Three Simple Principles of Trade Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Three Simple Principles of Trade Policy Three Simple Principles ofTrade Policy Douglas A. Irwin The AEI Press Publisher for the American Enterprise Institute WAS HING TON, D. C. 1996 Distributed to the Trade by National Book Network, 15200 NBN Way, Blue Ridge Summit, PA 17214. To order call toll free 1-800-462-6420 or 1-717-794-3800. For all other inquiries please contact the AEI Press, 1150 Seventeenth Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20036 or call 1-800-862-5801. ISBN 0-8447-7079-5 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2 ©1996 by the American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be used or reproduced in any manner whatso­ everwithout permission in writing from the American Enterprise Institute exceptin the case ofbriefquotations embodied in news articles, critical articles, or reviews. The views expressed in the publications of the American Enterprise Institute are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the staff, advisory panels, officers, or trustees ofAEI. THE AEI PRESS Publisher for the American Enterprise Institute 1150 17th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20036 Printed in the United States ofAmerica Contents ACKNOWLEDGMENTS v INTRODUCTION 1. A TAX ON IMPORTS Is A TAX ON EXPORTS 2 2. BUSINESSES ARE CONSUMERS Too 10 3. TRADE IMBALANCES REFLECT CAPITAL FLOWS 18 CONCLUSION 27 NOTES 29 ABOUT THE AUTHOR 31 iii Acknowledgments This is a revised version of an informal talk I gave at the American Enterprise Institute inJanuary 1996. I thankAEI President Christopher DeMuth for inviting me to write up my remarks and make them available to a broader audi­ ence, as well as for his constructive advice on the text. I also wish to thank Claude Barfield,Jagdish Bhagwati, and Donald Davis for helpful comments. v Introduction t the conclusion of a class I teach on international commercial policy, I try to distill the essence of a ten­ Aweek course down to a few simple principles that stu­ dents might remember long after the final exam is over. In this essay I expand upon three of these principles. I have selected these principles with the aim of cor­ recting some common economic fallacies in the political debate over U.S. trade policy. The principles are a bit more subtle, and more pointed, than elementary first principles such as "voluntary exchange is generally beneficial"-a proposition that almost everyone accepts but that rarely settles a practical policy issue. Indeed these principles might seem to be mistaken, on first reading, to many read­ ers whose understanding of trade issues is derived mainly from newpaper accounts-and yet I believe they can be explained persuasively and illustrated with straightforward data and examples that demonstrate their practical rel­ evance. Most of all, the three principles are offered as ex­ amples of important and enduring knowledge about inter­ national trade, as opposed to the unstructured (or tendentiously structured) information about trade that comes our way every day. Each principle is the distillation of generations of serious thinking about the nature of trade among nations-thinking that has endured much longer than the ad hoc arguments and partial informa­ tion of political debate. This thinking can help us make sense ofthe information supplied by politicians and inter­ est groups. Major improvements in U.S. trade policy may be out of reach at the present time, but a greater under­ standing of the three principles offered herein would improve the trade policy debate. 1 IMPORT AND EXPORT TAXES 1. A Tax on Imports Is a Tax on Exports The first proposition is that a tax on imports is equivalent to a tax on exports. Any restraint on imports also acts, in effect, as a restraint on exports. The converse ofthis propo­ sition is also true: when a government undertakes policies to expand the volume of exports, it cannot help but to expand the volume of imports as well. The fundamental reason for this truth is that exports and imports are flip sides of the same coin. Exports are necessary to generate the earnings to pay for imports, or exports are the goods a country must give up in order to acquire imports. Exports and imports are inherently in­ terdependent, and any policy that reduces one will also reduce the other. At one level, the idea that import restraints will re­ duce exports is simple and straightforward: ifforeign coun­ tries are blocked in their ability to sell their goods in the United States, for example, they will be unable to earn the dollars they need to purchase U.S. goods. In policy discus­ sions about international trade, however, there is a ten­ dency to view a country's exports and imports as being separate, independent phenomena. In this view, govern­ ment policy can diminish imports without adversely affect­ ing exports, or vice versa. This view is erroneous because exports and imports do not wander too far from one an­ other. The two are inexorably linked even if the mecha­ nism by which they are linked is not immediately obvious. (Trade imbalances will be considered in proposition 3.) Before I present some simple data that illustrate this point, let me briefly discuss the intellectual history of this proposition. Economists will recognize it as the "Lerner symmetry theorem," named for the distinguished econo­ mist Abba Lerner, who wrote a short but brilliant paper on the subject as a graduate studentat the London School of Economics in the mid-1930s. I Lerner established the for­ mal truth of the proposition, but it had been a feature of 2 DOUGLAS A. IRWIN trade policy debates long before then. The principle was used extensively in the House of Commons in the early 1840s and before, when Parliament was considering whether to repeal the Corn Laws, legisla­ tion that limited British grain imports. Members in favor ofrepeal argued that the import tariffs restrained exports of manufactures, and that allowing greater imports of wheat would lead directly to greater exports of textiles. One Member of Parliament, James Deacon Hume, is re­ corded as saying that "he did not expect to hear it denied that every import must be paid for by an export. If so, every quarter of wheat imported put into employment some manufacturers to pay for that import."2 The symmetry between import and export taxes was recognized even in the seventeenth-eentury English mer­ cantilist literature. Popular understanding of mercantilist doctrine is that trade barriers were recommended in or­ der to achieve, among other things, a balance of trade surplus. By my reading of this literature, seventeenth-cen­ tury mercantilistwriters certainly wanted to achieve a trade surplus, but they were not at all sanguine about the efficicacy ofimport tariffs in achieving this objective. ~ Even these writers, who rejected free trade as a matter of prin­ ciple, recognized that exports and imports are fundamen­ tally interdependent. In discussing the tax burden on imports, the pamphleteer Henry Robinson cautioned as early as 1640 that "here is it worth remembrance that a great part of foreign commodities brought for England are taken in barter ofours, and we should not have vented ours in so great quantity without taking them." In 1680 William Petyt took this point to its logical conclusion: For the opening of a sufficient foreign vent and market for our home commodities, it is not only necessary to remove all unequal clogs on mere exportation, but also those on imported goods; 3 IMPORT AND EXPORT TAXES because ... the value of our English exporta­ tion must be in a manner confined to the value of the goods imported.... Whereas were the clogs on our imported goods taken off, we mightyearly vend of our own home commodities to the value of all foreign goods we should then import and re-export... whereby our exported home com­ modities would then amount to much more.4 Recognition of the interdependence of exports and im­ ports put mercantilists in a bind because import tariffs appeared to be the obvious instrument for improving the balance of trade by reducing imports without directly af­ fecting exports. Thus, the Lerner symmetry theorem has a long intellectual pedigree. Lerner's Symmetry: True and Nontrivial. What is particu­ larly marvelous about the Lerner symmetry theorem is that it is both true and nontrivial. (In this regard it is like an­ other fundamental principle of international trade: the theory of comparative advantage.) The equivalence of export and import taxes is not an obvious proposition, and it is often counterintuitive to most people. Imagine taking a poll of average Americans and asking the follow­ ing question: "Should the United States impose import tariffs on foreign textiles to prevent low-wage countries from harming thousands of American textile workers?" Some fraction, perhaps even a sizeable one, of the respon­ dents would surely answer affirmatively. Ifasked to explain their position, they would probably reply that import tar­ iffs would createjobs for Americans at the expense offor­ eign workers and thereby reduce domestic unemployment. Suppose you then asked those same people the fol­ lowing question: "Should the United States tax the expor­ tation of Boeing aircraft, wheat and corn, computers and computer software, and other domestically produced goods?" I suspect the answer would be a resounding and 4 DOUGLAS A. IRWIN unanimous "No!" After all, it would be explained, export taxes would destroy jobs and harm important industries. And yet the Lerner symmetry theorem says that the two policies are equivalent in their economic effects. This all goes to show that the issue of tax incidence is a tricky one. One may think that an import tariff is felt only in the import sector, but in the end this is not the case.
Recommended publications
  • U.S Trade Policy-Making in the Eighties
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Politics and Economics in the Eighties Volume Author/Editor: Alberto Alesina and Geoffrey Carliner, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-01280-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/ales91-1 Conference Date: May 14-15, 1990 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: U.S Trade Policy-making in the Eighties Chapter Author: I. M. Destler Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c5420 Chapter pages in book: (p. 251 - 284) 8 U. S. Trade Policy-making in the Eighties I. M. Destler 8.1 Introduction As the 1970s wound to a close, Robert Strauss, President Jimmy Carter’s Special Trade Representative, won overwhelming congressional approval of the Tokyo Round agreements. This was a triumph of both substance and polit- ical process: an important set of trade liberalizing agreements, endorsed through an innovative “fast-track” process that balanced the executive need for negotiating leeway with congressional determination to act explicitly on the results. And it was accompanied by substantial improvement in the nonoil merchandise trade balance. Both the substance of trade policy and the process of executive- congressional collaboration would be sorely tested in the 1980s. During the first Reagan administration, a mix of tight money and loose budgets drove the dollar skyward and sent international balances awry. The merchandise trade deficit rose above $100 billion in 1984, there to remain through the decade (see table 8.1). The ratio of U.S. imports to exports peaked at 1.64 in 1986, a disproportion not seen since the War between the States.
    [Show full text]
  • Balance Trade
    SECTION 2 • CHAPTER 4 Balance trade In this Oct. 18, 2011 photo, crew members look on as containers are offloaded from the cargo ship Stadt Rotenburg at Port Everglades in Fort Lauderdale. AP PHOTO/WILFREDO LEE oods and services trade—exports plus imports—now account for nearly one-third of overall U.S. economic Gactivity,2 meaning trade’s importance to the economy has never been greater. The United States is the world’s largest exporter,3 with exports directly supporting an estimated 9.7 million jobs.4 At the same time, the United States is also the world’s largest importer, and herein lies the problem. Over the past 30 years, our trade balance has been shifting in the wrong direction—toward more imports than exports—and reached a $560 billion deficit in 2012.5 While imports can be a boon to U.S. economic ing also carry offsetting costs, including job productivity and American living standards, losses domestically. Second, in order to pay providing consumers and business with for the imports from abroad that exceed U.S. access to a larger variety of goods and ser- exports, the U.S. economy must balance this vices at lower costs than would otherwise be trade deficit by selling assets—stocks, bonds, the case, there is also a price to pay. and other assets such as companies and real estate—to overseas purchasers. Mounting trade deficits present two key problems for the U.S. economy. First, the Our trade imbalance has resulted from a economic benefits made possible by import- number of factors.
    [Show full text]
  • Asean Statistical Yearbook 2020 Yearbook Statistical Asean Asean Statistical Yearbook 2020
    ASEAN STATISTICAL YEARBOOK 2020 ASEAN STATISTICAL YEARBOOK 2020 ASEAN: A Community of Opportunities for All ASEAN STATISTICAL YEARBOOK 2020 The ASEAN Secretariat Jakarta The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) was established on 8 August 1967. The Member States are Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, Indonesia, Lao PDR, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Viet Nam. The ASEAN Secretariat is based in Jakarta, Indonesia. For inquiries, contact: The ASEAN Secretariat Community Relations Division (CRD) 70A Jalan Sisingamangaraja Jakarta 12110, Indonesia Phone: (62 21) 724-3372, 726-2991 Fax: (62 21) 739-8234, 724-3504 E-mail: [email protected] Catalogue-in-Publication Data ASEAN Statistical Yearbook 2020 Jakarta, ASEAN Secretariat, December 2020 315.9 1. ASEAN – Statistics 2. Demography – Economic Growth – Social Indicators ISBN 978-623-6945-04-9 ASEAN: A Community of Opportunities for All The text of this publication may be freely quoted or reprinted, provided proper acknowledgement is given and a copy containing the reprinted material is sent to the Community Relations Division (CRD) of the ASEAN Secretariat, Jakarta. General information on ASEAN appears online at the ASEAN Website: www.asean.org Copyright Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) 2020. All rights reserved. The map in this publication is only indicative and is not drawn to scale. FOREWORD The ASEAN Statistical Yearbook is one of the ASEAN Secretariat’s most established publications since it was first released in 2002. Now in its 16th edition, the ASEAN Statistical Yearbook 2020 continues to provide accurate, timely, and reliable time series data on social and economic progress in the region. The ASEAN Statistical Yearbook 2020 covers data for the period of 2010-2019 comprising of sections on ASEAN population, education, health, employment, macroeconomic performance, trade in goods and services, foreign direct investment, transport, tourism, agriculture, manufacturing, and other socio-economic indicators.
    [Show full text]
  • TOMEŠ - JANDOVÁ: Political Economy of Trade Policy
    TOMEŠ - JANDOVÁ: Political Economy of Trade Policy POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TRADE POLICY Zdeněk Tomeš, Monika Jandová Abstract The paper deals with an explanation of the trade policy paradox which is a contrast between international trade theory and the reality of trade policy. The vast majority of economic schools of thought have realized general benefits of free trade. The advantages of free trade have been known from economic theory for more than two centuries. However the reality of trade policy is governed by various forms of protectionism. The protectionism has spread worldwide, in both developed and developing countries. In the first chapter of this paper, we sketch out the development of international trade theory from mercantilism to current economic theory. The second part is devoted to real trade policy of the most important economic centres of the world, i.e. the EU, the United States and Japan, and developing countries as well. We illustrate a practical contravening of the generally shared theoretical approach to trade policy on these examples. The most visible protectionist examples are the CAP in the EU, antidumping laws in the USA, non-tariff barriers in Japan and open protectionism in many developing countries. We offer four possible explanations of this situation: the discrimination of foreigners, invisibility of benefit from free trade, the pressure of interest groups and the turn to rigidity. Introduction The defence of the free trade principle is an integral part of general economic theory. It is one of a few areas that almost all economists agree on. On the other hand, the reality of trade policy is completely different and even in countries with relatively liberal economic policy there are many examples of flagrant contravening of the free trade principle.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of Trade and Tariffs on the United States FISCAL FACT Erica York No
    The Impact of Trade and Tariffs on the United States FISCAL FACT Erica York No. 595 Analyst June 2018 Key Findings • Trade barriers such as tariffs raise prices and reduce available quantities of goods and services for U.S. businesses and consumers, which results in lower income, reduced employment, and lower economic output. • Measures of trade flows, such as the trade balance, are accounting identities and should not be misunderstood to be indicators of economic health. Production and exchange – regardless of the balance on the current account – generate wealth. • Since the end of World War II, the world has largely moved away from protectionist trade policies toward a rules-based, open trading system. Post-war trade liberalization has led to widespread benefits, including higher income levels, lower prices, and greater consumer choice. • Openness to trade and investment has substantially contributed to U.S. growth, but the U.S. still maintains duties against several categories of goods. The highest tariffs are concentrated on agriculture, textiles, and footwear. • The Trump administration has enacted tariffs on imported solar panels, washing machines, steel, and aluminum, plans to impose tariffs on Chinese imports, and is investigating further tariffs on Chinese imports and The Tax Foundation is the nation’s automobile imports. leading independent tax policy research organization. Since 1937, our research, analysis, and experts have informed smarter tax policy • The effects of each tariff will be lower GDP, wages, and employment in the at the federal, state, and local levels. We are a 501(c)(3) nonprofit long run. The tariffs will also make the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Topic 12: the Balance of Payments Introduction We Now Begin Working Toward Understanding How Economies Are Linked Together at the Macroeconomic Level
    Topic 12: the balance of payments Introduction We now begin working toward understanding how economies are linked together at the macroeconomic level. The first task is to understand the international accounting concepts that will be essential to understanding macroeconomic aggregate data. The kinds of questions to pose: ◦ How are national expenditure and income related to international trade and financial flows? ◦ What is the current account? Why is it different from the trade deficit or surplus? Which one should we care more about? Does a trade deficit really mean something negative for welfare? ◦ What are the primary factors determining the current-account balance? ◦ How are an economy’s choices regarding savings, investment, and government expenditure related to international deficits or surpluses? ◦ What is the “balance of payments”? ◦ And how does all of this relate to changes in an economy’s net international wealth? Motivation When was the last time the United States had a surplus on the balance of trade in goods? The following chart suggests that something (or somethings) happened in the late 1990s and early 2000s to make imports grow faster than exports (except in recessions). Candidates? Trade-based stories: ◦ Big increase in offshoring of production. ◦ China entered WTO. ◦ Increases in foreign unfair trade practices? Macro/savings-based stories: ◦ US consumption rose fast (and savings fell) relative to GDP. ◦ US began running larger government budget deficits. ◦ Massive net foreign purchases of US assets (net capital inflows). ◦ Maybe it’s cyclical (note how US deficit falls during recessions – why?). US trade balance in goods, 1960-2016 ($ bllions). Note: 2017 = -$796 b and 2018 projected = -$877 b Closed-economy macro basics Before thinking about how a country fits into the world, recall the basic concepts in a country that does not trade goods or assets (so again it is in “autarky” but we call it a closed economy).
    [Show full text]
  • China's Economic Ties with ASEAN: a Country
    March 17, 2015 China’s Economic Ties with ASEAN: A Country-by-Country Analysis Nargiza Salidjanova, Senior Analyst, Economics and Trade and Iacob Koch-Weser, Former Policy Analyst, Economics and Trade with Jason Klanderman, Former Research Intern Disclaimer: This paper is the product of professional research performed by staff of the U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission, and was prepared at the request of the Commission to support its deliberations. Posting of the report to the Commission’s website is intended to promote greater public understanding of the issues addressed by the Commission in its ongoing assessment of U.S.- China economic relations and their implications for U.S. security, as mandated by Public Law 106-398 and Public Law 108-7. However, the public release of this document does not necessarily imply an endorsement by the Commission, any individual Commissioner, or the Commission’s other professional staff, of the views or conclusions expressed in this staff research report. Table of Contents Executive Summary....................................................................................................................................................3 Overview of ASEAN-China Economic Relations ......................................................................................................4 Trade .......................................................................................................................................................................4 Foreign Investment .................................................................................................................................................6
    [Show full text]
  • Taxes and Offshore Outsourcing
    = &=*8=&3)= ++8-47*= :984:7(.3,= 43&1)= _= &751*8= 5*(.&1.89=.3= :'1.(=.3&3(*= &3:&7>=-*`=,**3= 43,7*88.43&1= *8*&7(-=*7;.(*= 18/1**= <<<_(78_,4;= -,/21= =*5479=+47=43,7*88 Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress &=*8=&3)= ++8-47*= :984:7(.3,= = :22&7>= The impact of taxes on international trade and investment has been debated for decades. Most recently, a variety of bills addressing international taxation were introduced in the 110th Congress—some would have cut taxes for U.S. firms overseas, while others would have increased taxes on foreign investment. The debate over taxes and foreign outsourcing has tended to grow more heated during times of domestic economic weakness and high unemployment; questions arise over whether taxes contribute to such weakness by discouraging exports (or encouraging imports) or by encouraging U.S. firms to move abroad. The debate over international taxation has again become prominent as a part of the wider debate over “outsourcing.” With taxes, the debate asks how the current system affects outsourcing, and whether policies designed to limit the phenomenon might be desirable. The precise meaning of the term “outsourcing” varies, depending on the context. In one usage, outsourcing simply refers to the use by domestic firms of inputs produced by other firms. Other usages, however, refer exclusively to the international sector. The analysis in this report focuses on two types of such “offshore” outsourcing: the use by domestic firms of imported foreign inputs, including both the use of foreign technical services and the use of foreign-made goods; and the shifting by U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Expansion and the Balance of Trade: the Role of Aggregate Demand Elasticity
    St. John Fisher College Fisher Digital Publications Economics Faculty/Staff Publications Economics Fall 2014 Economic Expansion and the Balance of Trade: The Role of Aggregate Demand Elasticity Ben L. Kyer Francis Marion University, [email protected] Gary E. Maggs St. John Fisher College, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://fisherpub.sjfc.edu/economics_facpub Part of the Economics Commons How has open access to Fisher Digital Publications benefited ou?y Publication Information Kyer, Ben L. and Maggs, Gary E. (2014). "Economic Expansion and the Balance of Trade: The Role of Aggregate Demand Elasticity." American Economist 59.2, 176-181. Please note that the Publication Information provides general citation information and may not be appropriate for your discipline. To receive help in creating a citation based on your discipline, please visit http://libguides.sjfc.edu/citations. This document is posted at https://fisherpub.sjfc.edu/economics_facpub/3 and is brought to you for free and open access by Fisher Digital Publications at St. John Fisher College. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Economic Expansion and the Balance of Trade: The Role of Aggregate Demand Elasticity Abstract This paper investigates the role of aggregate demand elasticity for the balance of trade when economic expansion occurs. Our conclusions are two. First, when an economic expansion results from an increase of aggregate demand, the balance of trade deficit is larger the less elastic is aggregate demand with respect to the general price level. Second, when an economic expansion happens from an increase of short-run aggregate supply, the price level elasticity of aggregate demand determines both the direction of change of the balance of trade and the size of the resulting deficit or surplus.
    [Show full text]
  • World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division
    Staff Working Paper ERSD-2012-23 Date: 13 November 2012 World Trade Organization Economic Research and Statistics Division Trade Imbalances and Multilateral Trade Cooperation Juan Marchetti Michele Ruta Robert Teh World Trade Organization Manuscript date: 13 November 2012 ___________________________ Disclaimer: This is a working paper, and hence it represents research in progress. This paper represents the opinions of the author(s), and is the product of professional research. It is not meant to represent the position or opinions of the WTO or its Members, nor the official position of any staff members. Any errors are the fault of the author(s). Copies of working papers can be requested from the divisional secretariat by writing to: Economic Research and Statistics Division, World Trade Organization, Rue de Lausanne 154, CH 1211 Geneva 21, Switzerland. Please request papers by number and title. Trade Imbalances and Multilateral Trade Cooperation by Juan Marchetti World Trade Organization 154 rue de Lausanne Geneva, Switzerland Email: [email protected] Michele Ruta World Trade Organization 154 rue de Lausanne Geneva, Switzerland Email: [email protected] Robert Teh World Trade Organization 154 rue de Lausanne Geneva, Switzerland Email: [email protected] ¶ The opinions expressed herein are the sole responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the members of the WTO or of the WTO Secretariat. Abstract Rising current account and merchandise trade imbalances marked the years before the global financial and economic crisis. These imbalances either contributed to or precipitated the crisis and to the extent that they create systemic risks, it is desirable that they be reduced.
    [Show full text]
  • The Effects of Offshoring on Trade in Services. Evidence from Romania
    The Effects of Offshoring on Trade in Services. Evidence from Romania Agnes Ghibutiu* Irina Dumitriu** Abstract Relying on insights from theoretical and empirical contributions on the issue of services offshoring, the paper explores the possible effects of offshoring on Romania’s trade in services, by looking at its evolution during the 1995-2006 period in terms of dynamics, composition and balance. Given the multiple shortcomings of both statistical data and instruments available currently for tracing and measuring offshoring activities, the paper adopts a three-tier approach – based on official trade statistics, official FDI data and additional information from different private sources – to find evidence for enhanced services offshoring in Romania. The results of the empirical investigation underpin our assumption that the remarkable growth rates of exports in some individual services categories and the positive changes emerging in the patterns of Romania’s trade in services are largely attributable to intense offshoring activities associated with the growing presence of TNCs in the Romanian economy. Concurrently, the findings of the paper confirm that anecdotal evidence on the country’s rising attractiveness for offshored services is supported by official statistics, even though the interpretation of the final results remains subject to caveats. An examination of the current and future potential of Romania as location for services offshoring in the European and global context is closing our discussion, followed by conclusions and some policy considerations. Key words: trade in services, FDI, offshoring, Romania JEL classification: F14, F21, F23, L80 * Senior research fellow, Institute of World Economy, Bucharest. E-mail: [email protected] ** Business consultant and associated professor, Academy of Economic Studies, Bucharest.
    [Show full text]
  • The Situation of Trade Relation Between Vietnam and ASEAN
    The situation of trade relation between Vietnam and ASEAN Nhung Thi Thai In 1988, a year before the Soviet Union collapsed, the 13th National Congress of the Communist Party of Vietnam adopted a resolution to have ‘more friends and fewer enemies’. So it was not surprising when Vietnam expressed interest in joining ASEAN as early as 1992, or when it did in fact join in July 1995. Joining ASEAN had crucial social, political, economic and security implications for Vietnam. Vietnam’s membership of the grouping integrated its security with the whole of Southeast Asia and created a favourable environment for economic development. This, in turn, raised Vietnam’s global image, leading to increased cooperation with multiple players in the region and greater bargaining clout with super powers like the United States and China.5 Vietnam has undertaken domestic changes to integrate itself with the grouping. The country has gradually restructured its administrative apparatus to suit a market economy. A year after joining ASEAN it reorganized its bureaucracy by creating a National ASEAN Committee, to be headed by the deputy prime minister. This body is responsible for coordinating all the institutions that interact with ASEAN or ASEAN-affiliated bodies. It also established an ASEAN Department in its Foreign Ministry.5 In a result, the success of Vietnam – ASEAN relationship is reflected in the growth of Vietnam–ASEAN trade. According to Nhan Dan Online, trade between Vietnam and ASEAN countries sees steady growth.4 1. Exports Exports in Vietnam averaged 4763.88 USD Million from 1990 until 2016, reaching an all time high of 14481 USD Million in August of 2015 and a record low of 537 USD Million in February of 1997.2 Specific export value in Vietnam is reported by the General Statistics Office of Vietnam as Figure 1.
    [Show full text]