Development of Monetary Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Development of Monetary Policy This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Great Contraction, 1929–33 Volume Author/Editor: Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz Volume Publisher: Princeton University Press Volume ISBN: 0-691-00350-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/frie65-1 Publication Date: 1965 Chapter Title: Development of Monetary Policy Chapter Authors: Milton Friedman, Anna Jacobson Schwartz Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c9278 Chapter pages in book: (p. 66 - 95) THE GItEAT CONTRA(:TIQN to 1931, China was hardly affected internally by the holocaustthat wa. s%eeping the gold-standard world,Tjust as inl920-21, Germans' had been insulated byher hvperinfiation and associated floatingrxchan rate." The first major country to Cut the linkwas Britain, when she left tL gold standard in 1931. The trough of the depressionin Britain and in other countries that accompanied Britain in leavinggold was reached in the third quarter of 1932. In the countriesthat remained on tile gold standard or,like Canada, that went onlypart way with Britain, the depression dragged on. In China, whosecurrency appreciated relative to the pound as a result of the sharp depreciation of tile pound relativeto gold. the depression set in for die first timein 1931. Of course, the country in tile vanguard of such an internationalmove- rnent need not stay there. France, which hadaccumulatec, s laree stock of gold as a result of returning to the goldstandard in 1928 at .' exchange rate that undervalued the franc, and therefore had much leeway, atsome point passed the United States and not only beganto add to its gold stock but also, after late 1931, to draingold from the United States The between the franc and the dollar link was cut when the United Statessus- pended gold pa)ments in March 1933,which proved to be the business cycle trough for the United States and countries closely linkedto itIn France. which stayed on gold fora further interval, the contractioi1 (Iragged on still longer. Although there was an upturn from July1932 to July 1933, the low point of theinterwar years was not reached 1935. until April 5. Development ofMonetary Policy The course of monetary policy in the difficult and criticals'ears of the contraction was greatly influencedby the struggle for Federal Reserve S'.tem, the power within tile beginnings of whichwere described in the preceding chapter. At the timeof the stock market Reserve Bank acted in the crash, the New York tradition of its earlierdominance rapidly, decisively, andon its own. The adverse r11ovifl" greatly inhibited further reaction of the Board independent measures b.New York In 1930. New York strongly favored expansio!sarVopen markct opria. tions, but after the middleof the 'car was unable to persuadeeither ti:' other Bank governors_allof whom by thi5 time the reorganizyd Open Market had become members of Policy Conferencewhich replaced die earlier Open Market InvestmentCommittee..or the ington. The samewas true in Board in Wash- 1931, except thatNew Yorkwas less 'Arthur Salter, China andSilver, New York, 15-1?. Economic Forum 1934pp 3-6 Frank D. Graham, Exchange Gerrr.any, 1920-23. Princeton Prices, and Prdu.-'inn/i psr:?,'i, Univcrsjr. Precs, 1931, 2873g THE GREAT CONTRACTION at was vigorous ill 1)iesstng for expansionary action, though it was nowsupported v had by the new governor(Eugene Meyer) of the Federal Reserve Board. :hange The reaction to Britain's departure- from gold did not provoke a flare-up of those conflicts. The measuresadopted at that time were favored by cit the almostallaffiliatedwith the System. The agreement reflectedthe and in dominant importance then attached to the preservation of thegold cached standard and the greater signiuicance attached toexternal than to ic gold internal stability, by both the System and the community atlarge. Not n, the long after, the differences withinthe System that had been submcred tive to in the fall of 1931 rc-emered,New York generally pressing for ex- uve to palisiOnalY open marketoperations, supported by the governor and some other members ofthe Board and by a few Bank governors, and 'stove- opposed by most of the Bank governors. under Con- tuck of 'Ihe open market operation of 1932 was acceded to largely change gressiona1pressure and withthe new Glass-Steagall Act ostensibly The operation some 1ermittg release of the System's expansionary powers. shortly after Congress adjourned, because so d stock was terminated in August. remained unenthusiastic about the policy and ie link many Bank governors deadlock persisted through the es sus- reluctant or unwilling to pursue it. Tue usiness rest of the contraction. tt. in THE STOCK MARKET CP.ASH OCTOBER1929 rartion the Open Market Investment 932 to At the time of the stock market crash, Committee consisted of five Bank governors with theNew York governor I April as chairman. It wasoperating under its recommendation to the Board, September 4, which had been approved by theBoard on October 1. to purchase "not to exceed $25,000,000 a week"of short-term government "for the of the securitiesif needed to supplement purchases of acceptances, purpose of avoiding any increaseand, if possible, facilitating some further in the bank discounts ......Up to in the reduction in the total volume of member Committee had not made any govern- v York the week ending October 23, the bills had been available. The Ssstem's 110 VInC inent security purchases because bill holdings had increased Board holdings had declined by $16 million, while itS by $115 million.16 had no doubt about what nera- When the crash came, the New York Bank steps should be taken andproceeded to take them. It purchased $160 er rho encouraging New York oers of million of government securities in addition to banks to discount freely. The amountpurchased was far iii excess of the 'd the Investment Committee was authorized Wash- amount that the Open Market Bank did not claim to be operating forthe less to purchase, but the New York Committee. It contended it had the right topurchase government secu- 3-6, Harrison. Open Market. Vol.I, nhLnute5, Sept. 24, 1929, and letter,dated Oct. 1, 1929, Young to Harrison. // THE GRgAT CONTRAcflON rities for its own account,as a matter of general credit policy, without the Board's approval.lt Harrison informedGovernor Young of the Federal Reserve Board that his directors hadatithori;ed him to purchasegovern. rnent Securities without limitationas to amount, and that on October 29, before the call loan rate was announced, a purchase had beenarranged Members of the Board regarded the New York Bank's fai!ureto seek the authorization of the Boardbefore taking actionas smacking of in- subordinationthough some regarded theation itself as desirable As a legal matter, the Nw York Bank seemed clearly within its rightsUnder the 1923 agreement setting up the Open MarketInvestment each Reserve Bank retained the Coniiriittc'e, right to purchase and holdgovernment securities for its ownaccount, Young and most Board edged the legal right members acknow!- vet felt that the challengeto the Board's authority was Insupportable After much discussionthe Board finally Young to tell Harrison authorized that, if New York shouldrequest approval of a reduction of its rate to 5per cent, the Board would that no further purchases consent on condition ofgovernmentsecurities be made approval of the Board except with On November i, thediscount rate at the New ork Bank wasso reduced To the New York directors it was clearthat the Svstep-i oughtto proceed immediately with "unless thisis done, after the further purchases for events of the past weeks,therc ma' be creator danger of a recession inbusmess with linemplosment which consequent depression and we should do all in ourpower to prevent" as they declaredin a resolutionthey adopted on November 7,75Under the leadership of Harrison, theOpen Market Investment Nosemnber 12, Conimirtee mPeting recommended that "thepresent limit of $?5,0000ftO week on the purchaseof per os'ernmen( securities beremoved and that the Committee be authorizedin lieuthereof to purchasenot to exceed S200,00o 000 ofgovernment securities for to participate ..," having account of such banksas care in mind also the fact"that present condi- tions may possibly developto the point where, in the interest of as an ernergencmeasure, maimstaininrr hankine and business stabilityit may be n°cessarv quickly to purchaselarge amounts of ordertoavoid Government seclirities in anyundue stringency incredit, "' "Of the $160 t1!jon Cocrnmentsecuritje endinOct30, S5 million purchased be Ntv Vorl, inthe week me t5o was transferd to Sssmt'rn eeksthe Nework Bank liouwbi account During the follow. System arcounm an addiffllnJi $25 auth00diretlfor "HamIsa, Diary, Volt 6. Oct.29 01 1929 pp 1t17 sider the purchase desirablelie siCeested 196 Miller didrot ('On. wouid not hate a reioiutio0 to the effectthat the Board approsed the purchase hadit hen Consulted usas more concerned about thestock market than mh that Ness York forcing the banksto cot-ne to the discount general credit situationthat response window would Fat'been the prs-)er For the rosol t1ofl se-c ii arriso,.\ sc eI an'.,,05 '01 Open Market Vol. 1. 1 minutes of nuretd Not- 2 l9Q THE GREAT CONTRACTION The next day,Lli Bc,aïdnotified the Committee that "the general situation was not sufficientlyclarified for the System to formulate and adopt a permanent openmarket policy at that time," but conceded that if "an emergency shouldarise with such suddenness and be so
Recommended publications
  • Friedman and Schwartz's a Monetary History of the United States 1867
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NOT JUST THE GREAT CONTRACTION: FRIEDMAN AND SCHWARTZ’S A MONETARY HISTORY OF THE UNITED STATES 1867 TO 1960 Michael D. Bordo Hugh Rockoff Working Paper 18828 http://www.nber.org/papers/w18828 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 February 2013 Paper prepared for the Session: “The Fiftieth Anniversary of Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz, A Monetary History of the United States”, American Economic Association Annual Meetings, San Diego, CA, January 6 2013. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2013 by Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Not Just the Great Contraction: Friedman and Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 Michael D. Bordo and Hugh Rockoff NBER Working Paper No. 18828 February 2013 JEL No. B22,N1 ABSTRACT A Monetary History of the United States 1867 to 1960 published in 1963 was written as part of an extensive NBER research project on Money and Business Cycles started in the 1950s. The project resulted in three more books and many important articles. A Monetary History was designed to provide historical evidence for the modern quantity theory of money.
    [Show full text]
  • The Federal Reserve's Role
    The Federal Reserve’s Role: Actions Before, During, and After the 2008 Panic in the Historical Context of the Great Contraction Michael D. Bordo Economics Working Paper 13111 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 December 2013 This paper examines the Federal Reserve’s actions before, during and after the 2008 financial crisis. It looks to the Great Contraction of 1929-1933 for historical context of the Federal Reserve’s actions. Acknowledgements: For helpful comments I thank Allan Meltzer, Ashoka Mody, and David Wheelock. For valuable research assistance I thank Antonio Cusato. The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. The Federal Reserve’s Role: Actions Before, During, and After the 2008 Panic in the Historical Context of the Great Contraction Michael D. Bordo Introduction The financial crisis of 2007-2008 has been viewed as the worst since the Great Contraction of the 1930s. It is also widely believed that the policy lessons learned from the experience of the 1930s helped the US monetary authorities prevent another Great Depression. Indeed, Ben Bernanke, the chairman of the Federal Reserve during the crisis, stated in his 2012 book that, having been a scholar of the Great Depression, his understanding of the events of the early 1930s led him to take many of the actions that he did. This chapter briefly reviews the salient features of the Great Contraction of 1929-1933 and the policy lessons learned.
    [Show full text]
  • Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, and a Monetary History of the US
    Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz, and A Monetary History of the US Thomas S. Coleman∗ Draft – February 21, 2019 PEOPLE: Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz RELATED: Inflation, monetary stimulus, Quantitative Easing DATES: A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 was published in 1963. Friedman and Schwarz’s book was preceded and followed by substantial work on monetary policy and monetary history. CHICAGO: Milton Friedman is one of the best-known economists to have taught at University of Chicago. Anna Schwartz was Friedman’s co-author and collaborator, associated with the NBER REFERENCES: A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960, particularly chapter 7 VIGNETTE Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz published their book A Monetary History of the United States in 1963; in doing so re-wrote monetary theory and history. In fact, it is only something of an exaggeration to say their research saved the world during the 2008 financial crisis. To see why we need to delve into monetary history, starting with the financial crisis and depression of 1907-08, following the thread through the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1913, the 1930s Great Depression, Friedman and Schwartz’s revisions of monetary history (1960s), Ben Bernanke’s acknowledgement (in 2002) of the Fed’s role in creating the 1930s Great Depression, and finally the Fed’s 2008 response with QE1’s massive liquidity injection. Understanding the role of banks, money, and the Fed ties together the three episodes (the 1907-08 depression, the 1930s Great Depression, and the 2008 financial crisis) and illuminates how and why these differed.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy in the Great Depression: What the Fed Did, and Why
    David C. Wheelock David C. Wheelock, assistant professor of economics at the University of Texas-Austin, is a visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. David H. Kelly provided research assistance. Monetary Policy in the Great Depression: What the Fed Did, and Why SIXTY YEARS AGO the United States— role of monetary policy in causing the Depression indeed; most of the world—was in the midst of and the possibility that different policies might the Great Depression. Today, interest in the have made it less severe. Depression's causes and the failure of govern- ment policies to prevent it continues, peaking Much of the debate centers on whether mone- whenever the stock market crashes or the econ- tary conditions were "easy" or "tight" during the omy enters a recession. In the 1930s, dissatisfac- Depression—that is, whether money and credit tion with the failure of monetary policy to pre- were plentiful and inexpensive, or scarce and vent the Depression, or to revive the economy, expensive. During the 1930s, many Fed officials led to sweeping changes in the structure of the argued that money was abundant and "cheap," Federal Reserve System. One of the most impor- even "sloppy," because market interest rates tant changes was the creation of the Federal were low and few banks borrowed from the dis- Open Market Committee (FOMC) to direct open count window. Modern researchers who agree market policy. Recently Congress has again con- generally believe neither that monetary forces sidered possible changes in the Federal Reserve were responsible for the Depression nor that System.1 different policies could have alleviated it.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Was Monetary Policy So Inept?
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Great Contraction, 1929–33 Volume Author/Editor: Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz Volume Publisher: Princeton University Press Volume ISBN: 0-691-00350-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/frie65-1 Publication Date: 1965 Chapter Title: Why Was Monetary Policy So Inept? Chapter Authors: Milton Friedman, Anna Jacobson Schwartz Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c9280 Chapter pages in book: (p. 111 - 123) THE GREAT c:0NTRAcTI0N 7. Why Was Monetary Pohcy SoIncp:.' We trust that, in light of the preceding sections ofthis chaptet, the adjective used in the heading of this one to characterize monetary policy during the critical period from 1929 to 1933 strikes OUt readersas it does us, as a plain description of fact. The monetarysystem collapsed, hut it clearly need not have done so. The actions required to prevent monetary collapse didnot call for a level of knowledge of the operation of the banking systemor of the work- ings of monetary forces or of economic fluctuations whichwas developed only later and was not available to the Reserve System. Onthe contrary. as we have pointed out earlier, pursuit of the policies outlined by the System itself in the 192O's, or for that matter by Bagehot in 1873,would have prevented the catastrophe. The men'ho established thFederal Reserve System had many misconceptions about monetary theoryand banking operations. It may well be that a policy in accordancewith their understanding of monetary matters would not have preventedthe decline in the stock of mone' from 1929 to the end of 1930.562 But theyunder- For example, H.
    [Show full text]
  • Did Monetary Forces Cause the Depression?
    LIBRARIESIBR ^^^^ MIT I Basemeki iiiiiiiiiiIIIIIIIIII """" n03 ?8 3 l?_lMMllTlW LIBRARY OF THE MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/didmonetaryforceOOtemi DID MONETARY FORCES CAUSE THE DEPRESSION? Peter Temin Number 107 April 1973 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 DID MONETARY FORCES CAUSE THE DEPRESSION? Peter Temin Number 107 April 1973 This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. Their help and the help of Robert A. Taggert with the calculations are gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed in this paper are the author's sole responsibility and do not reflect those of the Department of Economics nor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. DID MONETARY FORCES CAUSE THE DEPRESSION? It is an uncomfortable reflection on the current state of economics that this question is still an open one. In the early 1930's, no one doubted that the answer was yes. In the 1940 's and '50's, no one doubted that 2 the answer was no. And since the brilliant exposition of a monetarist point of view by Friedman and Schwartz in 1963, there does not appear to be 3 a consensus on either side of the issue. The purpose of this paper is to review the discussion by Friedman and Schwartz to discover precisely what they did and did not conclude and then to approach the question anew, asking some questions that were not asked by Friedman and Schwartz. My conclusion is that monetary forces did not cause the Depression.
    [Show full text]
  • Brinkley New Deal
    Name: ______________________________________________ Purpose: the purpose of the reading and accompanying tasks is to think about the successes and failures of the New Deal. Directions: Complete the following tasks and answer the following questions in your composition books. Read the questions/tasks and then read the reading about the New Deal. 1. Describe the economic problems that FDR needed to address. 2. What programs did FDR implement during the “first hundred days”? 3. Explain three programs that helped address the problem of unemployment. 4. What is the “Second New Deal”? 5. Describe at least two reasons that the New Deal was a success. 6. Describe at least two reasons that the New Deal was a failure. The New Deal, Then and Now by Alan Brinkley Well before Barack Obama’s election, the New Deal was emerging as an instructive model for those trying to understand, and address, what is now known as the “worst financial crisis since the 1930s.” But is the New Deal in fact a useful model for our own troubled times? In some respects, the New Deal – and in particular its first hundred days – have important lessons for our time, lessons that President Obama seems already to have learned. Franklin Roosevelt’s first and most important contribution to solving the great economic crisis he inherited in 1933 was to exude confidence and optimism and to invite frightened Americans to put their trust in his energy and activism. In his Inaugural Address, Roosevelt promised “action, and action now,” and to a large degree he delivered on that promise. The frenzy of activity and innovation that marked those first months, a welcome contrast to the seeming paralysis of the discredited Hoover regime, helped accomplish the first, and perhaps most important, task he faced: ending the panic that was gripping the nation.
    [Show full text]
  • Great Expectations and the End of the Depression
    Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports Great Expectations and the End of the Depression Gauti B. Eggertsson Staff Report no. 234 December 2005 This paper presents preliminary findings and is being distributed to economists and other interested readers solely to stimulate discussion and elicit comments. The views expressed in the paper are those of the author and are not necessarily reflective of views at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the author. Great Expectations and the End of the Depression Gauti B. Eggertsson Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 234 December 2005 JEL classification: E52, E63 Abstract This paper argues that the U.S. economy’s recovery from the Great Depression was driven by a shift in expectations brought about by the policy actions of President Franklin Delano Roosevelt. On the monetary policy side, Roosevelt abolished the gold standard and—even more important—announced the policy objective of inflating the price level to pre-depression levels. On the fiscal policy side, Roosevelt expanded real and deficit spending. Together, these actions made his policy objective credible; they violated prevailing policy dogmas and introduced a policy regime change such as that described in work by Sargent and by Temin and Wigmore. The economic consequences of Roosevelt’s policies are evaluated in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with sticky prices and rational expectations. Key words: deflation, Great Depression, regime change, zero interest rates Eggertsson: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (e-mail: [email protected]).
    [Show full text]
  • The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: a Comparative Approach
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MACROECONOMICS OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION: A COMPARATIVE APPROACH Ben S. Bernanke Working Paper No. 4814 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 1994 Presented as the Money, Credit, and Banking Lecture, Ohio State University, May 16, 1994. I thank Barry Eichengrecn for his comments and han Mihov for excellent Research Assistance. This paper is part of NBER's research programs in Economic Fluctuations and Monetary Economics. Any opinions expressed are those of the author and not those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. © 1994 by Ben S. Bernanke. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. NBER Working Paper #4814 August 1994 THE MACROECONOMICS OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION: A COMPARATIVE APPROACH ABSTRACT Recently, research on the causes of the Great Depression has shifted from a heavy emphasis on events in the United States to a broader, more comparative approach that examines the interwar experiences of many countries simultaneously. In this lecture I survey the current state of our knowledge about the Depression from a comparative perspective. On the aggregate demand side of the economy, comparative analysis has greatly strengthened the empirical case for monetary shocks as a major driving force of the Depression; an interesting possibility suggested by this analysis is that the worldwide monetary collapse that began in 1931 may be interpreted as a jump from one Nash equilibrium to another. On the aggregate supply side, comparative empirical studies provide support for both induced financial crisis and sticky nominal wages as mechanisms by which nominal shocks had real effects.
    [Show full text]
  • Secrets of the Federal Reserve: the London Connection
    Secrets of the Federal Reserve: The London Connection SECRETS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE The London Connection By Eustace Mullins Dedicated to two of the finest scholars of the twentieth century GEORGE STIMPSON and EZRA POUND who generously gave of their vast knowledge to a young writer to guide him in a field which he could not have managed alone. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to thank my former fellow members of the staff of the Library of Congress whose very kind assistance, cooperation and suggestions made the early versions of this book possible. I also wish to thank the staffs of the Newberry Library, Chicago, the New York City Public Library, the Alderman Library of the University of Virginia, and the McCormick Library of Washington and Lee University, Lexington, Virginia, for their invaluable assistance in the completion of thirty years of further research for this definitive work on the Federal Reserve System. About the Author Eustace Mullins is a veteran of the United States Air Force, with thirty-eight months of active service during World War II. A native Virginian, he was educated at Washington and Lee University, New York University, Ohio University, the University of North Dakota, the Escuelas des Bellas Artes, San Miguel de Allende, Mexico, and the Institute of Contemporary Arts, Washington, D.C. The original book, published under the title Mullins On The Federal Reserve, was commissioned by the poet Ezra Pound in 1948. Ezra Pound was a political prisoner for thirteen and a half years http://hardtruth.topcities.com/federal_reserve_secrets.htm (1 of 50) [2001-12-30 3:26:40 AM] Secrets of the Federal Reserve: The London Connection at St.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction
    Charles Bean: The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction Text of the Schumpeter Lecture by Mr Charles Bean, Deputy Governor for Monetary Policy and Member of the Monetary Policy Committee, Bank of England, at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association, Barcelona, 25 August 2009. I am grateful for the assistance of Adrian Penalver. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect those of either the Bank of England or the Monetary Policy Committee. * * * Summary Charles Bean, the Bank of England’s Deputy Governor, Monetary Policy, was invited to deliver the Schumpeter lecture at the Annual Congress of the European Economic Association. The Great Moderation, the Great Panic and the Great Contraction, looks back at the causes of the financial crisis and subsequent recession. He argues that much of what went wrong can be analysed using standard economic tools. The Great Moderation was a period of unusually stable macroeconomic activity in advanced economies. This was partly thanks to good luck, including the integration of emerging market countries into the global economy, and partly a dividend from structural economic changes and better policy frameworks. The longer this stability persisted, the more markets became convinced of its permanence and risk premia became extremely low. Real short and long term interest rates were also low due to a combination of loose monetary policy, particularly in the US, and strong savings rates in a number of surplus countries. Low interest rates and low apparent risk created strong incentives for financial institutions to become highly geared.
    [Show full text]
  • Effects of New Deal Spending and the Downturns of the 1930S on Private Labor Markets in 1939/1940 Xing Liu and Price Fishback
    Effects of New Deal Spending and the Downturns of the 1930s on Private Labor Markets in 1939/1940 Xing Liu and Price Fishback This Version: December 15, 2016 Preliminary Draft: Please Do Not Quote Without the Authors’ Permission Abstract We examine the medium-term effects on private labor markets for males in 1939-40 of the earlier Great Contraction of 1929-1933, and the Second-Dip Recession of 1937-38, as well as the concurrent and medium run effects of New Deal grants between 1933 and 1939. The analysis combines county level data on New Deal spending on the relief, public works, and Agricultural Adjustment Administration farm programs from 1933 to 1939 with IPUMS information on individuals from the U.S. Census in 1940. The results show that workers in counties hit harder by the earlier contractions still had fewer work opportunities and lower earnings in 1939/40 and were less likely to move to more skilled jobs between 1930 and 1940. Workers in counties with more public works grants per capita had higher weekly and annual earnings and worked more hours in private jobs and were more likely to move to higher skilled jobs during the 1930s, but there was no difference in their hourly earnings or in their probability of private employment. In counties with more relief grants and AAA grants, workers had less access to private jobs and were paid lower annual, weekly, and hourly earnings. The probability of moving into more skilled jobs was also lower. Xing (Michelle) Liu is a Quantitative Analyst at the Bank of the West and Price Fishback is the Thomas R.
    [Show full text]