Historical Materialism Joshua Cohen

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Historical Materialism Joshua Cohen On the Track of Reason Essays in Honor of Kai Nielsen ___ EDITED BY Rodger Beehler, David Copp, and Bela Szabados Itjj fa us/ -:5 'A~ Westview Press \I-" BOULDER * SAN FRANCISCO * OXFORD I 10 Minimalist Historical Materialism Joshua Cohen Drawing on an Enlightenment tradition of historical sociology, Karl Marx proposed a comprehensive theory of historical evolution with optim- istic implications for the future course of that evolution.' What, if anything, is living in that theory and in the Enlightenment project it exemplifies? A principal attraction of G. A. Cohen's reconstruction of historical materialism lies in its contribution to addressing this question. 2 Self-con- sciously "old-fashioned" (Theory, p. x), Cohen's account of Marxism rep- resents a sharp departure from the tradition of Western Marxism inspired by Georg Lukacs's History and Class Consciousness. Where LukAcs had argued that Marxism is fundamentally a matter of method- the dialectical method of affirming "the all-pervasive supremacy of the whole over the parts"3 -Cohen has emphasized the substantive content of Marxism, locating the "materialist theory of history" at its center. 4 According to Cohen's technological interpretation,historical materialism is animated by an optimistic vision of the broad patterns of social and political evolution. It seeks to explain those patterns by reference to the scarcity-reducing transformations of the "built environment" brought about by human labor5, and to the implications of those transformations for the structure of social order. And, drawing its prognoses from this explanation of the historical patterns, it predicts liberation from toil and from the social adversity consequent on the need for toil. In a nutshell, then, historical materialism embraces four principal contentions: Development Thesis: Human productive power tends to increase over time.6 Social Adaptation Thesis: Social arrangements "rise and fall" according to their contribution to the expansion of productive power. Abundance Thesis: The material adversity that humanity has faced throughout its (pre)history will eventually be overcome. Good Society Thesis: Because "social adversity [is a consequence of material adversity" (History, p. vii), the social adversity that we have faced throughout our (pre)history will eventually be overcome. 156 Joshua Cohen Minimalist HistoricalMaterialism 157 In the course of elaborating and defending this technological interpre- 7 interpretation of the notion tation of historical materialism, Cohen has also suggested some "refor- of fettering that makes two ideas at least ini- tially plausible (History, pp. mulations" of historical materialism designed to address his own "reser- 109-110): (1) class societies will eventually fetter the forces of production; vations" about it (History, p. viii). I agree that the reservations are serious and (2) such fettering will result in a revo- lutionary transformation of the and propose here to examine the reformulations prompted by them. I relations of production. Proceeding from these requirements, Cohen will argue that the reformulated technological interpretation of historical rejects a conception of fettering in which social relations fetter productive materialism, even if true, does not have much power to explain historical forces just in case they cause absolute stagnation in productive development.' 2 change and does not lend much support to optimistic expectations about Instead he advances a relative 8 interpretation of fettering in the future course of social adversity. I do not claim that it is inconsistent which the existing relations fetter the forces when the forces do less with or irrelevant to more substantive historical theorizing with well than they would under an alternative set of opti- relations. mistic implications but rather that it is largely indeterminate Skipping interesting details about the role of static and dynam- and that the ic considerations interest of historical materialism is correspondingly diminished. in the interpretation of "do less well," we arrive at the proposal that the forces are fettered when I conclude that the technological interpretation of historical material- "the trajectory of output levels is less high than it could be" ism has, once more, reached a dead end. Human beings and our social (History, p. 119). When it is, a new system of property relations emerges that promotes world could be such that determinate material conditions impose inter- the higher trajectory. As Cohen points out (History, p. estingly tight constraints on forms of social order. But the problems of 119), the content and the explanatory power of the claim that formulating a plausible theory that expresses this idea suggest property relations adapt to the requirement of that we inducing the highest are not and it is not. If the Enlightenment project of optimism-supporting trajectory of output levels depend on the explication of the notion of a "trajectory historical theorizing can be sustained at all, it needs richer foundations of output levels." He suggests that the rele- vant notion of output may than are provided by the central idea of the technological interpretation: not be captured best by the idea of gross national product and may require instead a that human social relations must adjust to accommodate the growth in more "strongly qualitative" human productive power.9 conception of the "standard of living" (History, pp. 120-21).13 Reformulated to accommodate this proposal, historical materialism would hold that social relations fetter the productive forces and so can be Indeterminacy I: Fettering expected to be replaced when they generate a lower standard of living- a less good The historical materialist project is to explain the "way of life" (History, p. 121)--than some alternative set of evolution of social relations.' 4 interaction by reference to changes in the material constraints on such This "standard-of-living" interaction. Cohen has proposed two main reformulations of historical conception of fettering has one central virtue. By affirming that property materialism, each with important implications for this project. The first, relations change when their change is required for inmmediately addressed to Marx's notion of "fettering,"10 speaks general- a better way of life, it incorporates the optimistic expecta- tions of historical ly to the question How should we characterize the evolving material con- materialism directly into the formulation of the theory. But it also faces two difficulties. First, its straints (the expanding productive power) to which social interaction content is not at all clear and its consequences must adapt? The second, which suggests restrictions on the explanatory for historical materialism as a framework of historical explanation are correspondingly ambition of historical materialism,1i speaks to the question ust how con- uncertain. Second, it suggests, without much elaboration, an account of straining on the forms of social order are the material foundations of history whose main thrust is significant- ly different from the specifically social interaction? In this section I will briefly discuss the former, technological interpretation of historical and in materialism. Here the next section I will examine the latter in some detail. I will focus on the first of these concerns, postponing discussion of the second until 5 Elaborating the Social Adaptation Thesis, historical materialism the concluding section of the chapter.s Putting to the side important questions claims that the pattern of control over productive resources ("the social about the discount rate to be applied to future improvements in relations of production," or "property relations") changes when the evaluating alternative trajectories of output, we face two existing pattern of control impedes or imposes "fetters" on productive issues in understanding and assessing the standard- development. How is the idea of fettering to be interpreted? Given the ot-living conception o tettenng. n tne first place, there are issues about the interpretation of the notion background commitments of historical materialism, what is needed is an of an improvement in an individual's standard of living. For example, does more work and more pay represent 158 JoshuaCohen Minimalist HistoricalMaterialism 15V an improvement in standard of living? Because historical materialism Indeterminacy II: The Scope of Explanation'6 does not suppose that the preferences of individuals settle this question, We come now to the second reformulation. Cohen distinguishes two how are these issues to be interpreted? Second, we need a way to evalu- within the Marxist tradition associated with different answers ate the standard of living under alternative distributionsof advantage, an tendencies to the question How much does historical materialism need to explain? issue that is particularly important in view of the conflict-ridden charac- An inclusive tendency seeks materialist explanations for as wide a range of social change. For example, does a society have a higher standard ter of social phenomena as possible. By contrast, the restrictive tendency- of living if it has a higher average level of advantage, even if it also is asso- r - * < _ ... - and, in particular, the minimalist refinement of it that I will eventually ciated with a greater dispersion of advantage? Or a higher sum of advan- focus on-travels light. Less ambitious in its explanatory claims, mini- tage, even if the average is lower?
Recommended publications
  • Do Theorists of History Have a Theory of History? Reflections on a Non-Discipline
    HISTÓRIA DA Ouro Preto / MG - Brasil HISTORIOGRAFIA Do Theorists of History Have a Theory of History? Reflections on a Non-Discipline Os teóricos da História possuem uma Teoria da História? Reflexões sobre uma não disciplina Zoltán Boldizsár Simon https://orcid.org/0000-0001-8763-7415 ABSTRACT This brief article is a discussion-starter on the question of the role and use of theories and philosophies of history. RESUMO In the last few decades, theories of history typically intended to transform the practice of historical studies Este breve artigo faz uma discussão inicial sobre o papel through a straightforward application of their insights. e o uso de teorias e filosofias da história. Nas últimas Contrary to this, I argue that they either bring about décadas, as teorias da história em geral pretenderam particular historiographical innovations in terms of transformar a prática dos estudos históricos por meio methodology but leave the entirety of historical studies de uma aplicação direta de seus insights. Em vez disso, intact or change the way we think about the entirety argumento que essas teorias ou trazem inovações of historical studies merely by describing and explaining historiográficas particulares em termos de metodologia, it in fresh and novel ways, without the need (and mas deixam a totalidade dos estudos históricos intactos, possibility) of application. In the former case, theories ou transformam a maneira como nós pensamos sobre appear as internal to historical studies. In the latter case, a totalidade dos estudos históricos apenas descrevendo they appear as theories about history, and such theories e explicando-os através de formas novas e inovadoras, are no longer limited to study history understood as sem a necessidade (e possibilidade) de aplicação.
    [Show full text]
  • Yale University Department of Political Science Syllabus THE
    Yale University Department of Political Science Syllabus THE PHILOSOPHY, HISTORY, AND SOCIOLOGY OF INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS (Seminar) Nuno P. Monteiro Office: Rosenkranz 226, Tuesdays 2:00‐4:00 [email protected] Class: Rosenkranz 202, Tuesdays, 9:20‐11:10 Spring 2010 PLSC 193/671 COURSE OBJECTIVES This seminar explores the philosophical foundations of the study of international relations, as well as the history and sociology of the discipline. We’ll cover the historical development of IR as a professional discipline since the interwar period, going over the main foundational debates that organized the field, and addressing its sociological evolution. By the end of the course, students should have an understanding of the main meta‐theoretical issues in the discipline and thus be able to enlarge their toolkit to critically engage scholarship in IR, political science, and the social sciences more broadly. COURSE OUTLINE The course covers the historical evolution of IR as a professional discipline from the meta‐theoretical perspective. As the field evolves, we’ll look at the development of the philosophical foundations of IR scholarship, covering the main positions in it and addressing the main criticisms of each. Finally, we’ll study the sociology of IR, interrogating the ways in which scholarship is produced and the field is structured and disciplined. REQUIREMENTS, GRADING, AND DEADLINES Basic knowledge of IR theory is a plus. The course will consist in a series of seminar sessions with pre‐assigned readings. Students are expected to do all the readings prior to each session, as well as attend and participate in all sessions.
    [Show full text]
  • Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School
    Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School Ralph Raico Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Preface by David Gordon LvMI MISES INSTITUTE The cover design by Chad Parish shows the Neptune Fountain, at the Schönbrunn Palace, in Vienna. Copyright © 2012 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute. Permission to reprint in whole or in part is gladly granted, provided full credit is given. Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 mises.org ISBN: 978-1-61016-003-2 Dedicated to the memory of the great Ludwig von Mises Table of Contents Foreword by Jörg Guido Hülsmann . ix Preface by David Gordon . xiii Introduction . .xxv 1. Classical Liberalism and the Austrian School . .1 2. Liberalism: True and False . .67 3. Intellectuals and the Marketplace. 111 4. Was Keynes a Liberal? . .149 5. The Conflict of Classes: Liberal vs. Marxist Theories. .183 6. The Centrality of French Liberalism . .219 7. Ludwig von Mises’s Liberalism on Fascism, Democracy, and Imperalism . .255 8. Eugen Richter and the End of German Liberalism. .301 9. Arthur Ekirch on American Militarism . .331 Index. .339 vii Foreword “History looks backward into the past, but the lesson it teaches concerns things to come. It does not teach indolent quietism; it rouses man to emulate the deeds of earlier generations.” Ludwig von Mises1 The present book contains a collection of essays written through- out the past twenty years. I read virtually all of them when they were first published. They have been a central part of my education in the history of liberalism and of the Austrian School of economics, and I consider myself privileged indeed to have encountered Professor Raico and his work early on in my intellectual development.
    [Show full text]
  • Tensions Between Theory and History in Von Mises’S Critique of Socialism
    Revista de Economia Contemporânea (2018) 22(2): p. 1-23 (Journal of Contemporary Economics) ISSN 1980-5527 http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/198055272221 elocation - e182221 www.ie.ufrj.br/revista | www.scielo.br/rec TENSIONS BETWEEN THEORY AND HISTORY IN VON MISES’S CRITIQUE OF SOCIALISM Emmanoel Boffa aProfessor da Universidade Federal Fluminense (UFF). Manuscript received on 2017/06/13 and accepted for publication on 2018/03/13.1 ABSTRACT: The article investigates the relation between praxeology and history in the critique Mises directs at the possibility of the long-term existence of a socialist commonwealth. We argue that Mises makes no clear distinction between the praxeological concept of 'private property' (associated with the possession of means of production) and the historical concept of the ideal-type 'private property' (associated to property rights – see HODGSON, 2015). The lack of precision between the theoretical and the historical concepts of private property prevents Mises’s critique from being an 'exact law', as he would have it. Finally, we show in the last section the consequences for Mises’s critique of socialism of having a historical and a praxeological concept of private property. KEYWORDS: Mises; socialism; socialist calculation; critique. JEL CODE: B13, B14, B15. Corresponding Author: Emmanoel Boff Contact: [email protected] All the contents of this journal, except where otherwise noted, is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution Rev. Econ. Contemp., v. 22, n. 2, p. 1 -23, mai./ago. 2018: e182221 1 DOI: 10.1590/198055272221 License. BOFF, E. Tensions between theory and history in von mises’s critique of socialism TENSÕES ENTRE TEORIA E HISTÓRIA NA CRÍTICA DE VON MISES AO SOCIALISMO RESUMO: O artigo investiga a relação entre a praxeologia e a história na crítica que von Mises dirige à possibilidade da existência de socialismo no longo prazo.
    [Show full text]
  • Mises, Ludwig
    THEORY AND HISTORY An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution Copyright 1985 by Margit von Mises. All rights reserved. No portion of this book may be reproduced without written permission of the publisher by Ludwig von Mises (Auburn: AL, The Mises Institute), except by a reviewer who may quote brief passages in connection with a review. with new preface by Murray N. Rothbard Copyright 1957 by Yale University Press. Reprinted 1969 by Arlington House, Publishes, in an unaltered and unabridged edition. THE LUDWIG VON MISES INSTITUTE This online edition, The Mises Institute 2001, has retained the pagination Auburn, Alabama of the 1985 edition (Auburn: The Mises Institute) and the original 1957 www.mises.org edition (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press) for purposes of citation. Contents CHAPTER 3. THE QUEST FOR ABSOLUTE VALUES 9. The Issue (p. 35) Preface by Murray N. Rothbard (p. xi) 10. Conflicts with Society (p. 37) 11. A Remark on the Alleged Medieval Unanimity (p. 42) 12. The Idea of Natural Law (p. 44) INTRODUCTION 13. Revelation (p. 49) 1. Methodological Dualism (p. 1) 14. Atheistic Intuition (p. 50) 1. Economics and Metaphysics (p. 3) 15. The Idea of Justice (p. 51) 2. Regularity and Prediction (p. 4) 16. The Utilitarian Doctrine Restated (p. 55) 3. The Concept of the Laws of Nature (p. 5) 17. On Aesthetic Values (p. 61) 4. The Limitations of Human Knowledge (p. 8) 18. The Historical Significance of the Quest for Absolute Values (p. 5. Regularity and Choosing (p. 9) 63) 6. Means and Ends (p. 12) CHAPTER 4.
    [Show full text]
  • Notes and Recollections the Liberty Fund Library of the Works of Ludwig Von Mises Edited by Bettina Bien Greaves
    notes and recollections The Liberty Fund Library of the Works of Ludwig von Mises edited by bettina bien greaves The Anti-capitalistic Mentality Bureaucracy Economic Freedom and Interventionism: An Anthology of Articles and Essays Economic Policy: Thoughts for Today and Tomorrow Epistemological Problems of Economics Human Action: A Treatise on Economics Interventionism: An Economic Analysis Liberalism: The Classical Tradition Money, Method, and the Market Process Nation, State, and Economy: Contributions to the Politics and History of Our Time Notes and Recollections: With The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics Omnipotent Government: The Rise of the Total State and Total War On the Manipulation of Money and Credit: Three Treatises on Trade-Cycle Theory Planning for Freedom: Let the Market System Work A Collection of Essays and Addresses Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution The Theory of Money and Credit The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science: An Essay on Method edited by richard m. ebeling Selected Writings of Ludwig von Mises Volume 1: Monetary and Economic Policy Problems Before, During, and After the Great War Volume 2: Between the Two World Wars: Monetary Disorder, Interventionism, Socialism, and the Great Depression Volume 3: The Political Economy of International Reform and Reconstruction ludwig von mises Notes and Recollections With The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics ludwig von mises Edited and with a Preface by Bettina Bien Greaves L liberty fund Indianapolis This book is published by Liberty Fund, Inc., a foundation established to encourage study of the ideal of a society of free and responsible individuals.
    [Show full text]
  • Positivism, Natural Law and Conjectural History in Seventeenth- and Eighteenth-Century English Legal Thought
    Michael Lobban Theory in history: positivism, natural law and conjectural history in seventeenth- and eighteenth-century English legal thought Book section Original citation: Originally published in Del Mar, Maksymilian and Lobban, Michael, (eds.) Law in Theory and History: New Essays on a Neglected Dialogue. Hart Publishing, Oxford, UK. ISBN 9781849467995 © 2016 Hart Publishing This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/69172/ Available in LSE Research Online: January 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s submitted version of the book section. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. 12 Theory in History: Positivism, Natural law and Conjectural History in Seventeenth- and Eighteenth- Century English Legal Thought Michael Lobban Contemporary jurisprudence can be very tribal. Rival schools compete with each other to show that they have the best answers to fundamental questions about the nature of law and legal reasoning.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Theory of Bureaucracy: Insights from the Niskanian Model and the Misesian Approach
    THE QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF AUSTRIAN ECONOMICS 12, NO. 3 (2009): 57–78 THE ECONOMIC THEORY OF BUREAUCRACY: INSIGHTS FROM THE NISKANIAN MODEL AND THE MISESIAN APPROACH LAURENT A.H. CARNIS1 ABSTRACT: Governmental interventions in the economy take numerous forms, and they require the existence of a public authority, a bureaucracy, to implement them. This article pro- poses an analysis of the origins and the dynamics of bureaucracy, and discusses means of escaping bureaucracy’s disadvantages. I will proceed by means of a comparison between the theories of Niskanen and Mises, two impressive and very representative works from the Public Choice School and the Austrian School of economics. Although Mises and Niskanen share a common analy- sis of the defect of bureaucratic management, there are strong disagreements between the two authors about the reasons for the existence of bureaus and about their functioning and their defi- ciencies. Inevitably, the means proposed by Niskanen and Mises for escaping the disadvantages of bureaucracy are different and can not be reconciled. Laurent A.H. Carnis ([email protected]) is a transport economist for the French National Institute for Transport and Safety Research (INRETS). He is also associate researcher with CES, Sorbonne Economic Center, University of Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne. The author is solely responsible for ideas developed in this paper, and they in no way reflect upon INRETS. The author thanks Nicolai Gertchev and Gabriel Giménez Roche for their assistance to improve the English version of this article, Katarina Zajc, Sanford Ikeda and the attendees of the Mises Seminar organized by the Istituto Bruno Leoni in Sestri Levante for their comments on the comparison of Niskanian and Misesian models of bureaucracy.
    [Show full text]
  • Ludwig Von Mises
    Economic Insights FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS VOLUME 6, NUMBER 4 Ludwig von Mises This Economic Insights features one of Ludwig Elder von Mises’ life was Fritz Machlup, Oskar Morgenstern and testament to the saying that one man Lionel Robbins. the free economy’s most famous intellectual with courage makes a majority. Between his departure from Vienna warriors, Ludwig von Mises. Working from Mises was born in 1881 in in 1934 and his decision to go to America Lemberg, Austria-Hungary. He enrolled after the Germans breached the Maginot within the Austrian paradigm, in 1912 Mises in the University of Vienna in 1900 and Line in June 1940, Mises taught in became the first to apply marginal utility theory received his doctorate in law and eco- Geneva at the Graduate Institute of Inter- nomics in 1906. A student of Eugen von national Studies. He flourished in the to money itself, in The Theory of Money and Böhm-Bawerk—himself an admirer of Swiss city and was very reluctant to Credit, his first major work. He triggered one of Carl Menger, father of the Austrian school leave, especially as his English was much of economics—Mises became one of weaker than his French. But the fall of economics’ most contentious and enlightening the university’s most prominent figures. France, the antipathy of the Nazi gov- debates a few years later with his claim that cen- After graduating, Mises worked for the ernment—which blacklisted him—and Vienna Chamber of Commerce as an his wife Margit’s pleadings made his tral planning, regardless of its undesirability on economist and economic advisor to the departure a near certainty.
    [Show full text]
  • Epistemological Problems of Economics
    EPISTEMOLOGICAL PROBLEMS OF ECONOMICS THIRD EDITION Ludwig von Mises Translated by George Reisman Introduction to the Third Edition by Jörg Guido Hülsmann Grundprobleme der Nationalökonomie: Untersuchungen über Verfahren, Aufgaben und Inhalt der Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftslehre (1933) Epistemological Problems of Economics Translated from the German by George Reisman Published simultaneously in the United States and Canada by D. Van Nostrand Co., 1960 Reprinted 1978 by New York University Press, with Foreword by Ludwig M. Lachmann Copyright © 1976 Institute for Humane Studies Third edition 2003 by Ludwig von Mises Institute Copyright © Bettina Bien Greaves ISBN: 0-945466-36-6 CONTENTS Introduction to the Third Edition . .ix Foreword to the 1978 Edition . .lvii Preface to the English-Language Edition . .lxv Preface to the German Edition . .lxxi 1 THE TASK AND SCOPE OF THE SCIENCE OF HUMAN ACTION . .1 I. The Nature and Development of the Social Sciences . .1 1. Origin in the historical and normative sciences . .1 2. Economics . .3 3. The program of sociology and the quest for historical laws . .4 4. The standpoint of historicism . .5 5. The standpoint of empiricism . .8 6. The logical character of the universally valid science of human action . .13 7. Sociology and economics: Some comments on the history of economic thought . .18 II. The Scope and Meaning of the System of A Priori Theorems . .24 1. The basic concept of action and its categorical conditions . .24 2. A priori theory and empirical confirmation . .28 3. Theory and the facts of experience . .32 4. The distinction between means and ends: The “irrational” . .33 III. Science and Value .
    [Show full text]
  • Theory History Theses
    #THEORYREVOLT THEORYREVOLT.COM THESES ` ON THEORYAND HISTORY WILD ON COLLECTIVE MAY 2018 ETHAN KLEINBERG JOAN WALLACH SCOTT GARY WILDER PROLOGUE: DEDICATED TO CLIO, MUSE OF Sing Clio, daughter of Zeus, Theory’s rage HISTORY at the violations of your charge. You, who told Hesiod, “we know how to speak false things that seem true, but we know when we will, to utter true things.” Now is the time to utter true things, for Theory has been dishonored in your house, displaced by empires of empiricism, fetishism of archives, dictates of discipline, enforcement of orthodoxy, and impotent story-telling. Without Theory, History is naught but tales, told by victors and moralists, signifying nothing beyond themselves. Without Theory, the operations of power and sources of injustice remain mystified, impenetrable to us mortals. Our observations, when limited to description, ill-equip us for the critical thought we so desperately need, even to analyze those repositories of memory that are your charge. O Clio, we enlist your ear. Listen, please, to our voices of rage. With these theses on Theory and History we invite you to sanctify our mission and to commend us to the gods. DISCIPLINARYON THE LIMITSHISTORY OF I.1 Academic history has never managed to transcend its eighteenth century origins as an empiricist enterprise. By this we mean not David Hume’s earlier skeptical approach but the scientistic method intrinsi- cally inked to positivism, which Horkheimer called “modern empiricism” that was later adopted across the human sciences. Academic history remains dedicated to this method of gath- ering facts in order to produce interpretations by referring them to supposedly given contexts and organizing them into chronological narratives.
    [Show full text]
  • Chaos, Clio, and Scientific Illusions of Understanding" (PDF)
    Wesleyan University Chaos, Clio, and Scientific Illusions of Understanding Author(s): Paul A. Roth and Thomas A. Ryckman Reviewed work(s): Source: History and Theory, Vol. 34, No. 1 (Feb., 1995), pp. 30-44 Published by: Blackwell Publishing for Wesleyan University Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2505582 . Accessed: 20/04/2012 19:31 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Blackwell Publishing and Wesleyan University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to History and Theory. http://www.jstor.org CHAOS, CLIO, AND SCIENTISTIC ILLUSIONS OF UNDERSTANDING* PAUL A. ROTH and THOMAS A. RYCKMAN ABSTRACT A number of authors have recently argued that the mathematical insights of "chaos theory" offer a promising formal model or significant analogy for understanding at least some historical events. We examine a representative claim of each kind regarding the application of chaos theory to problems of historical explanation. We identify two lines of argument. One we term the Causal Thesis, which states that chaos theory may be used to plausibly model, and so explain, historical events. The other we term the Convergence Thesis, which holds that, once the analogy between history and chaos theory is properly appreciated, any temptation to divide history from the rest of science should be greatly lessened.
    [Show full text]