Clark A. Warburton (1896-1979) John B

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Clark A. Warburton (1896-1979) John B Marquette University e-Publications@Marquette Economics Faculty Research and Publications Economics, Department of 1-1-1990 Clark A. Warburton (1896-1979) John B. Davis Marquette University, [email protected] Published version. "Clark A. Warburton (1896-1979)," in Banking and Finance 1913-1989. Ed. Larry Schweikart. New York: Facts on File (Infobase Learning Imprint), 1990: 451-453. Publisher Link. © 1990 Facts on File (Infobase Learning Imprint). Used with permission. Business History and Biography Clark A. Warburton Edward Rosenbaum and Ari Sherman, M. M. Warburg & Archives: Company 1798-1938 (New York: Holmes & Meier, The papers of Paul M. Warburg are at Yale Univer­ 1979); sity Library. James P. Warburg, The Long Road Home (Garden City, N.Y.: Doubleday, 1964). Clark A. Warburton (January 27, 1896 - September 18, 1979) by John B. Davis Marquette University CAREER: U.S. Army (1917-1919); lecturer, Univer­ 1918 to 1919, Warburton returned to the United sity of Allahabad, India (1921-1924); instructor, States to attend Cornell University in Ithaca, New Rice Institute [later Rice University) (1925-1928); as­ York, where he received his B.A. in 1921. sociate professor, Emory University (1929-1932); Warburton took his first academic position as member, Brookings Institution (1932-1934); re­ a lecturer in economics at the University of Allaha­ searcher, chief administrator, Banking and Business bad in Allahabad, India, where he taught until Section, Division of Research and Statistics, Federal 1924. In his final two years in India he served as Deposit Insurance Corporation (1934-1966). the managing editor of the Indian Journal of Eco­ nomics and thus obtained an acquaintance with the Clark Abram Warburton, economist, educa­ standards and practices of scholarly publishing. He tor, and public administrator, was the author of returned to the United States in 1925 to take a posi­ more than 50 scholarly articles concerning the na­ tion as an instructor in economics at Rice Institute­ ture of fiscal and monetary policy in the United (later known as Rice University) in Houston, Texas, States. His practical experience came from working and he remained at Rice until 1928, when he re­ for more than three decades in the Federal Deposit ceived an M.A. from Cornell. He married Amber Insurance Corporation, where he developed his life­ Arthun on July 5, 1929, and accepted a position as long interest in the relationship of banking and mon­ associate professor of economics at Emory Univer­ etary policy to business fluctuations. Beginning in sity in Atlanta, Georgia. In 1932 Warburton re­ the Great Depression of the 1930s, Warburton en­ ceived his Ph.D. from Columbia University. His tered into a study of the role of the money supply dissertation, The Economic Results of Prohibition, in episodes of depression and inflation. That ulti­ was published by Columbia University Press that mately led him to conclude that monetary authori­ same year. ties in the United States had consistently failed to Warburton did not return to academia but in­ provide sufficient stability, at an appropriate rate of stead elected to devote his time and efforts to eco­ growth, in the supply of money available to the na­ nomic and financial research. He took a position in tion's people and its business enterprises. In those 1932 as a member of the research staff at the non­ conclusions, Warburton was later credited for pio­ profit Brookings Institution in Washington, D.C. neering the Quantity Theory of Money and cited as There he was among the first economists to work a forerunner of the economist Milton Friedman. on the newly conceived national income ~ccounts, Warburton was born in Shady Cove in upstate which summed total annual economic activity. In New York on January 27, 1896, the son of Mel­ 1934 Warburton left the Brookings Institution to vin Eugene Warburton, a clergyman, and Florence join the recently established Federal Deposit Insur­ Vough Warburton. He originally enrolled at ance Corporation (FDIC). As a result of the bank fail­ Houghton College in Houghton, New York, in ures and national financial panic of the early 1915, but with the U.S. entry into World War I he 1930s, the FDIC had been created by a provision of left school in 1917 to join the American Expedition­ the Glass-Steagall Act of June 1933 to guarantee ary Forces. After serving two years in France from small deposits in the banking system. Banks paid 451 Clark A. Warburton The Encyclopedia of American the cost of the insurance in the form of a fee based detailed analysis of the regional distribution of on the size of their deposits. Thus, first as a re­ bank failures and deposit contractions over the pe­ searcher and then later as chief of the Banking and riod from 1930 to 1935. He also needed to carry Business Sect;Jn of the Division of Research and Sta­ out a thorough evaluation of Federal Reserve opera­ tistics, Warburton acquired firsthand knowledge of tions during the same period. The results of those commercial banking operations in a fashion never be­ studies transformed Warburton's views. Despite his fore enjoyed by students of the American financial earlier adherence to a real theory of the business system. He remained at the FDIC until he retired cycle, whereby investment and production decisions from government service in 1966. accounted for economic fluctuations, Warburton Upon retirement Warburton briefly was made came to believe that money and monetary policy a visiting professor of economics at the University played the fundamental role in determining the of California at Davis through the efforts of Profes­ level of economic activity. sor Thomas Mayer. In poor health, which pre­ Warburton accordingly went on to challenge vented him from assuming a full teaching load, he Keynesianism, which was dominant at the time not conducted small weekly seminars for a few students so much in terms of its logical consistency as in investigating economic history (notably Thomas F. terms of its empirical relevance. By the early 1940s, Cargill). Though he had often encountered frustra­ after having comprehensively examined the annual tion from an economics profession less concerned tabulations of bank deposits from 1920 to 1935 with monetary phenomena than with Keynesian ex­ from country to country, he had concluded that penditure concepts, Warburton lived to see his ideas money quantity was indisputably the central factor gain broad acceptance among an emerging in the Great Depression downturn. By the late monetarist school of economics. He died at eighty­ 1940s and early 1950s he felt confident in blaming three on September 18, 1979, in Fairfax, Virginia. the Federal Reserve and "an erratic money supply Along with Carl Snyder, Lionel Edie, Lauchlin as the chief originating factor in business recessions Currie, James Angell, and Arthur Marget, War­ and not merely an intensifying force in the case of se­ burton was recognized by 1989 as one of the pioneer­ vere depressions." Indeed, his 1951 paper, "The ing voices of monetarism-the doctrine stating that Misplaced Emphasis in Contemporary Business Fluc­ changes in the quantity of money are the dominant tuations Theory"-perhaps his best known and independent determinant of cyclical changes in eco­ often considered his single most important contribu­ nomic activity. His special talent involved empirical tion to economic thought-argued against the view investigation into the relationship between money of Keynes and his followers that an imbalance in and economic activity, and it was on that basis that the savings-investment relationship alone provided he anticipated many of the conclusions of later mone­ a sufficient explanation of business fluctuations, pre­ tarists. However, despite his painstakingly careful ex­ cisely because of a conviction that the historical amination of economic data, and because he did his record placed the chief blame for business fluctua­ most extensive publishing during the height of the tions on the discretionary monetary policy of the Fed­ Keynesian- revolution in the 1940s and 1950s, his eral Reserve. work went largely unappreciated until the 1960s, Warburton's work has influenced present-day when, through the leadership of Friedman, monetarists in many respects. Mo~t important, in monetarism received attention from large numbers the course of his writings he developed an empiri­ of economists. Warburton's professional recognition cally useful version of the Quantity Theory of was thus belated, and the full nature of his contribu­ Money, distinguishing between the long-run or equi­ tion to an understanding of monetary phenomena librium version of the theory and the short-run or has accordingly only begun to gain the notice it disequilibrium version. Adapting Irving Fisher's will likely receive in future years. Equation of Exchange, which related an economy's Warburton first developed his understanding volume of money and velocity to output and prices, of the relationship between the quantity of money Warburton tested the relationship between money in the economy and economic activity as a ~esult of and prices across key periods in American eco­ research carried out at the FDIC in the 1930s- to de­ nomic history. In addition, he also provided evi­ termine the required insurance premium for bank de­ dence that the lag in the effect of monetary policy posits. He initially had to develop a reasonably was both long and variable, which led him to con- 452 Business History and Biography Clark A. Warburton clude that a discretionary monetary policy was unde­ That Warburton failed to have a significant im­ pendable and that the most appropriate strategy for pact upon his colleagues during his most active the monetary authority to pursue was that of a years as an economist can best be explained by his in­ steady growth in the money supply. Finally, War­ tellectual isolation in the immediate postwar pe­ burton also argued that because the Keynesians had riod.
Recommended publications
  • A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman-Meiselman
    A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman – Meiselman and St. Louis By Michael T. Belongia Department of Economics University of Mississippi Box 1848 University, MS 38677 [email protected] and Peter N. Ireland Department of Economics Boston College 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467 [email protected] June 2021 ABSTRACT: Friedman and Meiselman (1963) typically is recognized as the original study that used a reduced-form equation to evaluate whether fiscal or monetary actions were the dominant influence on aggregate spending. It also provided the foundation for the better- known St. Louis Equation that followed. Missing from this evolution, however, are important precedents by Brunner and Balbach (1959) and Balbach (1963) that also employed a reduced form framework to offer evidence on the same fiscal versus monetary debate. Moreover, they also investigated whether the demand for money function was stable and inversely related to an interest rate, properties necessary in their reasoning before any more general model of national income determination could be developed. With this foundation, they then derived a reduced form expression for personal income from an explicit theoretical model and, in its estimation, they anticipated and addressed some of the empirical criticisms later directed at Friedman-Meiselman and the early versions of the St. Louis Equation. Taken together, the theoretical and empirical work reported in Balbach (1963) and Brunner and Balbach (1959) suggest these papers are clear antecedents of later reduced form expressions and should be recognized as such. Keywords: St. Louis Equation, monetary policy, fiscal policy, reduced form equation JEL Codes: B2, B4, E3 A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman – Meiselman and St.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy Frameworks and Indicators for the Federal Reserve in the 1920S*
    Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Monetary Policy Frameworks and Indicators for the Federal Reserve in the 1920s* Thomas M. Humphrey ‡ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 00-7 August 2000 JEL Nos. E5, B1 Keywords: quantity theory, real bills doctrine, scissors effect, policy indicators. Abstract The 1920s and 1930s saw the Fed reject a state-of-the-art empirical policy framework for a logically defective one. Consisting of a quantity theoretic analysis of the business cycle, the former framework featured the money stock, price level, and real interest rates as policy indicators. By contrast, the Fed’s procyclical needs-of-trade, or real bills, framework stressed such policy guides as market nominal interest rates, volume of member bank borrowing, and type and amount of commercial paper eligible for rediscount at the central bank. The start of the Great Depression put these rival sets of indicators to the test. The quantity theoretic set correctly signaled that money and credit were on sharply contractionary paths that would worsen the slump. By contrast, the real bills indicators incorrectly signaled that money and credit conditions were sufficiently easy and needed no correction. This experience shows that policy measures and measurement, no matter how accurate and precise, can lead policymakers astray when embodied in a theoretically flawed framework. *This paper does not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. The author is indebted to William Gavin, Bob Hetzel, Judy Klein, Mary Morgan, and Anna Schwartz for helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Austrian Economics Newsletter
    as the final means of payment by all participants in the every depositor at a given bank or thrift against loss, but market means that fiat money can be literally lent and which, in practice, has almost always guaranteed the full spent into existence regardless of the public's existing de- worth of all deposits, usually by subsidizing the merger of, mand for it. For example, if an additional quantity of Fed an ailing institution with a healthy one.6 Second and moc' 1 notes is printed up and spent by government on various importantly, there is the Fed itself, which, in its much goods and services, an excess supply of money will tempo- publicized function as the "lender of last resort," always rarily be created in the economy. The initial recipients of stands ready to head off a banking panic by simply printing the new money will quickly get rid of the excess cash up and lending the needed quantities of Fed notes to banks simply by increasing their own spending on goods; those or thrifts unable to meet their demand liabilitie~.~For these who eagerly receive the new money as payments in the reasons, checkable deposits held at federally-insured banks second or later rounds of spending will do likewise, in the and thrifts are readily acceptable in exchange as perfect process bidding up the prices of goods, reducing the pur- substitutes, dollar for dollar, for Federal Reserve notes.8 chasing power of the dollar, and, consequently, increasing the quantities of dollars that each individual desires to In contrast, travelers' checks issued by nonbank financial keep on hand to meet expected future payments or for institutions, such as American Express, are excluded from other purposes.
    [Show full text]
  • Chicago Monetary Traditions
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Laidler, David Working Paper Chicago monetary traditions Research Report, No. 2003-3 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario Suggested Citation: Laidler, David (2003) : Chicago monetary traditions, Research Report, No. 2003-3, The University of Western Ontario, Department of Economics, London (Ontario) This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/70428 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Chicago Monetary Traditions by David Laidler (Bank of Montreal Professor) Abstract: This paper, prepared for the forthcoming Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics (Ross Emmett and Malcolm Rutherford eds.) describes monetary economics as it existed in four eras at the University of Chicago.
    [Show full text]
  • Appendix: Publications of Anna J. Schwartz
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Money in Historical Perspective Volume Author/Editor: Anna J. Schwartz Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-74228-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/schw87-1 Publication Date: 1987 Chapter Title: Appendix: Publications of Anna J. Schwartz Chapter Author: Anna J. Schwartz Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7513 Chapter pages in book: (p. 407 - 412) Appendix: Publications of Anna J. Schwartz 1940 “British Share Prices, 1811-1850.” Review of Economics and Statistics (May): 78-93. 1947 Currency Held by the Public, the Banks, and the Treasury, Monthly, December 191 7-December 1944. Technical Paper 4. National Bureau of Economic Research. (With E. Oliver) “The Beginning of Competitive Banking in Philadelphia, 1782- 1809.” Journal of Political Economy (October): 417-3 1. “An Attempt at Synthesis in American Banking History.” Jour- nal of Economic History (November): 208-16. 1953 The Growth and Fluctuation of the British Economy, 1790-1850. 2 vols. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 2d ed.: Sussex, Harvester Press, 1975. (With A. D. Gayer and W. W. Rostow) 1960 “Gross Dividend and Interest Payments by Corporations at Se- lected Dates in the 19th Century.” In Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century. Studies in Income and Wealth 24. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. Pp. 40745. 1963 “Money and Business Cycles.” Review of Economics and Sta- tistics supp. (February): 32-64. (With Milton Friedman) A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960.
    [Show full text]
  • The Contributions of Milton Friedman to Economics
    Economic Quarterly—Volume 93, Number 1—Winter 2007—Pages 1–30 The Contributions of Milton Friedman to Economics Robert L. Hetzel ilton Friedman died November 16, 2006, at the age of 94. Any attempt to put his contributions to economics into perspective can M only begin to suggest the vast variety of ideas he discussed. Bur- ton (1981, 53) commented that “attempting to portray the work of Milton Friedman...islike trying to catch the Niagara Falls in a pint pot.” 1 At the beginning of his career, Friedman adopted two hypotheses that isolated him from the prevailing intellectual mainstream. First, central banks are respon- sible for inflation and deflation. Second, markets work efficiently to allocate resources and to maintain macroeconomic equilibrium.2 Because of his suc- cess in advancing these ideas in a way that shaped the understanding of the major economic events of this century and influenced public policy, Friedman stands out as one of the great intellectuals of the 20th century. I make use of taped material from an interview with Milton and Rose Friedman that Peter Robinson and I conducted at the Hoover Institution on April 8, 1996. I also use taped material from an interview with Milton Friedman conducted June 29, 1996, taped material sent by Milton Friedman on November 26, 1996, and a taped interview with David Meiselman on August 20, 1999. I am grateful for comments from Thomas Humphrey, David Laidler, Aaron Steelman, and Roy Webb. The views expressed in this article are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]
  • A Monetarist Model for Economic Stabilization
    A Monetarist Model for Economie Stabilization* by LEONALL C. ANDERSEN and KEITH M. CARLSON rji I. HE MONETARIST VIEW that changes in the in curbing excessive growth in total spending, largely money stock area primary determinant of changes because the money stock grew at a historically rapid in total spending, and should thereby be given rate during the four years ending in late 1968. Eco- major emphasis in economic stabilization programs, nomic developments from 1965 through 1969 were in has been of growing interest in recent years. From general agreement with the expectations of the the mid-1930’s to the mid-1960’s. monetary policy re- monetarist view. ceived little emphasis in economic stabilization policy. Presumed failure of monetary policy during the This article develops a model designed to analyze early years of the Great Depression, along with the economic stabilization issues within a framework development and general acceptance of Keynesian which focuses on the influence of monetary expan- economics, resulted in a main emphasis on fiscal ac- sion on total spending. Most of the major econometric tions — Federal Government spending and taxing models have not assigned an important role to the 1 programs — in economic stabilization plans. Monetary money stock or to any other monetary aggregate. policy, insofar as it received any attention, was gen- Furthennore, most econometric models contain a large erally expressed in terms of market rates of interest. number of behavioral hypotheses to be empirically Growing recognition of the importance of money estimated and integrated with each other, because and other monetary aggregates in the determination they are designed to aid in understanding the deter- of spending, output, and prices has been fostered by mination of many economic magnitudes.
    [Show full text]
  • Clark Warburton: Pioneer Monetarist
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Money in Historical Perspective Volume Author/Editor: Anna J. Schwartz Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-74228-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/schw87-1 Publication Date: 1987 Chapter Title: Clark Warburton: Pioneer Monetarist Chapter Author: Michael D. Bordo, Anna J. Schwartz Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c7504 Chapter pages in book: (p. 234 - 254) 9 Clark Warburton: Pioneer Monetarist Michael D. Bordo and Anna J. Schwartz 9.1 Introduction The central question debated in monetary economics for at least the past decade has been whether changes in the quantity of money are the dominant independent determinant of cyclical changes in economic activity. The challenge to the Keynesian view of business fluctuations represented by the question has been taken up by a significant number of economists. Thirty years ago by contrast a lone voice expressed reservations about Keynesian neglect of the role of monetary change in analyzing business fluctuations. The voice was that of Clark War- burton who persisted in arguing the merits of his case, undaunted by the isolation of his position. By this date, he is a patriarchal figure. A retrospective on Warburton’s contribution to monetary thought is long overdue. A salient characteristic of Warburton’s work is that it was empirically oriented. His autobiographical discussion of the development of his ideas traces the shifts in emphasis they underwent as his examination of statistical data and the literature on banks and business cycles altered his perception.
    [Show full text]
  • January 1, 2011 the Influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman
    January 1, 2011 The Influence of Irving Fisher on Milton Friedman‘s Monetary Economics Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff Rutgers University Paper prepared for the AEA Session on Irving Fisher and Modern Economics: 100 years after the Purchasing Power of Money, Denver January 8, 2010 1 1. Introduction Irving Fisher was the most prominent American economist of the early twentieth century. Milton Friedman was the most prominent economist of the later twentieth century. Fisher‘s writings in monetary economics, especially the Purchasing Power of Money ( 1911) had a major impact on Friedman‘s theoretical and empirical work in monetary economics. In addition, Fisher‘s views on monetary policy and monetary reform aligned quite clearly with Friedman‘s views. This paper examines the influence of Fisher‘s writings on Friedman‘s work in monetary economics. We focus first on Fisher‘s influences in monetary theory ( the quantity theory of money, the Fisher effect, Gibson‘s Paradox, the monetary theory of business cycles and the Phillips Curve), empirics (eg distributed lags.). Then we discuss Fisher and Friedman's views on monetary policy and various schemes for monetary reform ( the k% rule, freezing the monetary base, the compensated dollar, a mandate for price stability, 100% reserve money, stamped money.) Section 2 provides a brief biography of the two scholars and brings out some of the similarities of their careers. Section 3 discusses Fisher‘s influence on Friedman‘s monetary theory. Section 4 discusses Fisher and Friedman on monetary reform. To clarify Fisher‘s influences on Friedman we document all the citations to Fisher in Friedman‘s published work in Table 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The Warburton Village Clan
    The Warburton Vilage Clan Last Updated September 5th 2021 ©2018, 2019, 2020, 2021 Ray Warburton PREFACE The Warburtons of Warburton Village are a very large clan, with over 700 Warburtons. Much of it was documented by Norman Warburton (himself a member) in his book Warburton: The Village and the Family. I have added to it from other sources, including my own researches into censuses. It includes one of the Warburton families of Sullivan County, Pennsylvania, another branch in California, and branches in Yorkshire and Stafordshire. Introduction The core of this tree is taken form Warburton: The Village and the Family by Norman Warburton, and represents Norman's own ancestry. Additional branches have been added from other sources, which include: - The Warburtons of Warburton and Arley," by Earl Cyrus Warburton and Geneva Warburton Dark, published in Monterey, California in 1956. - The Sullivan County Settlers website (http://www.rootsweb.ancestry.com/ ~pasulliv/settlers/settlers54/settlers54.htm). - A paper by Dr Alan Warburton of Lancaster University - Additional inputs from Mark Dalby, David Hartland, and Bridgit Koster A number of Warburton's are attested at Warburton in the 16th century. These are probably related to Thomas but there is no direct evidence of links. These Warburtons are: - Hamon Werburton of Partington, gentleman was a tenant at Warburton in 1520, as well as being a juror in 1517 and 1550. He was one of the Warburtons of Partington, and he is probably not an ancestor of Thomas. - Robert Werburton who was a leaseholder in the St John of Jerusalem moiety of Warburton under Sir John Warburton of Arley on 11th March 1520.
    [Show full text]
  • The Debate Widens - Introduction
    The University of Notre Dame Australia ResearchOnline@ND Business Book Chapters School of Business 2003 The Debate Widens - Introduction Robert Leeson University of Notre Dame Australia, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://researchonline.nd.edu.au/bus_chapters Recommended Citation Leeson, R. (2003). The debate widens - Introduction. In R. Leeson (Ed), Keynes, Chicago and Friedman, Vol 1 (2). London, United Kingdom: Pickering and Chatto. This Book Chapter is brought to you by the School of Business at ResearchOnline@ND. It has been accepted for inclusion in Business Book Chapters by an authorized administrator of ResearchOnline@ND. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Keynes, Chicago and Friedman Chapter 13: The Debate Widens Robert Leeson 3 June 2002 Shortly after Don Patinkin’s initial assault on Milton Friedman, Thomas Humphrey (chapter 14 [1971], 12) highlighted the importance of the contributions (“overlooked by both Patinkin and Friedman”) made to the quantity theory between 1930-50 by four non- Chicagoan economists: Carl Synder, i Lionel Edie, ii Lauchlin Currie and Clark Warburton. There are similarities between Friedman’s version of the Chicago monetary tradition and Currie’s Supply and Control of Money in the United States (1934). Also, Currie’s (1962 [1934]) essay on ‘The Failure of Monetary Policy to Prevent the Depression of 1929-32’ interpreted the Great Depression as a Great Contraction in a manner which foreshadowed the later work by Friedman and Anna Schwartz (1963). Humphrey commented that “oddly enough, however, [Lloyd] Mints and Friedman do not seem to be aware of the extent to which their criticisms were anticipated by Currie, for they cite him infrequently”.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Chicago Monetary Traditions By
    Chicago Monetary Traditions by David Laidler (Bank of Montreal Professor) Abstract: This paper, prepared for the forthcoming Elgar Companion to the Chicago School of Economics (Ross Emmett and Malcolm Rutherford eds.) describes monetary economics as it existed in four eras at the University of Chicago. It begins with analysis, based on the Real Bills Doctrine, developed by J. Laurence Laughlin, the first chairman of the Chicago Economics Department, and such students as Henry Parker Willis, which had an important influence on the original Federal Reserve Act, and then successively discusses: the inter-war “Chicago tradition” of such economists as Jacob Viner and Henry Simons, but also encompassing Paul Douglas’s under-consumptionism; Milton Friedman’s “Monetarism”; and New-classical economics as pioneered by Robert E. Lucas Jr. The paper’s basic theme is that, although Chicago monetary thought has never been quite as unique and single-minded as some of its admirers have claimed from time to time, it did maintain a certain distinctiveness during its first three eras that has now disappeared. 1 In popular understanding, the University of Chicago monetary tradition is inextricably linked to the ideas of Milton Friedman, which extend well beyond that area to encompass a general belief in the efficacy of market mechanisms as regulators of economic life, and an equally general skepticism about the desirability of government intervention therein (Reder 1987). Chicago “monetarism” is seen as having challenged (more or less successfully, depending on the commentator) a previously dominant “Keynesian” consensus on these matters. Though Chicago monetary economics can, and should, be judged on its theoretical and empirical merits, I shall also pay some attention to its broader political connections in this essay, because such considerations are important in locating its position in the broader history of American economic thought.
    [Show full text]