THE RIDE Larger, Less Crowded Areas Seeing Faster Growth
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY / SPRING 2019 ENJOYING THE RIDE Larger, less crowded areas seeing faster growth ANNUAL REPORT EDITION Stability and Stewardship Why Is Wage Growth Low? | Diversity and Inclusion Report | New Tenth District Directors TEN MAGAZINE | | SPRING 2019 A FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY / SPRING 2019 FEATURES VOLUME 14 • ISSUE 4 • ISSN 1554-7469 SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT Diane Raley VICE PRESIDENT Krissy Young ASSISTANT VICE PRESIDENT & PRODUCTION ADVISOR Lowell Jones 20 ASSISTANT VICE PRESIDENT & FASTER GROWTH Year-over-year percent change, seasonally adjusted PUBLIC INFORMATION OFFICER Over several years, locations with populations of 500,000 Bill Medley6 to 3 million often grew faster than the national6 rate. EDITOR4 4 Stan Austin MAGAZINE2 DESIGNER 2 Alison Reichert 0 WHY IS WAGE GROWTH0 SO LOW? MANAGING EDITOR Despite continued improvement Rick Babson-2 in labor market -conditions,2 low productivity growth affects CREATIVE DIRECTOR compensation. Angela -Anderson4 12 -4 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013 2016 CONTENT CONTRIBUTORS Real compensation per hour Su Bacon, Gary Barber, Sam Chapman, Cynthia Edwards, David McNeese, Sarah Pope, Marlina Yates DIVERSITY AND INCLUSION In its yearly report to Congress, the RESEARCH CONTRIBUTORS Kansas City Fed outlines how its Jun Nie, Jordan Rappaport, business practices represent the range Willem Van Zandweghe of backgrounds and experiences 30 across the Tenth District. TEN magazine is a quarterly publication of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City focused on the connection between the Bank’s research and the Tenth Federal Reserve District. TEN features articles on the Federal Reserve’s history, structure and operations. The views and opinions expressed in TEN are not 2018 ANNUAL REPORT necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank A detailed look at Bank operations, of Kansas City, the Federal Reserve System, its Tenth District officers, directors, advisory governors, officers or representatives. 34 councils, roundtables and more. TEN articles may be reprinted if the source is credited and the Public Affairs Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City is David Todd, program manager of Metropolitan Area provided with copies. Permission to photocopy ON THE COVER» Projects in Oklahoma City. Photo by David McNeese is unrestricted. Learn more about the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City and the history, leadership and governance of the Federal Reserve System at kansascityfed.org/aboutus. From the President ESTHER L. GEORGE Evaluating our inflation objective Should we be concerned about this low level of inflation? As I listen to business and community ostering a strong labor market while leaders around my region, I hear few complaints maintaining price stability is of course the about inflation being too low. In fact, I am more Fcore of the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate likely to hear disbelief when I mention that from Congress. With the unemployment rate inflation is as low as measured in a number of key at a historically low level and inflation currently sectors. I see this reaction to inflation as a good running just under the Federal Open Market sign, and consider this performance consistent Committee’s (FOMC) objective, a longer-run with the definition of price stability that former policy issue is whether the persistent undershoot Fed chairs Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan of our inflation objective is undermining its preferred. Both of them judged price stability credibility and causing inflation to be anchored as an inflation rate that is sufficiently low (and at too low a level. If inflation expectations fall stable) that it is not considered a key factor in persistently below 2 percent, the extent we could the decisions of businesses or households. lower real interest rates by reducing our nominal target for the funds rate would be diminished. This could limit the accommodation we could provide Even so, I supported the FOMC’s decision if we were to return to the zero lower bound. to adopt a 2 percent longer-run objective for inflation in 2012, and I support it today. I believe At the time the FOMC adopted its 2 percent it has been effective in helping anchor longer- inflation objective in 2012, monetary policy was run inflation expectations. Arguably, though, highly accommodative, unconventional policy tools adopting a point estimate instead of a range were being deployed, and inflation was running has placed considerable attention on a precise above 2 percent. Since then, inflation has run target and has exaggerated the precision with persistently below 2 percent. I have not viewed this which monetary policy can achieve this particular as a major concern given that, aside from the effects numerical target. It would seem reasonable that of wide fluctuations in energy prices, inflation has even somewhat persistent deviations from the remained low and relatively stable. Since 2012, objective, if they are limited to, say 50 basis points core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) above or below the objective may be acceptable, inflation has fluctuated in a range of roughly 1.5 to depending on broader economic conditions. 2 percent, except during 2015 when a strong dollar I also support the idea that the objective should pushed core inflation somewhat below 1.5 percent. be symmetric so that deviations below and above TEN MAGAZINE | | SPRING 2019 1 the objective should be viewed as costly, taking What works in elegant economic models can have into account deviations of employment from our limitations and unintended consequences when put employment objective. Consistent with the FOMC’s into practice. Fundamentally, an effective price-level “Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy target could substantially reduce uncertainty about Strategy,” this suggests that when our objectives are the price level many years into the future and thereby not complementary, we follow a balanced approach in help households and businesses make long-term plans promoting them, taking into account the magnitude and commitments. It also could increase the variability of the deviations and the potentially different time of, and uncertainty about, inflation over the medium horizons over which employment and inflation are term. This is because a price-level target would require projected to return to mandate-consistent levels. In policymakers to engineer an increase in inflation in current circumstances, with an unemployment rate response to the price level falling below its target well below its projected longer-run level, I see little path and engineer a decrease in inflation in response reason to be concerned about inflation running a to the price level rising above the target path. These bit below its longer-run objective. Moreover, I am benefits and costs would need to be carefully weighed. not convinced that a slight undershoot of inflation below objective requires an offsetting overshoot of the objective. As I mentioned earlier, the current benign inflation outlook gives us the opportunity to WHILE I SEE LITTLE VALUE IN PURSUING test our assumptions about the degree of slack in the economy and the level of the natural rate of interest. “ A HIGHER INFLATION TARGET GIVEN Going forward THE CREDIBILITY WE HAVE BUILT OVER As we look ahead, however, there is a legitimate THE LAST DECADE AROUND 2 PERCENT, concern that monetary policy “space” could be limited in the next downturn because of the low level of EVALUATING ALTERNATIVE POLICY interest rates. This has led some to argue for a higher inflation target or the adoption of some kind of a STRATEGIES IS APPROPRIATE. price-level target. While I see little value in pursuing a higher inflation target given the credibility we have ” built over the last decade around 2 percent, evaluating alternative policy strategies is appropriate. Some On a more practical level, there are a number of have promoted the use of a temporary price-level issues to be considered. First, in a price-level targeting target that takes effect when the federal funds rate regime, choosing the base period can make a big target hits the zero bound. Another approach might difference. For example, getting back to a 2 percent be an inflation target that is achieved on average price-level path that was based in a year just prior to over a fixed period of time or over the business cycle. the Great Recession would require a much longer In theory, a price-level target that is fully credible period of above 2 percent inflation than if the base could potentially smooth fluctuations in output and year were set more recently. This is simply because the employment, especially at the zero lower bound. cumulative undershoot of the 2 percent price path would be so much greater under the earlier base period. While not prejudging the potential efficacy of such strategies, I see both fundamental and practical Second, given the difficulty over the last decade issues to grapple with in moving to such regimes. in getting inflation up to 2 percent on a sustained TEN MAGAZINE | | SPRING 2019 2 basis, it is not clear to me that adopting a price-level target would be any more effective than our current inflation target. And deliberately pushing inflation above 2 percent at a time when the unemployment rate is well below its presumed longer-run level could be costly. It would likely require a further overheating of the labor market with related misallocation of resources, along with increased uncertainty about the future inflation rate and price level. KENNETH KIM Third, a price-level targeting strategy is time inconsistent unless policymakers can photo by credibly commit to following it. If the goal is to have inflation of 2 percent on average, President Esther George spoke on March 27 at a finance a period of below 2 percent inflation scholarship group’s event in New York City. would require an equal period of inflation above 2 percent.