Ernst Moritz Arndt University of Greifswald

The Impact of Land Administration and Common-Pool Resource Management on Wetland Utilisation along the Eastern Shore of Lake Tana,

Alteration of Wetlands – Risk or Chance for Rural Livelihoods?

Diploma thesis Maxi Springsguth

4th January 2013

Landscape Ecology and Nature Convervation Matriculation number 115518

Supervisor: Dr. Anne Cristina de la Vega-Leinert, Sustainability Science and Applied Geography, Institute of Geography and Geology Co-supervisor: Prof. Dr. Susanne Stoll-Kleemann, Chair of Sustainability Science and Applied Geography, Institute of Geography and Geology

Acknowledgements

I want to thank Dr. Anne Cristina de la Vega-Leinert and Prof. Dr. Susanne Stoll-Kleemann for the supervision of my thesis. I am very grateful to Dr. Anne Cristina de la Vega-Leinert for her comments and the discussion on my work. I want to thank all the people who took part in Participatory Rural Appraisal and the interview respondents for their willingness to share their knowledge, for the discussions and their time. Very special thanks goes to my counterpart and friend, Babiyew Sibhat. Thanks to your open mind, your endeavours, critique and experience our work was successfully accomplished. I am very happy to have spent my stay in Ethiopia together with Christian Sefrin, Fanny Mundt, Friedrich zur Heide, Ren´eeMoreaux, Johannes Poetzsch, the ‘fun-raising group’ and all the other wonderful people we met. Thanks for sharing a great time and for exchanging ideas. I further appreciate the assistance of Dr. Ayalew Wondie, Getasew Abebaw of the Fogera woreda administration, Tigistu Tilahun, the Michael Succow Founda- tion for the Protection of Nature, the Amhara Bureau of Culture, Tourism and Parks Development, Woinshet Sibhat as well as captain Gebrie and captain Maru in my research. Only with your crucial input, the financial support, the transport facilitation and your care this work became possible. I am very grateful to Thomas Lotze, Telsche Piechottka, Ren´eeMoreaux and Stephan Kuberski for the revision of my thesis, their constructive comments and technical advice. I am thankful to J¨orgBachmann for his technical support and his patience to endure my impatience. I also want to thank my little son, Levi Springsguth, for successfully diverting my thoughts of the remaining work and for the wonderful, unique time we spend together. Last but not least, I want to express my honest gratitude to my family, my sister Gabi Springsguth, Birgit Springsguth, Dagmar and Conny Springsguth as well as Christa and Gerhard K¨unzeland Karl-Heinz Springsguth (†), who supported me throughout this work and my life.

Contents

Abbreviations ix

Abstract 1

Zusammenfassung 3

1 Introduction 5 1.1 Rationale and Research Objective ...... 6 1.2 Structure ...... 8

2 The Study Area 9 2.1 Ethiopia: Social-Economic Background ...... 9 2.2 The ...... 9 2.3 The Research Site ...... 11 2.4 Wetlands between Conservation and Growth ...... 16 2.5 Land Policy in Ethiopia ...... 17

3 Theoretical Background and Framework 21 3.1 Common-Property Theory ...... 21 3.2 Resilience Thinking ...... 22 3.3 Political Ecology ...... 23 3.4 Theoretical Assumptions ...... 23 3.5 Theoretical Framework ...... 24

4 Methodology and Methods 31 4.1 Research Approach ...... 31

i ii CONTENTS

4.2 Data Collection ...... 32 4.2.1 Participatory Rural Appraisal and Group Discussions . . . 32 4.2.2 Problem-Centred Expert Interviews ...... 40 4.3 Data Preparation and Analysis ...... 42

5 Results 45 5.1 Values of Wetlands ...... 45 5.2 Perceptions on Well-being and People’s Objectives ...... 47 5.3 Environmental and Land Use Changes ...... 48 5.3.1 Flooding and Sedimentation ...... 48 5.3.2 Rice Cultivation ...... 49 5.3.3 Conversion of Wetlands ...... 51 5.3.4 Fishery ...... 51 5.4 Impact on Rural Livelihoods ...... 52 5.4.1 Impact on Crop Production and Livestock Rearing . . . . 53 5.4.2 Impact on Social Life ...... 54 5.4.3 Impact on Food Security and Income Generation . . . . . 55 5.5 Conflicts over Wetlands and Associated Resources ...... 56 5.5.1 Conflicts Related to Encroachment ...... 56 5.5.2 Conflicts over Grazing Land ...... 57 5.5.3 Cropland Boundary Conflicts ...... 57 5.5.4 Conflicts between Tana Kirkos Monasteries and the Com- munity ...... 58 5.5.5 Conflicts between Wetland Conservation and Use in Agid Kirigna ...... 58 5.5.6 Conflicts Related to Fishing ...... 59 5.5.7 Conflicts Arising from Stakeholders’ Perceptions on Gov- ernment Plans ...... 59 5.5.8 The Consequences of Conflicts for Communal Life . . . . 60 5.6 Land Administration ...... 61 5.6.1 Land Registration and Certification ...... 61 5.6.2 Constraints to the Land Registration and Certification Process ...... 63 CONTENTS iii

5.6.3 Land Use Planning ...... 65 5.7 Common-Pool Resource Management ...... 65 5.7.1 Local Resource Management Systems ...... 66 5.7.2 Conflict Resolution Mechanisms ...... 68 5.7.3 Federal and Regional Policies with Implications for Wetland Management ...... 69 5.7.4 Constraints to and Recommendations for Common-Pool Resource Management ...... 70 5.8 Summary ...... 74

6 Analysis 77 6.1 The Cyclical Process of Environmental Entitlements ...... 77 6.2 Mapping Endowments: Access to Wetlands ...... 78 6.2.1 Rights-Based Access to Wetland Resources ...... 79 6.2.2 Structural and Relational Mechanisms of Access . . . . . 81 6.2.3 Property Rights to Wetlands ...... 84 6.3 Power Relations and the Question of Who Benefits ...... 86 6.4 The Complexity of Conflicts ...... 92 6.5 Institutions Shaping Wetland Use and Management ...... 93 6.5.1 Land Administration ...... 93 6.5.2 Common-Pool Resource Management ...... 95 6.6 Summary ...... 107

7 Discussion 111 7.1 The Institutional Framework ...... 111 7.1.1 A National Wetland Policy? ...... 112 7.1.2 Signing the Ramsar Convention? ...... 113 7.1.3 Property Rights to Wetlands – A Critical Issue ...... 114 7.1.4 Land Administration and Conservation ...... 115 7.1.5 Land Use Planning and Conservation ...... 117 7.1.6 Environmental Impact Assessment ...... 117 7.2 Governance of Wetlands ...... 119 7.2.1 The Role of Social Actors in Wetland Management . . . . 119 iv CONTENTS

7.2.2 Drawing on Conditions Facilitating the Governance of Wetlands ...... 122 7.2.3 Unequal Power Relations and Empowerment ...... 122 7.2.4 Building Trust and Assurance ...... 123 7.2.5 Ensuring Participation ...... 124 7.2.6 Collaboration and Coordination ...... 124 7.2.7 Recognising Legal Rights ...... 125 7.2.8 Establishing, Implementing and Enforcing Regulations . . 125 7.2.9 Monitoring User Behaviour and Ecological Conditions . . 126 7.2.10 Resolving Conflicts ...... 126 7.2.11 Integrating Knowledge Pluralism and Ensuring Information Exchange ...... 127 7.2.12 Understanding Heterogeneity ...... 128 7.2.13 Large or Small? ...... 129 7.2.14 Delineating Wetland Boundaries: Remarks on a Zonation Proposition ...... 130 7.2.15 Providing Incentives and Livelihood Opportunities . . . . 132 7.3 Alteration of Wetlands – Risk or Chance? ...... 134

References 137

Appendices I Appendix 1: Methods of Participatory Rural Appraisal ...... I Appendix 2: Interview Catalogue of Questions ...... XI Appendix 3: Codes ...... XVIII Appendix 4: Well-Being Ranking ...... XVIII Appendix 5: Responses to Livelihood Insecurity ...... XIX Appendix 6: Land Use/Cover Changes in the Research Area ...... XXIV Appendix 7: Overview of the Impact of Anthropogenic Activities on Wetland Ecosystems ...... XXVIII Appendix 8: Biosphere Reserves ...... XXIX Glossary ...... XXX List of Tables

2.1 Research sites ...... 12

3.1 Bundles of property rights associated with positions ...... 28

4.1 Methods of PRA and group discussions ...... 36 4.2 Overview of Interviews ...... 41

5.1 Advantages and disadvantages of rice production ...... 55 5.2 Social actors involved in conflicts ...... 57 5.3 Recommendations for the governance of wetlands ...... 73

6.1 Property rights to wetlands associated with positions ...... 86 6.2 Beneficiaries, social actors and access mechanisms ...... 89

8.1 List of codes ...... XVIII 8.2 Responses of social actors to livelihood insecurity ...... XXI

v vi LIST OF TABLES List of Figures

2.1 ...... 10 2.2 Map of the research site ...... 13 2.3 Wetlands around Lake Tana ...... 14 2.4 Mean annual isohyets in the Lake Tana watershed ...... 15 2.5 Altitudinal range in the Lake Tana watershed ...... 15 2.6 Organogram of land administration in ANRS ...... 19

3.1 Three complementary bodies of scholarship ...... 24 3.2 Environmental entitlements framework ...... 28 3.3 Integrating theory and research questions ...... 30

4.1 Trend analysis ...... 38 4.2 Cause-effect diagram ...... 38 4.3 Impact diagram ...... 39 4.4 Well-being ranking with youth ...... 39 4.5 Well-being ranking with women ...... 39 4.6 Pair-wise ranking ...... 39

5.1 Ecosystem services of wetlands ...... 46 5.2 Rice cultivation in Agid Kirigna ...... 50 5.3 Cattle grazing in a wetland ...... 50 5.4 Wetland conversion ...... 52 5.5 Fishing ...... 52 5.6 Drivers of environmental and land use change ...... 53 5.7 Flooded rice field in Wagetera ...... 54

vii viii LIST OF FIGURES

5.8 Flooded settlements...... 54 5.9 Tana Kirkos Island...... 58 5.10 Wetland of Tana Kirkos Island ...... 58 5.11 Land Registry Book ...... 62 5.12 Land administration, land use changes and wetland system . . . . 66 5.13 Cut and carry system ...... 67 5.14 Fishermen’s association ...... 68 5.15 Fishermen in the morning ...... 68 5.16 Main causal chains of wetland alteration ...... 75

6.1 ‘Entitlement chains’ ...... 79 6.2 Mapping endowments ...... 91 6.3 Conflicts over wetlands ...... 92 6.4 Institutions conditioning resource subtraction ...... 103 6.5 Conditions facilitating wetland management ...... 107 6.6 Conditions constraining wetland management ...... 108 6.7 Environmental entitlements analysis ...... 109

7.1 Institutional framework for wetland conservation ...... 118 7.2 Zonation proposal for a Lake Tana Biosphere Reserve ...... 131 7.3 Features and conditions for a successful common-pool resource management ...... 134 8.1 Matrix of a well-being ranking (1) ...... XIX 8.2 Matrix of a well-being ranking (2) ...... XX 8.3 Land use/cover in 1986 ...... XXV 8.4 Land use/cover in 2001 ...... XXVI 8.5 Land use/cover in 2011 ...... XXVII Abbreviations

ADLI Agriculture Development-Led Industrialisation AECID Spanish International Development Cooperation Agency ANRS Amhara National Regional State ARARI Amhara Regional Agricultural Research Institute BDU University BoARD Bureau of Agricultural and Rural Development BoCTPD Bureau of Culture, Tourism and Parks Development BR Biosphere reserve CBD Convention on Biological Diversity CBINReMP Community-based Integrated Natural Resource Man- agement Programme DA Development agent EIA Environmental impact assessment EPA Environmental Protection Authority EPLAUA Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use Authority ETB Ethiopian Birr EWNRA Ethio Wetlands and Natural Resources Association EWRDM Early warning and risk disaster management processes coordinator EWRP Ethiopian Wetlands Research Programme FDRE Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia GDP Gross Domestic Product

ix x ABBREVIATIONS

GEF Global Environment Facility GTP Growth and Transformation Plan IFAD International Fund for Agricultural Development LAC Kebele land administration (and use) committee MoARD Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development MoWE Ministry of Water and Energy MSF Michael Succow Foundation for the Protection of Nature PIF Agricultural Sector Policy and Investment Framework PRA Participatory Rural Appraisal TaSBO Tana Sub-Basin Organisation UNESCO United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization WoARD Woreda Agricultural and Rural Development office WoEPLAU Woreda Environmental Protection Land Administra- tion and Use office WoWE Woreda Water and Energy office Abstract

The wetlands of Lake Tana, Ethiopia, harbour a rich biodiversity and provide various ecosystem services to humans. However they have been subject to resource overuse and degradation. The continuous conversion of these ecosystems is driven by an ever increasing population, targeted agricultural development and the open unregulated access to wetland resources. Attempts to conserve the biodiversity and the cultural landscape have resulted in a feasibility study for a Lake Tana biosphere reserve and baseline surveys on wetlands for the establishment of a Community- Based Integrated Natural Resource Management Project (CBINReMP). Against this background, the present work aims at analysing the decisive condi- tions that determine an effective management and a sustainable resource utilisation of the wetlands east of Lake Tana. For analytical purposes, the environmental entitlements framework by Leach et al. (1999), as the theoretical framework, is chosen incorporating insights from common-property theory, resilience thinking and political ecology. Research findings show that local institutions tackling urgent problems of mis- management and overexploitation of wetland resources were recently established. The management systems vary in regard to the elaboration of their institutional arrangements. Their ability to conserve the resource system is often restricted due to a complex of internal and external factors. These include among others the not manageable size of wetlands and user groups, the heterogeneity of social actors concerning their objectives and resource use priorities, and the unequal power realtions that influence the distribution of benefits obtained from wetland resources. Furthermore, the lack of participation in decision-making over wetland utilisation and management render management efforts ineffective. Flooding events increase pressures on resources through an increased utilisation an impede

1 2 ABSTRACT a sustainable resource subtraction. A plurality of rights and regulations pertaining to wetland utilisation, overlapping management jurisdictions and an ambiguous property rights system complicate wetland management. Based on these findings, recommendations are provided and objections raised regarding the establishment and functioning of the planned CBINReMP and the Lake Tana biosphere reserve. Zusammenfassung

Die Feuchtgebiete am Tana See Athiopiens¨ beherbergen eine hohe Biodiversit¨at und erbringen verschiedene Okosystemdientsleistungen.¨ Sie unterliegen jedoch der Ressourcen¨ubernutzung und Degradierung. Eine stets wachsende Bev¨olkerung, die angestrebte landwirtschaftliche Entwicklung und der freie unregulierte Zugang zu den Ressourcen sind treibende Kr¨aftef¨urdie fortlaufende Konvertierung dieser Okosysteme.¨ Bestrebungen, die Biodiversit¨atund Kulturlandschaft zu sch¨utzen, m¨undetenin einer Machbarkeitsstudie zum Tana See Biosph¨arenreservatund in Grundlagenstudien ¨uber die Feuchtgebiete, die dem Aufbau eines gemeinschafts- gest¨utzenintegrierten Projekts zum Management der nat¨urlichenRessourcen dienen sollen. Vor diesem Hintergrund ist es Ziel dieser Forschungsarbeit, die Bedingun- gen zu untersuchen, die ein erfolgreiches Management und eine nachhaltige Ressourcennutzung der Feuchtgebiete am Ostufer des Tana Sees bestimmen. Zu Analysezwecken wird der Environmental Entitlements Framework von Leach et al. (1999) als theoretischer Rahmen gew¨ahltund Erkenntnisse aus der Theorie ¨uber Gemeing¨uter,dem Resilienzansatz und der Politischen Okologie¨ eingebunden. Die Forschungsergebnisse zeigen, dass lokale Institutionen, die sich den Prob- lemen des Missmanagements und der Ubernutzung¨ der Feuchtgebietsressourcen widmen, unl¨angst etabliert wurden. Die Managementsysteme unterscheiden sich hinsichtlich der Ausgestaltung ihrer institutionellen Regelungen. Ihre F¨ahigkeit, das Ressourcensystem zu sch¨utzen,wird oft durch einen Komplex an inter- nen und externen Faktoren eingeschr¨ankt.Diese Faktoren umfassen u. a. die un¨uberschaubare Gr¨oßeder Feuchtgebiete und der Nutzergruppen, die Hetero- genit¨atder Akteure bez¨uglichihrer Ziele und Ressourcennutzungspriorit¨atensowie

3 4 ZUSAMMENFASSUNG ungleiche Machtverh¨altnisse,die die Nutzenverteilung der Ressourcen beeinflussen. Desweiteren machen eine mangelnde Partizipation in Entscheidungsprozessen zur Nutzung und der Bewirtschaftung von Feuchtgebieten Managementbestrebungen unwirksam. Uberflutungsereignisse¨ erh¨ohenden Nutzungsdruck auf Ressourcen und behindern eine nachhaltige Ressourcennutzung. Eine Vielzahl von Rechten und Regulierungen bez¨uglichder Feuchtgebietsnutzung, sich ¨uberschneidende Man- agementkompetenzen und das uneindeutige System der Besitzrechte erschweren das Feuchtgebietsmanagement. Auf Grundlage dieser Ergebnisse werden Empfehlungen und Bedenken bez¨uglichdes Aufbaus und der Arbeitsweise des angedachten gemeinschafts- gest¨utzenRessourcenmanagementprojekts und des Tana See Biosph¨arenreservats ausgesprochen. Chapter 1

Introduction

Wetland ecosystems are essential in conserving wetland-dependent biodiversity and in delivering important and vital services for human well-being. The wetlands of Lake Tana in the northern highlands of Ethiopia in the Amhara National Regional State (ANRS) (figure 2.2, p. 13) critically contribute to local people’s livelihoods, e. g. through the provision of food and building materials, water supply or flood control (Amsalu 2006: 17; IFAD 2007: 15). The continuous conversion of wetlands into crop and grazing land, overfishing, drainage, eutrophication, sand mining or siltation due to erosion in the upper watersheds threaten biodiversity, impair environmental functions of the lake and its wetlands and affect people’s livelihoods (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 47; IFAD 2007: 30–31). The alteration of wetlands is driven by a complex of interacting factors. These include population growth, unsustainable use practices and intensification of agriculture (Amsalu 2006: 19), ambiguous property-rights regimes of and open access to wetlands that are communally used but state-owned (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 38), missing appropriate legal frameworks and strategic management plans for the protection of wetlands (Abunie 2003: 16; Wood 2000: 20) and sectoral policy thinking (Abbot et al. 2000: 20). To tackle the problems of mismanagement and overuse, several attempts have been made and projects initiated, aiming at conserving wetlands in the Lake Tana region (see e. g. IFAD 2007; Hailu & Gebrekidan 2006; Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a, 2006 b). After discussing various options for the most appropriate

5 6 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION management approach to conserve biodiversity and the resource base for local people simultaneously, the establishment of a biosphere reserve (BR) has proven most feasible and suitable (e. g. Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 b: 23–24; IFAD 2007: 15). BRs are protected areas seeking to harmonise nature conservation and human development (UNESCO 1996). Until recently, the further initiation of the BR designation has been reluctant due to lack of awareness, cooperation, and political commitment (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b; zur Heide 2012: 10). In 2011, a feasibility study for a Lake Tana BR was conducted by the Michael Succow Foundation for the Protection of Nature (MSF), Germany, supported by the ANRS Bureau of Culture, Tourism and Parks Development (BoCTPD), reviving the attempt of conserving the important and unique biodiversity and the cultural landscape (zur Heide 2012). Based on existing research and expertise, the feasibility study has identified wetlands along the lake shore as important ecosystems in terms of biodiversity conservation (zur Heide 2012: 27–30, 39–41; see Gebrekidan 2006 b: 40–46). They therefore constitute an important pillar for planning and management in the Lake Tana BR (zur Heide 2012: 128). This research work was conducted as part of the feasibility study for a Lake Tana BR. Preliminary results of this work have already been integrated into and complemented the feasibility study (zur Heide 2012).

1.1 Rationale and Research Objective

The main objective of this research study is to identify the contextual conditions that facilitate or constrain an effective management and a wise use of wetlands along the eastern shore of Lake Tana. Effectiveness in this regard refers to the degree to which management systems are capable of sustaining wetland resources and human livelihoods. To sustain wetland resources, further research on the contextual conditions could “provide answers for future management action” (Abunie 2003: 16). Being motivated to fill some of the existent research gaps, this work seeks to distinguish the incentives and perceptions of wetland users on resource use and management as well as the values they ascribe to wetlands. This is important since the interests of different social actors shape wetland use and management 1.1. RATIONALE AND RESEARCH OBJECTIVE 7 in various ways (see Abbot et al. 2000; Wood 2003). Second, changes in wetland use and their implications for local wetland users should be assessed. Thirdly, this work seeks to better comprehend the effect of land administration on wetlands. Therefore the impact of the land registration and certification process in Amhara (see Adenew & Abdi 2005: supra note 23, 25) and land use planning on wetland management are reconstructed. Property rights and property regimes of wetlands are analysed. Fourthly, conflicts over wetlands (see Hailu & Gebrekidan 2006; Taffa 2005; Wood 2003) should be addressed. Fifthly, local management systems should be analysed in terms of their effectiveness to sustain human-wetland systems. The outcomes can then be harnessed to contribute to discussions on the designation of the Lake Tana BR by providing useful insights on the management of wetlands along the eastern lake shore. The results can be integrated into further BR planning processes. Besides, recommendations and objections deduced from the findings substan- tiate socio-economic baseline surveys on wetlands around Lake Tana that have been undertaken by an expert team of various ANRS authorities and research institutes1. These baseline surveys are part of the Community-Based Integrated Natural Resource Management Project (CBINReMP) of the Amhara regional government that aims at establishing a participatory integrated wetland ecosystem management (personal communication: BDU). In line with the objective and deduced from the outcomes that should be achieved, the main research question is the following: What are the decisive structural and relational conditions that determine an effective management and a sustainable resource utilisation of the wetlands along the eastern shore of Lake Tana? The following subquestions help answering the main question:

1. In what way do land use changes and land administration affect wetland use and management?

2. Which conflicts over wetlands and associated resources arise between the 1Bureau of Agricultural and Rural Development (BoARD), Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use Authority (EPLAUA), Bureau of Water and Energy (BoWE), BoCTPA, Bahir Dar/ University, Amhara Regional Agricultural Research Institute (personal com- munication: BoARD) 8 CHAPTER 1. INTRODUCTION

various social actors, what are their causes and consequences?

3. What are the mechanisms and means local actors draw on to benefit from the utilisation and management of wetlands?

4. Which specific factors positively or negatively influence the ability of local management institutions to effectively conserve wetland resources?

1.2 Structure

Before answering these questions, the study area is introduced in chapter 2. The theoretical background and framework that underlie analysis is outlined in chapter 3. Chapter 4 sets out the research methodology and the applied methods. The research findings are then presented in chapter 5 (Results) and analysed in chapter 6 (Analysis). They form the basis of discussion in chapter 7. Chapter 2

The Study Area

This chapter provides a description of the study area, background information on the status of wetlands in the broader political, economic context and an introduction to the national and regional land tenure policy.

2.1 Ethiopia: Social-Economic Background

Ethiopia is one of the poorest countries worldwide. Even though a continuously high economic growth has been achieved in the past years, poverty and food insecurity are still serious problems. Most of the almost 84.8 million Ethiopians live in rural areas (MoARD 2010: 2; UNEP 2011). 85% of the rural population is engaged in small-holder agriculture that significantly contributes to the gross domestic product (GDP) (MoARD 2010: 3). Consequently, agriculture is seen to be the mainstay of economic growth and development as proclaimed by the Agriculture Development-Led Industrialisation (ADLI) strategy that has been implemented since 1991 and which is a central pillar for Ethiopia’s development policies (MoARD 2010: 5).

2.2 The Amhara Region

The Amhara region (figure 2.1, p. 10, see also figure 2.2, p. 13) in which research was conducted lies in the northern part of Ethiopia. With a total of 17,214,056

9 10 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA inhabitants and a size of approximately 156,960 km2, the Amhara region is the second most populous regional state in Ethiopia (Population Census Commission 2008: 10).

Figure 2.1: Regions of Ethiopia. Source: USAID/MoARD 2010: 2

Most people are employed in agricultural activities. The high agricultural po- tential (resulting from suitable climatic conditions) and the availability of water re- sources are important preconditions for agricultural development (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 c: 4–5). Located in the region and being the country’s largest freshwater reservoir, Lake Tana significantly contributes to national economic growth through the generation of hydropower and the supply of irrigation water (Amsalu 2006: 16). The four major permanent inflowing rivers, Gilgel Abay, Gumara, Ribb and Megech are part of planned large-scale irrigation schemes (MoWE 2010: 6-8; figure 7.2, p. 131). Amhara is mainly characterised by a mountainous terrain. The major land cover/land use types that occur in ANRS are: cultivated land (35%), grazing land (18%) and woodlands (7%). Forests cover only 1.4% of the surface, marshland less than 0.2% and water bodies 2% (DSA/SCI 2006: 71–74, percentages are rounded 2.3. THE RESEARCH SITE 11 by the author). During seasonal flooding extensive wetlands1 form in the plains around Lake Tana, e. g. Kunzila in the southwest, Fogera in the east and Dembia in the north (figure 2.3, p. 14) (Amsalu 2006: 16). Seasonal flooding is an important feature of Lake Tana and its associated wetlands creating diverse wetland habitats (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 51). These harbour a rich flora and fauna, including endemic fish species of Labeobarbus and Barbus, endemic amphibians, globally threatened waterfowl, (ibid.: 40–41), large mammals such as Hippopotamus amphibius or critically endangered papyrus populations (ibid.: 45–46).

2.3 The Research Site

Field research was undertaken along the eastern shore of Lake Tana in three woredas (districts) of the in ANRS: Dera, Fogera and Libo Kemkem. According to the 2007 population census, 246,351, 226,595 and 198,374 people lived in Dera, Fogera and Libo Kemkem woredas, respectively (Population Census Commission 2008: 60). In the three woredas, population densities with 189.9 persons/km2 in Dera, 246.8 persons/km2 in Fogera and 205 persons/km2 in Libo Kemkem are higher than the regional average of 109.7 persons/km2 (Demographic data). The kebeles2 and villages/communities which were part of the investigation are listed in table 2.1, p. 12.

1 The large literature in Ethiopia defines wetlands in accordance with the Convention on Wetlands of International Importance (shortly Ramsar Convention, 1987): “wetlands are areas of marsh, fen, peatland or water, whether natural or artificial, permanent or temporary, with water that is static or flowing, fresh, brackish or salt, including areas of marine water the depth of which at low tide does not exceed six metres” (Article 1(1)). 2The kebele is a lower administrative unit, comparable to a municipality, followed by the lowest unit, the sub-kebele. 12 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA

Table 2.1: Research sites

Woreda Kebele Village/Community Dera Tanametsele Ahun Wota, Gulash, Sedechila Maryam, Sewtiye Fogera Nabega Bobatie, Luhawit, Tigremender Shina Angurbad, Girbisha Wagetera Amana, Barye, Sela, Sindeye, Wagetera Libo Kemkem Agid Kirigna/Kirnya Bahir Mender, Fota Mender, Guwala, Qurtbahir Kab Lamgie, Koker Tez Amba Daga

All of the kebeles, apart from Shina, border Lake Tana (figure 2.2, p. 13). A significant share of this border is made up of permanently or seasonally flooded wetlands (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 45; figure 2.3, p. 14)3. People living along the shores and in the fertile plains have used the lake’s resources and the associated wetlands for several hundreds of years (ibid.: 38) as (recession) farmlands4, grazing lands, for fishing, handicraft making, the construction of small fishing boats (tanquas), or as building materials (Amsalu 2006: 17; Gebrekidan 2006 b: 47). These wetlands are held under different property regimes and are often subject to an open access (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 38). Local communities mainly depend on small-holder crop production for their subsistence (Mulatu 2006: 26). Cattle rearing (traditionally, the Fogera breed (IFAD 2007: 16)), fishing and apiculture significantly contribute to rural livelihoods (Mulatu 2006: 27). The woredas lie within the tepid moist agro-ecological zone (Woina Dega, traditional classification) (DSA/SCI 2006: 13, 41–51). This corresponds to a mean annual temperature of 18.5◦C in Lake Tana watershed (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 a: 3) and one main rainy season (kiremt) between June to September, contributing to more than 70% of the mean annual rainfall (Ayalew et al. 2012:

3Two out of five main wetland types recognised by the Ramsar Convention occur along the eastern shore of Lake Tana, i. e. lacustrine and palustrine wetlands (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 45). Lacustrine wetlands are areas of permanent water with little flow (wetlands associated with lakes). Palustrine wetlands have more or less permanent water (papyrus swamps, marshes, fens, bogs) (Barbier et al. 1997: 2; Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2011: 7). 4Recession farmland is land of the lake shore zone cultivated during the dry season with the retreating water (recession cropping). 2.3. THE RESEARCH SITE 13

Agid Kirigna Kab Tana Kirkos Tez Amba Island Nabega Wagetera Shina Tanametsele

Figure 2.2: Right: Geographic location of the research area. Source: modified after Busse, MSF (2011, design, in zur Heide 2012: 152). Left: Administrative boundaries of woredas in the Lake Tana watershed. Highlighted are the three woredas (black rectangles) and the seven kebeles (black circles) included in the research study. Source: GIS Team of ANRS BoFED, modified after Busse, MSF (2011, design, in zur Heide 2012: 152)

1480; IFPRI/CSA/EDRI 2006: 20). The average annual rainfall is about 1,200 mm (SMEC 2008: 7; figure 2.4, p. 15). The study sites are located at an elevation between 1,781 m to 1,850 m a. s. l. (MoWE 2010: 4-5; figure 2.5, p. 15). The Woina Dega zone is very suitable for the cultivation of different crops, e. g. teff (Eragrostis teff ), maize (Zea mays), wheat (Triticum spp.) or pulses (DSA/SCI 2006: 108). The area is moderately to intensely cultivated (ibid.: 67–82). Vertisols (black, heavy clay soils) are the dominant soil types in the research sites. The development of wide and deep cracks during the dry season and swelling during rainy season make Vertisols difficult to plough and susceptible to erosion 14 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA

AK K TA

N W S TM

Figure 2.3: Wetlands around Lake Tana. Kebeles within the research site are indicated with black circles. TM Tanametsele, W Wagetera, N Nabega, TA Tez Amba, K Kab, AK Agid Kirigna, S Shina. Source: modified after Busse, MSF (2011, design, in zur Heide 2012: 32)

(MoWE 2010: 4-13) and water logging. Traditionally, Vertisols were used for teff production, as pastures or hay meadows. Nowadays, the cultivation of water logging tolerant rice (Oryza spp.) and residual moisture crops such as grass pea (Lathyrus sativus) and chickpea (Cicer arietinum) are important (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 a: 5; Mulatu 2006: 26). Droughts triggered by sporadic fluctuations of dry and wet years occur fre- quently (Ayalew 2012: 1481), as well as flooding of the kebeles. Flooding is caused by persistent rainfalls in combination with the Vertisols and poor water infiltration rates. Another causal factor is bank overflow from the Gumara and Ribb rivers (which mark the borders between Dera and Fogera, and Fogera and Libo Kemkem, respectively, figure 2.2, p. 13). Sediment depositions at the outlets of the rivers accelerate the overflow by reducing the rivers’ conveyance capacities. 2.3. THE RESEARCH SITE 15

Figure 2.4: Mean annual isohyets in the Figure 2.5: Altitudinal range in the Lake Lake Tana watershed in mm. Kebeles in Tana watershed in m. Kebeles in the re- the research site are indicated with black search site are indicated with black circles. circles. Source: ANRS BoARD (2011 in zur Source: MoWE (2009 in zur Heide 2012: Heide 2012: 22) 22)

Flooding is further triggered by the runoff from other local rivers and high water levels of Lake Tana with backwater effects inland (MoWE 2010: 4-9; SMEC 2008: 30–31). Annual lake level fluctuations in the range of 3.55 m (1,784.26 m a. s. l. to 1,787.81 m a. s. l.) have occurred historically (MoWE 2010: 4-9) but have been influenced due to the artificial regulation for hydropower generation (SMEC 2008; Tessema 2006: 12–14). 16 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA

2.4 Wetlands between Conservation and Development for Growth

Development projects such as the planned irrigation schemes and hydropower plants often sharply contrast with biodiversity conservation goals (see e. g. MoWE 2010). Federal policies and development strategies critically and indirectly impact on wetland ecosystems (Wood 2000). As a result, conservation efforts are often discounted in the light of attempts to ensure economic growth and food security (Mesfin 2003: 84). The Ethiopian Water Sector Strategy (2001) states that by using appropriate mechanisms such as drainage, existing wetlands should be reclaimed and the formation of new ones should be prevented (MoWR 2001: 4). The Water Sector strategy translates the Water Resources Management Policy into action (MoWE: 2010: 3-7). By contrast, the Water Resource Management Policy, only indirectly referring to wetlands, calls for the conservation, protection and enhancement of water resources and the aquatic environment to assure sustainability (Fisseha 2003: 77; MoWR 1999). The federal Growth and Transformation Plan (GTP) and Ethiopia’s Agri- cultural Sector Policy and Investment Framework (PIF) aim at transforming subsistence agriculture to a more market-led, commercialised production (MoARD 2010: 18–19; MoFED 2010: 45). A high GDP growth of at least 10% per annum is envisaged by the GTP (MoARD 2010: 2). With the agricultural sector being the main source of growth, a shift to and an intensification of the production of marketable crops such as rice is essential (MoFED 2010: 22–23, 46). The Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development (MoARD, undated) announced the area east of Lake Tana as suitable for rain-fed rice production. Rice is considered to be the “millenium crop” (BoARD 2011 b: 1), valued for its high potential of securing food, generating income and provisioning employment (BoARD 2011 b: 2; MoARD undated: 22–23). In order to increase productivity in areas where moisture is adequate, modern drainage methods are required to gain maximal benefit from Vertisol soils (MoARD 2010: 50). The need for an increased productivity is justified by a rising demand 2.5. LAND POLICY IN ETHIOPIA 17 for products due to population and GDP growth5, and the growing demand of international markets (MoARD 2010: 45). The Environmental Policy states that “wetlands [. . . ] are fundamental in regulating water quality and quantity” (EPA/MoEDC 1997: 11) and “their rehabilitation and protection [are essential for] the conservation, development and management of water resources” (ibid.: 11). Wetland conservation constitutes an integral part of water resource development and management (Fisseha 2003: 77). But similar to the Water Resource Management Policy, the Environmental Policy is rather functionalist in its approach to wetland conservation, disregarding the broad spectrum of environmental services that wetlands provide (Wood 2000: 10). Ethiopia ratified the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) in 1994 and prepared a National Biodiversity Strategy and Action Plan in 2005 (IFAD 2007: 8) indicating the importance of wetlands for biodiversity conservation and the threats for their preservation (Institute of Biodiversity Conservation 2005: 16–18). The Convention on Wetlands of International Importance has not yet been signed (zur Heide 2012: 121). So far, agricultural development often remains the antagonist of wetland protection. After outlining the status of wetlands in the political, economic context, a short introduction to the land administration system in Ethiopia and ANRS follows, providing information to allow for a better understanding of the effect of land administration on wetland management.

2.5 Land Policy in Ethiopia

“The right to ownership of rural and urban land, as well as of all natural resources, is exclusively vested in the State and in the peoples of Ethiopia. Land is a common property of the Nations, Nationalities and peoples of Ethiopia and shall not be subject to sale or to other means of exchange” (Federal Constitution 1994: Article 40(3)). Article 40(3) of the Federal Constitution announced the continuation of state ownership of land after the fall of the socialist regime (1975–

5Hence agricultural growth becomes an itself accelerating process. 18 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA

1991). The nationalisation of land has not been discussed without controversies. The government builds its arguments for nationalisation on the principles of egalitarianism and equity: Any farmer should have an equal right to access of land. Tenure security should be accomplished by preventing land grabbing. Landholders are granted only usufruct rights excluding the rights to sell or mortgage land. The advocates of the privatisation of land ownership stress the increased efficiency of production on privatised land through encouraging land investments and sustainable land use practices that are lacking under state ownership (Crewett et al. 2008: 1–2; Crewett & Korf 2008: 203–207; Miller & Tolina 2008: 367–369). To ensure that each farmer had access to land, land redistribution during the socialist regime and under the current government became frequent. Redistribution resulted in the continuous fragmentation of land and an increased tenure insecurity since land could be taken from the farmers at any time for the purpose of allocation (Miller & Tolina 2008: 363–366; see Pausewang (undated); Rahmato 1993). In ANRS, the last major legally permitted land redistribution was carried out in 1997 (Deininger et al. 2007: 5). Land redistribution has yet not completely been banned (Miller & Tolina 2008: 365). The legislation allows for a local redistribution procedure that requires the consent of the majority of landholders (Regulation No. 51/2007: §6). With the objective to improve tenure security and to address environmental degradation related to this insecurity, land registration and certification pro- grammes were introduced in several regions of Ethiopia. The beginning of registra- tion and certification in Amhara in 2003 marked the first attempt to systematically register rural land (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 8, 10; SARDP/BoEPLAU/ORGUT 2010: 9)6. The Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use Authority (EPLAUA), established in 2000, is responsible for land administration, including the coordination of the registration process (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12). Land registration and certification is designed as a participatory process, democratic, transparent, seeking the involvement of the farmers in land survey and registration and the election of Kebele Land Administration (and Use) Committees (LAC) (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 16; Deininger et al. 2007: 13; Regulation No.

6A brief overview of the steps of land registration and certification is provided by SARDP/BoEPLAU/ORGUT (2010) and Deininger et al. (2006). 2.5. LAND POLICY IN ETHIOPIA 19

51/2007: §§19, 24(3), 26, 27, 28). The duties and responsibilities of the kebele and sub-kebele LAC members include: undertaking registration activities (Deininger et al. 2006: 8–9), adminis- tering communal holdings, managing unused land and planning for its utilisation or keeping documents (Regulation No. 51/2007: §§27, 28). LAC members are elected for a period of three years (ibid.: §26(1)). In Amhara, survey teams and land administration experts of the Woreda Environmental Protection and Land Administration and Use office (WoEPLAU) are involved in and supervise land registration (Deininger 2007: 7, 16–17). The duties and responsibilities of the woreda authorities involve among others the administration and management of state holding, training of LACs, supervision of the fulfilment of farmers’ obligations regarding resource use and management (Regulation No. 51/2007: §25). Figure 2.6, p. 19 shows the organogram of land administration in ANRS.

Region: Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use Authority (EPLAUA)

Zone: Zonal Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use

Woreda: Woreda Environmental and Land Administration and Use office (WoEPLAU)

Kebele: Kebele Land Administration Committee (LAC)

Sub–kebele: Sub-Kebele Land Administration Committee

Figure 2.6: Organisation of land administration in ANRS. Source: modified after Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12

The following chapter presents the theoretical background and framework of this study. 20 CHAPTER 2. THE STUDY AREA Chapter 3

Theoretical Background and Framework

Wetlands are open linked human-nature systems. In order to get a thorough understanding of how system interlinkages influence the effectiveness of wetland management, this work seeks to “integrate insights from three bodies of schol- arship” (Armitage 2008: 8): common property theory, resilience and political ecology. Wetland resources are common-property resources owned by the state but used by local people as well as non-residents. Common-property theory provides useful insights into the problems but likewise opportunities of common-pool resource governance. Resilience thinking then contributes significant implications for an adaptive and multi-level governance of wetlands (Armitage 2008: 15; Folke 2006: 262). Political ecology unveils the socio-political processes that underlie wetland utilisation and management. The theoretical framework, which guides the present work’s analysis and will be presented later on, incorporates these three complementary bodies of scholarship (figure 3.1, p. 24).

3.1 Common-Property Theory

Common-pool or common-property resources are characterised by the difficulty of exclusion and the subtractability of benefits (Becker & Ostrom 1995: 115). To

21 22 CHAPTER 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND FRAMEWORK manage common-pool resources sustainably, users must solve a collective action problem. A collective action problem arises out of a social dilemma in which the outcomes of individual rationality of resource appropriation (overuse, degradation) conflict with optimal outcomes for a group (Agrawal 2001: note 6, 1666; Ostrom 2009 b: 30). In the 1990s, Ostrom identified design principles of robust property rights institutions1 (Becker & Ostrom 1995: 118–122; Ostrom 2009 b) “that help to account for the success of these institutions in sustaining the [common-pool resources]” (Ostrom 1990: 90 in Agrawal 2001: 1652) and to overcome collective action problems. “Robustness [. . . ] focuses on adaptability to disturbance: ‘the maintenance of some desired system characteristics despite fluctuations in the behaviour of its component parts or its environment’”(Carlson and Doyle 2002 in Ostrom 2009 b: 31).

3.2 Resilience Thinking

Resilience thinking enriches this concept of robust institutions. As an important component of social-ecological systems, robust institutions (Folke 2006) may not only be characterised by the capacity to sustain the system and adapt to change, but also to develop and transform the system (ibid.: 254, 262). Social-ecological resilience includes “(1) the ability of a system to absorb or buffer disturbances and still maintain its core attributes; (2) the ability of the system to self-organise; and (3) the capacity of learning and adaptation in the context of change” (Armitage 2008: 15; see Folke 2006: 259–260). Uncertainty and system change require an understanding of both the ecological and social dimensions of resilience (Folke 2006: 260). A comprehension of the role of social capital and conflicts and a recognition of the flexibility of organisations and institutions are important to understand social system features (ibid.: 261). Resilience thinking provides four essential norms for multi-level governance2 (also termed adaptive co-management) of common-property resources: (1) to

1For a definition of institutions, see p. 29. 2In general, governance of natural resources can be defined as “[. . . ] the whole of public as well as private interactions taken to solve societal problems and create societal opportunities” and includes “[. . . ] the formulation and application of principles guiding those interactions and care for institutions that enable them” (Kooiman & Bavinck 2007: 17 in Armitage 2008: 9). 3.3. POLITICAL ECOLOGY 23

“learn to live which change and uncertainty” (Armitage 2008: 16) (2) by integrating different knowledge systems, (3) to cherish diversity to allow for the re-organisation and renewal of the system and (4) to facilitate self-organisation to enhance the sustainability of the social-ecological system (ibid.: 16).

3.3 Political Ecology

Political ecology can help to understand the social processes and values shaping commons governance (Armitage 2008: 8, 19). With Bryant (1991), political ecology “may be defined as an inquiry into the political sources, conditions, and ramifications of environmental change” (p. 165). In political ecology (1) the context of environmental change, i. e. the impact of state and policies on changes, is approached, (2) location-specific aspects of environmental change are investigated, e. g. the conflict over access, and (3) the effects such changes have on social, economic and political relationships are assessed (Bryant 1991: 165). A core theme is the role of power that conditions relationships between social actors as well as human-environment links (Armitage 2008: 21; Bryant 1997: 10). The concept of power can be understood as “the capacity of some actors to affect the practices and ideas of others” (Weber 1978: 53; Lukas 1986: 3 both in Ribot & Peluso 2003: 155–156) or as the control actors exercise over the environment of other actors (Bryant 1997: 11). Armitage (2008) points to the intersections of political ecology and resilience thinking, e. g. nested hierarchies, multiple scales, and the self-organisation of complex systems.

3.4 Theoretical Assumptions

Based on these insights, the following theoretical assumptions which are of relevance to this work can be made. (1) The alteration of wetlands is driven by social, economic, political and ecological factors, at the same time influences these contextual factors, and is shaped by various social actors, organisations and institutions. (2) Wetland use changes involve conflicts over access to and use of common-pool resources. (3) Conflicts affect people’s livelihoods and the resource 24 CHAPTER 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND FRAMEWORK

COMMON RESILIENCE PROPERTY THEORY Change Property rights Adaptabtability Institutions Transformability Collective action Self-organisation

POLITICAL ECOLOGY Power relations Influence of policies Conflicts Social processes

Figure 3.1: Three complementary bodies of scholarship. Source: modified after Armitage 2008: 10 base. (4) The access to and use of common-property resources is mediated by social relations and underlying power relations. (5) The unregulated utilisation of common-property resources often entails degradation and overexploitation of these resources (e. g. Ostrom 2009 b: 30). (6) The resilience of the social-ecological system depends, inter alia, upon the robustness and effectiveness of resource management institutions. “Governance of the commons is a complex systems problem [drawing] attention to social and ecological system properties” (Armitage 2008: 8). The theoretical framework, as described below, helps to unravel, structure and deconstruct the complexity of the social-ecological system under consideration.

3.5 Theoretical Framework

The environmental entitlements approach (Leach et al. 1999) provides a useful entr´eeinto the analysis of complex human-wetland systems by focusing on the role of institutions and their cross-scale interactions in shaping system components. The entitlements analysis emphasises the structural and relational mechanisms 3.5. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 25 social actors draw on to benefit from wetland resources that likely influence system properties. Furthermore, the social-ecological, political and economic ramifications of wetland use changes, including conflicts over wetland resources, can be adequately depicted. To understand which actors use what wetland resources with what intention and to subsequently address the social implications of wetland alteration, this section commences with a basic introduction to environmental entitlements. In their approach, Leach et al. (1999) refer to endowments as the rights and resources (i. e. capitals or assets, see DFID 1999 a) social actors3 have. Endowments can be obtained from environmental goods and services, e. g. wetland resources and provided ecosystem services. Environmental entitlements are “alternative sets of utilities derived from environmental goods and services over which social actors have legitimate effective command4 and which are instrumental in achieving well-being” (Leach et al. 1999: 233), i. e. what people can have (de Haan and Zoomers 2005: 35). Capabilities are seen with Sen as what people can do or be with their entitlements (Leach et al. 1999: 233) including non-material aspects (Scoones 1998: 6) such as information and knowledge, relationships, reputation or acquisition of skills (see the ‘endowment-entitlements-capabilities chains’ in figure 3.2, p. 28). In a cyclical process, the practices of wetland users, directed towards the maintenance or enhancement of capabilities, are able to transform wetland compo- nents in various ways (see Leach et al. 1999: 239). These practices are performed within an institutional setting and a broader context5 (see the arrows emanating from the ‘capabilities/well-being’ box and the ‘context’ in figure 3.2, p. 28). Thereby ‘endowment-entitlements-capabilities chains’ of resource users are altered to their advantage or disadvantage. Importantly, in social-ecological systems, the sustainability of livelihoods is closely tied to the ecological resilience of the system

3Following Leach et al. 1999, ‘social actor’ refers to (1) individuals and (2) a group having common characteristics, like social status or ethnicity. 4A ‘legitimate command’ is a command that is socially sanctioned either by formal or informal rights. (Leach et al. 1999: 233). 5Environmental entitlements are embedded in a social, political, economic and ecological context which shapes livelihoods, defined as people’s “capabilities, assets (material and social resources) and activities required for a means of living” (Chambers & Conway 1992 in DFID 1999 b). 26 CHAPTER 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND FRAMEWORK

(Folke 2006)6. How people gain endowments from wetlands and how these are transformed into entitlements are questions addressed through endowment and entitlement mapping, respectively (Leach et al. 1999: 232–233). The mapping processes are essential to an entitlements analysis, for this is where underlying aspects concerning power within social relations and access to resources emerge (ibid.: 233). Here, the environmental entitlements approach is complemented with the theory of access by Ribot & Peluso (2003). Unlike in property theory, Ribot & Peluso (2003) define access “as the ability to benefit from things” (p. 153), e. g. from wetland resources. Access is more related to a “bundle of powers” than a “bundle of rights” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 153; see Ostrom 2009 b: 27–29), and “focusing on ability, rather than rights [. . . ] brings attention to a wider range of social relationships that can constrain or enable people to benefit from resources without focusing on property relations alone” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 154). Ribot & Peluso (2003) define access control as “the ability to mediate others’ access” (p. 158), and access maintenance as keeping access. Actors mediate (or determine) and keep access through means of power and resource expenditure. Gaining access refers to a “more general process by which access is established” (ibid.: p. 159). Access analysis comprises the identification (1) of a particular benefit flow of interest to social actors (comparable to the identification of endowments, entitlements, capabilities), (2) the mechanisms through which people gain, control and maintain access to benefits, and (3) an analysis of power relations which determine whether, how and to which extent social actors gain access to resources (ibid.: 160–161). Mechanisms of access can be categorised into (1) rights-based mechanisms, and (2) structural and relational access mechanisms (Leach et al. 1999: 233; Ribot & Peluso 2003: 161–172; see horizontal arrows in figure 3.2, p. 28). “When the ability to benefit from [wetland resources and services] derives

6“A livelihood is sustainable when it can cope with and recover from stresses and shocks and maintain or enhance its capabilities and assets both now and in the future, while not undermining the natural resource base” (Chambers & Conway 1992 in DFID 1999 b). Livelihood sustainability comprises social and ecological resilience. Ecological or ecosystem resilience means the “capacity of a system to absorb disturbance and re-organise while undergoing change so as to still retain [. . . ] function, structure, identity and feedbacks” (Walker et al. 2004 in Folke 2006: 259). 3.5. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 27 from rights attributed by law, custom, or convention” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 162), the benefited person may then have a property right, i. e. an endowment, to benefit from these resources and services (ibid.: 162). At this junction, the theory of access encounters the concept of property rights (Schlager & Ostrom 1992 in Ostrom 2003: 249–252 and Ostrom 2009 b: 27–29). The supplement of a property rights perspective to the theoretical framework is useful for identifying the differently positioned social actors and their property rights over wetlands, and for understanding the way different bundles of property rights affect wetland management. Schlager & Ostrom 1992 (in Ostrom 2009 b: 27–29) proposed thinking of property rights systems not as a single right but rather in terms of bundles of rights. They defined the following five rights which are “most relevant for the use of common-pool resources” (Ostrom 2003: 249):

1. Access: the right to enter a defined area and enjoy non-subtractive benefits,

2. Withdrawal: the right to obtain resource units or products of a resource system,

3. Management: the right to regulate internal use patterns and transform the resource by making improvements,

4. Exclusion: the right to determine who will have an access right, and how that right may be transferred,

5. Alienation: the right to sell or lease exclusion, management or withdrawal rights

(Ostrom 2003: 249–250). In a later work Ostrom & Schlager (1996 in Ostrom 2003: 250–252) associate bundles of rights with positions, i. e. property-rights holders (table 3.1, p. 28). 28 CHAPTER 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND FRAMEWORK

Table 3.1: Bundles of property rights associated with positions. Source: Ostrom & Schlager (1996) in Ostrom 2003: 251

Full Proprietor Authorised Authorised Authorised owner claimant user entrant Access + + + + + Withdrawal + + + + – Management + + + – – Exclusion + + – – – Alienation + – – – –

The way people gain endowments and entitlements is mediated by various interacting institutions that manage wetland resources and work on different scales (micro, meso, macro; see the blue boxes appearing to the right in figure 3.2, p. 28).

Context (social, ecological, Environmental political, economic) goods & services SOCIAL & POWER RELATIONS

Macro Meso Institutions Micro Endowment mapping

Endowments MECHANISMS (capital & rights) OF ACCESS Macro Meso Institutions Micro Entitlement mapping

Entitlements

Macro Meso * Institutions Micro

Capabilities/ well-being

Social actors

Figure 3.2: Environmental entitlements framework. * It was not part of this investigation to analyse according to which concrete mechanisms and arrangements entitlements are transformed into capabilities at the household level. Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234 3.5. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 29

The focus of this work is on local management systems but considers local institutions as being nested inside and interacting with larger ones. The large literature defines institutions as sets of formal and informal rules and conventions, shaping behaviour and interactions (e. g. Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 637, note 46, 644; but cf. Leach et al. 1999: 237). Rules are made and remade through regularised practices and patterns of behaviour and may be challenged in the course of institutional change (Leach et al. 1999: 237, 238). Institutions impinge on access to resources, influence the use and management of resources, shape and transform wetland ecosystems (Leach et al. 1999: 234, see also 238–240), and by so doing affect the resilience of social-ecological systems. The analysis of institutions pertaining to wetland management further draws on insights from the research on governance of common-property resources and community-based natural resource management by Agrawal (2001), Agrawal & Gibson (1999), Becker & Ostrom (1995), Ostrom (2003, 2009 a, 2009 b), Ostrom et al. (1999) and others. Comprehensive studies on these topics provide useful knowledge of the conditions that strengthen or weaken local wetland management institutions. To conclude this chapter, figure 3.3, p. 30 simplistically depicts how common- property theory, resilience thinking and political ecology as well as the research questions (p. 7) fit in the theoretical framework. The methodology and methods applied for the present research work are elaborated in the next chapter. 30 CHAPTER 3. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND FRAMEWORK

Context Wetland What are the decisive structural and relational resources & PE: SOCIAL & POWER services RELATIONS conditions that determine Macro Meso an effective wetland Institutions Micro management and a sustainable resource utilisation? Endowment mapping CPT PE Endowments What are the mechanisms and means local actors (capital & rights) draw on to benefit from In what way does wetlands? land administration SER affect wetland use In what way do Entitlement mapping and management? land use changes affect wetland use Entitlements Which factors influence and management? the ability of local management institutions to effectively conserve wetland resources?

Capabilities/ well-being Which conflicts over wetlands Social actors arise?

Figure 3.3: Integrating theory and research questions. The emergence of the three complementary bodies of scholarship and research questions within the theoretical framework. CPT common- property theory, PE political ecology, SER social-ecological resilience (the focus here is on the question of why social-ecological resilience is or is not achieved). Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234 Chapter 4

Methodology and Methods

This chapter provides a short introduction to the research approach of this study and further describes the methods applied and procedures for data collection. An outline on data preparation and analysis adjoins.

4.1 Research Approach

This research study follows a qualitative research approach. Qualitative research seeks to describe social realities through an internal perspective of the actor(s) (Flick et al. 2009: 14). People act according to their subjective intentions and the meanings they ascribe to phenomena within a historical and situational context (Flick et al. 2009: 20; Mayring 2002: 22–23). To understand these actions and their outcomes, subjective perspectives and intentions need to be reconstructed and interpreted (Flick et al. 2009: 20; Mayring 2002: 22). Qualitative research concentrates on theory generation on the basis of em- pirical data and employs an inductive approach (without questioning deductive approaches per se) (Lamnek 2010: 222). Theories are generated in the course of the entire research process rather than verified by means of the research entity (Mayring 2002: 36–37). The inductive approach allows the researcher to continuously develop, verify, reject, modify and integrate hypotheses forming the basis of the theoretical framework (Lamnek 2010: 98). Theory generation is not a linear but a cyclical process. Data collection and data analysis thus take

31 32 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS place simultaneously and are mutually supportive (ibid.: 97). Grounded theory, developed by B. G. Glaser and A. L. Strauss in the 1950s and 60s (Mayring 2002: 103), is a methodology to generate theories which was applied for data collection and analysis of the present research study. Grounded means anchored in empirical evidence (Lamnek 2010: 90, 91). A qualitative approach is considered suitable for this study. In order to gain insights on the decisive conditions for an effective wetland management, it was indispensable to understand actors’ perceptions and incentives on wetland use and management and their attitudes towards conservation. Further on, though the kebeles do not extend over a large geographical area (figure 2.2, p. 13) it could neither be assumed that local conditions are the same everywhere, nor that they are distinct. Developing a definite theory before visiting the kebeles was therefore unfeasible. Likewise, it was unreasonable to create fixed hypotheses, given the assumed heterogeneity of local communities and even more importantly the lack of information on local management systems and influencing factors. The methods for collecting empirical data on the research topic are elaborated below.

4.2 Data Collection

This section presents the research designs of the applied data collection methods, namely Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA) and problem-centred interview meth- ods. All PRA discussions and interviews were held and conducted from September to November 2011.

4.2.1 Participatory Rural Appraisal and Group Discussions

In order to get an understanding of the complex structural and relational conditions that determine the effectiveness of wetland management, the participation of relevant actors is crucial. Since dialogues with responsible stakeholders and communication with local communities on wetland resource management have been rare (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 38), this work is especially motivated to ask and involve relevant social actors to understand their internal perspectives. PRA comprises suitable methods motivating people to become involved, and can be 4.2. DATA COLLECTION 33 defined as “a family of approaches and methods to enable rural people to share, enhance, and analyse their knowledge of life and conditions, to plan and to act” (Chambers 1994 b: 953). “PRA is thus designed to empower” (Chambers 1994 a: 1266) local people1.

4.2.1.1 Selection of the Research Sites

Wetlands of the study area were considered to be potentially relevant to both the Lake Tana biosphere reserve and the CPINReMP (personal communication: BDU; BoCTPD; zur Heide) due to their importance for biodiversity conservation and concurrent critical linkages with exploitative human activities. The insufficiency in available social-ecological data motivated the site selection. Rather pragmatical criteria were the proximity to the regional capital, Bahir Dar which was the base camp (figure 2.2, p. 13), and the accessibility of the villages. Due to flooding, the kebeles along the shore of Lake Tana could only be accessed by boat or car using ‘rocky’ roads. Travelling was costly in terms of money and time.

4.2.1.2 Group Size, Composition and Selection of the Participants

PRA is a group activity. The group size ranged from two to many, usually five to eight participants. Occasionally, interested persons joined the discussions during the process. Discussions were thus generally open to all, except during discussions with women and fishermen of the Woito tribe when explicitly unwelcome. Local participants should live close to a wetland or use the wetland resources (theoretical relevance, Glaser & Strauss 2010: 65–66). The persons should have time and interest in discussing the relevant topic. Locally and especially on working and conference days, it was difficult to find people who had enough time to take part in PRA (timing bias, see Kumar 2002: 37). Thus the few ones present were asked to participate. (Due to the lack of people’s time some PRA processes were rushed and interrupted.) At central locations (e. g. village centres where many people gathered), there was a possibility to ‘pick out’ PRA participants which

1Note that the objective of this research work and the expected outcomes justify a rather ‘extractive’ data mining, i. e. local people were asked to share their knowledge about the human-wetland system. 34 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS were otherwise difficult to reach (e. g. development agents, kebele leaders, LAC members or people trained in wetland management). PRA sessions were also held with woreda officials. Their official duties or their expertise in the relevant topic were seen to be of interest for this study. PRA groups were either homogeneous (e. g. women, Woito fishermen, young- sters) or heterogeneous (e. g. landless and livestock farmers, farmers and kebele leaders) (see Glaser & Strauss 2010: 70–71). Group composition, important to make people feel easy during the discussions, was mainly chosen intentionally and sometimes randomly depending on the situation. In very heterogeneous groups, marginalised people (e. g. poor and young) were at times incapable of freely expressing their views (elite bias, see Kumar 2002: 35). Efforts were made to address them directly and provide them a chance to talk. Women and Woito fishermen felt easier and were more open when discussions were held separate from men or members of other communities, respectively. Generally, women infrequently participated in PRA. Their perceptions and knowledge is therefore inadequately represented (male bias, see Kumar 2002: 36).

4.2.1.3 General Procedure

After selecting the PRA participants a suitable, often shadowy location was chosen. Each PRA session began with an introduction of the research team. The purpose of the discussion and the procedure was explained. Mostly, the names, age, occupation, official duties and partly endowments of the participants were registered. The process was initiated by a general question, e. g.: ‘Which services does the wetland provide to you?’ or ‘Have you perceived any changes in your environment or the way the land is used?’. Further questions went along with the visualisation of the answers (maps, diagrams, matrices etc.) using paper and pen. Some participants were unfamiliar utilising pens and paper, and felt shy or uneasy drawing. Utilisation of other (natural) materials would have been a solution but was often unfeasible. Due to the lack of time or spontaneously arising opportunities of conducting discussions, visualisation was occasionally omitted. Subsequent to visualisation, the discussion, i. e. the interview about the visual 4.2. DATA COLLECTION 35 output, helped clarifying questions and understanding complex issues and problems that emerged (see Chambers 1994 a: 1263; Kumar 2002: 44). Very often, the discussion itself revealed additional interesting facts. Occasionally, participants were highly suspicious when asked sensitive questions, e. g. about land tenure and conflicts (diplomatic bias; see Kumar 2002: 37), and the discussion had to be shifted into ‘calm water’. At the end of the PRA session, participants were asked whether they wanted to give additional comments and recommendations or to make some statements. Each session took approximately one to two and a half hours.

With the help of my colleague, Babiyew Sibhat, the PRA sessions were directly translated from Amharic to English and vice versa. Of course, research that is not conducted in the researcher’s mother tongue makes an entire understanding of social realities even more difficult. Subsequent reflections on the processes helped to adequately understand people’s ‘words between the lines’ and the hidden social relations.

During the PRA sessions, participants’ contributions to discussions were noted as precisely as possible. Sketches of the maps, diagrams etc. were made to add personal comments and memos. These scripts, sketches and photographs of the maps, diagrams etc. form the basis of data analysis (see p. 42).

The sampling of further data on the research subject usually terminated when, apparently, no additional information and issues emerged (theoretical saturation, see Glaser & Strauss 2010: 77). Due to the inaccessibility of Agid Kirigna kebele, sampling did not reach its theoretical saturation, making further research necessary.

Despite constraints to data collection, most of the participants vigilantly observed the gradual development of maps and diagrams and vitally discussed the emerging issues. PRA was a welcome variation of everyday life and a method perceived as positive to ask people about their views and ideas (personal commu- nication: farmers in Agid Kirigna). Appendix 1, p. I lists the concrete application procedure of each PRA method. 36 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS

4.2.1.4 Methods of Participatory Rural Appraisal

Table 4.1, p. 36 provides an overview of the applied PRA methods and their intended use. For a general description of the PRA methods and their application see Kumar (2002).

Table 4.1: Methods of PRA and group discussions. The identification numbers (ID No.) follow the numbering used in the field. Group discussions indicated with the abbreviation ‘BS’ were held by Babiyew Sibhat. Numbers in brackets indicate primary document (P) numbering in ATLAS.ti. * Discussions without visualisation

Purpose ID No. Participants Location2 Resource map Depiction of wetland uses and 2 (P2) Farmers, landless, Sedechila management, land tenure, re- priest Mariam, source use conflicts; get an idea Sewtiye about the broader landscape, 6 (P6) Farmers, priest, DA, Wagetera locate relevant communities for health extension expert further PRA sessions 14 (P15) Landless, farmers Luhawit 18 (P21) Farmers, kebele leader, Guwala WoEPLAU representa- tive, health extension expert Trend Analysis

Get a historical perspective of 1 (P1) Farmers, nuns Ahun Wota change of land/wetland use, how 7 (P7) Farmers, nun Amana it is perceived and influences 13 (P14) Farmers Tigremender livelihoods (figure 4.1, p. 38) 19 (P22)* WoEPLAU (environ- Addis Zemen mental impact assess- ment expert, envi- ronmental education expert, land use expert, environmental impact assessment expert)

2See p. 12 4.2. DATA COLLECTION 37

Purpose ID No. Participants Location Cause-effect diagram Analyse environmental/land 3 (P3) Farmers Sedechila use changes, drivers and social- Mariam ecological ramifications (figure 4 (P4) Male and female farm- Woreta (par- 4.2, p. 38) ers ticipants are from Angur- bad) 10 (P10, DAs (natural resource Wagetera P11) management, animal science) Impact diagram (1) Perceptions on wetland con- 5 (P5) Farmers and three nuns Woreta (par- servation, management scenarios, ticipants are possible effects of these scenarios from Gir- on livelihoods; (2) livelihood basha) strategies, land use change (fig- 11 (P12) Farmers, two priests Sela ure 4.3, p. 39) 22 (P25) N/A (farmers) Fota Mender 23 (P26) Farmers Gulash Well-being ranking Identify well-being groups3; study 8 (P8) Women Sindeye conceptions of well-being, de- 15 (P16) Landless, youngsters Bobatie velopment, livelihood strategies (figure 4.4, p. 39, figure 4.5, p. 39) Venn diagram Study the importance of services, 12 (P13)* Farmers, priest Barye administrative bodies, other or- 21 (P24)* Farmers Bahir ganisations for local people, and Mender their cooperation 28 (P27) WoARD, WoEPLAU, Woreta WoWE

3The identification of well-being groups by local people includes the mapping of in-/tangible assets and their accessibility to different well-being groups. 38 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS

Purpose ID No. Participants Location Pair-wise ranking Detect resource use conflicts, 9 (P9) Farmers Sindeye conflicts between wetland con- 16 (P18) Farmers, LAC/elder Daga servation and use; causes and court, model farmer, consequences of these conflicts police man, wetland (figure 4.6, p. 39) trainee 20 (P23) Fishermen of the Woito Qurtbahir tribe Group discussions Fishery management and conser- 17 (P20)* Members of the fisher- Daga vation men’s association

Land/wetland use change; impli- BS4 Kebele leaders Addis Zemen cations on livelihoods (P54)* (participants are from Lamgie and Koker) BS5 Kebele leaders Addis Zemen (P56)* (participants are from Daga)

Figure 4.1: Trend analysis in Amana, Figure 4.2: Cause-effect diagram drawn by Wagetera. Photograph: Springsguth, M. development agents in Wagetera. Photo- graph: Springsguth, M. 4.2. DATA COLLECTION 39

Figure 4.3: Impact diagram: Livelihood Figure 4.4: Well-being ranking with strategies, Sela, Wagetera. Photograph: youth in Bobatie, Nabega. Photograph: Springsguth, M. Springsguth, M.

Figure 4.5: Well-being ranking with Figure 4.6: Pair-wise ranking with Woito women in Sindeye, Wagetera. Photograph: fishermen in Qurtbahir, Agid Kirigna. Pho- Springsguth, M. tograph: Springsguth, M.

4.2.1.5 Testing the Methods

At least two application procedures of PRA methods were tested in a PRA work- shop preliminary to their application. Though ‘PRA participants’ were almost unexceptionally experts and scientists, their comments on how to best communi- cate with farmers in the field helped to improve the PRA design. PRA procedures were continuously revised and improved to adequately respond to farmers and to enhance the data validity. Hereinafter, the second data collection method is explained. 40 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS

4.2.2 Problem-Centred Expert Interviews

Experts, woreda and regional officials and key informants were interviewed using the problem-centred interview method. The interviews were semi-structured, the questions open. A catalogue of research question was compiled and used as an interview guideline (see Appendix 2, p. XI). This method was applied to (1) verify hypotheses which were developed in the field (theory-driven method, see Mayring 2002: 70), (2) validate information and resolve questions, (3) apprehend complex human-wetland linkages by drawing on expertise and (4) arrive at the subject perspectives, interpretations and opinions of the respondent.

4.2.2.1 Selection of the Respondents

Respondents were selected according to their specialised knowledge or their official mandates which were seen to be associated with the research subject. Fairly frequently, potential further informants were filtered from previous interviews.

4.2.2.2 Interview Procedure

Each interview commenced with a personal introduction and explanation of the interview purpose. Subsequently, the respondent was asked to introduce himself (educational background, field of research, project work etc.). This intended short warm-up phase helped to choose pertinent questions from the catalogue. Introductory questions were asked followed by an open interview conversation. Spontaneously emerging issues of concern were addressed. The interviews were mainly conducted in English, a familiar language to me, and were noted in manuscript form.

4.2.2.3 Overview of the Interviews

Table 4.2, p. 41 provides an overview of the interviews conducted. 4.2. DATA COLLECTION 41

Table 4.2: Overview of Interviews. The identification numbers (ID No.) follow the numbering used in the field. Interviews marked ‘BS’ were held by Babiyew Sibhat. Numbers in brackets indicate primary document (P) numbering in ATLAS.ti.

Subject area ID No. Respondent Location Wetland 1 (P28) EWNRA Addis Ababa management 2 (P29) EWNRA Addis Ababa institutions; 5 (P32) BoARD Bahir Dar human- 6 (P33) EPLAUA (Department of Environmental Pro- Bahir Dar wetland tection) system 13 (P40) BDU Bahir Dar Human- 4 (P31) BoWE Bahir Dar wetland 7 (P34) BoWE Bahir Dar system 8 (P35) WoARD (water harvesting expert, irrigation Addis Zemen expert, rural road construction) 9 (P36) ARARI Bahir Dar 11 (P38) TaSBO Bahir Dar 12 (P39) Ethiopian Nile Irrigation and Drainage Project Bahir Dar BS2 Early warning and risk disaster management Addis Zemen (P55) processes coordinator (EWRDM) BS3 Kebele leader Wagetera (P52) Land adminis- 3 (P30) Institute of Land Administration BDU (ILA) Bahir Dar tration 10 (P37) EPLAUA Bahir Dar 17 (P42) WoEPLAU Woreta 18 (P43) WoEPLAU Addis Zemen Fisheries 14 (P41) Bahir Dar Fisheries and other Aquatic Life Bahir Dar Research Centre (ARARI) BS1 WoARD (fish resources development expert) Addis Zemen (P53) 42 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS

4.3 Data Preparation and Analysis

Primary data (PRA, group discussions, interviews, own observations) were available in manuscript notes. The preparation of primary data before analysis comprised summarising and selecting the relevant data material (see Mayring 2002: 94–99). The analysis of the processed primary data and secondary data (two group discussions and three interviews conducted by Babiyew Sibhat) was done us- ing ATLAS.ti, a qualitative data analysis software that helps organising data and facilitates the conceptualisation and categorisation of research data and the development of hypotheses (see Friese 2012: 9–10). In grounded theory, coding/conceptualisation is a fundamental method which aims at developing categories (Glaser & Strauss 2010: 119–120). Concepts can be defined as con- cise designations which can be attributed to events, phenomena, occurrences etc. (Muckel 2007: 216–217), and are “relevant theoretical abstractions of what happens in the analysed field” (Glaser & Strauss 2010: 41). Categories can be created by classifying concepts which refer to similar phenomena. Hypotheses are generalised relations between categories (Glaser & Strauss 2010: 56–57). Conceptualisation and categorisation already take place during data collection. The processed primary and secondary data material was stored as primary documents in one hermeneutic unit of ATLAS.ti, i. e. the “container” for each project that includes all primary documents (Friese 2012: 13–14). Open coding in ATLAS.ti marked the beginning of data analysis. The data material was freely associated with codes (see Appendix 3, p. XVIII) and accurately analysed for already assigned or new codes. Questions and memos were written (see Muckel 2007: 221; Strauss 1994: 57–62). The writing of memos is a central element of Grounded Theory and aims at clarifying, combining and differentiating aspects and concepts to finally integrate them to form a theoretical construct. Memos are essential during data collection and analysis (see Friese 2012: 18; Mayring 2002: 105). PRA sessions, group discussions and interviews were screened for the same codes. In this way, the different data sets could be analysed for conformity and consistency and for variety and differences to make them comparable. Axial and selective coding in ATLAS.ti was mainly done with the help of the query tool and the co-occurrence table explorer (see Friese 2012: 251–267, 285– 4.3. DATA PREPARATION AND ANALYSIS 43

287), by linking of quotations and drawing networks on paper (since it was not possible to create ‘sub-networks’ in ATLAS.ti). Axial coding aims at developing and consolidating categories and helps to structure a theory. A provisional concept is analysed according to the coding paradigm, i. e. a code is tested for its conditions, interactions, strategies and consequences (Muckel 2007: 224). Selective coding means to systematically relate various categories to key categories. The further analysis of this relation according to the coding paradigm, and writing of focused memos can finally be integrated into a grounded theory (Strauss 1994: 63–64). The output of each query result was stored as a super code (see Friese 2012: 267–271). Analysis itself was a gradual and cyclical process: codes and memos were developed according to the material, completed, complemented, revised, compared and linked (see Mayring 2002: 106, 145–146). ATLAS.ti very well supported this open, flexible, dynamic and reflective analytical process. Data was validated by triangulation. Triangulation offsets the weaknesses of one way to access data with the strengths of another (Lamnek 2010: 141–142). Sources of primary, secondary and tertiary data (e. g. paper, legal documents) were combined to validate information and findings, and to clarify uncertainties (data triangulation). PRA sessions and interviews were discussed and analysed with my research colleague so that misconceptions could be resolved and subjective influences could be corrected (investigator triangulation). Different PRA methods, and PRA with problem-centred interviews were combined for methodological triangulation (see Denzin 1978, in Lamnek 2002: 142). In order to allow for the comparison of research data, the following comparison groups were identified and categorised:

• Social actors in different research sites: Distinctions and similarities between comparison groups are determined by the locality, local conditions, ecological conditions or social processes.

• Social actors of different well-being groups, social status, ethnicity: Distinc- tions and similarities between comparison groups are determined by their membership of well-being groups (landless, lower, middle, upper), social status (kebele leaders/administration, LAC members, rich people, nuns, 44 CHAPTER 4. METHODOLOGY AND METHODS

priests) and ethnicity (Woito tribe).

• Social actors distinguished by their values, objectives and priorities. (This category is often linked to the former.)

The manuscript notes of primary and secondary data sources are quoted using the quotations assigned to the notes in ATLAS.ti. A quotation, e. g. 2:34, indicates the number of the primary document (2) and the consecutive quotation number within the primary document (34). Names of the institutes of interview respondents are indicated. The results that were obtained by the above mentioned methods are presented in the following chapter. Chapter 5

Results

The results presented in this chapter provide insights into environmental and land use changes, and the consequences of these changes on rural livelihoods. Further on, the conflicts over wetlands and their associated resources, and the effects of land administration on wetland utilisation are addressed. Finally, common-pool resource management institutions and the conditions that constrain an effective management are presented. But first of all, this chapter provides an introduction to the values of wetlands, perceptions of well-being and people’s objectives regarding their lives. These are fundamental in understanding wetland utilisation.

5.1 Values of Wetlands

Wetlands provide various tangible assets to local people: • fodder and hay for livestock (e. g. 6:1; 7:25; 9:4; 14:13; 24:17)

• crops (due to high wetland soil fertility) (e. g. 6:1; 9:4; 14:11; 25:3; 26:4)

• water for domestic supply, animal drinking (e. g. 7:25; 9:4; 14:13)

• irrigation water (using water pumps, canisters, by wetland drainage) (e. g. 6:1; 9:4; 21:7)

• fish (especially valued by the Woito tribe, whose livelihoods depend upon fishery) (e. g. 7:25; 9:4; 23:3)

45 46 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

• plant species for roof thatching, handicraft making, protection against flood, ornamental purposes or tanqua building (e. g. 8:16; 9:4; 21:10; 52:19).

Wetlands are further valued for their social and cultural importance (15:13; 25:15). Rather seldom the regulating (2:17; 7:25; 9:4; 15:3; 24:31) and the habitat function of wetlands are acknowledged (e. g. 7:25; 14:13; 18:10). The instrumental (direct use) value of wetlands for humans is given high priority. The socio-economic contribution of wetlands is recognised by officials (crop production, irrigation water supply, addressing landlessness) (BoWE: 31:5; BoWE: 34:1; TaSBO: 38:1; WoARD: 35:1). The Ethiopian government recognises the ability of wetlands to store carbon as a contribution to mitigate climate change (EWNRA: 29:1; see MoARD 2010: 15). Scientists and conservationists generally emphasise the ecological functions of wetlands (ARARI: 36:26; EPLAUA: 33:1; figure 5.1, p. 46).

Regulating Supporting Sediment trapping, Carbon sequestration temperature regulation, ground water retention, flood control, buffer zone

Provisioning

Animal feed, productive arable land, domestic water supply, Cultural irrigation water supply, fish, Recreation (refreshment), plants for handicrafts, roof ornamental purposes, thatching etc., ceremonies, habitats for fauna and flora distribution as a solution to socio-economic problems

Figure 5.1: Ecosystem services of wetlands as perceived by various stakeholders. Ecosystem services, providing benefits to humans, can be classified into: provisioning, regulating, supporting and cultural (MA 2005: v-vi). Source: compiled from own results

The values people ascribe to wetlands are reflected in personal objectives set to enhance well-being and shaping wetland use. 5.2. PERCEPTIONS ON WELL-BEING AND PEOPLE’S OBJECTIVES 47

5.2 Perceptions on Well-being and People’s Objectives

Though wetlands fulfil important functions, local people perceive them to be unproductive, useless wastelands (4:38; 5:8; 7:25; 25:6; EWNRA: 32:3). One official formulated this exaggeratedly: “Wetlands are like the flesh of a monkey, people do not eat it so they do not use it” (BoWE: 31:10). Intrinsically unimportant, wetlands instrumentally contribute to people’s well- being (4:24; cf. 15:34). The natural resource endowments of the kebeles (soil fertility, water availability) are seen to be sufficient to secure and support livelihoods (8:11; 12:40; 15:10, 23:38, 56:17). “Around Lake Tana in central Amhara, [. . . ] landholdings are limited, but good rainfall, high fertility and the sales value of the abundant mix of crops (including some paddy rice) and livestock and butter make this one of the country’s wealthiest areas” (USAID/MoARD 2010: 67, see also 63–75). However, well-being ranking (see p. 37) revealed a varied picture of wealth. Local people identified four well-being groups (8:5; 16:1) which were classified on the basis of landholding size and livestock numbers as indicators of wealth1: (1) landless people: no land, (2) lower well-being group: 0.25 ha to 0.5 ha land, no or 1 ox and a few cows, (3) middle well-being group: 0.75 ha to 1.0 ha land, 1 ox and a few cows, (4) upper well-being group: more than 1.25 ha land, 2 oxen, a few to many cows, 1 horse or donkey. The four well-being groups are differently endowed with tangible and intangible assets such as health, education, authority, social status, food or clothes (see Appendix 4, p. XVIII). The application of livelihood strategies to respond to insecurities and enhance well-being varies between these groups (see 8; 16; see Appendix 5, p. XIX). For the participants (landless and members of the lower and middle well-being groups; see 8; 16), ‘development’ aims at attaining prosperity and establishing

1This classification was verified by indications of farmers’ assets (6:23; 8:35; 9:1; 15:29; 16:2; 52:2). Though de Haan and Zoomers (2005) suggest “characterising [farmers] in terms of their objectives and priorities” (p. 40), it seemed to be appropriate to classify well-being groups in terms of tangible assets due to the importance people ascribe to them (see 8:27). Woito people whose livelihoods depend rather on fish resources than on agriculture are not classified due to insufficient data. 48 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS social status. A good life encompasses education, employment, health, reputation, respect, reduced workload and material goods such as quality and balanced food, clothing, household items, farm inputs, livestock or landholding (8:24; 16:7, 16:9). By hard work a good life can be achieved (8:22; 16:4). Giving birth to many children earns respect, helps to better represent own interests within the community and reduces workload for household individuals (8:17). Whereas poor peasants strive to accumulate wealth for a good life, richer peasants are interested in the consolidation of wealth (see p. 56). The values actors ascribe to wetlands, people’s perceptions on well-being and their objectives shape wetland resource appropriation. Different well-being groups utilise and manage wetland resources in different ways (e. g. 7:48; 8:20; 23:24; 43:16; see p. 56). The next section addresses changes in wetland resource utilisation and use regimes, which is necessary to understand the effects of land use changes on wetland management.

5.3 Environmental and Land Use Changes

Land use changes in the wetlands around Lake Tana have significantly increased and become a threat to the integrity of the ecological system (Amsalu 2006: 19). The major environmental and land use changes in the wetlands east of the lake as perceived by local people are: unusual flooding events, sedimentation, changes in the cropping pattern (including the conversion of wetlands especially for rice cultivation, resulting in a continuous loss of wetlands) and increasing fishing activities (e. g. 1:18; 3:6; 4:30; 7:52; 14:23; 23:10; 54:8, 54:12; ARARI: 36:3; EWNRA: 29:4). These changes and their drivers are shortly described below. Other changes detected by farmers are the increase in area of settlements (Appendix 6, p. XXIV) and Eucalyptus plantations (1:38; 4:30).

5.3.1 Flooding and Sedimentation

The “flooding era” began around 1996 (9:9). Despite the natural occurrence of flooding events, it is stressed that the floods in 2010 and 2011 have been more severe than in the past, with inundations lasting until the dry season (April/May) 5.3. ENVIRONMENTAL AND LAND USE CHANGES 49 and lake levels exceeding the annual average (52:4; ARARI: 36:8; BDU: 40:7; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 22:1). Assumptions are made that flooding might be caused by the artificial regulation of the lake level for hydropower generation (e. g. 3:4; 6:13; 11:3; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 22:4). Due to inconclusive correlations between water level and rainfall (3:3) as well as the artificial regulation, it is difficult for farmers to forecast the severity of flooding (1:22; 18:13; ARARI: 36:8; EWRDM: 55:6). A few farmers in Tanametsele kebele related flooding to catchment degradation in the upper watershed resulting in depositions of sediment at the river mouth of Gumara (3:4). Officials argued that flooding was also caused by the degradation of wetlands through farmers ‘capturing’ the lake shore and thereby impairing the flood regulating function of wetlands (TaSBO: 38:3; cf. BoWE: 34:3; Bakema & Mafabi 2003: 101). Sedimentation is recognised by farmers (3:4; 4:3; 14:3; personal communi- cation: farmers in Daga). Sediment depositions are seen to improve soil fertility, increase crop production at least for a short period and make the application of fertilisers dispensable (15:10; 52:33; 56:4; personal communication: farmers in Sedechila Mariam). According to SMEC (2008) the total annual sediment load from the upper catchments into Lake Tana is estimated to be 9.6 million tons. Thereof 8.6 million tons (equivalent to 1 to 2 mm of sediment per year) settle in the lake basin, mainly near the outlets of the rivers.

5.3.2 Rice Cultivation

Rice cultivation was promoted by the Derg (socialist regime) (7:3) and introduced by North Korea in 1978 (BoARD 2011 b: 1; cf. 52:9). Initially, rice cultivation was less accepted and its expansion failed due to difficulties regarding the threshing and pealing of rice grains (lack of dehiscent mills), and the absence of markets during the communist regime (1:39; ARARI: 36:2; Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 45). Since the reintroduction of rice in the 1990s by the former Bureau of Agriculture (today BoARD), rice cultivation has kept expanding (1:39; 7:3; 14:23; ARARI: 36:2; Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 45; figure 5.2, p. 50). When asked about the trends of rice cultivation, farmers argued that rice 50 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS cultivation would further increase but rice productivity would decrease. Thus the application of fertilisers and additional crop land would be necessary to maintain high yields (7:39). BoARD (2011 b) projects an increasing demand for rice seeds in the Amhara region and will further on promote rice production and research (see p. 16).

Figure 5.2: Vast rice fields in Agid Kirigna. Figure 5.3: Cattle grazing in a wetland. Pho- Photograph: Springsguth, M. tograph: Springsguth, M.

Rice tolerates water logging (1:18; 4:7; 7:3) and is a very productive crop. Rice yields are around five to seven times higher than teff2 yields (12:51; cf. 4:7; Teshome et al. 2009: 24). Besides, harvesting teff was tiresome (4:34). Rice is a multi-purpose crop used for food production (bread, injera, the traditional pita) and the brewing of beer. Its straw serves as fodder for livestock and thatching (1:18; 12:27; 52:44). Due to the introduction of rice, crops such as teff, maize, finger millet (Eleusine coracana), safflower (Carthamus tinctorius) and pulses were continually replaced in all kebeles (1:25; 7:1; 56:3). Whereas formerly three to four harvests per year could be obtained (7:53; 8:9), one to two are common today with the second harvest being maize, pulses or marketable horticulture crops, e. g. potatoes and tomatoes (1:24; 5:17; 6: 4; 7:3; 12:13; 21:8; Teshome et al. 2009: 18). Fallowing was abandoned due to land scarcity and the changed cropping pattern resulting from the introduction of rice cultivation (5:4; 5:19; 7:1; 12:5, 12:10; 52:30).

2Teff is an old cereal crop, traditionally cultivated in Ethiopia. 5.3. ENVIRONMENTAL AND LAND USE CHANGES 51

5.3.3 Conversion of Wetlands

The encroachment of crop and grazing land into wetlands (figure 5.3, p. 50) is one of the most critical land use changes (see p. 56). Whereas before 1990 wetlands were almost exclusively used as pastures and small-scale cultivation of pulses, the conversion of these wetlands has tremendously increased (7:52; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:39), particularly during the last five to six years (ARARI: 36:3). In Wagetera, Nabega and Tanametsele, wetlands have been converted for rice production (e. g. 2:18; 7:12; 14:10; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:24). Increasingly, wetlands have been changed to recession farmlands (15:17; 24:23; 26:13; ARARI: 36:7) for the cultivation of maize, teff, barley, oats, finger millet, potato, pepper lentils, grass pea or chickpea, using residual moisture (15:13; 52:8). It was stated that in 1982 around 85% of the Fogera floodplain had been covered by grass. In 2003 an estimated 80% of these grasslands were already converted into crop land (ARARI: 36:6; see Appendix 6, p. XXIV). Wetlands in Agid Kirigna kebele were less encroached than elsewhere in the research area (40:6; own observation). The high population growth in the kebeles entailing an increased need for land results in the encroachment of non-cultivated, fertile wetlands (e. g. 2:18; 3:19; 4:14; 7:12; 14:10; figure 5.4, p. 52). Since lack of land entails food insecurity, the enhancement of food security is a fundamental aspect involving conversion (2:18; see table 5.1, p. 55). In a study on sustainable wetland management in Illubabor (southwestern Ethiopia), Dixon & Wood (2001) found that “wetland drainage and cultivation was originally initiated in response to food shortages” (p. 7).

5.3.4 Fishery

“Fishing has never been an important activity historically” (Dejen 2005: 41). Commercial gillnet fishery of Lake Tana was introduced in 1986 (cf. 52:40; 54:7) to meet the increasing demand from the capital, Addis Ababa (Dejen 2005: 41) and today also from the regional capital Bahir Dar (9:13; ARARI: 41:10). Only the Woito fishermen have been completely dependent on the lake’s resources (23:3, 23:4; Gebrekidan & Teka 2006: 45). Nowadays fishing has become an increasingly important practice (12:37; 15:45; 52 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

23:35; figure 5.5, p. 52). This phenomenon can be explained with (1) population growth, land scarcity and unemployment, urging young and landless3 to search for alternative livelihood options (e. g. 2:6; 8:38; 16:12; 20:2; 23:10; 26:8) and (2) the occurrence of flooding in the last years, leading to crop losses and urging affected people to draw on fish resources (e. g. 9:6; 12:46; 26:8). During flooding, fishing activities take place in the wetlands and rice fields (9:6; 52:12).

Figure 5.4: Wetland conversion. Photo- Figure 5.5: Children and their catch: graph: Moreaux, R. African Catfish, locally called Ambaza (Clarias gariepinus). At present, this species is being increasingly consumed (23:18; 52:41). Photograph: Springsguth, M.

Figure 5.6, p. 53 depicts the drivers of change. The next section addresses the impact of environmental and land use changes on rural livelihoods which is useful to apprehend the broader context of wetland management.

5.4 Impact of Environmental and Land Use Changes on Rural Livelihoods

Environmental and land use changes do often have two faces and the potential to positively or adversely affect people’s livelihoods.

3The category of landless mainly comprises young adults and families. They are often more formally educated than their parents (MoARD 2009: 19.) 5.4. IMPACT ON RURAL LIVELIHOODS 53

? Economic growth

External shocks (e.g. flooding) Economic incentives WETLAND

Increasing Unemployment Vulnerability/ overexploitation livelihood insecurity

Conversion of wetlands

Degradation of the Structural and upper watershed functional changes*

Land scarcity Loss of genetic and species diversity*

amplifying effect Population growth attenuating effect

Figure 5.6: Drivers of environmental and land use change. Simplified scheme. For a definition of vulnerability, see supra note 9, p. 134. * See Appendix 7, p. XXVIII. Source: compiled from own results

5.4.1 Impact on Crop Production and Livestock Rearing

Due to the unusually high flooding, crop production and productivity has decreased, in some villages drastically (e. g. 6:21; 12:10; 14:6; EWRDM: 55:19; figure 5.7, p. 54). Mango, coffee and gesho (Rhamnus prinoides, ‘local hop’) production, formerly an additional income source to buy clothes, salt or oil, has ceased (1:25; 7:19; 12:15). Rice production is said to have declined, partially because of declining soil fertility (12:51). Useful trees such as eucalyptus (Eucalyptus spp.) and wanza (Cordia africana) have died due to water stress (12:15). Recession farming is impossible or delayed (e. g. 6:12; 12:51; 15:15; EWRDM: 55:3, 55:7). Flooding and encroachment, exacerbating overgrazing (Mulatu 2006: 27) and degradation of wetlands (Amsalu 2006: 19), engender fodder shortages for 54 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

Figure 5.7: Flooded rice field in Wagetera. Figure 5.8: Flooded settlements in Ahun Photograph: Sibhat, B. Wota at the Gumara river mouth: Photo- graph: Springsguth, M. livestock (e. g. 3:4; 14:9, 14:14; 18:40; 24:8) and a reduction in quantity and quality of animal produce as a consequence (7:6; 11:6; 24:14; 26:20). “Water fire burns the grass”, one farmer said (14:9). Cattle suffer from diseases, and medical treatment requires additional expenses (11:6; 12:26; 14:7;).

5.4.2 Impact on Social Life

Most evidently, flooding puts people’s lives at risk by destroying their settlements (figure 5.8, p. 54) and in the worst case claiming victims among humans and animals (3:4; 4:11; cf. EWRDM: 55:5). Severe flooding is an obstacle to devel- opment and reduces well-being (8:23; 12:40; 15:34; 16:4). Malaria, water-born diseases and diarrhoeal disorder spread (15:20; EWRDM: 55:6). Physical and thus communication barriers during flooding adversely affect social networks, the access to social services (e. g. health centres, family planning trainings), schools, churches and markets (8:18; 13:7; 15:20; 52:6; EWRDM: 55:12; 55:13). Searching for additional sources of fodder due to shortages increases workload (18:39). Flooding and encroachment of cultivated land into wetlands involve land and resource use conflicts (e. g. 9:20; 18:22: EWNRA: 28:6) which are dealt with in detail below (see p. 56). 5.4. IMPACT ON RURAL LIVELIHOODS 55

5.4.3 Impact on Food Security and Income Generation

During flooding, residents of the lakeside communities are subject to an insecure food situation (3:4; 6:9; 15:23). To ensure food security wetlands are cultivated in compensation for as yet flooded recession farmland which is important for dry season food production (14:18; 52:8; see Dixon & Wood 2001: 9). Rice production has an ambivalent impact on food and income security (table 5.1, p. 55).

Table 5.1: Advantages and disadvantages of rice production for local people

Advantages Disadvantages

• Staple food (food security) (4:14; • Losses of income for livestock farm- 5:2; 12:29) ers (4:14; 4:19; 12:48; 52:44)

• Income generation (4:14; 12:29) • Loss of variation in cultivated crops (4:18; 7:2; 56:3) and a healthy and • Investments, e. g. house thatching balanced nutrition (7:29; cf. 12:30) with corrugated iron roofs (4:10; 52:44) • Unsustainability of long-term wet- land cultivation: nutrient depletion, • Sold in exchange for other crops, loss of soil quality and productiv- fuel, cloths, berbere, oil or medicine ity (EWNRA: 28:8; Tegene & Hunt (6:11; 8:3; 12:29) 2000: 25; Wood 2000: 10)

By tendency, and especially during flooding, fishing serves as a source of food and income (12:36; 15:30; 20:2; 26:8; ARARI: 41:37), but often leads to an overexploitation of fish resources (e. g. 9:11; 15:30; 23:10). Due to increasing prices (25:22; but cf. 9:37; ARARI: 41:12), the fish market has become very attractive (ARARI: 41:7, 41:13; Getahun et al. 2008: 51). However, the transportation of fresh fish to the market (Woreta, Yifag, Hamusit) is no option due to long travel times (24:12; 41:10; see IFPRI/CSA/EDRI 2006: 27) and the absence of portable cooling boxes (23:18). Generally, prices for fresh fish are higher than for dried ones (41:12). For the Woito, though flooding is perceived as positive (23:30), the 56 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

fishing activities of the other communities led to a reduction of their income and contribute to poverty (23:31, 23:36). It must be noted that both the advantages land use changes entail for local people (rice cultivation) and the disadvantages evoked by flooding, encroachment and overfishing involve the degradation of wetland resources (see Appendix 7, p. XXVIII). As mentioned earlier, changes in wetland use are accompanied by conflicts over wetland resources. The life objectives (see p. 47) and priorities of the different wetland users underlying resource appropriation are a crucial source of conflict, as will be shown in the next section.

5.5 Conflicts over Wetlands and Associated Resources

To better understand the conditions that determine the effectiveness of wetland management, this section addresses the conflicts that arise over wetlands and their resources, the social actors involved, and the consequences of conflicts for local communities.

5.5.1 Conflicts Related to Encroachment

The conversion of wetland pastures into cultivated land engenders conflicts between livestock and crop farmers expanding their private landholding (e. g. 1:37; 18:27; 21:16). Encroachment dynamics do not simply follow a certain principle. The cultivation at the edges of wetlands by farmers with plots adjacent to the wetland (e. g. 2:28; 3:13; 15:17) seems to be a more silent form of continuous encroachment. The conversion may be more obvious when “jumpers” (18:23) encroach parts of formerly uncultivated wetland. Due to land scarcity, all eyes focus on the redistribution of wetlands for cultivation (e. g. 2:10; WoARD: 35:5)4. Consequently, conflicts occur between various parties (table 5.2, p. 57). The conflicts are reinforced when herds of cattle browse the rice fields (9:20).

4Redistribution is expected with fear due to decreasing landholding sizes (5:3; 7:59; 22:9; ILA: 30:3; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:31), and perceived to be unjust (2:8). 5.5. CONFLICTS OVER WETLANDS AND ASSOCIATED RESOURCES 57

Table 5.2: Parties of actors involved in conflicts related to encroachment

Party A Party B Landless interested in wetland cultivation Livestock farmers, kebele administration (inter alia collective cultivation in groups (mostly elderly of the upper well-being (54:13)) and group): preserve pastures for livestock rearing (2:21, 2:23, 2:28, 2:29; 14:14; cf. DSA/SCI 2006: 98) Landless interested in wetland cultivation Other community residents interested in and wetland cultivation (7:56; 24:22) Landless claiming wetlands and recession Farmers unwilling to allot their recession farmland for fishing during the rainy sea- land and waive customary rights (24:22; son (2:30) and cultivation during the dry see EPLAUA 37:15) season and Community interested in redistribution Kebele administration interested in wet- and land preservation for livestock rearing (14:14; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:10) Rich farmers interested in wetland cultiva- Poorer community members interested in tion and wetland cultivation (8:34) Households with young people (lower, Households of the upper well-being group middle well-being group) interested in re- with no interest in redistribution and distribution and less/no land to bequeath enough land to bequeath to their offspring to their offspring and (5:3; 7:31; 15:37; 25:14; see 8:34)

5.5.2 Conflicts over Grazing Land

Traditionally, the number of livestock owned by one person is not limited (IFAD 2007: 17). Along with an increase in livestock numbers (ibid.: 17; cf. 24:8) and encroachment, this entails overstocking of communal pastures which aggra- vates overgrazing. Consequently, competition over fodder sources arises between livestock farmers (9:20; 18:26).

5.5.3 Cropland Boundary Conflicts

Boundary conflicts, though rarely noted (DSA/SCI 2006: 98–99), occur among rice farmers and among farmers practising recession agriculture (9:23; 18:32). The reasons for such boundary conflicts are elaborated below (p. 61). 58 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

5.5.4 Conflicts between Tana Kirkos Monasteries and the Community

A near-natural wetland with patches of remnant populations of Cyperus papyrus lies at the foot of the rocky Tana Kirkos Island, inhabited by orthodox monks (figure 2.2, p. 13, figure 5.9, p. 58, figure 5.10, p. 58). The Derg regime promoted coffee production in farmers’ cooperatives on one of the four islands. After the subversion of the socialist regime, land use rights were transferred back to the monasteries. Farmers complained, land was redistributed in favour of the already rich monastery (2:31; personal communication: 1:23, expert, institute unknown). The boundary between the community and monastic land is questioned by local people. Today the conflict is latent, but becomes manifest with the encroachment into this near-natural wetland (personal communication: expert BDU; but cf. 26:19), and more overt by the theft of coffee from monastic plantations (personal communication: 1:23, monk, Tana Kirkos).

Figure 5.9: Tana Kirkos Island. Photograph: Figure 5.10: Papyrus swamp, Tana Kirkos. Moreaux, R. Background: Settlements and the Gumara river mouth. Photograph: Springsguth, M.

5.5.5 Conflicts between Wetland Conservation and Use in Agid Kirigna

In Agid Kirigna, the conservation efforts of local people (25:14; see p. 67) conflict with the need of others to raise crops and to feed their cattle. Farmers whose 5.5. CONFLICTS OVER WETLANDS AND ASSOCIATED RESOURCES 59 landholding does not have the capacity to feed their livestock herd it into the wetlands (25:17, 25:23). Besides, there is a conflict between sand mining activities at the lake shore and agriculture. Vehicles extracting the sand partly destroy wetland pastures resulting in a loss of livestock fodder and arable land (21:15).

5.5.6 Conflicts Related to Fishing

In Tanametsele, conflicts arise over the use of wetlands as fishing and grazing grounds: Whereas mostly elderly people prioritise grazing, the youth association of Aheyasat support young people to make a living of fishery. Youths of Sedechila Mariam and Sewtiye compete over fishing grounds (2:30). The increasing fishing practices of communities in Agid Kirigna conflict with the activities of the fisheries- dependant Woito (23:36; 24:21; but cf. 21:16). Stealing of fisher nets is a general problem and causes conflicts between the fishermen (9:14; 18:43; WoARD: 53:7), particularly in the months of August to October (9:39). Nets were even stolen by people from Dembia woreda, north of Lake Tana (23:36). Due to thieving and cutting of nets by motorised boats, small- scale fishery becomes economically unviable (12:32; 20:6). Fishermen who manage fishery resources more sustainably conflict with fishermen whose fishing practices are unsustainable and aggravate overfishing (18:30; 24:21; ARARI: 41:17). Stealing of fisher nets favours these unsustainable but more effective practices (41:16). Conflicts further arise over the amount of fish caught by individual persons (8:31; 20:9; 23:24).

5.5.7 Conflicts Arising from Stakeholders’ Perceptions on Government Plans

Statements on government plans for the use and management of wetland resources are diverse. At the local level, the government is said to have an interest in (1) distributing wetlands to landless (without a legal basis) (2:29; 7:37), (2) promoting drainage of wetlands (9:30) and (3) encroachment through community members (25:24) 60 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS as well as (4) supporting youth using wetland resources as an alternative income source (e. g. collecting plants) (22:15). It is further said to (5) not consider wetland management at all (2:20; 9:29) and (6) support the conservation of wetlands and ecotourism in Tana Kirkos (2:5). Woreda and regional officials stated BoARD advocated wetland cultivation and recession farming (WoARD: 35:3; BoWE: 31:5). By contrast, EPLAUA (33:4) pointed out the woreda government falsely associated the government’s promotion of agricultural modernisation and technological progress with the conversion of wetlands. Recession agriculture is generally prohibited (ARARI: 36:11). The conflicting interests of wetland use between BoARD and EPLAUA5 become most evident during the implementation of regulations at the woreda and kebele levels (33:4). The variety of these statements reflects the conflicting opinions about and interests in wetland use and management across levels and sectors and their partly incompatible strategies or plans (cf. EWNRA: 28:6)6.

5.5.8 The Consequences of Conflicts for Communal Life

Land and resource use conflicts divide the local society. Distrust and resentments prevail and compromise communal life. Cases of corruption and suppression by powerful people create fear (16:16; 18:34). Richer households argue with poorer ones about the legitimacy of their actions, kebele leaders with the community and lobby groups (2:21), fisherman with fisherman. Even among relatives there are disputes, dividing the family unit. Enemies within the community stir up hostility (9:28). But more often than open disputes, there is silence. And distrust and resentments are hidden (EWNRA: 29:8; cf. 18:34; own observations). The next section draws to a distinct but related topic: the land administration system.

5The Department of Land Use had been under BoARD and later was assigned to EPLAUA (EPLAUA: 37:12; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:32). 6See Wondefrash (2003) for a very provocative short overview of the conflicting sectoral interests. 5.6. LAND ADMINISTRATION 61

5.6 Land Administration

This section generally introduces the land titling process (see p. 17) and land use planning in the study sites and draws to the constraints to land registration. This contributes to an understanding of the effects of the land administration system on wetland use and management.

5.6.1 Land Registration and Certification

In Fogera and Libo Kemkem7 the land registration process began in 2003/2004 using traditional ways of measurement (45:15; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:3; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:43). The land border demarcation of the last land re- distribution which took place in 1997 (January/February) in the two woredas (7:59; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:30, 42:31; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:1) is set as a benchmark for the land registration and certification programme (54:16; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:31). In 1997 boundaries were inadequately documented and pertinent documents got lost (18:37, 18:38; ILA: 30:6; WoEPLAU Addis Ze- men: 43:3, 43:15). Not surprisingly the disputed land records and the subsequent certification process are less accepted (Deininger et al. 2006: 9; Deininger et al. 2007: supra note 16, 11; see p. 64). Since 2003/2004 private landholdings8 and communal lands9 have been reg- istered (WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:47). Wetlands and recession farmlands, often held and used according to customary right (EPLAUA: 37:5), tend to have been registered as (1) communal or (2) private landholding (26:15; EPLAUA: 37:16; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:17; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:1, 42:22, 42:52). Commonly, wetlands are subsumed under communal lands (EPLAUA: 37:17; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:8). In Libo Kemkem, the attempt to demarcate wetlands from communal lands failed (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:7). Occasion- ally, wetlands have not been registered, e. g. in Agid Kirigna (24:27; WoEPLAU

7Data for Dera is not available. 8Private holding is defined as a land which is in the possession of a farmer (or other body) having a withdrawal right and a certificate (Proclamation No. 133/2006: §2(9)). 9Communal holding is defined as rural land which is neither owned by the government nor individually, but rather commonly used by local people, e. g. for grazing (Proclamation No. 133/2006: §2(5)). 62 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

Woreta: 42:1, 42:12). Deficiencies in registering wetlands and recession farmlands are seen to result in a continuous open access situation (24:19).

Both Fogera and Libo Kemkem have not yet completed registration (WoE- PLAU Addis Zemen: 43:22; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:44) and missed the ambitious target to finalise this process by mid-2006 (see Adenew & Abdi 2005: 15, 18). The certification process includes the issuance of a temporary certificate to the farmer ensuring tenure rights at an early stage of registration. After a verification and entry of the contained data into the Land Registry Book (figure 5.11, p. 62) the temporary certificate is upgraded to an official primary certificate (Green Book of Holding). The secondary certificates are the permanent documents that contain the exact geographical coordinates of the parcel (SARDEP/EPLAUA/ORGUT 2010: 14). So far, no secondary certificates have been issued ( WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:10 and Addis Zemen: 43:14). The registration of communal lands is mainly undertaken by kebele chairmen (members of the kebele administration committee) (WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:13). Certificates for communal lands are partially issued and kept with the kebele leaders (3:9; 9:32; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:4).

Figure 5.11: The Land Registry Book. Photograph: Springsguth, M.

It is assumed that land titling ensures tenure security and results in land resource protection (3:9; cf. WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:26). Being issued a certificate, farmers would feel to be the owners of their holding (ILA: 30:4). 5.6. LAND ADMINISTRATION 63

5.6.2 Constraints to the Land Registration and Certification Process

Shortcomings in land registration and certification occurred at all stages and levels.

Lack of Good Governance LAC elections could have been corrupted (WoE- PLAU Woreta: 42:2) and biased towards an election of the elite. Deininger et al. (2007) found that many studied LACs “included at least one person in a leadership position” (p. 10; cf. 18:10). Criteria perceived to be most important for the LAC election are: being educated, being a member of the kebele administration, being rich and having knowledge about land registration (Adenew and Abdi 2007: 22). During registration, farmers tried to register encroached communal land as private holding (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:10; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:6). People also tried to hide illegal land occupations and leave them unregistered (WoEPLAU: 42:5). LAC members, often elders knowing the community (personal communication: WoEPLAU Woreta), might have “turned a blind eye” (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 24) on this and other issues to the benefit of their relatives or friends (27:8; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:4). Besides, working on a voluntary basis and with considerable workload (Deininger et al. 2006: 4, 9), LAC members “compensated themselves” (ibid.: 11) or were seen “sitting in the shadow” (54:15) under a tree instead of registering fields on-farm. Moreover, double counting of land occurred (27:8).

Lack of capacity LAC members have poor access to additional written materi- als, e. g. the proclamation (Deininger et al. 2007: 10). Misinformation of the public could therefore be unintentional, though it is often intentional (27:8). Woreda and regional land administration departments face lack of staff, trained personnel and financial resources for trainings, awareness-raising, upgrading certificates10, equipment and vehicles (EPLAUA: 37:3). Authorities thus lack the capacity to

10Cadastral surveys with modern surveying techniques for the issuance of secondary certificates have been accomplished in the priority kebeles of Fogera and Libo Kemkem which are part of the Ribb Irrigation and Drainage Project (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:18; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:27; see MoWE 2010). 64 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS adequately administer the responsibilities which have been imposed on them with the land administration decentralisation process (Miller & Tolina 2008: 372). Landholders complained that the support by the woreda administration depart- ment was insufficient and the upgrade of certificates dragging (13:6). Cases were reported where land was redistributed by communities without the acceptance of WoEPLAU which may retard the certification process (WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:25).

Documentation and Boundary Disputes Problems concerning the registra- tion of transferred land occur when the transaction was inadequately documented, e. g. when landless claim inherited wetland parcels (WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:5, 42:6). Loss of landholding documents from 1997 leads to disputes over hold- ing and use rights (see 18:37). Counterfeiting documents even exacerbates the conflicts (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:11). Only about one third of plots have again been measured after 1997 (Deininger et al. 2007: supra note 16, 11). Thus unresolved disputes related to boundary demarcation and encroachment further retard the registration process (54:15; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:13; 43:37; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:5). The inaccessibility of land holding due to flooding makes registration impossible (WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:5).

Lack of a Guideline for Wetland Registration Land administration desks have neither agreed whether wetlands and recession farmlands are to be subsumed under state, communal or perhaps even private holding, nor is there a clear definition for ‘wetland’ (see 9:2; 14:2; 24:19; EPLAUA: 37:5; WoEPLAU: 42:1, 42:21, 42:22, 42:45; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:8). Mandates between the department of environmental protection and the department of land administration within WoEPLAU concerning the registration and utilisation of wetlands often remain ill-defined (EPLAUA: 37:4; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:53, 42:54). A guideline for wetlands, whether and how they are to be registered is missing or inadequately considered. 5.7. COMMON-POOL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT 65

5.6.3 Land Use Planning

“The outcome of certification should be used as a base for land use planning and sustainable land management” (Deininger et al. 2006: 12). Land use plans, stipulated by Proclamation No. 133/2006: §13(1) and Regulation No.51/2007: §16(1)A, have not been formulated yet as certification processes have not been accomplished (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:40; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:27). Ac- cordingly, landholders can use their land as needed and wanted (EPLAUA: 37:9; Proclamation No. 133/2006: §13 (5); Regulation No. 51/2007: §9(1)). Farmers related land use changes to inadequate land use planning (21:12). To tackle urgent problems of mismanagement, land degradation and illegal settlement, land use plans based on simple physical observations, incorporating existing regulations, should be designed at kebele level in 2012 (EPLAUA: 37:10). Land use plans would increase tenure security and consequently investments in landholdings (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:31). Figure 5.12, p. 66 depicts the relation between the land administration system, land use changes, occurring conflicts and the wetland system. To avoid the overuse and mismanagement of wetland resources, management systems have been established.

5.7 Common-Pool Resource Management

The management of common-pool resources (wetlands, communal lands, fishery) is generally perceived to be difficult if not impossible due to the large number and size of user groups, the unlimited appropriation of open access resources and open boundaries of the resource system (e. g. 9:50; 11:1; 23:23; 26:7; BoWE: 31:3; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:15). Even though non-residents may sometimes be excluded from accessing and using wetlands (4:32), their management still often remains ineffectively regulated, entailing resentment and dissatisfaction among local people and officials (own observations; see p. 60). The following sections provide an overview of existent local management systems and the broader political context affecting wetland management, and draws on the factors that influence the ability of local institutions to manage wetlands. 66 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

HUMAN SYSTEM

WETLAND Land use change

Flooding Sedimentation Rice cultivation Encroachment Conflicts Fishery Open Registration access of wetlands? Land administration system

Disputed land records of 1997 Inadequate documentation Lack of good governance Lack of government capacity Corruption Missing guideline for the registration of wetlands Missing land use plan

Figure 5.12: Land administration and land use changes often adversely affect the wetland system. Source: compiled from own results

5.7.1 Local Resource Management Systems

Management systems target a restricted use of wetland resources, allowing for hay-making (figure 5.13, p. 67), grazing and other sound uses but prohibiting cultivation (25:12; 26:9). Wetland closure, i. e. conservation without any use, is infeasible (18:21; 25:13; 26:9). Most communities recently enacted by-laws to manage encroachment (2:34; cf. 15:18). Commonly, wetland cultivation is punished by grazing cattle destroying the yield (e. g. 2:35; 3:11; 14:19). In Agid Kirigna, trees planted on communal lands are cut (24:8). In Wagetera, the income from the crop yield of an encroached plot is used for undertaking communal investments (school construction, repair works) (15:18). At least locally, regulations resulted in improved resource management and decreasing incidences of encroachment (2:14, 2:35). More sophisticated management systems which are not only based on sanctions were established in Gulash (Wagetera), Tana Kirkos (Tanametsele) and Agid 5.7. COMMON-POOL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT 67

Figure 5.13: Sustainable harvesting of wetland grasses: cut-and-carry system, Wagetera. Photo- graph: Springsguth, M.

Kirigna. To regulate encroachment in Gulash five trustworthy persons were elected consensually by the community. They oversee communal land management, denounce those who do not comply to the consensus and create awareness of the problem. Illegal encroachment is fined 50 ETB. The five monitors are paid from the fines (26:9). Monks of the Tana Kirkos Island harvest and sell matured papyrus, e. g. to the neighbouring communities (2:31). The wetland is used in cut-and-carry system (1:28). Grazing is allowed during the dry season. To prevent wetland degradation, monks monitor the borders (personal communication: monk, Tana Kirkos Island). In Agid Kirigna, after public discussions an agreement on wetland management was signed. Grazing in the wetland is merely allowed during the dry season. The cut-and-carry system allows plant regeneration during the rainy season. Moreover, livestock should be fed with rice residuals and graze on private fallowed land to reduce pressure on the wetland. Landless people were asked to buy residuals or to rent land. A reduction of the number of cattle is envisaged. Guards were elected who oversee wetland use (25:12). In Amana village, Wagetera, no by-laws have been enacted, but PRA partici- pants see the need to regulate wetland use (7:34). Fish resource use has been mostly unregulated (9:44) with two exceptions. In Tez Amba, an informal fishermen’s association (figure 5.14, p. 68) was established in 2007 aiming at supporting and advising fishermen, creating awareness of sustainable fishing practices, to better control the stealing of fisher nets and to 68 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS reduce attacks by hippopotamus (20:3). Regulations include the prohibition of fishery from June to September and stipulate using nets with a mesh width of more than eight centimetres to allow regeneration of fish stocks, entering to and returning from the lake at the same time to prevent thieving, and fishing of maximum three kilogramme per day and capita (20:4; WoARD: 53:3; figure 5.15, p. 68).

Figure 5.14: Fishermen of the association in Figure 5.15: Fishermen in Tez Amba en- Daga, Tez Amba. Photograph: Springsguth, ter Lake Tana in the morning with their M. tanquas. Photograph: Springsguth, M.

In Agid Kirigna, an informal joint fishermen’s association was established in 2011 between the Woito and fishermen of other communities (21:22; 23:37). Regulations are similar. Non-compliance with the rules is fined 100 ETB. Besides, it was proposed punishing offences in church and to reduce the number of fisher nets owned by richer persons (23:24; 23:27). The effectiveness of these fishing management regulations appears to be dubious (23:28). Conflicting wetland uses and non-compliance to regulations are dealt with drawing on existing multi-level conflict resolution mechanisms.

5.7.2 Conflict Resolution Mechanisms

The first instances in resolving land and resource use and management conflicts are the kebele administration, the elder court and the LAC (5:13; 13:10; 18:33; 27:5 WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:8; Regulation No. 51/2007: §§19(5), 35). Discussions with the concerned parties are held and finally an agreement is negotiated and 5.7. COMMON-POOL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT 69 formulated (Regulation No. 51/2007: §35(1)). But many cases of conflicts over common-pool resources cannot be resolved locally and go beyond the kebele’s capabilities (7:44; 13:10; 24:8). Traditionally, discussions are also held at church (3:11; 13:12, 13:31; 18:18), a respected institution with the power to influence people. Where kebele adminis- trations were incapable to resolve disputes, public assemblies take place in church and priests act as counsellors (27:3). The confidence in God’s judgement of sins occasionally serves as a punishment of offences (20:4; 23:27). Higher-level instances comprise government bodies (e. g. woreda experts) (13:6) and woreda courts (Regulation No. 51/2007: §35(4)) that receive reports of law cases from kebele administrations (2:13; 5:13; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:8). Recently, the Book of Holding serves as a basis for neutral judicial decisions shifting the burden of proof from young people to the powerful elders (WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:27; Deininger et al. 2006: 13). Policemen also intervene in disputes (13:11). By tendency, problems are preferably resolved by the community without the involvement of third instances (13:13). Trustworthy persons are elected by the community, said to be unbiased, respected, morally good and able to take just decisions (13:12; see Regulation No. 51/2007 §35, selection of arbitrators). Occasionally, local people have asked for appropriate government support to settle yet unsolved conflicts (13:6). The next section shifts the focus from local to regional and federal institutions pertaining to wetland management.

5.7.3 Federal and Regional Policies with Implications for Wetland Management

With the aim to better represent wetlands in the national law, clarify property rights and management responsibilities, a National Wetland Policy has been developed by the Ethio Wetlands and Natural Resources Association (EWNRA) in cooperation with the Environmental Protection Authority (EPA) since 2003 (EWNRA: 28:3, 28:4). The wetland policy has yet not been ratified, but has been submitted to EPA for clarification and needs to be forwarded to the parliament 70 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS for final approval (personal communication: zur Heide). The broader policy context has mainly a negative impact on sustainable wetland management. Responsibilities for wetland management within land tenure policies are ill-defined (EWNRA: 28:4). The Water Resource Management Policy (see p. 16) and agricultural development policies (see p. 16) rather discourage a functioning wetland management by promoting the drainage and conversion of wetlands for agricultural production, hereby preventing the formation of new wetlands (EWNRA: 28:5, 29:3). EWNRA (29:8) predicated government policies were constructed as if the respective authorities had a mandate to access and manage wetland resources. To complement the section on common-property resource management, the conditions that influence the effectiveness of local management systems are outlined.

5.7.4 Constraints to and Recommendations for Common-Pool Resource Management

Constraints to common-pool resource management are diverse and identified at different management levels.

Attitudes Cultural attitudes towards the adoption of new farming techniques (11:7; BoARD: 32:7) and farmers’ short-term views (EPLAUA: 33:1) constrain a sustainable wetland management.

Participation and Knowledge Exchange People complain about insufficient participation in decision-making procedures of the kebele administration (13:23). Elders are not invited to conferences (13:18). Information and knowledge of wetland management is rarely disseminated by participants of wetland management workshops11 which leads to the assumption that they are only interested in the per diems received for participation (24:6). The kebele administration is appointed

11 Proving the opposite a kebele leader of Wagetera exchanged knowledge of common-pool resource management with the public at church (52:15). 5.7. COMMON-POOL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT 71 by the woreda authority rather than by the community, as were participants of wetland workshops (13:18; 24:6).

Arrangements and Conflict Resolution Sanctions and regulations are en- forced inconsistently and lack implementation (15:18). Fraudulent or unlawful conducts are not (adequately) prosecuted by kebele administrations or woreda authorities and courts (7:32; WoEPLAU Woreta: 42:26). Police support to settle conflicts is inadequate due to understaffing (13:11). Legal decisions of court cases are pending (7:32; 52:29). Wetland management is thus nearly impossible con- sidering all the unresolved cases of conflicts (56:14). Withal, cases of corruption (bribery, intimidation, drawing on beneficial relations) impede conflict resolution processes (7:32; 15:19; 18:34) and complicate wetland management (2:22; 13:14). Kebeles are too large to be governed efficiently and the kebele administration office is too far away (2:2; 13:21).

Who holds the Stick? To local people it remains unclear whether solutions to wetland management should be worked out by themselves or government authorities (13:24). A feeling of powerlessness to tackle the mismanagement of common-pool resources makes local actors hand over the stick to government bodies who ‘should do something about it’ (7:36, 13:26; 23:23, 23:25).

Monitoring The responsible bodies have not evaluated the effectiveness of management trainings and awareness creation campaigns (22:14; 52:16)12. They have also failed to monitor the performance of land users’ obligations of land management (EPLAUA: 37:11; WoEPLAU Addis Zemen: 43:26; Adenew & Abdi 2005: supra note 8, 7; see Regulation No. 51/2007: §16) 13.

Recognition Government bodies do not favour local by-laws (37:7) and have a limited perspective of wetland conservation (EWNRA: 29:5).

12A few farmers have already been trained in wetland management and resource conservation and participated in awareness creation workshops (22:21; 53:12; but cf. 24:6). 13According to §25(5, 7) of the Regulation No. 51/2007, the woreda department of land administration is responsible to “follow up whether or not landholders and users discharge the obligation legally entrusted upon them”, and to administer and manage state holding. 72 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

Fish Resource Management The implementation of the national and regional Fisheries Proclamation, developed in 2003 and providing guidelines on resource conservation (Gebrekidan 2006 b: 49), lacks substantiation (11:1; ARARI: 41:3, 41:17). Profit-oriented fishermen use illegal fishing equipment such as non-selective mono-filament gill nets with narrow mesh widths and unsustainable fishing prac- tices (e. g. fishing in spawning sites, fish poisoning) and thereby violate regional and local regulations (11:1; ARARI: 41:1). A gap between people’s and scientists’ understanding of fish resource management and conservation widens the problem. As long as disputes over fishing are not resolved, overuse continues (ARARI: 41:3). Fishing licences have not been issued so far and local fishermen’s associations are not legally recognised (ARARI: 41:20; BoARD: 53:3). More efficient fish production techniques and storage (e. g. more hygienic and faster drying methods and cooling boxes) add value to the fish produce and possibly reduce catches but are also costly (ARARI: 41:10). In Agid Kirigna, Woito fishermen expressed their preference for a separate association (23:27). Communication between the Woito and other communities was limited due to negative attitudes of the groups towards each other (cf. 21:18; 23:39). Discussions on fish resource management are sporadic (23:24). To counter the constraints of commons governance, local people, officials and experts expressed their ideas about a more sustainable and functioning wetland management. Their recommendations are summarised in table 5.3, p. 73. Remarkable are the similarities of recommendations across the scales with reference to stakeholders’ involvement in wetland management, the delineation of wetlands, or the monitoring and evaluation measures. 5.7. COMMON-POOL RESOURCE MANAGEMENT 73

Table 5.3: Measures recommended by local people, officials and experts for a sustainable wetland management

Governance Recommendations of local Recommendations of govern- of wetlands people ment officials and experts Stakeholder Participation of all kebele resi- Community-based management involvement dents in all kebele issues (13:25) (ARARI: 41:18; BDU: 40:11) and elaboration of rules and regulations by the government (ARARI: 36:27) Wetland delin- Register and demarcate commu- Designation of a buffer zone eation nal lands so as to reduce conflicts (BoARD: 32:5; EPLAUA: 37:4), (15:38; 18:35) including wetlands along rivers (Gumara, Ribb, Gilgel, Megech) to reduce sedimentation of the lake basin (ARARI: 36:18) Contextual • Decentralisation of the ad- • Reduce pressure on wetlands Factors ministration of large kebele through agricultural modernisa- sizes, administration left with tion (BoWE: 31:9) and increase sub-kebeles (see Regulation No. in productivity (EWNRA: 29:6) • 51/2007: §28), or division of ke- Integrate options for alternative beles (13:21) • Better adjustment wetland uses, livelihood diver- of market prices to fish resource sification (e. g. fishing, forage scarcity and the quality of the production using the cut-and- fish produce (23:19) carry system, collecting plants, tourism) and agricultural speciali- sation (e. g. 22:13; BoARD: 32:2; EWNRA: 29:6). Regulations Equitable but possibly unequal Seasonal area closure to allow distribution of resources, e. g. fish- for regeneration of fish species ing restriction for richer farmers (ARARI: 41:3) (23:24) Landscape Consider wetlands as a section of approach the larger watershed (EWNRA: 28:9) 74 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS

Governance Recommendations of local Recommendations of govern- of wetlands people ment officials and experts Measures to be • Advocacy for the rights of • Create management plans taken landless people by the kebele ad- (BDU: 40:14; BoWE: 31:4) ministration (2:22) • Ensure that • Overcome constraints to information on relevant subjects, change through additional train- such as wetland management, ing, awareness creation and is adequately disseminated by model farming (22:13) selecting people who participate • Adopt improved techniques in trainings and workshops on (e. g. for high-quality fish produc- wetland management through the tion) (ARARI: 41:10) community itself (24:6) • Assist farmers financially • Present and transfer the ac- (ARARI: 41:11) quired knowledge during kebele • Monitoring and evaluation of conferences held at church (24:6) outcomes, assessment of and research on wetlands (22:13) • Draw on traditional knowledge to develop tourism in wetlands (BoARD: 32:6)

5.8 Summary

Social actors mainly value wetlands for their instrumental purposes. These values as well as perceptions on living conditions and natural capital influence the way wetlands are used and managed. Wetland use changes (e. g. rice cultivation, fishery) are driven by internal but likewise external factors (e. g. population growth, unemployment, livelihood insecurity, economic incentives, flooding, sedimentation) and involve conflicts over the utilisation of wetland resources (figure 5.16, p. 75). The different priorities of social actors on wetland resource appropriation become manifest in these conflicts, adversely affecting communal life. The land administration system of the Amhara region contributes to the alteration of wetlands. Failures to register and clarify boundaries of landholding and lack of land use planning result in a continuous open access situation and mismanagement of wetlands. 5.8. SUMMARY 75

To tackle the unregulated resource utilisation, local management institutions were established in varying degrees of sophistication. Their functioning is con- strained by multi-level factors, such as the attitude of wetland users and a lack of participation in decision-making, further by failures to implement and enforce rules, and to monitor management outcomes. Local conflict resolution mechanisms should support an effective management but often remain ineffective. Government bodies are said to dislike local by-laws. Besides, their policies often negatively affect the sustainable use of wetlands and provide multiple authorities with a mandate to manage wetland resources (figure 5.16, p. 75).

? Economic growth

External shocks (e.g. flooding) Economic incentives WETLAND

Increasing Unemployment Vulnerability/ overexploitation livelihood insecurity ? Policies Conversion of ? wetlands Local institutions Conflicts

Degradation of the Structural and upper watershed functional changes*

Land scarcity Loss of genetic and species diversity*

amplifying effect Population growth attenuating effect

Figure 5.16: Main causal chains of wetland alteration and the effects of institutions on wetland management. * See Appendix 7, p. XXVIII. Source: compiled from own results

The research findings provide a basic insight on the distinct research topics (land use changes, conflicts over wetlands and associated resources, land adminis- tration and common-pool resource management). The subsequent analysis seeks to comprehensively combine the findings to illustrate the decisive conditions that determine an effective management and a sustainable resource utilisation of the 76 CHAPTER 5. RESULTS wetlands. Chapter 6

Analysis

Assessing the conditions that facilitate or constrain an effective wetland manage- ment involves several analytical steps (see p. 24): To put wetland management in a broader context, environmental entitlements and their feedback to wetland systems are analysed first. Subsequently, the mechanisms of access to wetland resources and services, and the institutions that impinge on these mechanisms are identified. These determine who can benefit from wetland management. Prop- erty rights to wetlands as essential endowments for common-property resource management are addressed. Further on, the power relations that underlie the mechanisms of access and wetland management as well as conflicts over wetlands are dissected. An institutional analysis on land administration and its effect on wetland management then follows. The chapter is closed by a comprehensive integration of the conditions that determine the effectiveness of common-pool resource management systems to conserve wetland resources.

6.1 The Cyclical Process of Environmental Entitlements

Wetlands provide various assets to local people. The set of entitlements directly derived from these endowments includes food for own consumption, income from selling produce to markets, construction materials, flood protection and recreation.

77 78 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

These utilities enhance people’s capabilities, e. g. by contributing to food and income security particularly at the end of the dry season when food and income become otherwise scarce. The income can be deployed to purchase other cash- dependent items and farm inputs, for children’s education or medical treatment. Benefits gained from wetland resources and services thus contribute to well-being, may increase social status and improve advocacy within the community. Enhanced capabilities may then be utilised to harness wetland resources more efficiently, draw on more advanced and unexploited assets, or access new opportunities regarding livelihood diversification, social relations, rights etc. (“the transformative role and potential of new capital”, Agrawal 2001: 1565; see the two shorter, curved arrows in figure 6.1, p. 79). Livelihood outcomes (e. g. capabilities, well-being) of people’s actions feed back to the ecological conditions and natural capital provided by wetlands (see Scoones 1998: 4–7; figure 6.1, p. 79). The activities of local actors (see p. 48) often involve the overuse and degradation of wetland resources, thereby eroding the resource base and the resilience of the ecosystem (see Appendix 7, p. XXVIII). It was shown (see p. 56) that local communities are not “homogeneous entities” (Leach et al. 1999: 229). Instead, social actors have different and often conflicting objectives and priorities regarding resource use and management. This implies that the configurations of the ‘endowments-entitlements-capabilities chains’ of social actors are quite diverse and that trade-offs between such ‘chains’ occur (for an example see figure 6.1, p. 79). In order to maintain or enhance capabilities and well-being, access to benefit from wetlands is essential. But how do people gain access to wetland resources and services in the first place?

6.2 Mapping Endowments: Access to Wetlands

Wetlands are communally used but state-owned (see p. 84). Exclusion of local communities or strangers is difficult and subtractability of benefits high, i. e. resources which are extracted by one person cannot be used by another person. These characteristics mostly lead to open access situations since wetlands are “owned by no one or paradoxically by ‘everyone’, [. . . ] used [. . . ] by whomever can 6.2. MAPPING ENDOWMENTS: ACCESS TO WETLANDS 79

Context Wetland Wetland (social, ecological, resources & resources & political, economic) services services

Pasture, hay Arable land Resilience? Resilience? Food, cash income from Food, (income) selling meat

Livelihood secu- Livelihood rity, accumula- security tion of wealth Trade-offs, Poor/Mid-rich Livestock farmer conflicts farmer

Figure 6.1: Exemplary ‘entitlement chains’. Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234 gain access” (Ostrom 2003: 249). This creates common-pool resource dilemmas in which people’s “short-term interests produce outcomes that are not in anyone’s long-term interest” (Ostrom et al. 1999: 279). The following sections describe the mechanisms of access and the institutions that mediate access to wetland resources.

6.2.1 Rights-Based Access to Wetland Resources

Rights-based access to resources and services includes (1) legal and (2) illegal mechanisms (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 162–164). Legal mechanisms refer to rights attributed by law and socially accepted customs or conventions (ibid.: 162). Illegal access means access that is not socially sanctioned by society or state (ibid.: 164). 80 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

6.2.1.1 Legal Mechanisms

In accordance with customary rights of access, wetlands have been used as communal pastures (see Taffa 2005: 61). Pastoralists particularly of the upper well-being group and members of the kebele administration rely on customary and statutory rights to preserve communal grazing lands. §16(1)F of the Regulation No. 51/2007 on rural land administration and use states that landholders or those being granted land use rights shall “not [. . . ] cross the borderlines of communal land”. By referring to these rights, livestock farmers and kebele leaders control the access of other users to wetland resources and maintain their own access. To gain or maintain access to wetland resources for agricultural production, poorer persons also draw on the land administration and use legislation. Landless who wish to engage in agricultural activities appeal to their right to acquire landholding (Proclamation No. 133/2006: §6(1)). Young people as the eligible heirs claim their fathers’ land (Regulation No. 51/2007: §11, bequeath land holding rights). Questions of inheritance may be hard to comprehend being exacerbated by inheritance disputes (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 25, 26). In some cases the Land Registry Book, indicating children’s names, may help mediating disputes (personal communication: WoEPLAU Addis Zemen). Conversion of communal lands, i. e. land (re)distribution to landless or poor, which “at least 80% of the kebele inhabitants have consented on” (Regulation No. 51/2007: §6(1)) complies with the law, provided that the request for land (re)distribution is accepted by WoEPLAU (ibid.: §6(1, 4)) and plot size is larger than the defined minimum (ibid.: §7). (See the right of figure 6.2, p. 91 for the institutions that mediate access.)

6.2.1.2 Illegal Mechanisms

Though wetlands might have been converted to cultivated land in the course of history (see p. 51), encroachment as a means to gain access to and use the fertile land is deemed illegal. This applies to anybody who converts communal land whether rich or poor. Illegal mechanisms to which mostly richer persons revert in order to gain, control and maintain access to wetlands include corruption, bribery at local and woreda levels, counterfeit of documents, suppression and intimidation. 6.2. MAPPING ENDOWMENTS: ACCESS TO WETLANDS 81

Farmers also illegally gain access to communal lands either by registering this land as their private holding or by trying to leave this land unregistered to continue tilling it silently. Allocation of land to landless without the consent of WoEPLAU is in breach of the statutory regulations (see p. 64). Grazing in Agid Kirigna’s wetlands during the rainy season contravenes local by-laws. Concerning fishery, stealing of nets is a way to prevent other fishermen from pursuing their activities, i. e. controlling access to the thieves’ benefit.

6.2.2 Structural and Relational Mechanisms of Access

Political-economic and cultural aspects may “influence who has resource access priority” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 164–165) and mediate the ability to benefit from resources and services (ibid.: 164).

Access to capital influences who is able to benefit from resources and services (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 165–166). A farmer who has the financial means to draw on labour, farm equipment and farm inputs may decide to encroach into wetland (Wood 2003: 59). Fishermen who are better off have the means to invest in a number of fisher nets and thereby increase their catch. Propertied social actors may also use their money to bribe courts, governmental bodies and other people into silence.

Access to knowledge can be another crucial factor to benefit from resources and services (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 168–169). Non-transfer of knowledge of wetland management may influence whether or how others are able to gain access to wetland resources and services. Further, education can be a criterion for the election of kebele administration and LAC members (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 22). Political elections can have implications for communal land administration. Lack of access to knowledge and misinformation similarly shapes resource access. If legal documents and other materials are unknown or inaccessible to an ordinary person or a LAC member, then access to wetlands may be gained, controlled or maintained by actors who then benefit from this lack of knowledge 82 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS or misinformation.

Access to participation is important to benefit from resources and services through negotiation and decision-making processes. §34 of Regulation No. 51/2007 calls for the involvement of the public to deliberate and decide on issues concerning communal land use. Where participation is not promoted, the kebele administration overrides community interests, preferences and concerns related to access, use and management of common-pool resources and in so doing controls access.

Access to authority shapes a person’s ability to benefit from wetland resources and services (see Ribot & Peluso 2003: 170). Ribot & Peluso (2003) emphasise the role of authority as “an important juncture in the web of powers [where] multiple access mechanisms or strands are bundled together in one person or institution” (p. 170). Through those juncture, people are able to access beneficial wetland resources. “With the authority to [. . . ] implement laws” (ibid.: 170), the LAC in con- sultation with the kebele administration and the woreda land administration department can decide upon the administration and development of communal lands (Regulation No.51/2007: §27(6)). “With the authority to make [. . . ] laws” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 170), the kebele administration can establish rules and regulations concerning the management of communal lands (Taffa 2005: 61) and hence influence the ability to gain access and benefit. Together with the authority to resolve disputes (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 638), the LAC, elders and the kebele administration hold a powerful instrument in their hands which can be used to shape the ability of others to access and use common-pool resources (see figure 6.2, p. 91). Failure to exercise legal authority to enforce regulations and impose sanctions upon delinquents favours illegal resource access. For example, the incapacity of WoEPLAU offices to monitor landholders’ compliance with land use obligations may result in continuous encroachment. Access to authority is also vested in community members through the ‘80% rule’ (see p. 80) which enables people, especially landless and young, to benefit from access to distributed land. 6.2. MAPPING ENDOWMENTS: ACCESS TO WETLANDS 83

“Overlapping systems of legitimacy” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 163), where claims are made on the basis of a plurality of formal and informal rights, encourage people to acquire resources “using different notions of legitimate or authoritative access” (ibid.: 170). There is a plurality of federal and regional policies and strategies (see p. 69; figure 6.2, p. 91) formulated as if related government bodies had legitimate command over wetland resources. This plurality is reflected in the diversity of people’s perceptions on and reactions to government plans and policies pertaining to wetland management (see p. 59). Resource use claims are further asserted through local by-laws and customary rights regulating and granting access to wetlands. The different institutional settings can essentially influence people’s decisions on resource utilisation (Henrich 2003: 320).

Access through social identity “profoundly affects the distribution of benefits from things” (Ribot & Peluso 2003: 170). The membership in a group or organi- sation mediates the ability to benefit from resources and services. Identity-based access conditions many other forms of access (ibid.: 172). Wealth is associated with reputation and respect. Members of the upper well-being group can more easily advocate their interests within the community and gain access to wetlands. LAC members being in a special position and kebele leaders enjoying a high regard can allocate and control access to land and other resources, and in so doing selectively give people advantages. Complaints of the Woito about the unlimited access of community members to fish resources imply a claim to access to fishing grounds, a traditional claim which can be hardly asserted today. The young landless gain access to wetlands and other communal lands by joining a youth association which advocates the interests of their members or by forming groups willing to jointly manage and use land then distributed to them (see Proclamation No. 133/2006: §2(19), §10). Established fishermen’s associations ensure that each member maintains access to fish resources. Scientists and conservationists focusing on wetland protection may wittingly or unwittingly control the ability of local people to benefit from resources and services, e. g. by prohibiting use or prescribing use regimes (see zur Heide: 136). The institutions which social actors draw on to gain, control or maintain 84 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS access to wetland resources and services are indicated in figure 6.2, p. 91.

6.2.3 Property Rights to Wetlands

The ability to access benefits from wetland resources and services can be derived from a statutory, customary or conventional right to access (see p. 80). The right to access, i. e. a property right (Ostrom 2003: 249), constitutes a person’s endowment which cannot directly be derived from wetland goods and services (figure 6.2, p. 91). Ribot & Peluso (2003) remark that “the distinction between rights-based ‘property’ approaches and illegal forms of access [. . . ] is predicated on notions of morality and legitimacy” (supra note 20, p. 164). Hence, what one considers to be a legal right may be questioned by another on moral and legitimate grounds (ibid.: supra note 20, 164). Moral claims such as basic need claims by landless or poor may often conflict with legal claims, e. g. preventing wetland encroachment. Legitimacy may often be challenged considering the partly incompatible rules of land administration and use policies and between customary and statutory law, e. g. where wetland and recession agriculture is allowed by the former but not by the latter. Property rights to wetlands are more complex than they appear at a first glance. This is due to the fact that practically, no distinction is made between state and common property (Pausewang undated; see p. 17), i. e. the property regime (Ostrom 2003: 249; see p. 93) and holding rights for wetlands are vague. The bundles of rights approach by Schlager & Ostrom (1992, 1996 in Ostrom 2003: 249–252 and Ostrom 2009 b: 28–29; see p. 26) helps analysing the complex property rights system of wetlands. Local people subtracting wetland resources are the authorised users. Since property regimes of wetlands are often ill-defined, it remains unclear whether these rights are de jure rights (compliant with customary or statutory law) or de facto property rights (see Ostrom 2003: 253). Social actors deciding on management regulations become authorised claimants (e. g. fishermen’s associations). They are then authorised to limit the withdrawal of resources by other users (ibid.: 250–251). If communities develop a management system determining access and harvesting conditions, proprietorship is established. The prohibition to cultivating 6.2. MAPPING ENDOWMENTS: ACCESS TO WETLANDS 85 wetlands is an example. In contrast to de jure owners of wetland plots, de facto owners illegally cultivate wetland parcels when their claims to those parcels are not sanctioned by community members or government authorities (see p. 80). LAC members may be regarded as proprietors in their double role: They are attributed de jure rights to manage, administer and develop communal lands (see p. 82) and, as members of the community, also have access and withdrawal rights. The woreda land administration and use authorities can influence the man- agement of communal lands. In cases of non-performance of land use obligations, the woreda authorities have the right to exclude users through deprivation of a holder’s right to use communal land ( Proclamation No. 133/2006: §21(3, 4); Regulation No. 51/2007: §§ 17(3, 4), 25(5), 27(6)). The departments are not the proprietors of wetlands anyway, since they lack the rights to withdrawal and access. The state, represented by the kebele administration at the lowest administrative level, is the owner of all land in Ethiopia (Constitution 1994: Article 40(3); see p. 17), holding all five property rights. Land can be expropriated for public use by paying compensation (Proclamation No. 133/2006: §28; Regulation No. 51/2007: §29; see also Proclamation No. 455/2005). Table 6.1, p. 86 summarises the property rights to wetlands associated with different social actors and indicates actors’ holding positions. 86 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

Table 6.1: Bundles of property rights to wetland resources associated with various social actors and positions (de facto and de jure situation). S State; KA Kebele administration; WoA Woreda land and use admin- istration authorities; LAC Land Administration and Use Committee; WeC Wetland cultivators; U1 Wetland users managing resource access; U2 Wetland users managing resource withdrawal; U3 Wetland users: no management. Source: modified after Ostrom & Schlager (1996) in Ostrom 2003: 251

S/KA WoA LAC WeC U1 U2 U3 Access + – + + + + + Withdrawal + – + + + + + Managem. + + + + + + – Exclusion + + + + + – – Alienation + – – (+)1 – – – Position owner – proprietor owner2 proprietor authorised authorised claimants users

The institutions that ascribe property rights to social actors are also indicated in figure 6.2, p. 91. The next section identifies the power relations that underlie both the mechanisms of access and the way wetlands are used and managed.

6.3 Power Relations and the Question of Who Benefits

Power, conditioning social relationships (Bryant 1997: 10), is a crucial element of access (de Haan & Zoomers 2005: 44). Power is often distributed unequally among different social actors whereas the more powerful have better capabilities to control the environment of others (Bryant 1997: 10–11). People can “exert different claims to power” (Armitage 2008: 23).

1Rights holders are allowed to bequeath (Regulation No. 51/2007: §11), rent (§12) and exchange landholding (§8). 2In the Ethiopian context, the term ‘holder’ may be more appropriate (see Proclamation No. 133/2005). 6.3. POWER RELATIONS AND THE QUESTION OF WHO BENEFITS 87

Powers of the Wealthier In many cases, the elite, i. e. richer farmers and people holding a public office, dominates and controls local resources. Richer livestock farmers try to control and maintain their access to traditional communal grazing lands, hereby preventing cultivation, and to condition resource withdrawal. More frequently than richer farmers, peasants of the middle and lower well-being groups may be involved in the conversion of wetlands (see Wood 2003: 62) for asset stabilisation and maintaining or enhancing well-being. Kebele leaders having the authority to administer and decide upon development of communal lands and to sanction or not sanction non-conformance to regulations, may suppress different opinions on and opposition to (Pausewang undated) the management of wetlands to the detriment of poor and landless.

Powers of Weaker Actors Though poor and landless may often be incapable of “making claims ‘stick’ against those of more powerful actors in the context of resource struggles” (Leach et al. 1999: 241), they are not entirely powerless. De Haan and Zoomers (2005) stress “the active or even proactive role played by the poor” (p. 28) to make a living and Bryant (1997) recognises the capabil- ity of weaker actors to resist the powerful. Legal mechanisms and drawing on social identity to gain access to and use wetland resources can become forceful instruments for poor. For example, land titling possibly redirects power from richer persons to younger and poor involved in land and resource related disputes. However, where middle-rich or poor farmers feel powerless to assert their claims, illegal mechanisms to exploit wetland resources (Bryant 1997: 13), e. g. illegal encroachment or fishing practices, may be deployed. Weaker actors employ a rather subtle way of protest which has certain advantages such as the avoidance of direct confrontation with the more powerful as well as the provision and bene- fit of endowments. Acts of illegal resource appropriation are a form of implicit resistance, mainly motivated by securing and stabilising livelihoods (see Holmes 2007: 185–186, 189, 193). Woito fishermen, belonging to an ethnic minority group and often negatively perceived by other communities, find it difficult to claim power in decision-making processes. Small-sized groups may be incapable to defend resources when external pressures increase (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 636). In this regard, the Woito are 88 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS often unable to defend fish resources given such pressures as flooding, land scarcity and unemployment that affect other communities.

Top-Down versus Bottom-Up Usually, policy formulation, development and implementation are top-down (Abbot et al. 2000: 20) and government bodies dislike local by-laws. By-laws emanate from the power to make decisions at local levels. Where local people feel incapable of tackling the mismanagement of common-pool resources, they surrender power to state agencies.

Power Relations between Governance Bodies Power relations also condi- tion interactions between various government sectors and levels. These claim power by appealing to their mandates and the “common good” (Bryant 1997: 12) of their interests. Mandates, often not clearly set, compete, for example between woreda land administration departments and LACs (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 18, 24) or between BoARD and EPLAUA. Arguing and convincing with the common good is a powerful strategy to “win the battle of ideas” (Bryant 1997: 12) over utilisation of common-pool resources. Growth as targeted by the GTP and PIF should eradicate poverty (MoFED 2010: 32; MoARD 2010), a goal to which the Food Security Strategy substantially contributes (MoARD 2009). The Environmental Policy underlines the ecological function value of wetlands (EPA/MoEDC 1997: 11) upon which basic-needs or health arguments could be predicated (see p. 16). All of these policies certainly have their justification and their stake in arguing for or against wetland conservation.

The Power of Knowledge Knowledge is a powerful instrument to influence access to and use of resources. Scientific understanding is not always approved by local people, possibly resulting in the continuation of access and use practices. Similarly, scientific resource management approaches are less accepted by local people but more accepted by official bodies.

Beneficiaries of Land Registration Since 2001, the decentralisation policy of land administration (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12) has transferred the govern- ment’s administrative power to the regions (Miller & Tolina 2008: 372). The 6.3. POWER RELATIONS AND THE QUESTION OF WHO BENEFITS 89 certification process has been “the most promising development from delegation of administrative power” (ibid.: 373). Nevertheless, this power now rests with the lower administrative levels: As Adenew & Abdi (2005) note, woreda and kebele administrations reckoned that land certification reduced their control over smallholders “who then may become less loyal, less willing to attend meetings or accept orders” (p. 24). In Ethiopia’s land tenure history, land has always been used as “a means to control peasants” (Pausewang undated; see also Miller & Tolina 2008). Rich are believed to benefit from land titling, e. g. due to their capability to bribe (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 31), and consequently shape wetland utilisation according to their interest. Table 6.2, p. 89 presents the analytical findings about the beneficiaries, their mechanisms to gain access to and the outcomes they achieve from harnessing wetland resources, including the actors involved in controlling the access of wetland users. See also figure 6.2, p. 91 for the power relations that condition resource access and use.

Table 6.2: The beneficiaries of wetland utilisation, their mechanisms to gain access to and the outcomes achieved from withdrawing wetland resources. In the lower part of the table: social actors involved in wetland management, the mechanisms to and outcomes of controlling access. Source: own compilation

Benefit Beneficiary, Mechanisms of access Outcomes -ies/Actors Grazing House- Control access through legal Accumulation of holds with mechanisms, capital, authority, wealth livestock social identity (mainly wealthier) Cultivation Richer farm- Gain access through illegal mech- Accumulation of ers anisms, capital, authority, social wealth identity Mid-rich, Gain access through legal, illegal Asset stabilisation, poor farmers mechanisms, implicit resistance, food security capital, participation 90 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

Benefit Beneficiary, Mechanisms of access Outcomes -ies/Actors Cultivation Landless Gain access through legal, illegal Livelihood security mechanisms, implicit resistance, social identity, capital, participa- tion Fishing Richer fisher- Gain access through capital, use Food secu- men of illegal means (?) rity, accumula- tion/stabilisation of wealth Middle- Gain access through capital, use Food security, em- rich, poor of illegal means, implicit resis- ployment fishermen tance (?) Landless Gain access through capital, use Livelihood security, of illegal means, implicit resis- employment tance (?) Woito Gain access through capital, so- Asset stabilisation cial identity, use of illegal means, and accumulation implicit resistance (?) Grazing, cut- Monks of Control access through legal Asset stabilisation and-carry, Tana Kirkos mechanisms, social identity and accumulation papyrus harvesting Depending Farmers Control access through knowl- ? on actor’s trained in edge priorities wetland management LAC mem- Control access through legal Personal or commu- bers mechanisms, authority, knowledge nal well-being Kebele Ad- Control access through legal Personal or com- ministration mechanisms, authority, knowledge munal well-being, keeping control over kebele residents Elders Control access through legal (Personal or) com- mechanisms, identity, authority munal well-being (disciplinary power3?)

3The unquestioningly accepted power by elders that makes people accept their situation, 6.3. POWER RELATIONS AND THE QUESTION OF WHO BENEFITS 91

Benefit Beneficiary, Mechanisms of access Outcomes -ies/Actors Public pur- Government Control access and use through ‘Common good’ poses/agric. agencies legal mechanisms and authority development Wetland Scientific Control access through authority, (Social-) ecological conservation community knowledge, identity resilience enhanced

Context Social status, political Wetland (social, ecological, office, mandates, cultural resources & Macro political, economic) identity, organisations, Constitution; federal policies services resistance, corruption… Meso Land administration & use proclamation & regulation; regional Endowment mapping policies; conflict resolution mechanisms Micro Endowments Legal, illegal, Customary rights; by-laws & regulations; (capital & property structural & relational conflict resolution mechanisms rights) mechanisms of access

Entitlement mapping Resilience?

Entitlements

Capabilities/ well-being Trade-offs, conflicts Social actors

Figure 6.2: Mapping endowments: the mechanisms of access, power and social relations and the institutions mediating access to wetlands. (Federal and regional policies include water and agricultural development policies.) Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234

As shown, the different mechanisms and means social actors draw on to benefit from wetland resources are not all considered legitimate, implying conflicts over wetlands. subservience and powerlessness (de Haan & Zoomers 2005: 36–37; Ribot & Peluso 2003: 156). 92 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

6.4 The Complexity of Conflicts

Conflicts over wetlands and their associated resources involve (1) conflicts over access, including (a) conflicts related to legally claimed property rights to wetlands (cultivation, grazing) and (b) conflicts related to illegal access (gained through means of power or implicit resistance), and (2) conflicts related to the use of resources and conditions of their appropriation (e. g. unsustainable fishing practices contrary to regulations, the amount of daily catch, seasonal grazing restraints; figure 6.4, p. 103). Conflicts related to the violation of rules tend to involve disputes about the illegality of resource harvesting. Conflicts within or between social communities appear to be specific to a certain local context. Disputes over wetlands are caused by a complex interplay of internal and external factors which are summarised in figure 6.3, p. 92.

Societal & economic trend; environmental changes Different values, needs, interests or incentives Sectoral thinking, of social actors overlapping jurisdiction & ambiguity over mandates Changes in wetland use Contested resource use claims Conflicting & inconsistent (Leach et al. 1999: 233) sectoral policies (see IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 76) Exposure to flooding Conflicts over wetlands

Property rights system: Unequal capacity of social legitimacy of access to wetlands, actors to cope with shocks withdrawal of resources, e. g. approved by customary but not statutory law, or by inconclusive Different degrees of statutory rules, management rights Inequalities of access (see Becker & Ostrom 1995: (Leach et al. 1999: 233) livelihood dependence 115; Bryant 1992: 22) on resources between social actors

Power relations (Bryant 1998: 85)

Figure 6.3: The casual factors for the occurrence of conflicts over wetlands. Source: own compilation

The previous sections briefly described how assets wetlands provide to local 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 93 people are deployed to enhance well-being and capabilities and the mechanisms of access. An attempt was made to unravel property rights to wetlands. A section was dedicated to the power relations that condition the way endowments and entitlements are gained. The complexity of conflicts which often emerge when gaining endowments and entitlements was addressed. Hereafter an analysis on the institutions which impinge on the way utilities are derived from wetland resources follows.

6.5 Institutions Shaping Wetland Use and Management

Relevant institutions have already been analysed in relation to their function of impinging on resource access and local interactions (figure 6.2, p. 91). The institutional analysis in this section concentrates on the influence of rules and regulations on wetland use and management, i. e. on how endowments can be transformed into entitlements.

6.5.1 Land Administration

This section refers to the property regimes of wetlands and the effects of land titling and land use planning on the governance of wetland resources.

6.5.1.1 Property Regimes of Wetlands

Ostrom (2003) distinguishes between the type of good (property) and the property regime4. “Common-pool resources [cannot] automatically [be] associated with common-property regimes” (Ostrom 2003: 249). As mentioned above, peasants make no difference between state property and common-property regimes as long as land is administered by the state (Pausewang undated) and in a decentralised manner by lower level authorities. The problem is that de jure state property is often treated as de facto open access (see Berkes et al. 1989: 92). Since land is

4Berkes et al. (1989) distinguish between four basic property regimes under which common- pool resources are held: (1) open access, (2) private property, (3) communal property and (4) state property. 94 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS the property of the state, incentives to invest in (communal) holdings (Miller & Tolina 2008: 367–368) and the sense of responsibility to these lands are often low (Abbot et al. 2000: 21). Wetlands lie in a legal grey area between state holding “for [. . . ] area devel- opment and growth” (Proclamation No. 133/2005: §2(7)), communal holding “used [emphasis of the author] by local people in common for grazing [. . . ] and other social services” (ibid.: §2(5)), and private holding. This grey area in the land administration and use legislation leads to confusion and discrepancies regarding wetland registration (see p. 61), and impinges on wetland use and management (see p. 95; figure 6.4, p. 103).

6.5.1.2 The Impact of Land Registration and Certification, and Land Use Planning on Wetland Management

In general, land registration and certification processes were “focused on mapping of agricultural holdings to the detriment of common property resources” (Deininger et al. 2007: 10). Failures to register common property resources result in a continuous crossing of communal borders and leave property issues unclear. Local registration processes have occasionally fostered and have at the same time been delayed by cases of encroachment and conflicts. Wetland management efforts are easily frustrated due to intransparencies during registration but likewise legal redistribution of communal lands if communally agreed. Registration activities are usually undertaken in the dry season when the area is accessible for woreda survey and administration teams and agricultural activities do not compete with registration activities for LACs (Deininger et al. 2007: 7). Being grazing or crop lands in the dry season, seasonal wetlands are difficult to identify, are consequently not demarcated and registered with respect to their actual use5. These shortcomings and power relations underlying the registration and certifi- cation process complicate local management attempts. On the other hand, studies (Adenew & Abdi 2005; Deininger et al. 2006, 2007; SARDP/EPLAUA/ORGUT 2010) and own findings show that certification is perceived to have a positive

5For example, in their land cover and use survey, DSA/SCI (2006) partially mapped marshlands together with intensively cultivated land. 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 95 effect on resource management and conservation if registration was undertaken properly. For example, communal investments are said to increase (Deininger et al. 2006: 13), common property resources to be managed more sustainably and encroachments on communal lands to be reduced (Deininger et al. 2007: 15, 27). These positive effects on resource management and conservation can be associated with an increased “subjective tenure security” (Crewett & Korf 2008: 209, 212–213) through certification. The clarification of boundaries through registration reduces conflicts (Deininger et al. 2006: 13; Deininger et al. 2007: 27) and may result in more sustainable wetland management. Unlike farmers stressing the importance of land use planning to avoid the mismanagement of natural resources, Mesfin (2003) points out that land use planning often fosters conversion of and sacrifices wetlands for other use purposes. The land administration system may thus have a double-edged effect on natural resource management (figure 6.4, p. 103). The further institutional analysis comprehensively addresses the conditions de- termining an effective wetland management. Attributes of common-pool resources (Becker & Ostrom 1995; Ostrom 2003) are identified and local management insti- tutions analysed regarding the design principles of robust common-pool resource management systems (Becker & Ostrom 1995; Ostrom 2009 b). The chapter concludes with an analysis of the effectiveness of institutions to conserve wetlands.

6.5.2 Common-Pool Resource Management

A collective action problem of the common-pool resource type is characterised by costly exclusion and subtractive consumption (Ostrom 2003: 241–243, 248). Generally, the probability that users organise is higher when expected benefits of collective resource management exceed the costs for investing in establishing institutional arrangements (Ostrom 2009 a: 420). Attributes of (1) the resource, (2) users, (3) the structure of the situation, i. e. contextual factors, and (4) the institutional arrangements (Agrawal 2001: 1653; Ostrom: 2003: 252–259) affect the likelihood of self-organisation of people (Ostrom 2009 a: 240–241) and a successful collective action as well as the feasibility of establishing a communal property regime for wetlands (Ostrom 2003: 243). These variables facilitate the 96 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS emergence and the functioning of institutions to effectively manage wetlands (Agrawal 2001: 1658).

6.5.2.1 Attributes of Wetlands and Associated Resources

Characteristics of wetlands may determine the effectiveness of institutional ar- rangements to sustain associated resources (Agrawal 2001: 1655). The size of a wetland can be a challenge to devising workable rules for its management (Ostrom et al. 1999: 279). The large wetland extending over the two Fogera kebeles may be more difficult to managed by a collective than the smaller ones in Tana Kirkos and Agid Kirigna (figure 2.3, p. 14). Low levels of resource mobility have been identified as enabling conditions for an effective community-based management (Agrawal 2001: 1655). Wetlands themselves are stationary resource systems, except some fish species, e. g. migra- tory fishes. The possibility to store endowments obtained from wetland resources (pastures, fish) for direct use is relatively low. Especially fish resource manage- ment is associated with higher costs of gaining reliable information on mobile fish species and constrained by an increasing pressure on the resource due to lower storage degrees. Besides, when harvesting biological resources, users need to preconceive various ecological aspects including the type of resource appropriated (e. g. only matured fish species or papyrus plants), the time (e. g. rejuvenation), or the extent of harvest (e. g. a certain amount of fish daily, restricted grazing). Considering these aspects is important in terms of possible ecological trade-offs and related economic ramifications (Becker & Ostrom 1995: 118, 124). Carrying capacity and time required for a resource to regenerate are further important attributes that need to be considered in common-property resource management (Ostrom et al. 1999: 279). Wetlands may not be able to sustain a continuously increasing livestock population, or may more easily re-organise from seasonal grazing than from cultivation (see Appendix 7, p. XXVIII). Netting (1976, 1981 in Ostrom 2003: 254) found that a low production value per unit area is conducive to the development of common-property rights. Initial high production values of wetlands provide incentives (high returns) to peasants 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 97 to individually cultivate plots.

6.5.2.2 Attributes of Wetland Users

Whether wetland users successfully solve collective action problems is determined by the size and heterogeneity of groups (Ostrom 2003: 257). The large size of resource user groups and the heterogeneity between and within groups may obstruct organisation for communal resource management. Given this heterogeneity, reaching a common understanding of the most beneficial, suitable land use regime (considering the objections and risks associated with different use regimes), and the institutional setting of a use regime (ibid.: 257) is awkward. Inaccurate information (ibid.: 257) and incomplete knowledge about sustainable wetland use and management as well as the importance of wetlands in terms of their regulating and supporting ecosystem functions hamper the creation of such a common understanding. The variation of interests in wetland use involve conflicts over the resources. Fabricius & Collins (2007) stress the negative effect conflicts have on community- based resource management. Reciprocity and trust in social relations “can be used as initial social capital” (Ostrom 2003: 257) to enhance the performance of common-pool resource management systems, the capacity of social-ecological systems and the ability to adapt to and shape system change (Folke 2006: 261). Conflicts over land issues, unequal power distributions, illegal acts and experiences related to Ethiopia’s tenure system are unconducive to building trust in local communities. The way wetland users are linked is important to consider when promoting collective action (Ostrom 2009 b: 30). Accentuating vertical linkages of authority between wetland users at community level may avert participation and display manifestations of power rather than equality. Where leadership and knowledge are actively invested in discussions on management they might positively influence the establishment of organisation (Ostrom 2009 a: 421). Inasmuch as local elites are powerful, they might also encourage collective wetland management by teaching people, strengthening institutional implementation or facilitating traditional conflict resolution (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 62; see supra note 11, 98 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS p. 70). Power relations can significantly influence the emergence and sustenance of institutional settings. Since natural endowments of the research area facilitate livelihoods, most peasants may seek to permanently live and work in their village6. Management thus has a stable component (Ostrom 2003: 257). Ostrom (2003) states that permanent residence and employment in one area reduced discounting the future. But due to historical experiences, e. g. frequent land redistribution or land sale to foreigners (personal communication: farmers in Tanametsele), and livelihood insecurity, farmers may still discount future resource use, consequently exacerbating degradation. People’s lack of confidence in their capabilities and powers to build their own future constrains collective action by inhibiting self-organisation and initiatives at the local level (see Fabricius & Collins 2007: 92). When resource users value solving common-pool resource dilemmas (Ostrom 2009 b: 30–31) and when the resource is of importance to them (Ostrom 2009 a: 421), collective action can be successful. All in all, there are many indications that people value solving problems of wetland degradation. The appreciation of the instrumental functions of wetlands to people’s livelihoods is further a good basis for self-organisation.

6.5.2.3 Structural Attributes – The Social, Political, Economic and Ecological Context

Collective action can stem from increasing pressures on common-pool resources (Abbot et al. 2000: 8; Ostrom 2003: 253; Wood 2000: 8), such as land scarcity, driven by demographic growth. Where livestock farmers see wetland pastures being converted into arable land, more or less sophisticated management systems have been developed to protect wetlands. Likewise, overexploitation of fish resources has locally been tackled by stipulating the amount and time of harvest. Large kebele sizes can be associated with increased transaction costs of communal wetland management. With the incorporation of kebeles into larger government units, the number of stakeholders and administrative expenses in-

6Moreover, absence from the residing locality and engagement in non-agricultural activities is otherwise prosecuted with the deprivation of landholding (Regulation No. 51/2007: §14). 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 99 crease, and conflict resolution consumes more time and costs. Besides, the enlargement of kebeles complicates overseeing resources. Moreover the capacity of kebele leaders to govern such a large area is exhausted (Abbot et al. 2000: 22). Local communities are nested into governance and other organisational struc- tures (Ostrom 2003: 256). Being the “guarantor of property rights arrangements” (Agrawal 2001: 1656), the state has a central stake in the management of wetlands (see p. 84 and p. 93). Governance structures, i. e. sectoral approaches, decentralised land administration, organisation across levels and top-down decision- making affect local management. Government bodies and other organisations create awareness on and complement local knowledge about sustainable wetland use and management through workshops, trainings etc. On the other hand, gaps between different knowledge systems are unconducive to joint action across various levels. Economic incentives such as the cultivation of cash crops stimulate wetland agriculture (see Wood 2000: 13), encouraged by the initial high productivity, and wetland alteration. Consequently, the (short-term) benefits obtained through individual decision-making outweigh the alternative benefits gained through making collective choices. Lower fish prices increase pressure on fish stocks and “reduce the incentive to organise and assure future availability” (Ostrom et al. 1999: 281). Markets and new technologies may affect resource management regimes (Agrawal 2001: 1656). New incentives for production, created by market demands and technical innovations (e. g. mono-filament gill net, dehiscent mills), have resulted in a change of cropping patterns and resource harvesting methods in the research sites. Flooding, as a natural characteristic of the resource system but also human- induced (see p. 11), hampers an organisation for collective action due to the inaccessibility of infrastructure and by rendering management ineffective in times of increased risks. Responses to severe flooding events include the cultivation of wetlands and fishing to cope with livelihood insecurities (see Appendix 5, p. XIX). The unpredictability of social-ecological system dynamics (e. g. occurrence of flooding) may complicate arriving at use and management agreements (Agrawal 2001: 1655; Ostrom 2009 a: 421). Structural attributes (appearing as the ‘context’ in figure 6.4, p. 103) are 100 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS rather incompletely listed, yet sufficiently for the present work. Although an attempt is made to list the different attributes separately, they cannot be clearly distinguished from one another due to interlinkages and intersections.

6.5.2.4 Institutional Arrangements and Design Principles for Governing Wetland Resources

Becker & Ostrom (1995) “stress the importance of design principles rather than institutional solutions to common-pool resource problems” (p. 122), i. e. the design principles should be considered when establishing specific institutional arrangements. Robust institutions tend to incorporate most design principles (Becker & Ostrom 1995: 118; see p. 21). The first of Ostrom’s design principles is that of clearly defined boundaries of a resource system, and the individuals and households with property rights (Ostrom 2009 b: 32–33). There are several aspects here which obstruct the clarification of boundaries: (1) ill-defined property rights to wetlands and property regimes, (2) continuing conflicts over resource access and use, (3) boundary conflicts, (4) lack of communal land registration and (5) seasonal changes of wetland boundaries. Two implications can be made: both the boundaries of who is authorised to use the resource and the physical boundaries are fuzzy and changing. Despite this, concepts of wetland boundary demarcation exist where access to the resources is managed, e. g. in Agid Kirigna or where sanctions are imposed on illegal wetland cultivators. The definition of a boundary inevitably asks for a definition of wetland. Defining ‘seasonal wetland’ may raise many questions, e. g. on seasonal changes in land use and cover, the definition of ‘seasonal’, how to deal with dynamics and uncertainties (prolonged flooding, drought). The second principle says that benefits need to be allocated proportional to costs of management system operation (ibid.: 33–34). In Agid Kirigna and Tez Amba, rules regulate use conditions, i. e. the amount of resources harvested, the time of their utilisation, and harvesting practices. Inequities in the allocation of benefits and costs occur when users, including non-residents, subtract resources without contributing to resource management, e. g. using unsustainable fishing practices or ignoring seasonal closure of wetlands for grazing. The fairness of 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 101 the allocation of benefits is also relevant (Agrawal 2001: 1660). Evidence shows that in some cases the allocation is not fair, e. g. where wealthier fishermen gain proportionally higher catches. A subpart of this principle includes the congruence of resource appropriation and local ecology (Ostrom 2009 b: 40), i. e. the resilience of social-ecological systems. In the two cases mentioned above, this congruence is partly considered (seasonal closure for resource regeneration). The third design principle is that of a collective choice arrangement. Collective choices are made through the participation of most resource users in establishing and modifying rules which may then be considered fair (ibid.: 34). Such arrange- ments should include simple and easily understandable rules about access to and management of wetlands (Agrawal 2001: 1659). With the authority to make and implement laws, the power to suppress opinions and participation, primarily local elites can be expected to benefit from institutional settings. For example, wetlands are preferably managed as pastures rather than cultivated by landless and poor. Regulations on grazing regimes in Agid Kirigna do not sufficiently enough con- sider the dependence of poorer livestock farmers on communal feeding resources. Apparently, collective choice arrangements made by fishing resource management organisations are perceived to be more fair. The voluntary membership in such an organisation is important in this respect. In the case of involuntary membership of the Woito in Agid Kirigna, agreements are rather perceived to be unjust. The principle of monitoring resource conditions, and more often, user be- haviour to enforce rules (Ostrom 2009 b: 34–35) is one of the more elaborated principles at the local level. In Gulash, Tana Kirkos and Agid Kirigna, guards were selected to oversee resource appropriation (see p. 66). Most of the simpler management systems may rely on a mutual monitoring system: everyone in the community monitors the behaviour of other users. Fishermen mutually monitor their practices by entering and returning from Lake Tana at the same time. As opposed to this, responsible woreda government bodies fail to evaluate resource conditions and patterns of appropriation. Monitoring is related to the fifth design principle, using graduated sanctions. Graduated sanctions range from informing people about an offence to more stringent punishments (ibid.: 35). Whereas Regulation No. 51/2007 at least men- tions graduated punishments in cases of non-performance of land use obligations 102 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

(§§17, 18), locally graduated sanctions are less well stipulated. When the costs of breaking regulations are still low compared to the benefits achieved when not being caught, it is difficult to achieve collective action (see Ostrom 2009 b: 35). This is the case in the study sites. For example, the possibly obtained yields on encroached land are still lucrative enough to risk the destruction of those yields or a moderate fine when encroachment is discovered. The same is true for using resources in times of seasonal closure or illicit fishing practices. The ease with which sanctions are enforced is crucial for a joint management (Agrawal 2001: 1659). In the research sites, the enforcement of sanctions and rules is often difficult. The existence of rapid, low cost and local conflict resolution mechanisms is the sixth principle (Ostrom 2009 b: 35). People’s preference to solve conflicts locally is to be considered positive in this regard. Resolution mechanisms are known by community members and can be applied according to customary law (Regulation No. 51/2007: §§35, 37). But especially communal land conflicts cannot be solved at the local level. The arbitration of disputes by “distant government agencies” (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 638) such as woreda courts and administrations then involves an increase in costs of and time for resolution. Structural attributes of the specific situation likewise influence conflict resolution. The socio-political context is crucial to the seventh principle of minimal recognition of rights to organise by external authorities (Ostrom 2009 b: 36). Local self-organisation is undermined if government authorities do not recognise that principle. Various management tasks and activities, e. g. monitoring, conflict resolution, enforcement of rules or resource appropriation, are organised in a decentralised manner with smaller institutions being nested in larger systems (ibid.: 36, 43). Problematic are the interrelations between those nested hierarchies determined by differences in levels of legal recognition, in priorities across layers, or by the lack of interest and capabilities at state levels to govern resource use and management and to deal with local problems. The pertinent institutional arrangements setting the conditions of wetland resource subtraction and governance and accounting for the functioning of man- agement are outlined in figure 6.4, p. 103. 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 103

Social status, political Context Wetland Macro (demographic growth, office, mandates, cultural Constitution; federal policies governance structure resources & identity, organisations, Meso & unit, economic services resistance, corruption… Land administration & use incentives, ecological proclamation & regulation; regional system dynamics, policies; conflict resolution mechanisms risk, uncertainty…) Micro Endowment mapping Customary rights; by-laws & regulations; conflict resolution mechanisms Endowments Legal, illegal, (capital & property structural & relational rights) mechanisms of access Macro Federal policies Meso Entitlement mapping Land administration & use Resilience? proclamation & regulation; fishery Entitlements Resource use conditions proclamation; regional policies; & sanctions conflict resolution mechanisms Micro Customary rights; by-laws & regulations, incl. regulations on fishery; conflict resolution mechanisms

Capabilities/ well-being Trade-offs, conflicts Social actors

Figure 6.4: The multi-level institutions conditioning wetland resource subtraction. Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234

The following remarks combine the insights from the previous sections to provide a comprehensive picture of the conditions that determine an effective wetland management and sustainable resource utilisation.

6.5.2.5 Robustness and Effectiveness of Wetland Management Institutions

Rural livelihoods maintain and enhance their capabilities and well-being by har- nessing wetland resources. Institutions are essential to manage wetland utilisation and to maintain ecosystem resilience. The sustainability of the social-ecological system is thus dependent on the robustness and effectiveness of established rules and regulations, their congruence with local conditions, their interaction with the ecosystem and their fit with the resilience of wetlands (Agrawal 2001: 1659; Folke 2006: 262; Ostrom 2009 a: 421). 104 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

The current institutional wetland management systems evolved just recently as a response to multi-level policies, socio-economic and related ecological processes and changes. Local communities can be seen as being in the process of developing adapted institutions which may be contested, tested and transformed over time (see Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 639). Yet, their management systems must be considered less robust and only partially effective in sustainably utilising and conserving wetlands. In most study sites, including Wagetera and Nabega and partly Tanametsele and Tez Amba, wetlands are poorly managed. The large size of the main wetland spanning four kebeles (figure 2.3, p. 14) and the high efforts that need to be undertaken for its management are probable explanations for this. The (seasonal) inaccessibility of administration offices, churches, services and organisations due to flooding, large distances or the remoteness of villages increase transaction costs of collective action. Deficiencies of stakeholder participation narrow the collective choice arrangements to arrangements made by elites and thus possibly make regulations and benefit allocations unacceptable. Inadequate information and knowledge of wetland management and conservation obstruct the evolution of a common understanding of wetland-related issues and contribute to wetland degradation. Management regulations through which proprietorship is established are restricted to mostly non-graduated sanctions against illegal access to wetlands without considering the specific characteristics of biological and physical resources. Mutual monitoring is not necessarily per se ineffective. Yet power relations may distort the mutuality. In Gulash village, wetlands are monitored by trustworthy and independent persons. Moderate sanctions are imposed on delinquents. Since the kebele admin- istration office of Wagetera is just nearby, transaction costs for village residents are presumably low. Wetlands of good management and better conservation status are those in Agid Kirigna and Tana Kirkos. They are much smaller in size. The monks, exercising the rights of proprietors over the wetland, are a relatively homogeneous group with common ideas on wetland use and management. In Agid Kirigna, intra- community differences (as in most study sites) exist, but also inter-community heterogeneity, i. e. between the Woito tribe and the other communities. According 6.5. INSTITUTIONS SHAPING WETLAND USE AND MANAGEMENT 105 to personal information, a total of 69 families of the Woito are supposed to live in one village and one sub-kebele (personal communication: Sibhat). Their presence might influence the degree of pressure on the wetland since they are rarely engaged in agricultural activities and livestock rearing. The office of the kebele administration is located around the centre of Agid Kirigna, in the vicinity of the villages with shares of wetland. A joint agreement on wetland management was reached through discussion. Ostrom (2003, 2009 b) stresses the importance of communication to develop effective management rules and to build assurance of wetland users about the behaviour of other users. The institutional setting considers biological and physical resource properties, different use regimes and alternatives to compensate for the use of wetland resources. A monitoring system is established. The management of mobile resources is often complicated and requires information that is mostly difficult to obtain (e. g. pregnancy of female fishes, regeneration rates; see p. 96). In most cases, fisheries are not organised and fishermen are the authorised users of a resource withdrawn by all. Livelihood insecurity due to flooding that requires seasonally and temporally limited rapid action, unemployment and lack of land has recently led to both commercial and non-commercial fishery. Potentially, more time and dedication are required to establish effective management systems. The two fishermen’s associations established in Tez Amba and Agid Kirigna share the rights of authorised claimants. The established collective choice ar- rangements, incorporating aspects of a sustainable fish resource utilisation on the basis of fish resource attributes, and monitoring systems are promising. So far, the exclusion of fishermen is unfeasible which, despite regulations, still entails overexploitation. The effectiveness of institutions is further eroded by inequities in the allocation of benefits and costs and a high tolerance of breaking rules due to the absence or the relative low severity of sanctions. Ethnic differences are a challenge to fish resource management in Agid Kirigna. Bundles of property rights play a key role in the management and use of wetlands. Ostrom (2003, 2009) points out that proprietorship, i. e. exercising collective-choice rights of management and exclusion, can be effective enough to manage common-property resources (see table 6.1, p. 86). Yet, communal 106 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS proprietorship to wetlands is often questioned, lacks recognition and endorsement by local community members as well as government bodies. Frequently, the establishment of rights of proprietors or even authorised claimants is impaired by prevailing contextual conditions, characteristics of the resource system and its users. Power relations (see p. 86) shape communal property rights in two ways: First, power and resistance to power can be exercised to actively counteract rules of access and management. Second, wielding of power and resistance can ensure claims to bundles of rights (right to manage or exclude) for one or more user groups. The incapability of institutions to “structure the interactions that take place around [wetland] resources” (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 637) ensues from failure to consider the design principles in making institutional arrangements. Common- property resource dilemmas probably persist and depletion continues. Institutional effectiveness depends upon the involvement and consideration of all relevant stakeholders, including landless, poor or Woito people whose interests and needs are currently mainly underrepresented. In many cases of encroachment and boundary disputes the “solution was leaving things for later” (Deininger et al. 2007: 23), rendering institutional settings ineffective. Ineffectiveness of institutions results from a lack of assurance that participants comply with the rules and that sanctions are consistently enforced. Though rules are compiled in a relatively simple way and appear to be comprehensible to many users, their enforcement proves rather difficult. Further on, external authorities who fail to monitor and enforce the implementation of regulations (e. g. on land administration and use or fisheries) insufficiently support and complement local management systems. Being nested in larger units, local institutions must consider conditions per- taining to wetland resource use and management, prescribed by federal policies, to work effectively (Ostrom et al. 1999: 281). In some cases, government plans for land development (e. g. cash crop cultivation) conflict with the interests of local communities in using common-pool resources more sustainably (cf. Abbot et al. 2000: 23). Overlapping management responsibilities of government bodies, emanating from various policies (see p. 16), are quite counterproductive to an effective local management. By claiming their mandates, external authorities allocate different rights to the same resource and shape the face of wetlands 6.6. SUMMARY 107 through different utilisation concepts, development and management approaches. Besides, sectoral top-down policy formulation and implementation with “a narrow technocratic perspective” (Abbot et al. 2000: 20) impede local initiatives for a more appropriate wetland management (ibid.: 20–21). Figure 6.5, p. 107 and figure 6.6, p. 108 summarise the structural and relational conditions that facilitate and constrain an effective wetland management.

Attributes of wetlands & associated resources Attributes of wetland users

– Small size of the wetland (Agid Kirigna, Tana – Small-sized and homogeneous wetland Kirkos) user group in Tana Kirkos – Less dependence of the Woito people on the cultivation of wetlands in Agid Kirigna

Structural attributes (external environment) Institutional arrangements

– External bodies create awareness and – Communication and discussions on wetland complement local knowledge on wetlands management – Rules and regulations appear to be easily understandable – Consideration of wetland resource properties – Alternative solutions to wetland use are provided – Mutual monitoring of user behaviour and selection of guards to oversee resource appropriation

Figure 6.5: Conditions facilitating an effective wetland management. Arrows indicate the interactions between the different management variables. Source: own compilation

6.6 Summary

Wetland resources and services contribute to the maintenance and enhancement of people’s capabilities and well-being. Access to these resources and services determines whether resources can become endowments. Whereas legal and illegal mechanisms of access are applied by all people, richer mainly draw on capital, knowledge or authority and poorer on social identity (structural and relational mechanisms) to gain, maintain or control access. The conditions for resource subtraction (e. g. harvesting time, amount, method, 108 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS

Attributes of wetlands & associated resources Attributes of wetland users

– Large size of the wetland (esp. Wagetera and – Large size of wetland user groups Nabega) (often undefined boundary, non-exclusion) – Fuzzy and changing wetland boundaries – Intra- and inter-community heterogeneity – Initial high production value of wetlands – Inaccurate information and incomplete – Fish resource mobility & low degrees of storage knowledge about the resource system – Lack of trust and assurance – Livelihood dependence on resource system – Lack of confidence in own powers – Unequal power distribution and implicit resistance – Unpredictability of social-ecological system Structural attributes (external environment) dynamics and risk – Increasing pressure on common-pool resources (demographic growth, unemployment) – Large government units (kebele size) Institutional arrangements – Economic incentives – Inequities in the allocation of benefits and – Failure of exteral authorities to monitor costs of wetland management user behaviour and the implementation of – Lack of participation in collective choice regulations arrangements – Local management systems lack legal – Inconsistently enforced and implemented rules recognition by government authorities – Lack of graduated sanctions – Ill-defined property rights and regimes – Increased efforts and costs in solving – Lack of land registration and missing land communal conflicts, lack of effective resolution use planning mechanisms – Overlapping management responsibilities – Problematic interactions between nested – Sectoral top-down policy-making systems (e.g. different resoure use priorities, – Flooding gap between knowledge systems)

Figure 6.6: Conditions constraining an effective wetland management. Arrows indicate the interactions between the different management variables. Source: own compilation prescribed practices) regulate whether and how endowments can be transformed into entitlements. These resource use conditions and likewise the access to wetlands is mediated by various customary, statutory and conventional rights and regulations. The plurality of and the inconsistency between these rights often raise questions about their legitimacy and consequently about the legitimacy of wetland management attempts. Power relations within and between communities, manifested in corruption, resistance, advocacy etc., influence endowment and entitlement mapping, and in so doing structure most of the efforts undertaken to manage wetland resources. A complex of interlinked internal and external factors affects the ability of local resource management systems to conserve wetlands (figure 6.5, p. 107; figure 6.6, p. 108). Internal factors comprise the characteristics of the resource system, the 6.6. SUMMARY 109 user group and the institutional arrangements. Contextual external factors include the higher-level institutions that interact with the resource system and local management institutions (figure 6.7, p. 109). The size of the resource system and wetland users is often not manageable and boundaries are fuzzy. The management is made more complicated by the heterogeneity of social actors and unequally distributed powers, benefits and costs of wetland management. Many of the design principles that most likely determine the success of institutions to conserve wetland resources are not sufficiently considered or cannot be implemented adequately. Grey areas of the property rights system which are reflected in failures to register wetlands and ill-defined management responsibilities render wetland management ineffective. Further on, economic incentives for the conversion of wetlands and external shocks often constrain a functioning wetland management. These findings are discussed in the following chapter.

Social status, political Macro Context Wetland (demographic growth, office, mandates, cultural Constitution; federal policies governance structure resources & identity, organisations, Meso & unit, economic services resistance, corruption… Land administration & use incentives, ecological proclamation & regulation; regional system dynamics, policies; conflict resolution mechanisms risk, uncertainty…) Endowment mapping Micro Endowments Legal, illegal, Customary rights; by-laws & regulations; (capital & property structural & relational conflict resolution mechanisms rights) mechanisms of access Macro Federal policies Entitlement mapping Meso Resilience? Land administration & use Entitlements Resource use conditions proclamation & regulation; fishery & sanctions proclamation; regional policies; conflict resolution mechanisms

Micro Customary rights; by-laws & Capabilities/ regulations, incl. regulations on fishery; conflict resolution mechanisms well-being Trade-offs, conflicts Social actors

Figure 6.7: Environmental entitlements analysis: Institutions mediating access to wetlands, conditioning resource subtraction, and institutional interactions. Source: modified after Leach et al. 1999: 234 110 CHAPTER 6. ANALYSIS Chapter 7

Discussion

This section seeks to provide recommendations and raise objections regarding a sustainable wetland management, and the establishment and functioning of the CBINReMP and Lake Tana biosphere reserve (BR)1, particularly. In this regard, the institutional framework for the conservation of wetlands as well as governance features and conditions facilitating the effective and sound management of common-pool resources are discussed. Concluding remarks on social-ecological resilience are made.

7.1 The Institutional Framework for the Conservation of Wetlands

Zur Heide (2012) states that “the general policy framework in the Amhara Region is conducive to the establishment of a biosphere reserve” (p. 119). Scaling up to wetlands as a landscape section of the BR, it is debatable whether institutional conditions enable the conservation of wetland ecosystems.

1See Appendix 8, p. XXIX for a description of the concept of BRs.

111 112 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.1.1 A National Wetland Policy?

There has been controversy about the adequate representation and consideration of wetlands in existing policy documents (Abbot et al. 2000; Fisseha 2003; Mesfin 2003; Wood 2000). Whereas Mesfin (2003) argues that wetlands are sufficiently represented in national policies and legislation (see p. 69), and that only synergies between those have to be better exploited, Fisseha (2003) calls for a National Wetland Policy. With their technical approach and sectoral thinking, the existing policies fail to adequately consider the role of wetlands for biodiversity conservation and people’s livelihoods. Thus, a rather holistic understanding of wetlands is required that emphasises the multiple functions of and benefits obtained from wetlands (Abbot et al. 2000: 20; Fisseha 2003: 79; Wood 2000: 10) or that even acknowledges their intrinsic value (Wood 2000: 10). It can be assumed and hoped that the as yet unratified Ethiopian National Wetland Policy comprises such a holistic approach. A National Wetland Policy as an overarching document should provide objec- tives, guidelines and orientation for management and conservation. In the case of Uganda, the Wetland Policy is not a legally binding document but wetland clauses are incorporated into legislation (Bakema & Mafabi 2003: 104). Fisseha (2003) proposes integrating the Ethiopian Wetland Policy into the land admin- istration and use proclamation and regulation. Likewise, other legislation such as the Environmental Policy, the National Biodiversity Strategy and Action Plan or the Water Resource Management Policy as well as development plans could be amended by clauses specifically related to wetlands. In this way it could be ensured that wetlands are concordantly represented within different policy sectors. At the regional level, provisions and goals need to be specified. Mesfin (2003) suggests the formulation of regional wetland policies to better address the specific local conditions and problems (see also Abbot 2000: 21; Wood 2000: 8). As part of the CBINReMP2 a policy document for Amhara is planned including strategies

2The CBINReMP is financed and technically supported by the International Fund for Agricul- tural Development (IFAD), the Global Environment Facility (GEF) and the Spanish International Development Cooperation Agency (AECID) (see BoARD 2011 a: 7). The programme includes the establishment of wetland user associations as well as local by-laws and management plans for single wetlands. It also envisages trainings and wetland policy awareness creation workshops, the provision of alternative diversified livelihood options and the integration of traditional knowl- 7.1. THE INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK 113 and regulations on wetland use and management (personal communication: BDU). At the woreda and local level, wetland management strategies have to be drafted in accordance to the social-ecological conditions and requirements together with all identified stakeholders and community representatives. Already existing management institutions need to be integrated. National and regional wetland policies have to be flexible and have to relinquish responsibility to allow local management systems to adequately adapt their management criteria to the peculiarities of the environment as well as to appropriately respond to changes and uncertainties. This research study and insights from wetland management in the Illubabor zone show that local people are capable of self-organising and adjusting to changes (see Abbot et al. 2000: 21). Hence, flexibility and learning from variation should not be undermined by another rigid or rigidly interpreted top-down policy.

7.1.2 Signing the Ramsar Convention?

For several years there have been cooperative efforts that have targeted the signing of the Ramsar Convention by Ethiopia (e. g. Abebe 2004; MoWE 2010: 3-17; zur Heide 2012). This convention urges its contracting parties to develop national wetland policies to better address the utilisation and management of wetlands (Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 a: 7). After the ratification of Ethiopia’s National Wetland Policy, a joining of the Ramsar Convention is envisaged (personal communication: EWNRA). Wetlands south and east of Lake Tana, including the Fogera plains, that fulfil the Ramsar selection criteria for wetland sites have already been identified (Abebe 2004). Signing the Ramsar Convention could possibly increase the success of wetland conservation (see zur Heide 2012: 121). Besides, the zonation concept for Ramsar sites is compatible with the zonation concept of BRs (Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 b: 30–31). Returning to the national level, the next section discusses property rights issues of wetlands. edge. Financial constraints hamper the programme’s implementation (personal communication: BDU). 114 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.1.3 Property Rights to Wetlands – A Critical Issue

Property Rights to common-pool resources are a critical issue. Failures to address them comprehensively will render any conservation effort ineffective. A with- drawal of the property rights of local people may give rise to severe community resentments and resistance, e. g. if recession farming and wetland cultivation are prohibited for conservation purposes (cf. zur Heide 2012: 136). On the other hand, the conservation of wetland resources may be bound to management and exclusion rights exercised by local people. Where the government does not recog- nise these rights, the protection of wetlands cannot be guaranteed. Discrepancies between customary and statutory regulations on access to and management of wetlands (and recession farmlands) as well as between local and government interests on wetland use have to be resolved. In this way conflicts arising during the establishment of conservation projects and resistance to conservation can be averted. Gebrekidan (2009 b) argues that the state ownership of wetlands and the use rights of local people provide an “ideal case” (p. 49) for the establishment of protected areas. But the mere right to withdraw resources from the lake and its as- sociated wetlands is not sufficient and does not encourage users to self-organise for community-based management, but rather stimulates continuous overexploitation and keeps wetlands exposed to open access. Consequently, communal propri- etorship of wetlands (and of defined boundaries of fishing grounds3) has to be more explicitly legally recognised and approved. Case studies on common-property management in the highlands of Ethiopia show that communal proprietorship of pastures has effectively been established under state ownership. These manage- ment systems have been legally recognised and characterised by most of Ostrom’s design principles (see Adenew & Abdi 2005: 18–20; Ashenafi & Leader-Williams 2005). But there have been more forceful voices calling for an alternative to state ownership or the privatisation of land (see p. 17). Rahmato (1994, 2004 in Crewett & Korf 2008: 206) and Pausewang (undated), for example, stress the importance

3Defining fishing zones and exclusion of non-registered fishermen within these zones are probably very ambitious and difficult tasks. 7.1. THE INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK 115 of associative collective ownership rights of communities as a third way. Granting of community ownership rights involves the transfer of control over land use and management to the community. This is supposed to establish democracy at the local level and to have a positive effect on resource conservation and livelihood security. Though the third alternative looks very attractive in terms of biodiversity and resource conservation, it is actually not viable. Instead, a combination of property regimes may be very convenient to wetland conservation (Berkes et al. 1989: 93). The UNESCO (1996) acknowledges a broad spectrum of property regimes within a BR. This is very suitable for the wetlands east of Lake Tana which are held under several property regimes constituted of varying bundles of rights. Proclamation No. 133/2006 grants landholding rights to groups (common holding, §2(10)) and communities (communal holding, §2(5)). Drawing on these rights is crucial to the establishment of common or communal proprietorship. A combination of property regimes could lead to common-pool resource co-management systems, provided that powers between government bodies and local communities are shared, property rights of various social actors are non-ambiguously assigned and responsibilities clarified to avert further resource mismanagement. Which further conditions does the existing land administration and use legis- lation provide to enable a sound and effective wetland management?

7.1.4 Land Administration and Conservation

With the decentralisation of land administration local people have gained power in an area which affects their livelihoods most: land and resources (Miller & Tolina 2008: 372). Regulation No. 51/2007 provides enabling conditions for the involvement of the public in communal resource management, for the application of local conflict resolution measures and customary rules. Currently, more emphasis needs to be put on public participation and horizontal decision-making in the administration of communal lands. An “ownership mentality” (Regulation No. 51/2007, preamble) of farmers regarding their landholding has been partly created by land titling. Still, communal lands have to be registered in order to reduce conflicts. Certificates need to be 116 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION upgraded and safely kept with the LAC. Interestingly, Crewett & Korf (2008) in their study on land administration in Oromia and Adenew & Abdi (2005) in their report on land registration in Amhara found that lack of tenure security is not the major concern, at least for those peasants possessing land. Land scarcity and poverty are probably the more important constraints to people’s livelihoods and a sustainable natural resource management. The regulation stipulates land use obligations. If properly implemented and enforced, these obligations represent a good starting point for sustainable wetland management. But being kept very general, they need to be specified through by- laws and locally appropriate wetland management plans. Rights and obligations of wetland users and seasonally changing wetland utilisation could be indicated in the certificate issued for communal landholdings (see Regulation No. 51/2007: §21). In so doing local institutional settings could be legally approved and recognised by the woreda authority. Whereas conservationists are familiar with the definition and classification of wetlands (see supra note 1, p. 11), the land administration staff faces difficulties in identifying wetlands. Therefore, it is a challenge to register or explicitly not register wetlands. Wetlands are most often simply subsumed under communal lands but should possibly be considered a specific sub-division due to their distinct ecological characteristics. This could contribute to a more adequate protection of the resource system. A guideline for the delineation of wetlands is required, including practical definitions and easily recognisable dry and rainy season wetland indicators in the field4. When registering wetlands, the survey and land administration teams need to be accompanied by an environmental protection expert. Registration should possibly be undertaken twice, during both the dry and the rainy season, to avoid boundary conflicts. The legislation considers integrating environmental protection into land use practices. Though generally welcome, the mixing of environmental issues and land administration has been criticised (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12; Miller & Tolina 2008: 372). Land administration should rather focus strictly on land registration and certification (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12). At regional and woreda levels, EPLAUA

4Indicators can be identified drawing on local knowledge about wetland plant species (see Dixon & Wood 2001: 8). 7.1. THE INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK 117 and WoEPLAU are sectioned into the department of environmental protection, the department of land administration and the department of land use. The mandates of these sections need to be clarified and cooperation enhanced to ensure the protection of resources and biodiversity. In terms of the conservation of (wetland-dependant) biodiversity, the role of the environmental protection department in assessing environmental impacts, evaluating land use practices and co-deciding on land use planning needs to be strengthened. The next two sections address the importance of land use planning and environmental impact assessments for wetland conservation.

7.1.5 Land Use Planning and Conservation

Rural land should be managed according to a land use plan. The Environmental Policy states that a strategic land use plan should “define broad land use and land user categories together with generalised resource management recommendations” (EPA/MoEDC 1997: 20) at the federal, regional and community level. Based on these plans, individuals and communities will be able to formulate detailed local resource use and management plans. Besides, strategic land use plans should integrate aspects of biodiversity conservation (ibid.: 10, 20). Plans and strategies are required to effectively manage a BR. The UNESCO (1996) underlines that BRs are to be included in regional development and land use planning projects. Community level land use planning approaches are flexible and allow for adequate considerations of and adaptations to local social- ecological conditions (Abbot et al. 2000: 22, 26). Further land distributions should be undertaken in compliance with land use and management plans. Land use planning is an important instrument to avoid mismanagement and to conserve wetlands. It possibly results in a reduction of conflicts over wetlands and therefore positively contributes to a resilient community-based management. However, land use plans have yet to be prepared urgently.

7.1.6 Environmental Impact Assessment

Sectoral policy approaches often fail to integrate aspects of wetland conservation. Policies pertaining to wetland management and development projects thus need 118 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION to be reviewed and their impact on wetland use and management evaluated (e. g. Fisseha 2003: 79; Tekaligne 2003: 90; see also Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 a). The Environmental Policy conceives environmental impact assessments (EIAs) holistically by addressing biological and physical as well as social, economic, political and cultural conditions (EPA/MoEDC 1997: 23). Proclamation No. 299/2002 provides an instrument to assess environmental impacts involving public consultations (§15). An EIA is a suitable mechanism to identify incompatibilities between conservation, sustainable resource appropriation and projects or policies at different levels. It may be very useful to effectively incorporate the conservation, development and logistic support functions of a biosphere reserve (see p. XXVIII) in the context of change and ongoing development. Furthermore, Wood (2003) suggests undertaking community-level EIAs to identify the impact of various wetland management options on the social-ecological system, taking into account the heterogeneity of social actors. Figure 7.1, p. 118 illustrates the aspects of the discussion on the institutional framework for the conservation of wetlands.

Ramsar Convention, CBD

Macro National Wetland Policy Land administration & Meso use legislation Regional wetland policy Micro Enabling conditions: Local wetland management – Public participation in communal strategies & plans resource management WETLAND – Application of local conflict resolution mechanisms & customary rules Incorporate policy – Land use obligations expanded by clauses of local by-laws and management plans – Registration & certification of wetlands, Multi-sectoral policies considering seasonality of wetland use

Clarify: (Community-level) – Property rights and regimes environmental impact Provide: – Guideline for the registration of assessments wetlands – Land use plans

Figure 7.1: The institutional framework for the conservation of wetlands. Source: own compilation 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 119

7.2 Governance of Wetlands

The sustainable management of wetlands requires a governance system that is adaptive, flexible and multi-level. This section lists and discusses some of the features of adaptive, multi-level governance (see Armitage 2008) and the conditions that enable successful common-property resource management (see Agrawal 2001; Ostrom 2009 a) and reverts to the design principles of robust management institutions (see Ostrom 2009 b) with regard to the establishment and functioning of the CBINReMP and Lake Tana BR.

7.2.1 The Role of Social Actors in Wetland Management

The establishment and functioning of the CBINReMP and BR requires networking across scales, ranging from international to local, and the cooperation of very different stakeholders (UNESCO, 1996, 2008). Zur Heide (2012) has already identified relevant stakeholders and their potential participation in and contribution to the Lake Tana BR. This section adds to the list of local stakeholders5 which have to be involved in wetland management and whose management roles need to be explored.

7.2.1.1 Kebele Administration and Elders

Since kebele leaders perform official duties and are often in a privileged position, they play an important role for networking actors across scales, e. g. local users with woreda and regional administrations or organisations. By following the formal procedures, external instances and organisations often contact local leaders first to grant permission for their projects. Leaders are in the position to express views, create awareness, propagate ideas and deliver useful input to matters of communal interest. Elders are respected people and, just like the kebele administration, involved in local settling of conflicts.

5Since gender issues were not included in the research, the role of women in community-based management is not mentioned specifically. But refer to Sibhat (2012). 120 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.2.1.2 Kebele Land Administration and Use Committee

At the local level, LACs are the highest legal decision-making instances concern- ing land administration and resource appropriation. Thus decisions on wetland conservation are taken at this hierarchical level (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 64). The influence of kebele and sub-kebele LACs on wetland management and resource utilisation is high. Consequently, these administrative bodies need to be involved in the establishment of a BR and the CBINReMP.

7.2.1.3 Development Agents

Four development agents (DAs) are assigned to every kebele by the woreda Agricultural and Rural Development office with responsibilities for crop production, livestock production, natural resource management and home economics (Abbot et al. 2000: 16; MoARD 2010: 8). They are the link between woreda authorities and local communities as well as ex-officio members of the kebele administrative committee. Being responsible for the implementation of agricultural policies, DAs communicate higher-level objectives down to the farmers (Abbot et al. 2000: 16, 19). In Illubabor zone, woreda experts who were granted responsibilities for wetlands have been trained in wetland management by the staff of the Ethiopian Wetlands Research Programme (EWRP). Information and extension materials on wetland management have been disseminated to DAs who have used them to train farmers (Hailu & Wood 2000: 19). Annually, DAs have also recorded data on wetlands, such as size (Hailu et al. 2000: 4). DAs could therefore play a key role in the management of wetlands within the BR.

7.2.1.4 Fishermen and Fishermen’s Associations

Fishermen have been identified as the most important stakeholders for a sus- tainable management and utilisation of fish resources (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 66; Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 53). With the formulation of regulations and local by-laws, fishermen’s associations in Tez Amba and Agid Kirigna showed ac- countability for a joint management. This is a good basis for further conservation action. 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 121

Woito Tribe Though being a rather under-represented group, the Woito could have a strong stake in the conservation of fish stocks. The Woito, traditionally tied to the lake and its fish resources, have acquired knowledge and fishing skills that need to be considered and possibly integrated into management and monitoring plans.

7.2.1.5 Poor and Landless

Very often unheeded, the interests of poor and landless should not be ignored though they might often conflict with conservation interests. Instead, increased attention has to be paid to the issues of more constrained groups. Youth associations are important stakeholders in so far as they advocate the interests of landless youth and assert claims to the utilisation of wetlands.

7.2.1.6 Community-Based Organisations

Local organisations are described to be the foundation for local development, for the enactment of institutions for wetland management, and controlling natural resource use (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 70). Conservationists should refer to the community-based institutional organisations found in the research area with an open mind and from a critical perspective. Conservation initiatives should draw on existing organisational structures by involving arbitrators for conflict settling, as well as wetland monitors. Both of these are selected using commonly shared and approved criteria. Persons have to be identified that are perceived to be neutral, unbiased, morally good and just. Their role as mediators and facilitators in the establishment of wetland management institutions needs to be strengthened.

7.2.1.7 Religious Leaders

Zur Heide (2012) and IFAD/EPLAUA (2007 b) underline the importance of respected and influential religious leaders for community-based resource man- agement. Churches offer a public arena for discussions and open expressions of concerns. 122 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.2.2 Drawing on Conditions Facilitating the Governance of Wetlands

The capability of local communities to respond to and self-organise in the face of changes depends upon the characteristics of the resource system, the communities themselves and external contextual factors. Taking into account the abilities of some local groups to self-organise, to develop rules and to adapt in the context of change, it can be assumed that established institutions can have a considerable potential to contribute to a resilient social-ecological system. These abilities can have important implications for the development and successful functioning of the CBINReMP and the BR. Conservationists can build on positive examples of wetland and fishery resource management in the region. In addition, local people who ascribe meaning and values to wetland resources in terms of livelihood security are motivated to preserve the resource base. Their strong ties to customary mechanisms and procedures provide a good basis for local management and conservation efforts. Charismatic leaders and thoughtful, knowledgeable persons could facilitate collective action as well as the establishment and management of a BR. They are vocal persons for two-way communication and networking.

7.2.3 Unequal Power Relations and Empowerment

Institutions are a reflection of the prevailing power relations within or between communities (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 637). Since powers are distributed un- equally, the powerless often remain under-represented. Therefore, collective choice arrangements need not necessarily be congruent with the local context and possi- bly disregard critical conditions which eventually render management ineffective. Unequal power distribution fosters implicit resistance of the more constrained groups, which can in fact weaken and undo conservation efforts (see Holmes 2007). Community-based management is all about empowerment. People sometimes lack confidence in their capabilities and the “power within” them, i. e. a kind of people’s self-understanding to shape their livelihoods. But “power within” is the precondition for the “power to” actively transform and improve lives. Collective 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 123 action, i. e. the power exercised with other actors, potentially contributes to the maintenance and enhancement of well-being ensuing from the utilisation of wetlands. Collective action thus can lead to “power over” a resource and its management (Rowlands 1997 in de Haan & Zoomers 2005: 37). Considering these layers of power is essential for the empowerment of local people to manage resources.

Power relations across and within different levels may often remain obscure in their complexity. Efforts need to be undertaken to untangle this web of power. Conservationists and political decision-makers need to respond to unequal power distributions by facilitating the empowerment of (1) the weaker and under- represented actors within communities and (2) local communities when asserting claims against government agencies and other external actors. Challenging the inequality of powers involves a willingness to share powers. Corruption which erodes empowerment and joint action has to be curtailed.

7.2.4 Building Trust and Assurance

Trust is the cornerstone for collective action, partnership and collaborative manage- ment. Groups and individuals who do not trust each other often fail to effectively communicate and develop agreements (Agrawal 2001: note 14, 1666; Armitage 2008: 17). Thus community-based management and conservation projects require trust-building. Confidence is based on people’s initial willingness to reinforce posi- tive attitudes towards each other. It further originates from reciprocity, honesty and the accountability of social actors, including project managers and conserva- tionists. Trust-building involves open discourse and deliberation about equality, equity, social issues and power distribution as well as the recognition of the value of all actors and their perspectives.

Communication builds assurance about the willingness of wetland users to contribute to the public good (Ostrom 2003: 247). Once this contribution is warranted, accountability can be increased through joint and fair agreements. 124 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.2.5 Ensuring Participation

Arriving at collective choice arrangements requires the participation or repre- sentation of all relevant stakeholders. The UNESCO (1996, 2008) calls for a participatory management approach to involve local communities in the planning and implementation of management procedures of BRs. Where participation is not promoted internally, thoughtful external mediation is necessary, bringing actors together to sit at one table. Participation should seek an active involvement of the concerned stakeholders and a “self-initiated mobilisation” (Kumar 2002: 25) of local people. It should emphasise the dialogue, the concertation of management objectives and actions as well as negotiation (zur Heide 2012: 111).

7.2.6 Collaboration and Coordination

An integration of sectoral thinking through legislation, binding commitments for cooperation and the signing of memoranda of understanding between various polit- ical levels is essential to adopting standard guidelines for the use and management of wetlands. Mandates for the management of and development interventions in wetlands need to be clearly set. An overall responsibility should possibly be assigned to EPA (Mesfin 2003: 84), EPLAUA and WoEPLAU, respectively. An integration of the local and the external broader perspective on wetland use and management could generate important synergies in terms of a successfully functioning governance of wetland resources (see table 5.3, p. 73). Appropriate mechanisms and methods (e. g. PRA, focus group discussions) have to be de- veloped to identify and consider local people’s interests and needs concerning wetland use and management, and to enhance the exchange between internal and external management systems. An equal cooperation accrues from a full recognition of local people as competent partners, as capable analysts of their own situation and as agents of change. Fabricius & Collins (2007) stress the importance of a “trialogue” (p. 94) between local communities, scientists and government to the promotion of good common-pool resource governance. The knowledge bridges between government agencies and local people built by scientists could help to overcome the existing knowledge gaps. 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 125

7.2.7 Recognising Legal Rights

Biosphere reserve vocal persons, project initiators and environmentalists need to focus on and promote the legal recognition of local people’s rights to self-organise. The legal recognition of collectively established local institutions should involve the recognition of communal proprietorship to wetlands to ensure an effective wetland management (especially within the BR buffer zone). Berkes et al. (1989) and IFAD/EPLAUA (2007 b) state that customary reg- ulations and local by-laws are often more effective to conserve common–pool resources than governmental laws. Government agencies should acknowledge the effectiveness of local regulations as well as their suitability and flexibility to adapt to local conditions and changes. Occasionally, informal institutional mechanisms reflect social actors’ interests better and thus need to be consid- ered and incorporated into cross-scale management attempts (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 76). The importance of local institutions in controlling resource harvest and management within the BR buffer zone has already been recognised by conservationists (Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 55). Licencing of fishermen’s associations and the legal organisation into fishermen’s cooperatives is believed to improve the control over illegal fishing and facilitates the implementation of regulations and by-laws on fish resource conservation (Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 53).

7.2.8 Establishing, Implementing and Enforcing Regulations

There are problems at various levels concerning the implementation and enforce- ment of regulations. The top-down national and regional legislation is often not properly implemented and enforced at the local level (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 77). The formulation, implementation and enforcement of policies pertaining to wetlands should therefore embrace bottom-up and top-down approaches and an evaluation of the compatibility between government and community regulations. Besides, national and regional policies with implications for the use and preser- vation of wetlands need to be clearly communicated to woreda officials, kebele 126 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION leaders and local people to avoid misunderstandings and misinterpretations. At the local level, by-laws and regulations need to be consistently implemented and enforced. To this end, prevailing unequal power relations must be denoted and more transparent and neutral decision-making structures introduced.

7.2.9 Monitoring User Behaviour and Ecological Conditions

Failures and the incapability of WoEPLAU to monitor landholders’ compliance with the land use obligations need to be addressed. In this regard, an increase in trained personnel, financial means and equipment is necessary. The more elaborated monitoring systems in Agid Kirigna and Gulash can serve as examples for an organised community-based wetland management. Their potentials regarding the management of the BR as well as the applicability and transferability of their operating principles need to be explored. In the future, more emphasis should possibly be placed on the monitoring of biological and physical wetland conditions undertaken by scientists in co- operation with local communities within the community-managed area or the buffer zone. This could support the identification of sustainability indicators for wetland management in the BR (see UNESCO 1996: 9–10). Local monitors could also safeguard the core zone or seasonal area closures from illegal resource appropriation.

7.2.10 Resolving Conflicts

Existing conflicts should be of particular concern and specifically managed. Other- wise conservation attempts may be frustrated at their initial stages. The resolution of conflicts becomes especially important when approaching the zonation of the Lake Tana BR (p. 130). Adenew & Abdi (2005) recommend a clear guideline for dispute resolution. Such a guideline could help to prevent and resolve conflicts over access to and use of wetland resources. Given that local resolution mechanisms are often ineffective, adequate (external) support needs to be provided. Capacity building of local mediators and arbitrators could nip emergent conflicts in the 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 127 bud and improve the effectiveness of dispute resolution (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 27; Fabricius & Collins: 2007: 93). Besides, accurate information and provision of legal documents and additional materials to arbitrators could help to adjudicate on conflicts on a legal and transparent basis. Conflicting interests between various sectors are to be addressed by enhancing cooperation to harmonise objectives and strategies as well as by reducing overlaps in jurisdiction.

7.2.11 Integrating Knowledge Pluralism and Ensuring Information Exchange

Wetland management profits from innovation and dissemination of wetland knowledge (Dixon & Wood 2001: 10–11). Knowledge that is collectively and mutually developed and shared encourages an iterative learning process (Armitage 2008: 17) and therefore a management that is flexible and adaptive. Multi-level governance of wetlands thus requires an integration of formal science and local or traditional knowledge. Mechanisms to better communicate acquired knowledge and to reach many people need to be developed (see p. 74 in table 5.3, p. 73). The UNESCO (1996) explicitly calls for on-site trainings and seminars for local people and other stakeholders to allow for full participation in the planning, management and monitoring of the processes that take place within the BR. Workshops and trainings with mixed or individual wetland user groups could be undertaken on-site to enhance understanding and raise awareness of the human-wetland interdependence, to analyse different resource use regimes and to combine different knowledge systems. In the Illubabor zone, three methods of information exchange on wetland management have been proven suitable by the staff of EWRP: First, PRA methods have been applied, empowering local people to critically analyse their situation and develop solutions to their wetland management problems. Information flow has been three-directional: from farmers-to-farmers, from farmers to scientists and from scientists to farmers. Second, farmer to farmer facilitated demonstrations of sustainable wetland management have promoted the sharing of knowledge, the 128 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION exchange of information on project findings, the demonstration of appropriate management techniques and the adoption of management recommendations. Thirdly, the training-of-trainers method has enabled officials and experts to better understand the ecology of wetlands, to identify proper use and management practices and to prepare (draft) management plans (Hailu & Wood 2000: 14–17). The training-of-trainers method has already been applied in the woredas under investigation (personal communication: Sibhat). But it could be extended, even to the regional governance level, thereby drawing on experiences from EWNRA and EWRP. In order to continuously promote wise wetland management, follow-up workshops and trainings need to be carried out. With the provision of adequate support, concepts for environmental education on wetlands for local school children, interested persons and other actors could be created. Wetland days, excursions or workshops (on medicinal and useful plants, birds etc.) could be accomplished by knowledgeable local people (see UNESCO 1996: 10).

7.2.12 Understanding Heterogeneity

Understanding “patterns of difference within communities [and] that actors within communities seek their own interests in conservation programmes” (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 637) is demanding but immensely important and can decide over the functioning of community-based management plans. Differences between communities or ethnic groups determine the likelihood of collective action and the establishment of effective institutions. However, the “concept of community as shared norms and common interests” (Agrawal & Gibson 1999: 635) is still present in the relevant literature (see IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 51)6. In the case of Agid Kirigna, rather than integrating the Woito people in collective fishery management, disintegration may be the more satisfactory solution. The self-determination of the Woito fishermen and the confidence in their powers

6IFAD/EPLAUA (2007 b) define their concept of community as follows: “[A] community [. . . ] has common interests and pays unreserved efforts mutually to meet [its] communal needs (p. 51).” Compared with the interests of other stakeholders, e. g. government bodies or conservationists, a community may appear as a homogeneous entity. At the intra-community level, communities are rather heterogeneous (Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 c: 6). 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 129 could be enhanced by establishing an autonomous association. Collaboration, negotiation and agreements about management between the Woito’s and the community’s associations would still remain indispensable and fishery activities would need to be coordinated. As can be seen here, wetland management requires approaches that take account of the specific socio-cultural context.

7.2.13 Large or Small?

There is no straightforward answer whether a larger or smaller group of wetland users is more conducive to successful collective action. The relationship between group size and collective action likely depends upon many variables such as the degree of excludibility, the interdependence among a wetland user group or the heterogeneity of the group (Agrawal 2001: 1657–1658). Small groups that are probably more homogeneous are often considered to be more successful in natural resource management (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 71). Given the large extent of connected wetlands along the eastern lake side, a management approach integrating a nested system of wetland user groups may be the most functional, with the smallest units (village user groups or even sub-groups within villages) being embedded in ever larger units (sub-kebeles, kebeles, possibly woredas). Cross-level interactions and an efficient information system then have to be developed to ensure collaboration.

The Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2010 b) suggests dividing large wetlands into contiguous zones. Each zone is managed according to a separate management plan that complies with the overall plan. The concept of nested systems is applicable to this zoning approach. Ostrom (2009 a) proposes that a “moderate territorial size is most conducive to self-organisation” (p. 420) since large territories increase management costs and smaller ones do not produce substantial resource flows. The most appropriate size of user groups and wetland zones is likely found through trial and error and further social-ecological research. 130 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

7.2.14 Delineating Wetland Boundaries: Remarks on a Zonation Proposition

A first draft of a zonation concept for the Lake Tana BR was proposed based on the expertise of scientists and the opinions of other relevant stakeholders (zur Heide 2012: 130). This concept suggests including primary wetlands and river mouths into the core zone and secondary wetlands (i. e. seasonally flooded agricultural land and wetlands of the Fogera floodplain) into the buffer zone (figure 7.2, p. 131). River mouths must be closed during the spawning season (July to October) to allow for the reproduction of fish species (ibid.: 134–135). Declaring the primary wetland in Tana Kirkos, the Gumara and Ribb river mouths a core zone will require strenuous efforts to strictly protect these areas (see EPLAUA 2007: 60 in zur Heide 2012: 130) given the high external pressure, unsolved boundary disputes and unregulated resource access. Besides, the river mouths, being the entry to the lake, serve as an infrastructural connection. It is proposed that the whole periphery of Lake Tana, i. e. 500 m from the lake shore outwards, should be protected. “To the minimum farming practices within this [zone] must be prohibited” (zur Heide 2012: 136). Since recession farming and wetland cultivation in the lake’s periphery contribute to food security and small-holders’ well-being, resistance to conservation can be anticipated. This prohibition may further raise discussions between various stakeholders about the question of where the ‘shore’ of the lake begins. Given that resentments and resistance are likely, a deliberate and prudent proceeding by conservationists and officials is highly important. Furthermore, agricultural growth and water development projects in the region (see figure 7.2, p. 131), market developments and related land use and environmental changes increase pressure on wetland ecosystems. Multi-sectoral and cross-scale cooperation is significant to reducing adverse ecological ramifications. Likewise, alternative livelihood options which are compatible with the management objectives of the buffer zone have to be provided for local communities (see p. 132). Ideally, the registered wetland boundary matches with the outer border of the buffer zone. This would reduce confusion about different zones. Besides, communal land boundaries may be more clearly identifiable by local people (cf. 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 131

Fogera Floodplains

Figure 7.2: Zonation Proposal for a Lake Tana Biosphere Reserve. Primary wetlands and river mouths within the research area are indicated with red circles and kebeles included in the research study with black circles. Source: modified after zur Heide 2012: 133 132 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 b: 33). During registration of wetlands and demarcation of the buffer zone, the participation of local stakeholders should be sought to reduce conflicts.

7.2.15 Providing Incentives and Livelihood Opportunities

Creating incentives for continuous sustainable wetland management and con- servation is essential (Fabricius & Collins 2007: 90; UNESCO 1996: 8). This includes incentives to act in favour of an optimal collective outcome of resource appropriation rather than to maximise individual benefits. Sustainably managed and conserved, wetland ecosystems contribute to the protection of ecosystem services, locally and globally, and thus to biodiversity conservation (and hereby to the objectives of the CBD), retention of water resources or mitigation of climate change (and hereby to the objectives of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). Lasting incentives for the conservation of the wetlands east of Lake Tana could be provided through the payment for ecosystem services (see Ramsar Convention Secretariat 2010 d: 39; UNESCO 2008: 26), notably for increased carbon sequestration (see Fabricius & Collins 2007: 86–87), but also sediment and nutrient retention (Barbier et al.: 1997). Long-term attempts to register these wetlands as recognised carbon offsetting projects should also be taken into consideration. A condition is that benefits be equitably shared among local people. Furthermore, potentials for the regional or international certification of organic agriculture, fisheries or organic honey production should be explored (see IFAD 2007: 42, 45). Developing a regional certificate label for the Lake Tana BR could serve as an identification mark, support product marketing and raise the degree of public recognition. Organic produce could be sold to the tourist destination centres like Bahir Dar at the southern tip of Lake Tana or Gonder in the north (see figure 7.2, p. 131). The land administration and use legislation speaks about “granting encourag- ing reward[s]” (Regulation No. 51/2007: §38) and a “motivating prize for the landholders and users who perform exemplary activities in land conservation and environmental protection” (Proclamation No. 133/2006: 20(4)). The lack of the 7.2. GOVERNANCE OF WETLANDS 133 capacity of the respective woreda administration offices might not have permitted awarding good agricultural and best practices. It could be very encouraging for farmers to reinforce this mechanism in future.

To raise commitment of LAC members to their voluntary work and to en- sure that land registration is undertaken properly, rewards should be introduced (IFAD/EPLAUA 2007 b: 65).

The restriction or prohibition of resource utilisation within the BR needs to be compensated by developing alternative means of livelihood for local people (see UNESCO 1996: 8). Options and opportunities have to be created, addressing the various stakeholder groups individually (e. g. women, young, landless, poorer households). Generally, the diversification of livelihoods as well as the modernisa- tion and specialisation of agriculture is hoped to result in declining pressures on wetland ecosystems (see p. 73). Sound tourism along the eastern lake side (see zur Heide 2012: 88–89), combined with the marketing of traditional handicrafts and organic food production can provide lasting livelihood opportunities for local people7.

Compensation payments should at least be taken into consideration by woreda authorities and the conservation community in case wetland protection requires the expropriation of farmland (see Proclamation No. 455/2005). This of course may involve controversies about the legitimacy of customary laws on access to wetlands and recession farmlands.

Figure 7.3, p. 134 provides an overview of the important features and enabling conditions of an effective common-pool resource management. Though listed separately, the features and conditions are mutually dependent.

The last section of this chapter makes concluding remarks on the resilience of human-wetland systems.

7Tourism is already an important sector in Amhara. Most of the tourist destinations are cultural attractions. Wetlands are identified as potential natural tourists attractions (zur Heide 2012: 88–89). Through an integration of natural sites, local communities could benefit from the existing tourism. 134 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

Clear guideline for Manageable wetland and conflict resolution user group size Integrate all relevant stakeholders Explore the applicability of in management existing monitoring systems to BR management Take account of the interests of the more constrained groups Cooperative monitoring of BR zones and outcomes of Consider group heterogeneity the CBINReMP Community- based wetland & Ensure local participation Provide incentives & buffer zone livelihood opportunities management Empowerment Untangle the web of powers Merge sectoral thinking Willingness to share power Recognise & enhance the abilities of local people to self-organise Building trust and assurance Vertical & horizontal Networking across scales information exchange Combine local and external perspectives and knowledge of wetland management

Figure 7.3: Features of adaptive, multi-level governance, conditions enabling a successful common-property resource management and recommendations that should be considered when establishing the BR and the CBINReMP. Source: own compilation

7.3 Alteration of Wetlands – Risk or Chance for Rural Livelihoods?

Resource overuse and continuous degradation have often curtailed the abilities of wetlands to absorb disturbances and to retain their structure and functions. This has entailed severe implications for biodiversity (see Appendix 6, p. XXIV) and human livelihoods. Degraded wetlands are no longer capable of providing ecosystem services. On the other hand, these services are instrumental to achieve well-being and to maintain and enhance the capabilities of local communities. The loss of resilience increases people’s vulnerability8 to external shocks and trends such as flooding, land scarcity or unemployment by reducing their ability

8 With Chambers (1989 in Devereux 2001: 508–509) “vulnerability [. . . ] refers to exposure to contingencies and stress, and difficulty in coping with them. Vulnerability has thus two sides: an external side of risks, shocks and stress to which an individual or household is subject; and an internal side which is defencelessness, meaning a lack of means to cope without damaging loss”. 7.3. ALTERATION OF WETLANDS – RISK OR CHANCE? 135 to cope with or adapt to these changes, shocks or stress. Vulnerability can be reduced by preserving wetlands to maintain people’s capabilities to mitigate, cope with or adapt to adverse impact. These capabilities include the cultivation of wetlands in times of risk, dry season wetland grazing, the water availability during drought years, income generation or the prevention and mitigation of flooding damage. To ensure benefits in the future, wetland resources need to be used and managed wisely. Sustainable wetland management involves an assessment of the carrying capacity of the respective wetland and an examination of the current institutional systems for their compatibility with the resource system characteristics (Abbot et al. 2000: 28–29). What has to be kept in mind is that different use regimes and approaches of conservation management may sustain the livelihoods of the different wetland users for different time periods. The question whether the alteration of wetlands poses a risk to rural livelihoods or rather enhances well-being can likewise be transformed into the question: Is the conservation of wetlands a risk to or a chance for local people? Dixon & Wood (2001) and Wood (2003) raise concerns that the conservation and designation of wetlands as protected areas result in increased food insecurity and poverty. The promotion of sustainable wetland use practices and restrictions on access to wetlands may benefit the privileged and better-off community members. Inasmuch as wetland users are unequally susceptible to changes, they might also be unequally susceptible to use restrictions and prohibitions. I. e. the heterogeneous users differ in their ability to buffer shifts in use regimes and to re-organise themselves in accordance with conservation objectives. Landless and poorer people are the most vulnerable stakeholders and less capable of a flexible response to conservation measures and use restraints. It becomes an indispensable prerequisite for any conservation attempt to re- spond to poverty, marginalisation and unequal power distribution as components of the social and political dimensions of sustainability. Inescapable questions per- taining to the equality and equity of conservation measures have to be addressed, e. g.: Who can assert which claims based on what legal and moral grounds? How to allocate benefits? How to distribute costs and risks associated with conservation? 136 CHAPTER 7. DISCUSSION

An integrated, multi-level, adaptive and flexible wetland management approach can help answering these questions and pave the road to successful wetland management. If the CBINReMP and the Lake Tana BR embrace such an approach, they can become a chance for the local people whose livelihoods depend upon wetland resources. References

Abebe, Y. D. (2004): Potential Ramsar Sites of Ethiopia. A pa- per presented at the National Stakeholder Consultative Work- shop on Ramsar Convention. http://www.scribd.com/doc/48793598/ Potential-Ramsar-Sites-of-Ethiopia-Paper [4th December 2012]

Abbot, P.; Hailu, A.; Wood, A. P. (2000): Sustainable Wetland Management in Illubabor Zone, South-west Ethiopia. Report 2 for Objective 3 (Report 6 of 9). Community Organisation for Natural Resource Management: the Potential for Community-based Wetlands Management and Planning. EWRP, Project B7-6200/96-05/VIII/ENV

Abunie, L. (2003): The distribution and status of Ethiopian wetlands: an overview. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 12–17

Adenew, B.; Abdi, F. (2005): Research Report 3: Land Registration in Amhara Region, Ethiopia. Nottingham: Russell Press

Agrawal, A. (2001): Common Property Institutions and Sustainable Governance of Resources, World Development (vol. 29, no. 10), 1649–1672

Agrawal, A.; Gibson, C.C. (1999): Enchantment and Disenchantment: The Role of Community in Natural Resource Conservation, World Development (vol. 27, no. 4), 629–649

Amsalu, T. (2006): Current Land Management in Lake Tana watersheds: Future challenges and opportunities for Sustainable Land Management. In: Hailu,

137 138 REFERENCES

Z.; Gebrekidan, W. (eds.), Proceedings of the National Consultative and Promotional Workshop on: Lake Tana and its Environs: Conservation, Utilization, Development and Threats. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar, 14–23

Armitage, D. (2008): Governance of the commons in a multi-level world, Inter- national Journal of the Commons (vol. 2, no. 1), 7–32

Ashenafi, Z. T.; Leader-Williams, N. (2005): Indigenous Common Property Resource Management in the Central Highlands of Ethiopia, Human Ecology (vol. 33, no. 4), 539–563

Ayalew, D.; Tesfaye, K.; Mamo, G.; Yitaferu, B.; Bayu, W. (2012): Variability of rainfall and its current trend in Amhara region, Ethiopia, African Journal of Agricultural Research (vol. 7, no. 10), 1475–1486

Bakema, R. J.; Mafabi, P. G. (2003): Towards Sustainable Wetlands Management: The Ugandan Experience. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 97–107

Barbier, E. B.; Acreman, M.; Knowler, D. (1997): Economic valuation of wetlands: A guide for policy makers and planners. Ramsar Convention Bureau, Gland, Switzerland

Becker, C. D.; Ostrom E. (1995): Human Ecology and Resource Sustainability: The Importance of Institutional Diversity, Annual Review of Ecology and Systematics (vol. 26, no. 1), 113–133

Berkes, F.; Feeny, D.; McCay, B. J.; Acheson, J. M. (1989): The benefits of the commons, Nature (vol. 340), 91–93

BoARD (Bureau of Agricultural and Rural Development) (2011 a): Community- Based Integrated Natural Resources Management Project (CBINReMP). Work Plan and Budget (March 2011–June 2012)

BoARD (Bureau of Agricultural and Rural Development) (2011 b): Rice Research and Development Strategy (ANRS RRDS): Implementation Plan (2011– 2014). Bahir Dar REFERENCES 139

Bryant, R. L. (1991): Putting politics first: the political ecology of sustainable development, Global Ecology and Biogeography Letters (vol. 1, no. 6), 164–166

Bryant, R. L. (1992): Political ecology: An emerging research agenda in Third- World studies, Political Geography (vol. 11, no. 1), 12–36

Bryant, R. L. (1997): Beyond the impasse: the power of political ecology in Third World environmental research, Area (vol. 29, no. 1), 5–19

Bryant, R. L. (1998): Power, knowledge and political ecology in the third world: a review, Progress in Physical Geography (vol. 22, no. 1), 79–94

Chambers, R. (1994 a): Participatory Rural Appraisal (PRA): Analysis of Experi- ence, World Development (vol. 22, no. 9), 1253–1268

Chambers, R. (1994 b): The Origins and Practice of Participatory Rural Appraisal, World Development (vol. 22, no. 7), 953–969

Constitution of the Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia (1994), Addis Ababa

Convention on Wetlands of International Importance especially as Water- fowl Habitat (1971, amended 1982 and 1987). Ramsar. http://www. ramsar.org/cda/en/ramsar-documents-texts-convention-on/ main/ramsar/1-31-38%5E20671_4000_0__ [3rd December 2012]

Crewett, W.; Bogale, A.; Korf, B. (2008): Land Tenure in Ethiopia: Continuity and Change, Shifting Rulers, and the Quest for State Control, CAPRi Working Paper 91. International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC.

Crewett, W.; Korf, B. (2008): Ethiopia: Reforming Land Tenure, Review of African Political Economy (no. 116), 203–220

de Haan, L.; Zoomers, A. (2005): Exploring the Frontier of Livelihoods Research, Development and Change (vol. 16, no. 1), 27–47 140 REFERENCES

Deininger, K.; Ali, D. A.; Holden, S.; Zevenbergen, J. (2007): Rural land certification in Ethiopia: Process, initial impact, and implications for other African countries. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4218

Deininger, K.; Zevenbergen, J.; Alf, D. A. (2006): Assessing the Certification Process of Ethiopia’s rural Lands. Colloque international “Les fronti`eresde la question fonci`ere– At the frontier of land issues, Montepellier

Dejen, E. (2005): Biodiversity of Lake Tana and Threats for Sustainability. In: EWNRA: Proceedings of the Second Awareness Creation Workshop on Wetlands in the Amhara Region. 37–47

Devereux, S. (2001): Livelihood Insecurity and Social Protection: A Re-emerging Issue in Rural Development, Development Policy Review (vol. 19, no. 4), 507–519

DFID (Department for International Development) (1999 a): Sustainable Liveli- hoods Guidance Sheets: Framework

DFID (Department for International Development) (1999 b): Sustainable Liveli- hoods Guidance Sheets: Introduction

Dixon, A.; Wood, A (2001): Sustainable Wetland Management for Food Security and Rural Livelihoods in South-west Ethiopia: the interaction of local knowledge and institutions, government policies and globalisation. Paper prepared for presentation at the “Seminaire sur l’amenagement des zones marecageuses du Rwanda”, 5–8th June 2001, at the National University of Rwanda.

DSA (Development Studies Associates); SCI (Shawel Consult International) (2006): Potential Survey, Identification of Opportunities and Preparation of Project Profiles and Feasibility Studies. Part One: Potential Assessment Survey. Land Cover and Land Use Report. Bahir Dar

EPA (Environmental Protection Authority); MoEDC (Ministry of Economic Development and Cooperation) (1997): Environmental Policy. Addis Ababa REFERENCES 141

Fabricius, C. ; Collins, S. (2007): Community-based natural resource management: governing the commons, Water Policy (vol. 9, supplement 2), 83–97

Fisseha, M. (2003): Water resources policy and river basin development as related to wetlands. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 76–80

Flick, U.; von Kardorff, E.; Steinke, I. (2009): Was ist qualitative Sozialforschung? Einleitung und Uberblick.¨ In: Flick, U.; von Kardorff, E.; Steinke, I. (eds.), Qualitative Forschung. Ein Handbuch. Reinbek bei Hamburg: Rowohlt Taschebuch Verlag. 7th edition, 13–29

Folke, C. (2006): Resilience: The emergence of a perspective for social-ecological systems analyses, Global Environmental Change (vol. 16), 253–267

Friese, S. (2012): ATLAS.ti 7 User Manual. Berlin. http://www.atlasti.com/ manual.html [13th December 2012]

Gebrekidan, W. (2006 a): Current water utilization level of Lake Tana and future trends: the case for conflicting interest. In: Hailu, Z.; Gebrekidan, W. (eds.), Proceedings of the National Consultative and Promotional Workshop on: Lake Tana and its Environs: Conservation, Utilization, Development and Threats. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar, 96–117

Gebrekidan, W. (2006 b): Wetlands and Biodiversity within and around Lake Tana Watershed: management options. In: Hailu, Z.; Gebrekidan, W. (eds.), Proceedings of the National Consultative and Promotional Workshop on: Lake Tana and its Environs: Conservation, Utilization, Development and Threats. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar, 37–66

Gebrekidan, W.; Teka, S. (2006 a): Ecological Significances, Threats and Man- agement Options of Lake Tana-Associated Wetlands. Part I: Analysis of the Biophysical and Cultural Resources, and Socio-economic Factors. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar 142 REFERENCES

Gebrekidan, W.; Teka, S. (2006 b): Ecological Significances, Threats and Man- agement Options of Lake Tana-Associated Wetlands. Part II: Alternative Strategic Management Options. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar

Getahun, A.; Dejen, E.; Anteneh, W. (2008): Fishery Studies of Ribb River, Lake Tana Basin, Ethiopia. Final Report. Addis Ababa

Glaser, B. G.; Strauss, A. L. (2010): Grounded Theory: Strategien qualitativer Sozialforschung. Bern: Verlag Hans Huber. 3rd edition

Hailu, A. (2003): Wetlands research in south-western Ethiopia: the experience of the Ethiopian Wetlands Research Programme. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 37–48

Hailu, A.; Wood, A. (2000): Sustainable Wetland Management in Illubabor Zone, South-west Ethiopia. Report for Objective 5 (Report 8 of 9). Training and Dissemination of Technologies to Develop Management and Monitoring Capacity for Sustainable Wetland Management. EWRP, Project B7-6200/96- 05/VIII/ENV

Hailu, A.; Wood, A.; Abbot, P.; Dixon, A. (2000): Sustainable Wetland Man- agement in Illubabor Zone, South-west Ethiopia. Understanding Wetlands and their Management. EWRP, Project B7-6200/96-05/VIII/ENV

Hailu, Z.; Gebrekidan, W. (eds.) (2006): Proceedings of the National Consultative and Promotional Workshop on: Lake Tana and its Environs: Conservation, Utilization, Development and Threats. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar

Henrich, K. (2003): Biodiversit¨atsvernichtung: Okologisch-¨okonomische¨ Ur- sachenanalysen, kausalit¨atstheoretische Grundlagen und evolutorische Es- kalationsdynamik. Okologie¨ und Wirtschaftsforschung Band 50. Marburg: Metropolis-Verlag

Holmes, G. (2007): Protection, Politics and Protest: Understanding Resistance to Conservation, Conservation and Society (vol. 5, no. 2), 184–201 REFERENCES 143

IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Development) (2007): Project Doc- ument (Third Draft): Community-Based Integrated Natural Resources Management Project in Lake Tana Watershed-Ethiopia.

IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Development); EPLAUA (Environmen- tal Protection Land Administration and Use Authority) (2007 a): Amhara National Regional State Community-based Integrated Natural Resources Management In Lake Tana Watershed. Baseline Information: On Agron- omy/Crop Production (Final). Bahir Dar

IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Development); EPLAUA (Environmen- tal Protection Land Administration and Use Authority) (2007 b): Amhara National Regional State Community-based Integrated Natural Resources Management In Lake Tana Watershed. Baseline Information: On Policies, Institutional and Legal Aspects (Final). Bahir Dar

IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Development); EPLAUA (Environmen- tal Protection Land Administration and Use Authority) (2007 c): Amhara National Regional State Community-based Integrated Natural Resources Management In Lake Tana Watershed. Baseline Information: On Water Resource, Watershed, Water Harvesting and Land Use (Final). Bahir Dar

IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute); CSA (Central Statistical Agency); EDRI (Ethiopian Development Research Institute) (2006): Atlas of the Ethiopian Rural Economy. Addis Ababa, Washington D.C.

Institute of Biodiversity Conservation (2005): National Biodiversity Strategy and Action Plan. Addis Ababa

Kumar, S. (2002): Methods for Community Participation: A Complete Guide for Practitioners. Practical Action Publishing

Lamnek, S. (2010): Qualitative Sozialforschung. Weinheim, Basel: Beltz Verlag. 5th edition 144 REFERENCES

Leach, M.; Mearns, R.; Scoones, I. (1999): Environmental Entitlements: Dynam- ics and Institutions in Community-Based Natural Resources Management, World Development (vol. 27, no. 2), 225–247

Mayring, P. (2002): Einf¨uhrungin die Qualitative Sozialforschung: Eine Anleitung zu qualitativem Denken. Weinheim, Basel: Beltz Verlag. 5th edition

MA (Millennium Ecosystem Assessment) (2005): Ecosystems and Human Well- being: Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press

Mesfin, D. (2003): Wetlands policy development in Ethiopia. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 81–85

Miller, D.; Tolina, E. T. (2008): Land to the Tiller Redux: Unlocking Ethiopia’s Land Potential, Drake Journal of African Law (vol. 13), 347–376

MoARD (Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development) (2009): Food Security Programme 2010–2014

MoARD (Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development) (2010): Ethiopia’s Agricultural Sector Policy and Investment Framework (PIF) 2010–2020

MoARD (Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development) (undated): National Rice Research and Development Strategy of Ethiopia

MoFED (Ministry of Finance and Economic Development) (2010): Growth and Transformation Plan 2010/11-2014/15. Volume I: Main Text. Addis Ababa

MoWE (Ministry of Water and Energy) (2010): Environmental and Social Impact Assessment of the Ribb Irrigation and Drainage Project. Volume 1/2: Main Report (Final Version)

MoWR (Ministry of Water Resources) (1999): Ethiopian Water Resources Management Policy

MoWR (Ministry of Water Resources) (2001): Ethiopian Water Sector Strategy REFERENCES 145

Muckel, P. (2007), Die Entwicklung von Kategorien mit der Methode der Grounded Theory, Historical Social Research, Supplement (no. 19), 211– 231

Mulatu, E. (2006): Socio-economic issues in Lake Tana Watershed: future chal- lenges & opportunities for sustainable development. In: Hailu, Z.; Gebrekidan, W. (eds.), Proceedings of the National Consultative and Promotional Work- shop on: Lake Tana and its Environs: Conservation, Utilization, Development and Threats. EPLAUA, Bahir Dar, 24–36

Ostrom, E. (2003): How Types of Goods and Property Rights Jointly Affect Collective Action, Journal of Theoretical Politics (vol. 15, no. 3), 239–270

Ostrom, E. (2009 a): A General Framework for Analyzing Sustainability of Social-Ecological Systems, Science (vol. 325), 419–422

Ostrom, E. (2009 b): Design Principles of Robust Institutions: What Have We Learned? In: Ingrim, G. K.; Hong, Y–H. (eds.), Property Rights and Land Policies. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 25–51

Ostrom, E.; Burger, J.; Field, C. B.; Norgaard, R. B.; Policansky, D. (1999): Revisiting the Commons: Local Lessons, Global Challenges, Science (vol. 248), 278–282

Pausewang, S. (undated): The Need for a Third Alternative: The Amputated Debate on Land Tenure in Ethiopia. www.irsa-world.org/prior/XI/ papers/4-8.pdf [17th September 2012]

Population Census Commission (2008): Summary and Statistical Report of the 2007 Population and Housing Consensus. Population Sized by Age and Sex. Addis Ababa

Proclamation No. 133/2006: The Revised Amhara National Regional State Rural Land Administration and Use Proclamation. Bahir Dar

Proclamation No. 299/2002: Environmental Impact Assessment Proclamation. Addis Ababa 146 REFERENCES

Proclamation No. 455/2005: Expropriation of Landholdings for Public Purposes and Payment of Compensation Proclamation. Addis Ababa

Rahmato, D. (1993): Agrarian Change and Agrarian Crisis: State and Peasantry in Post-Revolution Ethiopia, Journal of the International African Institute (vol. 63, no. 1), 36–55

Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2010 a): Laws and institutions: Reviewing laws and institutions to promote the conservation and wise use of wetlands. Ramsar handbooks for the wise use of wetlands. 4th edition, vol. 3. Ramsar Convention Secretariat, Gland, Switzerland.

Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2010 b): Managing wetlands: Frameworks for managing Wetlands of International Importance and other wetland sites. Ramsar handbooks for the wise use of wetlands. 4th edition, vol. 18. Ramsar Convention Secretariat, Gland, Switzerland.

Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2010 c): Participatory skills: Establishing and strengthening local communities’ and indigenous people’s participation in the management of wetlands. Ramsar handbooks for the wise use of wetlands. 4th edition, vol. 7. Ramsar Convention Secretariat, Gland, Switzerland.

Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2010 d): Wise use of wetlands: Concepts and approaches for the wise use of wetlands. Ramsar handbooks for the wise use of wetlands. 4th edition, vol. 1. Ramsar Convention Secretariat, Gland, Switzerland.

Ramsar Convention Secretariat (2011): The Ramsar Convention Manual: a guide to the Convention on Wetlands (Ramsar, Iran, 1971). 5th edition. Ramsar Convention Secretariat, Gland, Switzerland.

Regulation No. 51/2007: The Amhara National Regional State Rural Land Admin- istration and Use System Implementation, Council of Regional Government Regulations. Bahir Dar

Ribot, J. C.; Peluso, N. L. (2003): A Theory of Access, Rural Sociology (vol. 68, no. 2), 153–181 REFERENCES 147

SARDP (Sida-Amhara Rural Development Program); EPLAUA (Bureau of Environment Protection, Land Administration and Use); ORGUT Consulting AB (2010): Land Registration and Certification: Experiences from the Amhara National Regional State in Ethiopia

Scoones, I. (1998): Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: A Framework for Analysis. IDS Working Paper 72. Institute of Development Studies, Brighton

Sibhat, B. (2012, unpublished): Impact of land use dynamics on farmers liveli- hoods on the periphery of Eastern Lake Tana, Northwest Ethiopia. Bahir Dar

SMEC International Pty Ltd (2008): Hydrological Study of the Tana-Beles Sub-basins: Surface Water Investigation. Project Number: 5089018

Strauss, A. L. (1994): Grundlagen qualitativer Sozialforschung: Datenanalyse und Theoriebildung in der empirischen soziologischen Forschung. M¨unchen: Fink

Taffa, L. (2005): Findings of Participatory Field Studies in Fogera, Bahar Dar Zuria and Dangela wereda for Community and Catchment Based Pilot Demonstration Project. In: EWNRA, Proceedings of the Second Awareness Creation Workshop on Wetlands in the Amhara Region, 56–63

Tekaligne, B. (2003): Environmental impact assessment and the wise use of wetlands. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Pro- ceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 86–96

Tegene, B.; Hunt, C. (2000): Sustainable Wetland Management in Illubabor Zone, South-west Ethiopia. Report 2 for Objective 2 (Report 3 of 9) on: The Characteristics and Management of Wetland Soils of Metu Wereda, Illubabor Zone of Oromia Region. EWRP, Project B7-6200/96-05/VIII/ENV

Teshome, A.; Wale, M.; Mengistu, F.; Yitaferu, B. (eds.) (2009): Agricultural potentials, constraints and opportunities in the Megech and Ribb rivers 148 REFERENCES

irrigation project areas in the Lake Tana Basin of Ethiopia. ARARI, Bahir Dar

Tessema, S. M. (2006): Assemssment of Temporal Hydrological Variations due to Land Use Changes Using Remote Sensing/GIS: A Case Study of Lake Tana Basin

UNESCO (United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization) (1996): Biosphere Reserves: The Seville Strategy and the Statutory Frame- work of the World Network. UNESCO, Paris

UNESCO (United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization) (2008): Madrid Action Plan for Biosphere Reserves (2008–2013). UNESCO, Paris

USAID (United States Agency for International Development); MoARD (Ministry of Agricultural and Rural Development) (2010): An Atlas of Ethiopian Livelihoods. The Livelihoods Integration Unit

Wondefrash, M. (2003): Wetlands, birds and Important Bird Areas in Ethiopia. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 25–36

Wood, A. (2000): Sustainable Wetland Management in Illubabor Zone, South- west Ethiopia. Report for Objective 6 (Report 9 of 9) on: Policy Issues in Sus- tainable Wetland Management. EWRP, Project B7-6200/96-05/VIII/ENV

Wood, A. (2003): Wetlands, gender and poverty: some elements in the develop- ment of sustainable and equitable wetland management. In: Abebe, E. D.; Geheb, K. (eds.), Wetlands of Ethiopia: Proceedings of a seminar on the resources and status of Ethiopia’s wetlands. IUCN, 58–66

zur Heide, F. (2012): Feasibility Study for a Lake Tana Biosphere Reserve, Ethiopia. Bonn: BfN–Skripten 317 REFERENCES 149

Online References

Demographic data: http://www.ethiodemographyandhealth.org/Amhara. html [23rd August 2012]

UNEP 2011: http://hdrstats.undp.org/en/countries/profiles/ETH. html [9th December 2012] REFERENCES Appendices

Appendix 1: Methods of Participatory Rural Appraisal, Group Discussions

The following overview presents the application purposes of the PRA methods, the relevant PRA participants and the application procedure. These procedures are a manual to the application of the PRA methods. Changes of the implementation as well as omissions of single steps and questions were occasionally made in adaption to the situation in the field. Additional questions arising during the discussions are not part of the manual. Action guidelines, instructions or personal leaflets are indicated in italics.

Resource Map

Purpose Land/wetland use/cover, wetland use change, wetland management, food security, constraints to resource use, land tenure, resource use conflicts

Participants Men, women, kebele leaders, DAs

Procedure

1. Could you please show/draw your village and the surrounding? [Drawing of the map]

2. What are the major resources and where are they to be found? [Show major resources in the map]

I II APPENDICES

3. Can you show me: soil type and fertility, vegetation, wetlands, water, water bodies, rivers, irrigation sources, irrigation and drainage channels, cropping pattern (fallowing, crop rotation, kinds of crop), productivity, land uses and ownership, seasonal changes in land use, agricultural development measures (soil and water conservation), markets, towns, bigger villages

4. Discussion

(a) How did you make use of the land in the past? (b) How will you probably make use of the land in future? Will there be significant changes? What will these changes be? (c) Do you think you use the resources of your land efficiently? (d) What hinders you from using the resources efficiently? (e) Do you think that the resources of this land will last for a long time? (f) What could be done to enhance food production? (g) Are there any conflicts in the way you make use of the land?

Trend Analysis

Purpose Land/wetland use change/history, impact on livelihoods, perception of change

Participants Community members, kebele leaders, woreda officials

Procedure

1. Have you perceived any changes of your environment?/Has the land on/in which you live changed over time?

2. What has changed? [Initial discussion, followed by detailed mapping. Write the landmarks and aspects on cards and arrange them in a matrix on the ground]

3. What are the major changes? [Scoring/scaling using numbers or seeds placed below the table rows] APPENDIX 1 III

4. Which change has the greatest/least, a positive/negative impact on your livelihood? [Scoring/scaling using numbers or different seeds placed below the table rows]

5. Discussion

(a) What are the causes for the major changes? (b) Who will be affected by wetland use changes? (c) Who benefits from these changes? (d) Why do some people benefit? Why do others not benefit? (e) Will your children benefit from the land use changes? (f) Do you see the future trend positive or negative? Why? (g) What do you think, which impact does the changes have on wetlands? (ecology: plants, animals, soil moisture)

Cause Effect Diagram

Purpose Land/wetland use change and its drivers, effects of wetland alteration

Participants Male/female groups

Procedure

1. Have you perceived any changes of your environment during the last years?/You are living near this wetland. Have you perceived any changes in the way the wetland looks like?/ In what way did you make use of the land in the past and how do you make use of it today?

2. What has changed? [Listing changes on cards. Interview relevant cards specifically]

(a) Is the land use change a positive or negative change? [Listing land use changes on cards using different colours] IV APPENDICES

(b) What are major/minor land use changes? [Ranking of land use changes]

3. What are the causes for the land use change? [ Choose the two or three major changes. Write the causes for the major changes on cards. Ask par- ticipants to show linkages and interplay of drivers]

(a) Which cause is the most/least serious? [Scoring/scaling with numbers or seeds etc.] (b) Why is this cause the most/least serious one?

4. Which effects do these land use changes have on

(a) your livelihood? [Write the effects on cards] (b) wetlands/communal land (ecology: plants, animals, soil moisture. . . ) [Write the effects on cards. Ask the participants to link the effects] (c) Which effect is the most/least serious one? [Scoring/scaling with numbers or seeds etc.] (d) Why is this effect the most/least serious one? [Impact chain]

5. Discussion

(a) Who benefits from the changes? (b) Why do some people benefit? Why do others not benefit? (c) Will the causes in future become more or less severe? What are the reasons for this? (d) Will your children benefit from the (land use) changes? (e) Do you think that the resources of this land will sufficient in the future? (f) How could negative land use changes be prevented? (g) How could positive land use changes be promoted? (h) How could negative impacts of land use change on your livelihood more adequately be addressed? APPENDIX 1 V

(i) What do you do in order to cope with changes? [Livelihood strategies] (j) What do think about wetland conservation? How could it affect your life? Which effect could it have on the wetland ecosystem?

Impact Diagram

Purpose 1 Perception of wetland conservation and management, values of wetlands, impact of wetland conservation and management on livelihoods

Participants community members

Procedure

1. Which services does the wetland provide to you? [List services/uses on cards]

2. Now imagine, the wetland would be closed or the use restricted. Would it still provide services to you? Would you still value the wetland? [Draw a card with ‘area closure’ and ‘restricted use’]

3. How would the way the wetland is used today change? Which activities would be restricted and prohibited? [Link the cards ‘area closure’ and ‘restricted use’ to the cards ‘services/uses’ if services can still be provided and activities undertaken]

4. Which impact would area closure or restricted use of wetland resources have on

(a) your livelihood? (b) the wetland ecosystem?

5. Discussion

(a) Would a life be possible without using wetland resources? (b) Which assets wetlands provide to you could not be obtained any longer? VI APPENDICES

(c) For the sake of wetland conservation, could you imagine to use the resources in a restricted manner and according to agreed rules and regulations (e. g. seasonal area closure, restricted harvest of resources, using only certain wetland species)?

Purpose 2 Livelihood strategies, land use change

Participants Women, men separately, woreda officials, DAs

Procedure

1. Have you perceived any changes of your environment during the last years?

2. What has changed? [List changes]

3. In what way did you make use of the land in the past and how do make use of it today?

(a) Is the land use change a positive or a negative one? [Listing land use changes on cards using different colours] (b) Do the changes of your environment have any impact on the way you make use of the land today? [Linking changes adding + or – above the arrows]

4. What impact do the (land use/environmental) changes have on your life? [Listing impacts]

(a) Is it a positive or negative impact? [Write the impacts on cards of dif- ferent colour. Put the cards on the floor. Ask the participants whether they see any connections or linkages. Ask for impact chains if the par- ticipants do not come up with it] (b) Which impact on your life is the most serious one? [Ranking the impacts on livelihood]

5. How do you cope with this change? [Put the most serious changes in the middle. List the strategies on cards] APPENDIX 1 VII

(a) What is the most/least important/effective livelihood strategy that you apply? [Arrange the cards around the card ‘change’ and rank the strategies according to their importance]

6. Discussion

(a) Why do you apply the mentioned strategies? (b) Why is strategy x the most/least important/effective one? (c) What happens if people in the community cannot afford the means necessary for adaptation/coping? (d) Is it easy for you to cope with these changes in your life? (e) Why is it (not) easy? (f) Do you think that environmental and land use changes will occur in future? (g) Considering future trends of environmental change, will it be easy for you to cope with these changes? Why or why not?

Well-Being Ranking

Purpose Identification of well-being groups, conceptions of well-being, good life and development, visions, livelihood strategies

Participants community members, young people separately

Procedure

1. Do you think, you live a ‘good life’?

2. If you say, you live a good life, then what is good in your life?/ If you say, you do not live such a good life, then what is not good? [List]

3. Think about a life which is good for you. How does a good life look like? [List] VIII APPENDICES

4. Are there people within your village that use smaller or larger sizes of land? How huge is their land? [Name the well-being categories (groups) in terms of landholding size]

5. On which assets and strategies does the well-being of all groups depend? (E.g. land holding, quality of land, availability of water for irrigation, livestock ownership, quality of food, availability of labour, dependence on other income sources, kinds of the produced crops, production of cash crops, quality of house (roof, floor, construction material), children attending school, quality of clothes, health status, social status, reputation within the community) [List the assets and strategies (criteria). Ask the participants whether they want to add other criteria]

6. To which assets/capitals do the different well-being groups have access and upon which strategies do they depend most/least? [Circles of different shapes. The larger the circle, the better the well-being group has access to an asset or the more the livelihood of a well-being group depends upon the strategy.]

7. Discussion

(a) How do you wish to live? (b) Do you believe that your wishes and visions become true? (c) What are the constraints which hinder you from fulfilling your wishes and visions? (d) What does ‘development’ mean to you? (e) What should be developed? (f) Which livelihood strategies do you apply?

Venn Diagram

Purpose Perception of organisations, programmes, projects, government bodies etc. APPENDIX 1 IX

Participants Community members (women and men), kebele leaders, woreda officials

Procedure

1. Are there organisations, programmes, projects etc. which you perceive as positive?

2. What are they? [List them on cards]

(a) Can you put the organisations etc. in an order? Those perceived as positive on top and those perceived as less positive below. [Arrange the cards in an order (the organisations perceived as most positive on top). Write the organisations etc. on circular papers (the bigger the circle, the higher the rank, i. e. the more positive the experience). Place them around a centre (community/village/office)]

3. What are the positive/negative experiences you made with the organisations etc.?

4. Is the cooperation between you and the organisations etc. good/successful? [Rank according to the success of the cooperation. Place the organisations with that a more fruitful cooperation exists closer to the centre circle and the ones with a less successful cooperation further away from the centre]

(a) Why is the cooperation between you and the organisations etc. (not) good/successful?

5. Which organisations etc. do closely work together? [Place these organi- sations etc. that work closely together near to each other. The degree of overlap indicates the degree of interaction]

6. Discussion

(a) How could cooperation between you and organisations and among organisations etc. be improved? (b) What do you think about self-organising community issues? X APPENDICES

(c) Do local organisations exist which manage wetland resources? (d) Which regulations (by-laws, prohibition, permission, restriction. . . ) for the management of wetlands do exist?

Pair-Wise Ranking and Seasonal Diagram9

Purpose Values of wetlands, conflict (wetland conservation vs. use), causes and consequences of these conflicts, livelihood options

Participants Community members, young people separately, kebele leaders, DAs, woreda officials

Procedure

1. Which services do wetlands/communal land provide to you/the people?/How do you/people make use of the land? [List services/uses on cards (2x). Arrange them in a matrix]

2. Which service is the most beneficial to you? [Discussion on this is- sue/ranking possible with heterogeneous group?]

3. Do the ways you make use of the land conflict with each other? [Compare the various aspects in the matrix with one another]

4. During which months of the year do the conflicts arise? [Prepare a time line with 13 months. Depict the conflicts and their durations]

(a) What are the causes of the conflicts? (b) Will the particular cause x continue to exist in the future?

5. Discussion

(a) Do the conflicts influence your life? (b) How do you respond to the conflicts?

9The seasonal diagram was applied only once and was then omitted due to the enormous expenditure of time. It is not listed under the PRA methods in chapter 4. APPENDIX 2 XI

(c) Do you try to solve the conflicts? How? (d) What do think about wetland conservation (e. g. area closure, restricted use of resources)? Would conflicts arise? How would it affect your life? Which effect would it have on the wetland ecosystem?

Group Discussion with the Fishermen’s Association in Daga

1. Why do you fish?

2. When and for what purpose was the fishermen’s association established? Who can become a member of the association?

3. Which fishery rules and regulations have been established?

4. Which fishing practices/techniques do you apply?

5. Which problems occur related to fishing?

Appendix 2: Catalogue of Interview Questions

The following catalogue of interview questions was used as a guideline through various interviews. The catalogue was subdivided in several topics of research interest. The respondents that were considered to be of relevance are listed. Questions which spontaneously emerged during the conversations are not included.

Land Administration

Respondents BDU, EPLAUA, WoEPLAU (Dera, Fogera, Libo Kemkem), EWNRA

1. Could you provide me with a short overview of Ethiopia’s land tenure history?

2. Land (re)distribution:

(a) Which effect does (re)distribution of land have on (1) rural livelihoods and (2) the use and management of natural resources? XII APPENDICES

(b) How do people perceive frequent land (re)distribution? (c) Is the (re)distribution a potential source of conflict within the com- munity, between different resource user groups?

3. Land registration and certification:

(a) Have registration and certification been accomplished in ANRS and the research sites, specifically? (b) Have temporary/primary/secondary certificates been issued? How many? (c) When was registration undertaken? (d) Which land surveying techniques were applied? (e) Have communal lands/wetlands/recession farmland been registered and certificates been issued? (f) Who keeps the certificates of communal land? (g) Have wetlands/recession farmlands been registered as communal or private holding? (h) Is there any difference between wetlands and communal lands? (i) Which problems occurred during registration? (j) Which factors constrain the registration and certification of wetlands? (k) Which effects does certification have on (1) tenure security, (2) natural resource conservation, (3) communal lands, (4) wetlands? (l) How do farmers perceive land titling?

4. Conflicts:

(a) What are the conflicts about? (Land and resources use, access con- flicts) (b) Who are the social actors involved in these conflicts? Who is affected? (c) What are the consequences of the conflicts for the social-ecological system? APPENDIX 2 XIII

(d) How to manage these conflicts? What has been done to settle the conflicts?

5. Land use obligations:

(a) Are landholders aware of land use obligations? (b) Have land use obligations been effectively implemented? (c) Has the implementation been enforced and evaluated by responsible administrative bodies?

6. Does the government permit recession agriculture?

7. Have land use plans been developed? If not, what constrains the development of land use plans?

8. Buffer zone:

(a) Have buffer zones been designated along the lake side? (b) Who is responsible for the designation of buffer zones? (c) For what purpose are buffer zones delineated? (d) Which habitats/ecosystems/areas of high conservation value should be part of the buffer zone?

9. Landless:

(a) In which way do woreda/regional governments address the problem of landless people? (b) Which role do group rights play? (c) Which role do youth associations play?

10. Has there been a discussion on community or associative ownership of land?

11. “Reclaim existing wetlands” (Water Sector Strategy, MoWR 2001: 4). “From an environmental point of view, it is interesting that the Strategy in- cluded a call to ‘reclaim existing wetlands’ by drainage and other means, but not for their conservation or the protection of wetland values” (MoWE 2010: 3-8). Are wetlands considered a source of productive land for distribution? XIV APPENDICES

12. How much tax is paid for landholding (annual rural land use payment)?

Wetland Management Institutions

Respondents Wetland experts (BDU), youth association members, DAs, re- gional/woreda officials (WoEPLAU), fishery expert, EWNRA

1. Are there any local institutions (especially east of the lake) that regulate wetland resource use and management around Lake Tana?

(a) Which specific regulations and by-laws have been enacted locally? (b) Do these local institutions effectively conserve wetland resources? (c) What can be done to strengthen local institutions? (d) What can be done to facilitate the establishment of local institutions? (e) Are there any plans to facilitate the establishment of local institutions?

2. National/regional policies with implications for wetland management:

(a) Which national/regional policies affect wetland use and management? (b) In what way do they affect wetland management? (c) Is there any wetland policy?

3. Wetland management plan:

(a) Is there any wetland management plan? (b) How is/will the management plan (be) designed? (plans for specific wetlands, by-laws enacted, community-based, alternative livelihood options. . . ) (c) Should local/traditional knowledge be integrated into wetland man- agement projects? (d) Which steps have to be taken to create wetland management plans? (e) How to deal with cultural and behavioural constraints to change when adopting a wetland management plan? APPENDIX 2 XV

Human-Wetland System: Changes, Drivers, Ramifications

Respondents Wetland experts (BDU), fishery experts, EPLAUA, WoEPLAU, ARARI, BoCTPD, BoARD, WoARD, BoWE, WoWE, EWNRA, Rural Road Office Libo Kemkem, TaSBO

1. [Generally: ask for social-ecological information about wetlands in the re- search sites.]

2. Which land use changes have been detected around Lake Tana, specifically along the eastern lakeside?

3. Which implications does wetland conservation have for the livelihoods of local people?

4. Which role do wetlands and recession farmlands play for food security?

5. Have wetlands and recession farmlands been managed according to custom- ary law?

6. Conflicts:

(a) Which conflicts arise over wetland resources, their appropriation and management? (b) Who are the actors involved in these conflicts? (c) Which stakeholders assert claims to wetland resources and manage- ment? (d) Which consequences do these conflicts have for (1) people’s livelihoods, (2) wetland ecosystems, (3) future management options? (e) How could conflicts be resolved?

7. Which are the wetland species indicating different use regimes and anthro- pogenic influences?

8. Are wetlands used as a source of water for irrigation? XVI APPENDICES

9. Does sedimentation encourage recession farming and wetland conversion more than wetland grazing?

10. “From an environmental point of view, it is interesting that the Strategy included a call to ‘reclaim existing wetlands’ by drainage and other means, but not for their conservation or the protection of wetland values” (MoWE 2010: 3-8). Does the government promote the cultivation of wetlands? What are the governments’ perceptions on wetlands?

11. Impact of human activities on wetlands:

(a) Flooding: i. Which impact does flooding have on wetlands? ii. What are the causes of flooding? iii. In which way does hydropower generation influence the flooding regime of Lake Tana? (b) Which impact do grazing and wetland cultivation have on the ecosys- tem? (c) Water development projects: i. Which impact do the large-scale irrigation and drainage projects (Megech, Jamma, especially Ribb and Gumara) and other water development projects have on wetlands? ii. Which projects have been accomplished/are under plan- ning/construction? (d) Rice cultivation: i. When was rice introduced in the kebeles of the research site? ii. Which impact does rice cultivation have on wetlands? iii. Which factors have constrained rice cultivation? (e) Which impact does sand mining in Agid Kirigna have on wetlands? i. Is sand mining legal (licensed) or illegal in Agid Kirigna? ii. In how far is the rural roads office engaged in these activities? APPENDIX 2 XVII

Fisheries

Respondents Fishery experts (ARARI, woreda officials)

1. Bahir Dar Number One Fishermen’s Association:

(a) What is the Bahir Dar Number One Fishermen’s Association? (b) How is the association organised?

2. Have local fishermen’s associations been licensed, legally recognised or supported by the government?

3. Do you know something about the joint fishermen’s association in Agid Kirigna (between the Woito and other communities)?

4. Fisheries regulation:

(a) Are there legal/local regulations for the utilisation and conservation of fish resources? (b) What are the instructions, restrictions, prohibitions etc. of these rules and regulations? (c) Are local people aware of the regulations? (d) Which factors constrain an effective implementation and enforcement of the regulations? (e) Is fishing prohibited during the spawning season?

5. Fish species:

(a) Which species are most commonly caught? (b) What are their characteristics (habitat, feed, spawning time etc.)?

6. Are market conditions favourable for fishermen?

7. Which measures need to be taken to enhance the conservation of fishes?

8. Is there any correlation between the intensity of fishing and flooding? XVIII APPENDICES

Appendix 3: Codes

The codes that were used for analysis in ATLAS.ti are presented in table 8.1, p. XVIII.

Table 8.1: List of codes used for analysis

General codes “Numbers”; Access; Cause; Constraints; Definition; Government; Location; Perception; Policy; Power; Trends; Values Wetland use/land use and environmental change Crop production; Encroachment; Fishing; Flood; Land use/ environmental change; Recession Farming; Rice cultivation Land administration Land (re)distribution; Land registration and certification; Land tenure; Land use planning; Tenure security Conflict Conflict; Conflict Resolution Management and conservation Conservation; Management; WL/CL10 conservation; WL/CL management Impact on livelihood Adverse impact on livelihood; Positive impact on livelihood Livelihood Endowment; Food security; Livelihood strategies; Income source; Vision Actors Landless; Social actors Recommendation Recommendation; Recommendation deduced; Recommendation from expert; Recommenda- tion from within

Appendix 4: Well-Being Ranking

Figure 8.1, p. XIX and figure 8.2, p. XX depict the matrices of two well-being ranking sessions. The sizes of the circles indicate (1) the well-being groups (large

10WL wetland, CL communal land APPENDIX 5 XIX circle: upper well-being group, medium circle: middle well-being group, small circle: lower well-being group, smallest circle or cross: landless) and (2) the degree to which well-being groups have access to capitals or depend upon livelihood strategies (larger circles indicate better access to capitals or greater dependence on livelihood strategies).

Assets/ Livelihood

Strategies

of houses of

Crop varieties Crop

Quality/quantitly Quality/quantitly Soil fertility Soil Cloths

Childrenattending Size oflandholding

school

Dependance onother children of No.

incomesources Health Migration

Income from Eucalyptus Well-being groups

Upper

Middle

Lower

Landless

Figure 8.1: The matrix drawn during a well-being ranking with women of the lower and middle well-being group. Photograph: Springsguth, M.

Appendix 5: Responses to Livelihood Insecurity

Devereux (2001) makes a distinction between the following responses to livelihood insecurity: (1) ex-ante risk mitigation and (2) ex-post coping strategies including XX APPENDICES

Assets/ Livelihood

Strategies

within the community the within Respect & reputation & Respect

Quality food Cloths

No. of children of No.

Migration Health Fishing

Well-being groups

Upper

Middle

Lower

Landless

Figure 8.2: The matrix drawn during a well-being ranking with (landless) youth. Photograph: Springsguth, M. coping with and adaption to risk. Mitigation aims at reducing risks in advance, e. g. through choosing certain agricultural techniques or crop varieties. Coping strategies are short-term responses to a risk. Adaptation refers to strategies which have been incorporated into the normal behaviour (Devereux 2001: 511–512). He further points to the importance of social networks “for assistance in times of need” (Devereux 2003: 513). Zoomers (1999, in de Haan & Zoomers 2005: 39–40) distinguishes four categories of livelihood strategies11: (1) Accumulation strategies involve the

11Zoomers (1999, in de Haan & Zoomers 2005: 39–40) does not simply call these strategies intentional or unintentional. Rather she found that the success of farmers is not so much determined by strategic actions than by structural components, such as location, seasonality or APPENDIX 5 XXI establishment of “a minimum resource base” (p. 39) and a preparation for the expansion in future. (2) Consolidation strategies are applied to stabilise well-being and for short-term quality improvement. (3) Compensatory strategies serve the survival in cases of sudden shocks. (4) Security strategies include e. g. livelihood diversification and off-farm employment. Table 8.2, p. XXI below provides an overview of the responses to livelihood insecurity, tries to categorise the strategies and social groups as far as possible and indicates the outcomes for rural livelihoods. Strategies are classified according to (1) Devereux (2001) and (2) Zoomers (1999, in de Haan & Zoomers 2005). This has pragmatic reasons: The literature on vulnerability, resilience and sustainable livelihoods is more often familiar with the terms used by Devereux. However, Zoomers’ approach is very well applicable to this research work.

Table 8.2: The responses of different social actors to livelihood insecurity

Response Strategies Social Actors12 Outcome Rice cultivation Adaptation; accu- All well-being Food security, in- mulation, consoli- groups (8:8) come (also when dation faced with flooding) increased Apply fertiliser, com- Adaptation; con- N/A Increase productivity, post, herbicides, irriga- solidation food security tion (4:42) Fishing Adaptation; se- Landless, Woito Food security, in- curity, accumula- (26:17; 53:9; come maintained or tion 54:9) increased Coping; compen- All local residents Food security, in- satory, security (8:38; 12:46; come during flood- 15:45) ing ensured Bying fodder (18:54) Coping, adap- N/A Investment to keep tation; compen- livestock (also dur- satory, consolida- ing flood) tion

household characteristics. Her categorisation comprises both intentional and structural elements. 12For the classification of well-being groups, see p. 47. XXII APPENDICES

Response Strategies Social Actors Outcome Leaving livestock with Coping, adap- Livestock farm- Secure household relatives for payment tation; compen- ers with social savings (during (6:16; 15:26) satory networks flooding) Selling of cattle (15:26) Coping; compen- Livestock farmers Reduce expenses satory for fodder, income obtained Change cattle breed Adaptation; accu- Livestock farmers Reduce expenses for (56:12) mulation fodder Protect settlement Coping, adap- All flood-prone Securing tangible (house construction on tation; compen- households goods during flood- hills, elevating house- satory ing hold items with poles, pile leaves) (12:34; EWRDM: 55:21) Food rationing (12:39) Coping; compen- All local residents Survival in times of satory flooding and during the dry season Displacement Coping; compen- Flood-prone Maintaining liveli- satory households, hood, survival woreda officials (12:18; 18:19; EWRDM: 55:9) Using Tanqua, con- Coping; compen- All flood-prone Movement during tainer, swimming satory households flooding ensured (12:34; EWRDM: 55:21) Using a boat (15:31; Coping; compen- Upper well-being Movement during EWRDM: 55:21) satory group flooding ensured, receive payments from people without a boat, e. g. for the transportation of sick persons Wooden bridge con- Coping; compen- Communities Movement during struction (EWRDM: satory flooding ensured 55:21) APPENDIX 5 XXIII

Response Strategies Social Actors Outcome Informing regional level Coping; compen- Woreda officials Disaster risk man- (EWRDM: 55:8) satory, security agement [Supporting measures Coping; compen- Woreda officials Disaster risk man- (e. g. granting contin- satory agement (55:11) gency funds)] Children living with rel- Adaptation; con- Middle to upper Education ensured atives to attend nearby solidation well-being groups school (13:19) with social net- works Alternative income adaptation; se- Landless Income ensured, sources (beer brewing, curity, accumula- (women), lower maintained or in- handicrafts, cloth de- tion well-being group creased signing) (women) (8:15) Rent land from rich Coping, adap- Landless, lower Crop production, (upper well-being group, tation; security, well-being group food security en- Woito)/sharecropping accumulation (8:8) sured (23:6) 13 Lend money from rich Coping, adap- Landless, lower Investments tation; security, well-being group accumulation (8:15; 16:8) Migration (Bahir Dar, Adaptation; se- Landless, lower Income and food Hamusit, Humera in curity, accumula- well-being groups security ensured, Tigray) (2:7) tion (8:6), youth increased (15:26, 15:46), Woito (23:31) Day labour/employed Adaptation; se- Landless, lower Income ensured by richer farmers (2:7; curity, accumula- well-being group 7:33) tion (16:8) Sand mining Adaptation; se- People in Agid Income during the curity, accumula- Kirigna, church dry season ensured tion (21:13)

13According to IFPRI/CSA/EDRI (2006), the proportion of small-holder landholdings that is rented in the kebeles of the research area is one of the highest in Ethiopia, ranging from 16% to more than 20%. XXIV APPENDICES

Response Strategies Social Actors Outcome Assigning group rights Adaptation; accu- Groups of land- Food security and for land use 14 mulation less and young income ensured (> 18 years) (54:13) Association/group Adaptation; Fishermen in Resource manage- membership accumulation, Tez Amba, Agid ment consolidation Kirigna Farmers Purchase of costly goods such as water pumps (6:22) Adaptation; se- Landless Representation in curity, accumula- land issues and ac- tion cess to resources

Appendix 6: Land Use/Cover Changes in the Research Area

The land use/cover maps are based on satellite images of February 1986 and 2001, and January 2011 (dry season). Remarkable are the decline in wetland and grassland in favour of cultivated land/settlements, and the land use dynamics along the littoral zone.

14According to Proclamation No. 133/2006 §2(19) and §10 landholders can be groups. In Kab kebele, for example, communal lands were distributed to groups of landless and young older than 18 years with the consent of the communities. These groups comprise 30 to 73 members, and collectively cultivate rice (54:13). Assigning groups rights is a strategy reducing land fragmentation and resource degradation (Deininger et al. 2007: 20). APPENDIX 6 XXV

K

TA

N

W

TM

Figure 8.3: Land use/cover in 1986 in the research area. TM Tanametsele, W Wagetera, N Nabega, TA Tez Amba, K Kab. Source: modified after Sibhat, B. (2012) XXVI APPENDICES

K

TA

N

W

TM

Figure 8.4: Land use/cover in 2001 in the research area. TM Tanametsele, W Wagetera, N Nabega, TA Tez Amba, K Kab. Source: modified after Sibhat, B. (2012) APPENDIX 6 XXVII

K

TA

N

W

TM

Figure 8.5: Land use/cover in 2011 in the research area. TM Tanametsele, W Wagetera, N Nabega, TA Tez Amba, K Kab. Source: modified after Sibhat, B. (2012) XXVIII APPENDICES

Appendix 7: Overview of the Impact of Anthropogenic Activities on Wetland Ecosystems

According to Gebrekidan (2006 b), “major threats to the long-term ecological integrity of Lake Tana and its associated wetlands [can be] summarised into four main categories” (p. 47): (1) alteration of ecosystems leading to habitat fragmentation and loss, (2) species loss, (3) loss of genetic diversity and (4) intro- duction/invasion of exotic species. Anthropogenic activities immensely contribute to these processes. The conversion and long-term cultivation of wetlands is seen to be the most destructive interference with the ecosystem. It results in a complete destruction of vegetation (ARARI: 41:24), in biodiversity and habitat loss as well as habitat fragmentation (see Institute of Biodiversity Conservation 2005: 18). Drained wetland soils lose their capacity to reabsorb water (Tekaligne 2003: 8). They are exposed to rapid decomposition and mineralisation (Tegene & Hunt 2000: 25). The increase in numbers of fishermen, more efficient methods and fishing in times of reproduction and migration result in a decline of fish populations (11:1; 52:10; ARARI: 41:7, 41:17, 41:29; BoARD: 32:4; Getahun et al. 2008: 3). Flooding events, in part human-induced, increase pressures on fish stocks and wetlands (9:11; 18:12; ARARI: 41:33), inhibit vegetation growth and lead to habitat loss (Tekaligne 2003: 87). Livestock grazing is associated with the destruction of vegetation, a shift in species composition, soil compaction and erosion (Hailu 2003: 46). Wetland vegetation is also cut and trampled by cattle in order to disturb breeding grounds for disease vectors and pathogenic agents (6:17; Wondefrash 2003: 28). Sand mining activities in Agid Kirigna result in the degradation of the lake shore (Gebrekidan & Teka 2006 a: 26–27). Local people mentioned that larger-scale sand mining activities destroyed arable land and wetland pastures (21:15). An increased sediment load of wetlands “reduces the penetration of light and hence primary productivity [and] can have abrasive effects on aquatic organisms, especially fish” (Tekaligne 2003: 88). The release of chemicals and fertiliser into Lake Tana may result in eutroph- APPENDIX 8 XXIX ication and, consequently, in algal bloom and loss of biodiversity (ibid.: 88). Development projects in the “Growth Corridor” (MoARD 2010: 7) of Amhara such as the Ribb Irrigation and Drainage Project aim at an intensification of agriculture. The targeted growth of the agricultural sector involves the application of fertilisers, pesticides and other chemicals and may adversely affect water quality (ibid.: 10, 17; MoWE 2010: 5-37) and wetland ecosystems (BDU: 40:10; EWNRA: 28:8; cf. 22:10). It is further assumed that water development measures (e. g. dam construction, hydropwer generation) alter the water balance of Lake Tana (MoWE 2010: 6-23–6-24) and thereby of wetland ecosystems.

Appendix 8: Biosphere Reserves

The Sevilla Strategy states that a BR should include areas in which human- environment interactions are critical, e. g. (degraded) wetlands (UNESCO 1996: 7). BRs are established within and recognised by the UNESCO Man and the Biosphere Programme (ibid.: 16). The Statutory Framework of the World Network of Biosphere Reserves defines BRs as areas of terrestrial and/or coastal/marine ecosystems (ibid.: 16, Article 1), designed as places for the reconciliation of social and economic development with the conservation of natural and cultural landscapes. This reconciliation is achieved by combining the three functions BRs should meet, i. e. the conservation of biodiversity, sustainable development and logistic support (learning, research and demonstration) (ibid.: 16, Article 3). An integrated zoning approach tends to link the three functions to each of the three zones that a BR should contain (UNESCO 2008: 16). The core zone(s) of a BR serves protecting biodiversity, non-destructive research and indirect uses (such as education). The clearly defined buffer zone(s) is contiguous to or surrounds the core zone. Within the buffer zone only those human practices are allowed which are in line with conservation objectives (like environmental education or ecotourism). The transition zone is characterised by sustainable resource appropriation and management (e.g. agriculture, industry, settlement) (ibid.: 4, 17, Article 4(5)). XXX GLOSSARY

Glossary

Berbere Mixed spices traditionally used in the Ethiopian cuisine Cut-and-carry system The making of hay by cutting (wetland) plant species and carrying the hay to the homestead Derg The military socialist regime in Ethiopia ruling from 1975 to 1991 ETB e 1 = 24.09 ETB (Ethiopian Birr), as of 29th De- cember 2012 Gesho Rhamnus prinoides, a kind of “local hop” used to brew beer (Green) Book of Hold- Certificate issued to the farmer indicating his/her ing or Land Holding landholding, fertility, present use of the parcels Certificate Book and the responsibilities of the land holder(s) (SARDP/EPLAUA/ORGUT 2010: 6–7; Regula- tion No. 51/2007: §21) Injera The traditional pita, originally produced from teff flour Kebele/sub-kebele The lowest administrative units. The kebele admin- istrative committee consists of a chairman, vice chairman, economic head, judicial head and a sec- retary (Abbot et al. 2000: 14). Kiremt The main rainy season between June to September Land Registry Book Contains all the data of a landholding and is kept with the woreda land administration and LAC of- fices Recession agriculture The cultivation of the shore zone of Lake Tana during the dry season Tanqua Small fishing boat made from papyrus Woito An ethnicity that has traditionally been living from the lake’s resources GLOSSARY XXXI

Woreda A lower administrative unit, comparable to a dis- trict Selbstst¨andigkeitserkl¨arung

Ich versichere an Eides statt, dass ich die anliegende Diplomarbeit mit dem Thema: “The Impact of Land Administration and Common-Pool Resource Management on Wetland Utilisation along the Eastern Shore of Lake Tana, Ethiopia. Alteration of Wetlands – Risk or Chance for Rural Livelihoods?” selbstst¨andigverfasst habe und keine anderen Hilfsmittel als die angegebenen verwendet habe. Die Stellen, die anderen Werken dem Wortlaut oder dem Sinne nach entnommen sind, habe ich in jedem Fall durch Angabe der Quelle, auch der Sekund¨arliteratur,als Entlehnung kenntlich gemacht.

Berlin, den Maxi Springsguth