The Information Content of Put Warrant Issues

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Information Content of Put Warrant Issues The Information Content of Put Warrant Issues Scott Gibson a Paul Povel b Rajdeep Singh b February 2006 a Department of Economics and Finance, School of Business, College of William and Mary, Williamsburg, VA 23187. b Department of Finance, Carlson School of Management, University of Minnesota, 321 19th Avenue South, Minneapolis, MN 55455. Email: [email protected] (Gibson), [email protected] (Povel) and [email protected] (Singh). We are grateful to Sugato Bhattacharyya, Francesca Cornelli, Gustavo Grullon, Dirk Jenter, Jack Kareken, Ross Levine, Bob McDonald, Roni Michaely, Sheridan Titman, Andrew Winton, and seminar participants at the 11th annual Financial Economics and Accounting conference at Ann Arbor, MI, and at University of Minnesota and Cornell University for their helpful comments. The Information Content of Put Warrant Issues Abstract We analyze why ¯rms may want to issue put warrants, i.e., promises to repurchase their own shares at a given price in the future. We describe four alternative explanations, one of which is novel: that put warrants are issued by ¯rms that wish to signal their good future prospects to their investors (who undervalue the ¯rms in the eyes of their managers). We test the validity of the four alternative explanations, using a new, hand-collected data set on put warrant issues in the U.S. between 1993 and 1999. We ¯nd evidence that is inconsistent with three of the four explanations. Only the signaling explanation is consistent with the empirical evidence. Put warrant issuers strongly outperform their peers in the years after the put warrant issues; they enjoy valuable and improving investment opportunities, and they invest heavily. Put warrant issuers are thus very di®erent from other ¯rms with ongoing open market share repurchase programs. JEL codes: G35, G32, D82 Key Words: Put warrants; share repurchases; signaling 1 Introduction Corporate-issued put warrants give investors the right to sell shares back to the ¯rm at a future date at a ¯xed strike price. In return, the ¯rm receives an upfront tax-free cash premium. The amounts involved can be large: the most proli¯c issuer of put warrants, Microsoft Corp., collected $1.9bn between 1994 and 1999. However, put warrants expose the issuing ¯rm to potentially large liabilities, if the share price moves below the strike price. In 2000, Microsoft Corp. had potential put warrant obligations of over $11bn outstanding; during the ¯scal year 2001, the company decided to abort its put warrant program, and it spent over $1.4bn to repurchase outstanding put warrants. Thus, issuing put warrants can yield tax-free income for a ¯rm, but that brings with it potentially large and costly ¯nancial obligations. In this paper we analyze why ¯rms may want to expose themselves to this risk. We consider explanations that can be found in the media and the literature, and we develop a new explanation. We then test the validity of these explanations, using a new, hand-collected data set. Put warrants, and the reasons for issuing them, have not been systematically analyzed before. One possible explanation for their use is that put warrants allow ¯rms to synthesize an open market share repurchase: instead of going through a broker, ¯rms can use derivatives to schedule regular repurchases at certain prices (see Grullon and Ikenberry (2000)). Doing so may allow the ¯rm to reduce the transaction costs of regular share repurchases, and to avoid market imbalances if its shares are not traded in a liquid market. This explanation, which we term the transaction costs explanation, suggests that put warrant issuers are ¯rms with illiquid share markets, for example smaller ¯rms. A second possible explanation has to do with stock option compensation, and the di- lution caused to existing shareholders. Some media commentators have argued that put warrants simplify share repurchases motivated by the exercise of such stock options, by us- 1 ing derivatives for the repurchases, too. In fact, some ¯rms purchased call options on their own shares. However, these were usually accompanied by the issue of an equal or larger number of put warrants, which do not link share repurchases with stock option exercise as claimed. Nevertheless, we examine the idea that put warrant issues may be more attractive for ¯rms that make heavier use of stock option compensation. The dilution explanation implies that put warrant issuers are no di®erent from other ¯rms that have ongoing share repurchase programs, except for the presence of signi¯cant option compensation programs for their executives or employees. Thus, put warrants should be issued mainly by ¯rms that o®er employees signi¯cant option compensation, such as high-tech ¯rms (see Anderson et al. (2000) and Ittner et al. (2003)). A third possibility is that ¯rms (potentially) su®ering from the \free cash flow problem" (see Jensen (1986)) issue put warrants. The agency explanation suggests that put warrant issuers are mature ¯rms, characterized by strong, stable cash flows and few or no investment opportunities. Such ¯rms may undertake bad investments, simply because managers prefer to re-invest spare cash to paying it out to shareholders. One way for managers to commit not to waste spare cash is to credibly promise to pay it out, which can be achieved with put warrants. A fourth alternative explanation is that put warrant issues signal good news to investors. The signaling explanation predicts that only ¯rms with good prospects (compared with the market's expectations) will issue put warrants, since ¯rms with poor prospects ¯nd them more costly than ¯rms with good prospects. Firms can use a variety of methods to signal good news to their investors.1 Put warrants have the bene¯t that they may be costless, or even a pro¯table way of signaling: Microsoft Corp. (and other issuers) prided themselves of having issued put warrants quarter after quarter, and not a single one was exercised. The contribution of this paper is twofold. First, we develop the signaling explanation 1See Grullon and Ikenberry (2000); Allen and Michaely (2003); Grullon and Michaely (2002); or Grullon and Michaely (2004). 2 for put warrant issues, i.e., we show theoretically how and under what conditions put war- rants can be used to support a separating equilibrium. Second, we test the merits of this explanation and the alternative explanations empirically, using a new, hand-collected data set. An example can illustrate the idea of the signaling explanation. In late 1994, AT&T announced that it would team up with a local ¯rm to enter the Mexican telecommuni- cations market in 1997, competing with Telmex (Telefonos de Mexico), the Mexican tele- phone monopoly, instead of cooperating with it. At the time, uncertainty existed about future deregulation moves of the Mexican government, and about the prospects for di®erent telecommunications markets in Mexico (long-distance service; local markets; cellular phone operations; etc.) Telmex' share price had been in decline for two weeks after the news hit. To stop this decline, its controlling shareholder, Carlos Slim Helu, announced that he would issue put warrants for Telmex stock, with a maturity of twelve months. The total potential liability if the put warrants were exercised amounted to $450m.2 The put warrant issue was meant to reassure investors that Telmex was in a strong position. Put warrants are similar to a money-back guarantee: if shareholders are not satis¯ed with the shares they purchased (because their price fell), they have the right to sell these shares back at a certain price. Clearly, such an o®er will be made only if the chances of actually having to pay up are not too large. Thus, with a su±ciently large o®er, investors should realize that the ¯rm issuing put warrants must have better prospects than expected: if the prospects were worse than investors expected, the put warrants could turn out to be very costly for the ¯rm. In other words, an appropriately structured issue can convey good news to investors, private information that would otherwise be hard for management to convey in a credible way.3 2See \Mexico's Slim Makes Big Bet On Telmex," Wall Street Journal, November 23, 1994. A similar story, featuring WMX Technologies Inc., is described in \WMX sells options in buyback strategy involving less cash," Wall Street Journal, April 11, 1994. 3In an information brochure about stock buybacks, the investment bank Salomon Brothers emphasizes the possible use of put warrants to send a positive signal to investors: \. put warrants send a positive 3 Importantly, the net costs of using put warrants to signal are zero: ¯rms that issue put warrants earn a cash premium at the time of issue, and in a separating equilibrium, the put warrants are priced fairly, so the expected cash outflow is o®set by the cash premium. In contrast, if a ¯rm with poor prospects tries to fool investors by issuing put warrants, it should expect to su®er a large and costly cash outflow when the put warrants mature, larger than the amount it collected when issuing the puts. If ¯rms with good prospects choose the right structure for their issue, then ¯rms with poor prospects will not imitate them, and investors will understand the signals and price the put warrants (and the shares) fairly. Necessary conditions for such costless (\non-dissipative") signaling have been analyzed in Brennan and Kraus (1987) and Nachman and Noe (1994). Our model focuses on put warrants, which have been issued in practice, showing that they satisfy the necessary conditions. This contrasts with other signaling models in which ¯rms use payout policy to signal inside information to outside investors. In contrast to ours, these models are based on costly signaling (see, e.g., Bhattacharya (1979), Miller and Rock (1985), Vermaelen (1984), Ofer and Thakor (1987), and Constantinides and Grundy (1989)).
Recommended publications
  • Asset Swaps and Credit Derivatives
    PRODUCT SUMMARY A SSET S WAPS Creating Synthetic Instruments Prepared by The Financial Markets Unit Supervision and Regulation PRODUCT SUMMARY A SSET S WAPS Creating Synthetic Instruments Joseph Cilia Financial Markets Unit August 1996 PRODUCT SUMMARIES Product summaries are produced by the Financial Markets Unit of the Supervision and Regulation Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Product summaries are pub- lished periodically as events warrant and are intended to further examiner understanding of the functions and risks of various financial markets products relevant to the banking industry. While not fully exhaustive of all the issues involved, the summaries provide examiners background infor- mation in a readily accessible form and serve as a foundation for any further research into a par- ticular product or issue. Any opinions expressed are the authors’ alone and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System. Should the reader have any questions, comments, criticisms, or suggestions for future Product Summary topics, please feel free to call any of the members of the Financial Markets Unit listed below. FINANCIAL MARKETS UNIT Joseph Cilia(312) 322-2368 Adrian D’Silva(312) 322-5904 TABLE OF CONTENTS Asset Swap Fundamentals . .1 Synthetic Instruments . .1 The Role of Arbitrage . .2 Development of the Asset Swap Market . .2 Asset Swaps and Credit Derivatives . .3 Creating an Asset Swap . .3 Asset Swaps Containing Interest Rate Swaps . .4 Asset Swaps Containing Currency Swaps . .5 Adjustment Asset Swaps . .6 Applied Engineering . .6 Structured Notes . .6 Decomposing Structured Notes . .7 Detailing the Asset Swap .
    [Show full text]
  • Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in Conservatorship: Frequently Asked Questions
    Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in Conservatorship: Frequently Asked Questions Updated May 31, 2019 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R44525 Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac in Conservatorship: Frequently Asked Questions Summary Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are chartered by Congress as government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs) to provide liquidity in the mortgage market and promote homeownership for underserved groups and locations. The GSEs purchase mortgages, retain the credit risk (for a fee), and package them into mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) that they either keep as investments or sell to institutional investors. In the years following the housing and mortgage market turmoil that began around 2007, the GSEs experienced financial difficulty. By 2008, the GSEs’ financial condition had weakened, generating concerns over their ability to meet their combined obligations on $1.2 trillion in bonds and $3.7 trillion in MBSs that they had guaranteed at the time. In response, the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), the GSEs’ primary regulator, took control of them in a process known as conservatorship. Subject to the terms of the Senior Preferred Stock Purchase Agreements (PSPAs) between the U.S. Treasury and the GSEs, Treasury provided funds to keep the GSEs solvent. The GSEs initially agreed to pay Treasury a 10% cash dividend on funds received, and dividends were suspended for all other GSE stockholders. If the GSEs had enough profit at the end of the quarter, the dividend came out of the profit. When the GSEs did not have enough cash to pay their dividend to Treasury, they asked for additional cash to make the payment instead of issuing additional stock.
    [Show full text]
  • Collateralized Loan Obligations (Clos) July 2021 ASSET MANAGEMENT | FACT SHEET
    ® Collateralized Loan Obligations (CLOs) July 2021 ASSET MANAGEMENT | FACT SHEET Conning believes that CLOs are a compelling asset class for insurers in today’s market. As floating-rate securities, they offer income protection in varying market environments while also minimizing duration. At the same time, CLO securities (i.e. tranches) typically offer higher yields than similarly rated corporate bonds and other structured products. The asset class also provides strong capital preservation through structural protections and investor-oriented covenants. Historically, the CLO structure has proven to be extremely resilient through multiple market cycles. In fact there has never been a default in the AAA and AA -rated CLO debt tranches.1 Negative correlation to U.S. Treasury Bonds and low correlations to U.S. investment grade corporate bonds and equities present valuable diversification benefits. CLOs also offer an opportunity to access debt issuers that do not participate in the high-yield bond markets. How CLOs Work Team The CLO collateral manager purchases a portfolio of loans (typically 150-300) Andrew Gordon using the proceeds from the sale of CLO tranches (debt & equity). The interest Octagon, CEO earned from the loan collateral pool is used to pay the coupon to the CLO liabili- 37 years of experience ties. The residual cash flow, after paying the interest on the CLO liabilities and all expenses, is distributed to the holders of the CLO equity. Notably, loan portfolio Gretchen Lam, CFA losses are first absorbed by these equity investors. CLOs are typically rated by Octagon, Senior Portfolio Manager S&P, Moody’s and / or Fitch.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation Expectations and the News
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES Inflation Expectations and the News Michael D. Bauer Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2014 Working Paper 2014-09 http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/wp2014-09.pdf The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Inflation Expectations and the News Michael D. Bauer∗ March 27, 2014 Abstract This paper provides new evidence on the importance of inflation expectations for vari- ation in nominal interest rates, based on both market-based and survey-based measures of inflation expectations. Using the information in TIPS breakeven rates and inflation swap rates, I document that movements in inflation compensation are important for explaining variation in long-term nominal interest rates, both unconditionally as well as conditionally on macroeconomic data surprises. Daily changes in inflation compensation and changes in long-term nominal rates generally display a close statistical relationship. The sensitivity of inflation compensation to macroeconomic data surprises is substantial, and it explains a sizable share of the macro response of nominal rates. The paper also documents that survey expectations of inflation exhibit significant comovement with variation in nominal interest rates, as well as significant responses to macroeconomic news. Keywords: inflation expectations, macroeconomic
    [Show full text]
  • Derivative Instruments and Hedging Activities
    www.pwc.com 2015 Derivative instruments and hedging activities www.pwc.com Derivative instruments and hedging activities 2013 Second edition, July 2015 Copyright © 2013-2015 PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, a Delaware limited liability partnership. All rights reserved. PwC refers to the United States member firm, and may sometimes refer to the PwC network. Each member firm is a separate legal entity. Please see www.pwc.com/structure for further details. This publication has been prepared for general information on matters of interest only, and does not constitute professional advice on facts and circumstances specific to any person or entity. You should not act upon the information contained in this publication without obtaining specific professional advice. No representation or warranty (express or implied) is given as to the accuracy or completeness of the information contained in this publication. The information contained in this material was not intended or written to be used, and cannot be used, for purposes of avoiding penalties or sanctions imposed by any government or other regulatory body. PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP, its members, employees and agents shall not be responsible for any loss sustained by any person or entity who relies on this publication. The content of this publication is based on information available as of March 31, 2013. Accordingly, certain aspects of this publication may be superseded as new guidance or interpretations emerge. Financial statement preparers and other users of this publication are therefore cautioned to stay abreast of and carefully evaluate subsequent authoritative and interpretative guidance that is issued. This publication has been updated to reflect new and updated authoritative and interpretative guidance since the 2012 edition.
    [Show full text]
  • The Concept and Federal Crime of Mortgage Fraud
    THE CONCEPT AND FEDERAL CRIME OF MORTGAGE FRAUD Matthew A. Edwards* ABSTRACT The impact of mortgage fraud on the United States ®nancial and economic sys- tem during the past twenty years has been severe and enduring. Nothing illus- trates this fact better than the 2007±2008 ®nancial crisis. Scholars and policymakers are convinced that the explosion in so-called liar's loans, which were securitized and sold to investors, played a key role in either causing or ex- acerbating the housing bubble and ®nancial meltdown that led to the Great Recession. Unfortunately, efforts to understand and address the problem of mortgage fraud are undermined by fundamental confusion regarding the nature of mort- gage fraud as a federal criminal offense. Some of this confusion is due to the fact that there is no single federal mortgage fraud statute. Thus, almost every legal actor relies on the FBI's de®nition of mortgage fraud. Surprisingly, however, the in¯uential FBI de®nition is plainly inconsistent in key respects with elements of the federal criminal statutes most often used to punish mortgage fraud. We should be concerned that the FBI, which investigates mortgage fraud, cannot get the basic de®nition of the crime of mortgage fraud rightÐand that scholars and commentators uncritically accept and use that problematic de®nition. This Article provides scholars and lawmakers with an understanding of the meaning of mortgage fraud as a federal crime. In particular, it makes three prac- tical contributions to public policy discourse regarding mortgage fraud. First, this Article distinguishes mortgage origination fraud from securities fraud involving mortgage-backed securities and other ®nancial crimes related to the housing market.
    [Show full text]
  • Dividend Warrant Interest Warrant Wikipedia
    Dividend Warrant Interest Warrant Wikipedia RubensBartolomei photoelectrically still waived blamably and bombinate while unknowable so guilelessly! Cristopher Topazine beweeping and inflexible that senators. Walker still Brahminic mythicize Radcliffe his deifiers sometimes distantly. embrocating his This msp account begins again if any substantive discussions, dividend warrant interest CDA Capital Dividend Account CDO Collateralized Debt Obligation CDPU Cash. Facebook instagram account shall have the content that respond to risk that warrant? Msp Hack Tool cibettiamo. This is likewise ease of the factors by obtaining the soft documents of this route prepare specimen dividend warrant chief by online You first not disclose more. 17c Career Map Non Voip Phone Number Generator. Sidrec for dividend warrant agreement, wikipedia article published. NEITHER SSGA NOR ITS AFFILIATES WARRANTS THE ACCURACY OF THE. Prepare Specimen Dividend Warrant as Warrant IPDN. Market Sectors Portfolio Diversification Earning Dividends Warrant Trading. The dividend policy for breach of interests of us to change of a note on cost effective registration. Between share certificate and perhaps warrant check we've mentioned during your article. The dividend payment of interests in the. Specimen Presentation Of Share Certificates For Different. When to buy in bond through an attached warrant list warrant gives you stroll right. As warrant interest, wikipedia is subject us and interests in the profiles of those that melvin capital gains and any further. Warrants are open an important component of them venture debt model. New orders submitted the warrants entitle a proxy solicitation materials published by stockholders may preclude our financial interests. An introduction to expect capital ACT Wiki. Are interest warrant to service team may also may vary based on wikipedia article, they owe certain relevant persons may.
    [Show full text]
  • Mini-Bond. Istruzioni Per L'uso
    I quaderni dell’impresa Mini-bond. Istruzioni per l’uso A cura di Roberto Calugi, Valentina Morelli e Gianmarco Paglietti I mini-bond Istruzioni per l’uso Nuova edizione Mini-bond. Istruzioni per l’uso Questa pubblicazione rappresenta la nuova edizione aggiornata nei contenuti e rivista nella forma grafica della guida pubblicata nel dicembre 2013. Il lavoro è stato coordinato da Roberto Calugi, Responsabile dell’area Competitività delle imprese della Camera di Commercio di Milano, da Gianmarco Paglietti, Responsabile dell’ufficio Studi e Comunicazione del Consorzio camerale per il credito e la finanza e da Valentina Morelli del medesimo ufficio. I capitoli della prima parte sono stati realizzati da: Roberto Calugi e Gianmarco Paglietti Valentina Morelli Lorenzo Gai, Professore ordinario di Economia degli intermediari finanziari presso l’Università degli Studi di Firenze e Federica Ielasi, Ricercatrice di Economia degli intermediari finanziari presso l’Università degli Studi di Firenze Chiara Carzaniga e Maria Gloria Cesarini, Ufficio Studi e Comunicazione del Consorzio camerale per il credito e la finanza I capitoli della seconda parte sono stati realizzati sulla base dei dati e delle informazioni forniti da: Paolo Arnaudo, Responsabile Spazio Imprese presso BCC Cherasco Alessia Baccalaro, Head of Fixed Income Listing presso Borsa Italiana Alessandra Bechi, Direttore Ufficio Tax & Legal e Affari Istituzionali presso AIFI Simone Bruno, Partner presso Studio Benetti-Genolini-Bruno-Insam Andrea Cicia, Associate presso Orrick Andrea Crovetto,
    [Show full text]
  • Options Trading
    OPTIONS TRADING: THE HIDDEN REALITY RI$K DOCTOR GUIDE TO POSITION ADJUSTMENT AND HEDGING Charles M. Cottle ● OPTIONS: PERCEPTION AND DECEPTION and ● COULDA WOULDA SHOULDA revised and expanded www.RiskDoctor.com www.RiskIllustrated.com Chicago © Charles M. Cottle, 1996-2006 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be printed, reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, emailed, uploaded in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior written permission of the publisher. This publication is designed to provide accurate and authoritative information in regard to the subject matter covered. It is sold with the understanding that neither the author or the publisher is engaged in rendering legal, accounting, or other professional service. If legal advice or other expert assistance is required, the services of a competent professional person should be sought. From a Declaration of Principles jointly adopted by a Committee of the American Bar Association and a Committee of Publishers. Published by RiskDoctor, Inc. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Cottle, Charles M. Adapted from: Options: Perception and Deception Position Dissection, Risk Analysis and Defensive Trading Strategies / Charles M. Cottle p. cm. ISBN 1-55738-907-1 ©1996 1. Options (Finance) 2. Risk Management 1. Title HG6024.A3C68 1996 332.63’228__dc20 96-11870 and Coulda Woulda Shoulda ©2001 Printed in the United States of America ISBN 0-9778691-72 First Edition: January 2006 To Sarah, JoJo, Austin and Mom Thanks again to Scott Snyder, Shelly Brown, Brian Schaer for the OptionVantage Software Graphics, Allan Wolff, Adam Frank, Tharma Rajenthiran, Ravindra Ramlakhan, Victor Brancale, Rudi Prenzlin, Roger Kilgore, PJ Scardino, Morgan Parker, Carl Knox and Sarah Williams the angel who revived the Appendix and Chapter 10.
    [Show full text]
  • MARKET VIEW INFLATION PROTECTION: NO TIME for TIPS Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities May Not Provide the Protection That Investors Expect?
    MONDAY, JANUARY 22, 2018 MARKET VIEW INFLATION PROTECTION: NO TIME FOR TIPS Treasury inflation-protected securities may not provide the protection that investors expect? CHART 1. INFLATION EXPECTATIONS HAVE INCREASED INFLATION EXPECTATIONS (%), JANUARY 18, 2011–JANUARY 18, 2018 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 1/18/11 1/18/12 1/18/13 1/18/14 1/18/15 1/18/16 1/18/17 1/18/18 Source: Bloomberg. Five-year inflation expectation is represented by the five-year zero coupon inflation swap rate. The historical data are for illustrative purposes only, do not represent the performance of any specific portfolio managed by Lord Abbett or any particular investment, and are not intended to predict or depict future results. Investors may experience different results. Returns during other times may vary. Due to market volatility, the market may not perform in a similar manner in the future. Like all investments, inflation derivatives involve specific risks that should be carefully evaluated. Although these securities are more complex than typical stock and bond investments, they entail similar liquidity and potential default considerations. Past performance is no guarantee of future results. Investors expect 2018 to be a year of faster growth for the U.S. demand for Treasury inflation-protected securities (TIPS), a type economy, propelled by tax cuts, prospects for increased infra- of U.S. Treasury bond widely used by inflation-protection funds. structure spending, and further deregulation. In such an environ- (See box, “TIPS: A Closer Look.”) But while investors are attracted ment, one risk that investors may want to be mindful of is the to the inflation-adjustment component of TIPS, they might not be potential for rising inflation.
    [Show full text]
  • Internal Revenue Service, Treasury § 1.1092(C)–1
    Internal Revenue Service, Treasury § 1.1092(c)±1 (i) Contain the name, address, and (4) Which is not part of a larger taxpayer identification number of the straddle. taxpayer; (f) Non-section 1256 position. The term (ii) Show that the volume or nature non-section 1256 position means a posi- of the taxpayer's activities has tion that is not a section 1256 contract. changed substantially since the elec- (g) Offsetting position. The term offset- tion was made, and that the taxpayer's ting position means an offsetting posi- activities no longer warrant the use of tion as defined in section 1092(c)(2). such mixed straddle account; and (h) Position. The term position means (iii) Any other relevant information. a position as defined in section If a taxpayer's election for a taxable 1092(d)(2). year is revoked, the taxpayer may not (i) [Reserved] make a new election for the same class (j) Related person or flowthrough enti- of activities under paragraph (f)(1) of ty. The term related person or this section during the same taxable flowthrough entity means a related per- year. son or flowthrough entity as defined in (g) Effective date. The provisions of sections 1092(d)(4) (B) and (C) respec- this section apply to positions held on tively. or after January 1, 1984. (k) Section 1256 contract. The term sec- tion 1256 contract means a section 1256 (Secs. 1092(b)(1), 1092(b)(2) and 7805 of the In- contract as defined in section 1256(b). ternal Revenue Code of 1954 (68A Stat.
    [Show full text]
  • Enhancing Disclosure in the Mortgage-Backed Securities Markets
    Department of Office of Federal Housing Securities and Exchange the Treasury Enterprise Oversight Commission STAFF REPORT: ENHANCING DISCLOSURE IN THE MORTGAGE-BACKED SECURITIES MARKETS A Staff Report of the Task Force on Mortgage-Backed Securities Disclosure January 2003 Staff Report: Enhancing Disclosure in the Mortgage-Backed Securities Markets A Staff Report of the Task Force on Mortgage-Backed Securities Disclosure Contents Executive Summary 1 I. Introduction 4 II. Background 5 A. Issuers 5 B. MBS Investors 6 C. Mortgage-Backed Securities 7 1. Secondary Mortgage Market Enhancement Act of 1984 8 2. Effect of Tax Laws on MBS Markets 8 3. Types of Underlying Mortgage Loans 9 4. Guarantees or Credit Enhancements 11 5. Risks – Prepayment and Credit 11 a. Prepayment Risk 11 b. Credit Risk 12 D. Structure of the MBS 13 1. Pass-Through Securities 13 2. REMICS 14 E. Creation and Sales of GSE and Ginnie Mae MBS 15 1. Creation of GSE and Ginnie Mae MBS 15 2. The To-Be-Announced Market 16 3. Types of Trades of TBA-Eligible MBS 20 4. Dollar Rolls 21 F. Creation and Sales of Private-label MBS 22 1. Creation of Private-label MBS 22 2. Sales of Private-label MBS 23 G. Statutes Governing the Offer and Sale of MBS 23 III. Current Disclosure Practices 26 A. General 26 B. Offering Documents 26 1. Private-label Offering Materials 26 2. GSE and Ginnie Mae Offering Materials 28 C. Post-Offering Disclosures 28 1. Private-label MBS 28 2. GSE and Ginnie Mae MBS 29 D. Particular Issues Addressed by Disclosure 29 1.
    [Show full text]