In Defense of the Real Bills Doctrine
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
The Region, Vol
Henry Parker Willis and the Location of the Federal Reserve Districts and the Headquarter Cities By David Hammes, Professor of Economics, University of Hawaii-Hilo 200 W. Kawili Street, Hilo, HI 96720-4091 [email protected] The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 called for dividing the USA into eight to twelve separate Reserve districts to help provide regional and national economic stability. The Committee responsible for designating the districts and headquarter cities made its decision public on April 2, 1914. Since that time, suspicion has been that political influences determined both the number and location of the reserve bank districts and cities. Based on the writings of Henry Parker Willis (1874 – 1937), this paper outlines the process used in 1914 to determine the number and locations of reserve districts and banks. Introduction1 The framers of the Federal Reserve System intended each of the Federal Reserve district banks to play a significant role in regional economic stability. Given changes in legislation (e.g. the Federal Reserve Act of 1935), and the greater mobility of capital, people, and information through time, monetary policy has been centralized in the Board of Governors and 2 Federal Open Market Committee. Public interest in the System has naturally followed the policy-power shift to the Board in Washington, DC. Interest today in the Reserve district banks is often limited to questions such as: ‘Why are there two Federal Reserve banks in the state of Missouri?’ and/or ‘Why are there so many reserve bank cities in the east versus the west?’ Following early commentary the answers are usually attributed to ‘politics’. -
Monetary Policy in a World of Cryptocurrencies∗
Monetary Policy in a World of Cryptocurrencies Pierpaolo Benigno University of Bern March 17, 2021 Abstract Can currency competition affect central banks’control of interest rates and prices? Yes, it can. In a two-currency world with competing cash (material or digital), the growth rate of the cryptocurrency sets an upper bound on the nominal interest rate and the attainable inflation rate, if the government cur- rency is to retain its role as medium of exchange. In any case, the government has full control of the inflation rate. With an interest-bearing digital currency, equilibria in which government currency loses medium-of-exchange property are ruled out. This benefit comes at the cost of relinquishing control over the inflation rate. I am grateful to Giorgio Primiceri for useful comments, Marco Bassetto for insightful discussion at the NBER Monetary Economics Meeting and Roger Meservey for professional editing. In recent years cryptocurrencies have attracted the attention of consumers, media and policymakers.1 Cryptocurrencies are digital currencies, not physically minted. Monetary history offers other examples of uncoined money. For centuries, since Charlemagne, an “imaginary” money existed but served only as unit of account and never as, unlike today’s cryptocurrencies, medium of exchange.2 Nor is the coexistence of multiple currencies within the borders of the same nation a recent phe- nomenon. Medieval Europe was characterized by the presence of multiple media of exchange of different metallic content.3 More recently, some nations contended with dollarization or eurization.4 However, the landscape in which digital currencies are now emerging is quite peculiar: they have appeared within nations dominated by a single fiat currency just as central banks have succeeded in controlling the value of their currencies and taming inflation. -
1 Financial and Monetary History of the United States 1700 to 1933
Financial and Monetary History of the United States 1700 to 1933 Economics 344:01 (Fall 2012) Monday/Thursday 11:30-12:50 Murray 211 Professor Michael D. Bordo Department of Economics New Jersey Hall, Room 304 Rutgers University (732) 932-7363 [email protected] http://econweb.rutgers.edu/bordo Office hours: Mondays 11-12 and Thursday 11-12 or by appointment Prerequisites Econ 320 (Intermediate Microeconomic Analysis) and Econ 321 (Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis). Money and Banking Econ 301 is recommended. This is an upper level elective course where you are expected to apply the knowledge and expertise that you have gained in the prerequisites. Course Objective The focus of the course is on American Monetary and Financial history. The methodology of the course is to apply modern tools of monetary and macroeconomic theory to important historical issues. The introduction of theoretical tools and historical data can shed new light on controversies of the past and yield new insights for today’s economic problems. Attendance Policy and Academic Integrity Students are expected to attend every class. Attendance is highly correlated with performance in the course. As this is an upper level class I will not take attendance. It is the student’s responsibility to master the course work including the lectures and the readings. As always at Rutgers, you are expected to follow the University’s precepts of academic integrity. ( See http://academicintegrity.rutgers.edu/integrity.shtml). Course Requirements There will be a short research paper of maximum 12 pages, double-spaced including references, tables and figures worth 40% of the grade. -
86-2 17-37.Pdf
Opinions expressedil'lthe/ nomic Review do not necessarily reflect the vie management of the Federal Reserve BankofSan Francisco, or of the Board of Governors the Feder~1 Reserve System. The FedetaIReserve Bank ofSari Fraricisco's Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank's Research and Public Information Department under the supervision of John L. Scadding, SeniorVice Presidentand Director of Research. The publication is edited by Gregory 1. Tong, with the assistance of Karen Rusk (editorial) and William Rosenthal (graphics). For free <copies ofthis and otherFederal Reserve. publications, write or phone the Public InfofIllation Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 974-3234. 2 Ramon Moreno· The traditional critique of the "real bills" doctrine argues that the price level may be unstable in a monetary regime without a central bank and a market-determined money supply. Hong Kong's experience sug gests this problem may not arise in a small open economy. In our century, it is generally assumed that mone proposed that the money supply and inflation could tary control exerted by central banks is necessary to successfully be controlled by the market, without prevent excessive money creation and to achieve central bank control ofthe monetary base, as long as price stability. More recently, in the 1970s, this banks limited their credit to "satisfy the needs of assumption is evident in policymakers' concern that trade". financial innovations have eroded monetary con The real bills doctrine was severely criticized on trols. In particular, the proliferation of market the beliefthat it could lead to instability in the price created substitutes for money not directly under the level. -
US Monetary Policy 1914-1951
Volatile Times and Persistent Conceptual Errors: U.S. Monetary Policy 1914-1951 Charles W. Calomiris * November 2010 Abstract This paper describes the motives that gave rise to the creation of the Federal Reserve System , summarizes the history of Fed monetary policy from its origins in 1914 through the Treasury-Fed Accord of 1951, and reviews several of the principal controversies that surround that history. The persistence of conceptual errors in Fed monetary policy – particularly adherence to the “real bills doctrine” – is a central puzzle in monetary history, particularly in light of the enormous costs of Fed failures during the Great Depression. The institutional, structural, and economic volatility of the period 1914-1951 probably contributed to the slow learning process of policy. Ironically, the Fed's great success – in managing seasonal volatility of interest rates by limiting seasonal liquidity risk – likely contributed to its slow learning about cyclical policy. Keywords: monetary policy, Great Depression, real bills doctrine, bank panics JEL: E58, N12, N22 * This paper was presented November 3, 2010 at a conference sponsored by the Atlanta Fed at Jekyll Island, Georgia. It will appear in a 100th anniversary volume devoted to the history of the Federal Reserve System. I thank my discussant, Allan Meltzer, and Michael Bordo and David Wheelock, for helpful comments on earlier drafts. 0 “If stupidity got us into this mess, then why can’t it get us out?” – Will Rogers1 I. Introduction This chapter reviews the history of the early (1914-1951) period of “monetary policy” under the Federal Reserve System (FRS), defined as policies designed to control the overall supply of liquidity in the financial system, as distinct from lender-of-last-resort policies directed toward the liquidity needs of particular financial institutions (which is treated by Bordo and Wheelock 2010 in another chapter of this volume). -
Friedman and Schwartz's a Monetary History of the United States 1867
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NOT JUST THE GREAT CONTRACTION: FRIEDMAN AND SCHWARTZ’S A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES 1867 TO 1960 Michael D. Bordo Hugh Rockoff Working Paper 18828 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18828 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2013 Paper prepared for the Session: “The Fiftieth Anniversary of Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States”, American Economic Association Annual Meetings, San Diego, CA, January 6 2013. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2013 by Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Not Just the Great Contraction: Friedman and Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff NBER Working Paper No. 18828 February 2013 JEL No. B22,N1 ABSTRACT A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 published in 1963 was written as part of an extensive NBER research project on Money and Business Cycles started in the 1950s. The project resulted in three more books and many important articles. A Monetary History was designed to provide historical evidence for the modern quantity theory of money. -
The Real Bills Views of the Founders of the Fed
Economic Quarterly— Volume 100, Number 2— Second Quarter 2014— Pages 159–181 The Real Bills Views of the Founders of the Fed Robert L. Hetzel ilton Friedman (1982, 103) wrote: “In our book on U.S. mon- etary history, Anna Schwartz and I found it possible to use M one sentence to describe the central principle followed by the Federal Reserve System from the time it began operations in 1914 to 1952. That principle, to quote from our book, is: ‘Ifthe ‘money market’ is properly managed so as to avoid the unproductive use of credit and to assure the availability of credit for productive use, then the money stock will take care of itself.’” For Friedman, the reference to “the money stock”was synonymous with “the price level.”1 How did American monetary experience and debate in the 19th century give rise to these “real bills” views as a guide to Fed policy in the pre-World War II period? As distilled in the real bills doctrine, the founders of the Fed under- stood the Federal Reserve System as a decentralized system of reserve depositories that would allow the expansion and contraction of currency and credit based on discounting member-bank paper that originated out of productive activity. By discounting these “real bills,”the short- term loans that …nanced trade and goods in the process of production, policymakers ful…lled their responsibilities as they understood them. That is, they would provide the reserves required to accommodate the “legitimate,” nonspeculative, demands for credit.2 In so doing, they The author acknowledges helpful comments from Huberto Ennis, Motoo Haruta, Gary Richardson, Robert Sharp, Kurt Schuler, Ellis Tallman, and Alexander Wolman. -
Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Rockoff, Hugh Working Paper Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking Working Paper, No. 2010-04 Provided in Cooperation with: Department of Economics, Rutgers University Suggested Citation: Rockoff, Hugh (2010) : Parallel journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the regulation of banking, Working Paper, No. 2010-04, Rutgers University, Department of Economics, New Brunswick, NJ This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/59460 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu February, 2010 Parallel Journeys: Adam Smith and Milton Friedman on the Regulation of Banking Hugh Rockoff Rutgers University and NBER Department of Economics 75 Hamilton Street New Brunswick NJ 08901 [email protected] 1 Abstract Adam Smith and Milton Friedman are famous for championing Laissez Faire, yet both supported government regulation of the banking system. -
The Federal Reserve's Role
The Federal Reserve’s Role: Actions Before, During, and After the 2008 Panic in the Historical Context of the Great Contraction Michael D. Bordo Economics Working Paper 13111 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 December 2013 This paper examines the Federal Reserve’s actions before, during and after the 2008 financial crisis. It looks to the Great Contraction of 1929-1933 for historical context of the Federal Reserve’s actions. Acknowledgements: For helpful comments I thank Allan Meltzer, Ashoka Mody, and David Wheelock. For valuable research assistance I thank Antonio Cusato. The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. The Federal Reserve’s Role: Actions Before, During, and After the 2008 Panic in the Historical Context of the Great Contraction Michael D. Bordo Introduction The financial crisis of 2007-2008 has been viewed as the worst since the Great Contraction of the 1930s. It is also widely believed that the policy lessons learned from the experience of the 1930s helped the US monetary authorities prevent another Great Depression. Indeed, Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Federal Reserve during the crisis, stated in his 2012 book that, having been a scholar of the Great Depression, his understanding of the events of the early 1930s led him to take many of the actions that he did. This chapter briefly reviews the salient features of the Great Contraction of 1929-1933 and the policy lessons learned. -
Textbooks and Pure Fiscal Policy: the Neglect of Monetary Basics
Econ Journal Watch, Volume 4, Number 1, January 2007, pp 60-70. Textbooks and Pure Fiscal Policy: The Neglect of Monetary Basics LEE C. SPECTOR AND T. NORMAN VAN COTT * ABSTRACT AGGREGATE DEMAND CANNOT CHANGE WITHOUT THE CONCOMITANT support of the monetary sector. At the initial level of output, either the money supply must change, the demand for money change, or the quantity of money demanded change. The link between money demand and money velocity means that changes in the demand for money and quantity of money demanded correspond to exogenous and endogenous changes in the velocity of money at the initial level of output. In any event, absent the support of the monetary sector, aggregate demand does not change. End of story. 1 One would hope that macroeconomic discussions of fiscal policy would utilize such monetary basics. Unfortunately, most leading textbooks in macro and monetary economics do not elucidate the monetary mechanisms crucial to understanding the effects of fiscal policy. Indeed, one must go back at least thirty years to find textbook discussions that do * Department of Economics, Ball State University. Muncie, IN 47306. The authors thank Milton Friedman and Richard Timberlake for their encouraging comments on a previous version of this paper. 1 At the initial level of output, endogenous changes in the quantity of money demanded or velocity can occur as a result of a change in the interest rate. Moreover, endogenous and exogenous changes in velocity at the initial level of output are probably better thought of as changes in the “desired” velocity since they stem from changes in people’s willingness to hold money. -
A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman-Meiselman
A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman – Meiselman and St. Louis By Michael T. Belongia Department of Economics University of Mississippi Box 1848 University, MS 38677 [email protected] and Peter N. Ireland Department of Economics Boston College 140 Commonwealth Avenue Chestnut Hill, MA 02467 [email protected] June 2021 ABSTRACT: Friedman and Meiselman (1963) typically is recognized as the original study that used a reduced-form equation to evaluate whether fiscal or monetary actions were the dominant influence on aggregate spending. It also provided the foundation for the better- known St. Louis Equation that followed. Missing from this evolution, however, are important precedents by Brunner and Balbach (1959) and Balbach (1963) that also employed a reduced form framework to offer evidence on the same fiscal versus monetary debate. Moreover, they also investigated whether the demand for money function was stable and inversely related to an interest rate, properties necessary in their reasoning before any more general model of national income determination could be developed. With this foundation, they then derived a reduced form expression for personal income from an explicit theoretical model and, in its estimation, they anticipated and addressed some of the empirical criticisms later directed at Friedman-Meiselman and the early versions of the St. Louis Equation. Taken together, the theoretical and empirical work reported in Balbach (1963) and Brunner and Balbach (1959) suggest these papers are clear antecedents of later reduced form expressions and should be recognized as such. Keywords: St. Louis Equation, monetary policy, fiscal policy, reduced form equation JEL Codes: B2, B4, E3 A Missing Stop on the Road from Warburton to Friedman – Meiselman and St. -
Monetary Policy Frameworks and Indicators for the Federal Reserve in the 1920S*
Working Paper Series This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://www.richmondfed.org/publications/ Monetary Policy Frameworks and Indicators for the Federal Reserve in the 1920s* Thomas M. Humphrey ‡ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 00-7 August 2000 JEL Nos. E5, B1 Keywords: quantity theory, real bills doctrine, scissors effect, policy indicators. Abstract The 1920s and 1930s saw the Fed reject a state-of-the-art empirical policy framework for a logically defective one. Consisting of a quantity theoretic analysis of the business cycle, the former framework featured the money stock, price level, and real interest rates as policy indicators. By contrast, the Fed’s procyclical needs-of-trade, or real bills, framework stressed such policy guides as market nominal interest rates, volume of member bank borrowing, and type and amount of commercial paper eligible for rediscount at the central bank. The start of the Great Depression put these rival sets of indicators to the test. The quantity theoretic set correctly signaled that money and credit were on sharply contractionary paths that would worsen the slump. By contrast, the real bills indicators incorrectly signaled that money and credit conditions were sufficiently easy and needed no correction. This experience shows that policy measures and measurement, no matter how accurate and precise, can lead policymakers astray when embodied in a theoretically flawed framework. *This paper does not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. The author is indebted to William Gavin, Bob Hetzel, Judy Klein, Mary Morgan, and Anna Schwartz for helpful comments.