy aimed at Jews in the nineteenth-century Polish lands was the issue of where Jews could reside. Medieval in its roots, the conviction that some form of separation was needed was vested in contemporary arguments. Pertinent in this context was the stance taken by the authorities of the Duchy of Warsaw. The article discusses the ques- tion whether old city privileges imposing restrictions on Jews were in force at that time. The author claims—contrary to previous historiography—that this question cannot be reduced to a simple “yes” or “no” answer. Referring to the concepts of sociology of law, the double dimension of law (law in books and law in action) can be identified. The issue may serve as an interesting example of legal pluralism and the power of law-convictions. Based on ministerial and local correspondence, the analysis leads to two ma- jor conclusions. First, while in theory old city privileges were no longer in force— and this was clearly stated by ministers—the latter decided to refrain from an- nouncing this to the public. Moreover, they agreed to develop an unofficial policy of resolving some cases “as if the old privileges were still binding.” Second, the officially introduced concept of district (rewir) was designed to replace the old privileges, as it offered a variety of new justifications.
    [Show full text]
  • Sigismund of Luxembourg's Pledgings in Hungary
    DOI: 10.14754/CEU.2018.10 Doctoral Dissertation “Our Lord the King Looks for Money in Every Corner” Sigismund of Luxembourg’s Pledgings in Hungary By: János Incze Supervisor(s): Katalin Szende, Balázs Nagy Submitted to the Medieval Studies Department, and the Doctoral School of History Central European University, Budapest in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Medieval Studies, and for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in History CEU eTD Collection Budapest, Hungary 2018 DOI: 10.14754/CEU.2018.10 Table of Contents Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 3 Chapter 1. Pledging and Borrowing in Late Medieval Monarchies: an Overview ......................... 9 Western Europe ......................................................................................................................... 11 Central Europe and Scandinavia ............................................................................................... 16 Chapter 2. The Price of Ascending to the Throne ........................................................................ 26 Preceding events ....................................................................................................................... 26 The Váh-Danube interfluve under Moravian rule .................................................................... 29 Regaining the territory .............................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Guilds, Towns, and Cultural Transmission in the North, 1300-1500
    Guilds, Towns, and Cultural Transmission in the North, 1300-1500 Guilds, Towns Ombr NY 6.8.indd 1 17/10/13 08.44 Guilds, Towns, and Cultural Transmission in the North, 1300-1500 Lars Bisgaard Lars Boje Mortensen Tom Pettitt UNIVERSITY PRESS OF SOUTHERN DENMARK 2013 Guilds, Towns Ombr NY 6.8.indd 2 17/10/13 08.44 Guilds, Towns, and Cultural Transmission in the North, 1300-1500 Lars Bisgaard Lars Boje Mortensen Tom Pettitt UNIVERSITY PRESS OF SOUTHERN DENMARK 2013 Guilds, Towns Ombr NY 6.8.indd 3 17/10/13 08.44 © The authors and University Press of Southern Denmark 2013 Printed by Narayana Press Cover Design by Donald Jensen Cover illustration: The banquet of king Ahasveros on the retable of the Corpus Christi Guild in Lübeck. © St. Annen-Museum – Fotoarchiv der Hansestadt Lübeck. ISBN 978 87 7674 557 8 Printed with grant support from: The Nordic Centre for Medieval Studies Publikationsudvalget ved Det Humanistiske Fakultet Syddansk Universitet Editorial assistant: Réka Forrai University Press of Southern Denmark Campusvej 55 DK-5230 Odense M www.universitypress.dk Distribution in the United States and Canada: International Specialized Book Services 5804 NE Hassalo Street Portland, OR 97213-3644 USA www.isbs.com Distribution in the United Kingdom: Gazelle White Cross Mills Hightown Lancaster LA1 4 XS U.K. www.gazellebookservices.co.uk Guilds, Towns Ombr NY ret.indd 4 25/10/13 10.57 Table of Contents Introduction: Late Medieval Urban Civilization and its North European Variant 7 Lars Boje Mortensen and Lars Bisgaard Late Medieval Migration across the Baltic: The Movement of People between Northern Germany and Denmark 31 Bjørn Poulsen How Middle Low German Entered the Mainland Scandinavian Languages 57 Kurt Braunmüller Water or Beer? Anti-German Sentiments in Scandinavia in the Late Middle Ages.
    [Show full text]
  • Transplanting Swedish Law? the Legal Sources at the Livonian Courts 238 5.1 the Theory of Legal Spheres 238 5.2 the Ius Commune in the Livonian Court Records 239
    Conquest and the Law in Swedish Livonia (ca. 1630–1710) <UN> The Northern World North Europe and the Baltic c. 400–1700 ad. Peoples, Economics and Cultures Editors Jón Viðar Sigurðsson (Oslo) Ingvild Øye (Bergen) Piotr Gorecki (University of California at Riverside) Steve Murdoch (St. Andrews) Cordelia Heß (Gothenburg) Anne Pedersen (National Museum of Denmark) VOLUME 77 The titles published in this series are listed at brill.com/nw <UN> Conquest and the Law in Swedish Livonia (ca. 1630–1710) A Case of Legal Pluralism in Early Modern Europe By Heikki Pihlajamäki LEIDEN | BOSTON <UN>  This title is published in Open Access with the support of the University of Helsinki Library. This is an open access title distributed under the terms of the CC BY-NC-ND 4.0 license, which permits any non-commercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided no alterations are made and the original author(s) and source are credited. Further information and the complete license text can be found at https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ The terms of the CC license apply only to the original material. The use of material from other sources (indicated by a reference) such as diagrams, illustrations, photos and text samples may require further permission from the respective copyright holder. Cover illustration: Livoniae Nova Descriptio, cartographers: Johannes Portantius and Abraham Ortelius (Antwerp 1574). Collection: National Library of Estonia, digital archive digar (http://www.digar.ee/arhiiv/ nlib-digar:977, accessed 18 August 2016). Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Names: Pihlajamaki, Heikki, 1961- author.
    [Show full text]
  • History of Slovakia
    History of Slovakia Obchodná akadémia, Veľká okružná 32, 011 57 Žilina Prehistory Slovakia's territory had been inhabited in the Palaeolithic - Nové Mesto nad Váhom, Bojnice and Gánovce. The best known artifact is the Venus of Moravany from Moravany nad Váhom. Neolithic habitation was found in Želiezovce, Gemer, the Domica cave and at Nitriansky Hrádok. 2 History of Slovakia Prehistory Bronze Age was marked by the Čakany andVelatice cultures, followed by the Calenderberg culture and the Hallstatt culture.The major Celtic tribes living in Slovakia were Cotini and Boii. The great invasions of the 4–8th centuries saw the emergence of the Huns, followed by the expansion of the Ostrogoths, Lombards, Gepids, Heruli. Eurasian Avars followed, battling the Byzantine Empire, to be replaced by the Slavs. 3 History of Slovakia The Slavs Parts of the Slavic population that settled in the Middle Danube area were unified by King Samo,after a successful Slavic insurrection against the Avar Khaganate in 623. In 631, Samo defeated the Frankish army of King Dagobert at the Battle of Wogastisburg. Samo's Empire, the first known political formation of Slavs, disappeared after the death of its founder in 665 and its territory was again included into Avar Khaganate. Around 828, Archbishop Adalram of Salzburg consecrated a church for Prince Pribina in Nitrava. In 833, Mojmír I, Duke of the Moravians, expelled Pribina. 4 History of Slovakia The era of Great Moravia Great Moravia arose around 830 when Mojmír I unified the Slavic tribes settled north of the Danube and extended the Moravian supremacy over them.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rise of Europe in the High Middle Ages: Reactions to Urban Economic Modernity 1050 - 1300
    The Rise of Europe in The High Middle Ages: Reactions to Urban Economic Modernity 1050 - 1300 Dan Yamins History Club June 2013 Sunday, October 12, 14 Today: Strands that are common throughout Europe. Next time: Two Case Studies: Hanseatic League (Northern Europe) The Italian Maritime Republics (Southern Europe) Sunday, October 12, 14 Interrelated Themes During an “Age of Great Progress” Demographic: rise of cities and general population increase Socio-economic: Rise of the middle class, burghers and capitalism Commercial: intra-European land trade and European maritime powers Legal: Development of rights charters and challenge to feudal system Labor & production: Rise of guilds and craft specialization. The time during which Europe “took off” -- switching places with Asia / Middle East in terms of social dynamism. Development of Western modernity Sunday, October 12, 14 General population increase AREA 500 650 1000 1340 1450 For context: Greece/Balkans 5 3 5 6 4.5 Italy 4 2.5 5 10 7.3 Population levels of Europe during the Middle Ages can be Spain/Portugal 4 3.5 7 9 7 roughly categorized: Total - South 13 9 17 25 19 • 150–400 (Late Antiquity): population decline France/Low countries 5 3 6 19 12 • 400–1000 (Early Middle Ages): stable at a low level. British Isles 0.5 0.5 2 5 3 • 1000–1250 (High Middle Ages): population boom and Germany/Scandinavia 3.5 2 4 11.5 7.3 expansion. Total - West/Central 9 5.5 12 35.5 22.5 • 1250–1350 (Late Middle Ages): stable at a high level. Slavia. 5 3 • 1350–1420 (Late Middle Ages): steep decline (Black death) ---Russia 6 8 6 ---Poland/Lithuania 2 3 2 • 1420–1470 (Late Middle Ages): stable at a low level.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Economics and Politics of Mobility
    On the Economics and Politics of Mobility Mounir Karadja ii © Mounir Karadja, Stockholm, 2016 ISBN 978-91-7649-448-6 ISSN 0346-6892 Cover Picture: Alexander Kircher, “M/S Kungsholm”. 1928. Public Domain. Printed in Sweden by Holmbergs, Malmö 2016 Distributor: Institute for International Economic Studies iii Doctoral Dissertation Department of Economics Stockholm University Abstract Exit, Voice and Political Change: Evidence from Swedish Mass Migration to the United States. During the Age of Mass Migration, 30 million Europeans immigrated to the United States. We study the long-term political effects of this large-scale migration episode on origin communities using detailed historical data from Sweden. To instrument for emigration, we exploit severe local frost shocks that sparked an ini- tial wave of emigration, interacted with within-country travel costs. Be- cause Swedish emigration was highly path dependent, the initial shocks strongly predict total emigration over 50 years. Our estimates show that emigration substantially increased membership in local labor organiza- tions, the strongest political opposition groups at the time. Further- more, emigration caused greater strike participation, and mobilized voter turnout and support for left-wing parties in national elections. Emigra- tion also had effects on formal political change, as measured by welfare expenditures and adoption of inclusive political institutions. Together, our findings indicate that large-scale emigration can achieve long-lasting effects on the political equilibrium in origin communities. Mass Migration and Technological Innovation at the Ori- gin. This essay studies the effects of migration on technological inno- vations in origin communities. Using historical data from Sweden, we find that migration caused a long-run increase in patent innovations in origin municipalities.
    [Show full text]
  • Alice M. Choyke and Katalin Szende Submitted to the Medieval Studies
    Doctoral Dissertation WHO STOLE THE WATER? THE CONTROL AND APPROPRIATION OF WATER RESOURCES IN MEDIEVAL HUNGARY by András Vadas Supervisors: Alice M. Choyke and Katalin Szende Submitted to the Medieval Studies Department, Central European University, Budapest in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Medieval Studies CEU eTD Collection Budapest, Hungary Budapest, 2020 TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Figures and Tables ......................................................................................................... iv Acknowledgments ................................................................................................................... viii A Note on Names ....................................................................................................................... x 1. INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................ 1 1.1. Riverine Landscapes as Conflict Environments in Pre-Modern Europe – Some Historiographic Reflections ....................................................................................................... 3 1.1.1. New Directions in Research – Where Environmental, Social, and Technological History Meet ........................................................................................................................................... 9 1.1.2. Hungary and Central Europe – Research traditions and recent results .......................... 17 1.2. The Goals of this Work ....................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter One: the Origins of the Great Transformation (1879-1900)
    THE CATHOLIC UNIVERSITY OF AMERICA Constructing the People’s Home: The Political and Economic Origins and Early Development of the “Swedish Model” (1879-1976) A DISSERTATION Submitted to the Faculty of the Department of Politics School of Arts and Sciences Of The Catholic University of America In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements For the Degree Doctor of Philosophy © Copyright All Rights Reserved By Josiah R. Baker Washington, DC 2011 Constructing the People’s Home: The Political and Economic Origins and Early Development of the “Swedish Model” (1879-1976) Josiah R. Baker Director: James P. O’Leary, Ph.D. When Marquis Childs published his book The Middle Way in 1936, he laid the foundation that inspired the quest for an efficient welfare state. The Folkhemmet, or “people’s home,” initiated by the Social Democrats symbolized the “Swedish Way” and resulted in a generous, redistributive welfare state system. By the early 1970s, experts marveled at Sweden’s performance because the Swedish model managed to produce the second-wealthiest economy as measured by per capita GDP with virtually no cyclical unemployment. This dissertation demonstrates that capitalist and pre-industrial cultural forces dominated Swedish economic policy development throughout the years that the Social Democrats constructed Folkhemmet. The Swedish economy operated as a variety of capitalism that infused unique traditional cultural characteristics into a “feudal capitalism.” The system was far more market-oriented, deregulated, and free from direct government ownership or control than most assumed then or now. A process of negotiation and reason, mixed with pragmatism and recognition of valuing opportunity over principles, drove Swedish modernization.
    [Show full text]
  • Zurich's Coins – a Short History Through Time
    Zurich's Coins – a Short History through Time By Calista Fischer, © MoneyMuseum (Translated by Graham Pascoe) From the Ladies' convent Fraumünster in the Middle Ages to the introduction of the Swiss franc in the 19th century, many important steps may be observed. The coins of the free city of Zurich bear witness of that fact: they document trade and commerce in Europe of the past 1200 years. 1 von 31 www.sunflower.ch Paradeplatz Zurich – Switzerland's international metropolis of finance and trade, where countless banks have their headquarters. Billions of Swiss francs are traded at the stock exchange every day and business people from all over the world are busily crossing paths. Switzerland is cosmopolitan in Zurich where sciences and politics are also actively pursued. If you're lucky you will even meet Nobel prizewinners and federal councilors on the street. Zurich is also a cultural city, offering a wide range of events at the stately Opera House right down to the tiniest alternative armchair theatre. In short: there's a buzz to Zurich. Or as they say in French: "Zurich, c'est une grande ville dans un mouchoir" (Zurich is a big city in a handkerchief). How did the town on the Limmat River get its reputation? Was it for its central location on the blue lake or for the fresh air? Find out here how Zurich became what it is today. 2 von 31 www.sunflower.ch Regensburg – Turegum/Zurich July 21, 853 AD. The weather was oppressively hot. Everything seemed quiet in the East Frankish Empire.
    [Show full text]
  • Conceptualization of the Historic Mining Towns in Slovakia in the Institutional, Urban-Physiological and Urban- Morphological Context
    QUOTATION: Matlovič R., Matlovičová K., Kolesárová J. (2014): Conceptualization of the historic mining towns in Slovakia in the institutional, urban-physiological and urban-morphological context. In Radics, Z., Penczes, J. (Eds), 2014. Enhancing competitiveness of V4 historic cities to develop tourism. Spatial-economic cohesion and competitivness in the context of tourism. Debrecen, 2014. ISBN 978-615-5212-22-2, s. 165-193 René Matlovič – Kvetoslava Matlovičová – Jana Kolesárová CONCEPTUALIZATION OF THE HISTORIC MINING TOWNS IN SLOVAKIA IN THE INSTITUTIONAL, URBAN-PHYSIOLOGICAL AND URBAN- MORPHOLOGICAL CONTEXT Introduction The issue of strengthening the competitiveness of towns has an increasing importance in contemporary globalizing world. The gradual removal of barriers and increasing information linkages of today's world, expose individual towns to the hyper-competitive environment. Towns compete with each other in order to attract financial and human capital. Globalization brings certain unifying tendencies, but on the other hand, it also encourages cities to become different in some ways and attractive to the inflows of financial capital, residents, and visitors. Individual cities are, therefore, seeking to strengthen their competitiveness. In these efforts, it can be observed a rising tendency to apply the tools of territorial marketing and branding. These statements are particularly true in case of the historic towns possessing cultural heritage in the form of material relics and specific atmosphere (genius loci), which are related to their previous functions. If such potential is subject to proper preservation and promotion, it can be further exploited especially in the tourism industry. Historic towns, therefore, face the challenge of how to use this potential of cultural heritage and apply it on the market.
    [Show full text]
  • Ethnic and Class Identity Formation Within the Germans of Hungary
    ETHNIC AND CLASS IDENTITY FORMATION WITHIN THE GERMANS OF HUNGARY Balázs A. Szelényi The National Council for Eurasian and East European Research 910 17th Street, N.W. Suite 300 Washington, D.C. 20006 TITLE VIII PROGRAM Project Information* Principal Investigator: Balázs Szelényi Council Contract Number: 818-15g Date: October 22, 2004 Copyright Information Individual researchers retain the copyright on their work products derived from research funded through a contract or grant from the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research (NCEEER). However, the NCEEER and the United States Government have the right to duplicate and disseminate, in written and electronic form, reports submitted to NCEEER to fulfill Contract or Grant Agreements either (a) for NCEEER’s own internal use, or (b) for use by the United States Government, and as follows: (1) for further dissemination to domestic, international, and foreign governments, entities and/or individuals to serve official United States Government purposes or (2) for dissemination in accordance with the Freedom of Information Act or other law or policy of the United States Government granting the public access to documents held by the United States Government. Neither NCEEER nor the United States Government nor any recipient of this Report may use it for commercial sale. * The work leading to this report was supported in part by contract or grant funds provided by the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research, funds which were made available by the U.S. Department of State under Title VIII (The Soviet-East European Research and Training Act of 1983, as amended). The analysis and interpretations contained herein are those of the author.
    [Show full text]