Liberalism and Democracy: Can't Have One Without the Other Author(S): Marc F

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Liberalism and Democracy: Can't Have One Without the Other Author(S): Marc F Liberalism and Democracy: Can't Have One without the Other Author(s): Marc F. Plattner Reviewed work(s): Source: Foreign Affairs, Vol. 77, No. 2 (Mar. - Apr., 1998), pp. 171-180 Published by: Council on Foreign Relations Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20048858 . Accessed: 19/10/2012 08:58 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Council on Foreign Relations is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Foreign Affairs. http://www.jstor.org Response and Liberalism Democracy Can't Have One Without the Other Marc F. Plattner Less than a as an quarter-century ago, demo changed dramatically, astonishing to a cracy appeared be confined, with few number of autocratic regimes around the to North America andWestern world from were exceptions, fell power. They generally These nations had in at to Europe. advanced succeeded by regimes that least aspired dustrial sizable middle be rise to economies, democratic, giving the phenome and rates?factors non P. classes, high literacy that Samuel Huntington termed as that many political scientists regarded the "third wave" of democratization. for over a prerequisites successful democracy. Today, well hundred countries, in were home not to free and continent in the can They only every world, plausibly to competitive multiparty elections but also claim have freely elected governments. to the rule of law and the of Outside of few of protection Africa, these aspiring individual liberties. In were new short, they democracies have suffered outright what had come to be called reversions to authoritarianism. But many, "liberal democracies." even among those that hold unambigu rest In the of the world, by contrast, ously free and fair elections, fall short of most countries were neither liberal nor providing the protection of individual were a democratic. They ruled by variety liberties and adherence to the rule of law of in dictatorships?military, single-party, commonly found the long-established revolutionary, Marxist-Leninist?that democracies. As Larry Diamond has put new are rejected free, multiparty elections (in prac it, many of the regimes "electoral if not in not tice, always principle). By the democracies" but "liberal democracies." this situation early 1990s, however, had Citing Diamond's distinction, Huntington Marc F. Plattner is Co-Editor o? tht Journal of Democracy, and Co Director of the International Forum for Democratic Studies. [171] Marc F. Plattner the has argued that the introduction of elec mechanism by which people exercise tions in non-Western societies may often their rule. Today it is further presumed to lead victory by antiliberal forces. And that democracy implies virtually universal Fareed Zakaria has contended that the adult suffrage and eligibility to run for of around the world office. are as promotion elections Elections, then, regarded the or has been responsible for "the rise of illiberal embodying popular majoritarian of liberal democracy"?that is, of freely elected gov aspect contemporary democracy. ernments to that fail safeguard basic liber The word "liberal" in the phrase liberal not to matter ties. "Constitutional liberalism," Zakaria democracy refers the of to the matter of how that argues, "is theoretically different and his who rules but rule is exercised. Above it that torically distinct from democracy_ all, implies two is limited in its Today the strands of liberal demo government powers and cracy, interwoven in theWestern political itsmodes of acting. It is limited first by are rest a fabric, coming apart in the of the the rule of law, and especially by funda mental or world. Democracy is flourishing; consti law constitution, but ultimately tutional liberalism is not." Drawing upon it is limited by the rights of the individual. or this distinction, Zakaria recommends that The idea of natural inalienable rights, not increase which are most called Western policymakers only today commonly their efforts to foster constitutional liberal "human rights," originated with liberalism. ism but diminish their support for elec The primacy of individual rights means autocra tions, and suggests that "liberal that the protection of the private sphere, are to illiberal democracies. with the and of cies" preferable along plurality diversity ends that people seek in their pursuit of DECONSTRUCTING DEMOCRACY a a happiness, is key element of liberal The basic distinction made by all these political order. and liberalism authors is both valid and important. Lib The fact that democracy most are eral democracy?which iswhat not inseparably linked is proven by the mean of historical existence both of nonliberal people today when they speak an and of liberal nondemocracies. democracy?is indeed interweaving democracies of two different elements, one democratic The democracies of the ancient world, a sense were in stricter and the other liberal. As although their citizens incomparably the more involved in themselves its etymological derivation suggests, governing most we are not basic meaning of the word "democ than today, did provide freedom of or of racy" is the rule of the people. As the speech religion, protection pri or rule of the many, it is distinguished from vate property, constitutional govern of one aristo ment. On the other the monarchy (the rule person), side, birthplace cracy (the rule of the best), and oligarchy of liberalism, modern England, retained (the rule of the few). In the modern a highly restricted franchise well into the world, where the sheer size of states has nineteenth century. As Zakaria points direct offers the classic rendered impossible the democracy out, England example once some ancient of democratization a extension practiced by republics, by gradual of well after the essential institu the election of legislative representatives suffrage is the chief tions of constitutional liberalism were and other public officials FOREIGN AFFAIRS [172] Volume77No.2 Liberalism and Democracy in In our own Zakaria the of the this will already place. time, authority government; offers Hong Kong under British colonial shall be expressed in periodic and genuine as an a of lib rule example of flourishing elections which shall be by universal and secret eralism in the absence of democracy. equal suffrage and shall be held by vote or by equivalent free voting proce ALL MEN ARE CREATED EQUAL as a dures." One may regard this formal the or even definitional link between Although "unpacking" component merely it elements of modern liberal democracy is liberalism and electoral democracy, but a to a more crucial first step toward comprehending points profound kinship. For at source its character, overstating the disjunction the political doctrine the can a between liberalism and democracy of liberalism also contains deeply egali to new tarian and dimension. This easily lead misunderstanding. majoritarian While many new electoral democracies is the doctrine that all legitimate political fall short of liberalism, on the whole, power is derived from the consent of are over are nature not countries that hold free elections individuals, who by only more whelmingly liberal than those that free but equal. In the opening pages of his Second Treatise do not, and countries that protect civil lib of Government^ John are more to states men are in "a erties overwhelmingly likely Locke that naturally not. state "a state hold free elections than those that do of perfect freedom," which is not an It is the also of wherein all the This is simply accident. equality, power no one result of powerful intrinsic links between and jurisdiction is reciprocal, a more electoral democracy and liberal order. having than another: there being are more Some of these links immediately ap nothing evident, than that Creatures same parent. Starting from the democratic side, of the species and rank promiscu seem to to same elections would require the guaran ously born all the advantages of tee of certain civil liberties?the freedoms Nature, and the use of the same faculties, one of speech, association, and assembly?if should be equal amongst another are to or they be genuinely free and fair. Thus without Subordination Subjection." even is no man a minimalist definitions of democracy The essential point that has offered by political scientists usually include natural claim to rule over another, and its a must clear is that the rule of man over stipulation that such liberties be corollary to extent man can on maintained at least the necessary be justified only the basis of to a or make possible open electoral competi mutual agreement "compact." tion. Ifwe begin insteadwith the human Now it is true that neither Locke nor rightsmandated by the liberal tradition, his immediate successors concluded from are to this was these generally held today include that democracy the only legitimate some to kind of right electoral participa form of government. For while they held tion. Thus Article 21 of the U.N. Univer that the consent of all is essential to the states: a sal Declaration of Human Rights original compact that forms political to "Everyone has the right take part in the community, they also contended that the or to government of his country, direcdy political community is free decide ... to through freely chosen representatives where it chooses bestow legislative a an The will of the people shall be the basis of power?whether it is in democracy, FOREIGN AFFAIRS March/April i998 i^-73] Marc F. Plattner a or a as itwas in not in oligarchy, monarchy, mix, any share the latter, and the total the and Commons exclusion among King, Lords, of the representatives of the people not from the administration in England.
Recommended publications
  • The Strongmen Strike Back Robert Kagan
    POLICY BRIEF The strongmen strike back Robert Kagan Authoritarianism has returned as an ideological and strategic force. And it returns at just the moment when the liberal world is suffering a major crisis of confidence. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY INTRODUCTION Today, authoritarianism has emerged as the Of all the geopolitical transformations confronting greatest challenge facing the liberal democratic the liberal democratic world these days, the one world—a profound ideological, as well as strategic, for which we are least prepared is the ideological challenge. Or, more accurately, it has reemerged, and strategic resurgence of authoritarianism. We for authoritarianism has always posed the most are not used to thinking of authoritarianism as a potent and enduring challenge to liberalism, since distinct worldview that offers a real alternative the birth of the liberal idea itself. Authoritarianism to liberalism. Communism was an ideology—and has now returned as a geopolitical force, with strong some thought fascism was, as well—that offered a nations such as China and Russia championing comprehensive understanding of human nature, anti-liberalism as an alternative to a teetering politics, economics and governance to shape the liberal hegemony. It has returned as an ideological behavior and thought of all members of a society in force, offering the age-old critique of liberalism, every aspect of their lives. and just at the moment when the liberal world is suffering its greatest crisis of confidence since We believed that “traditional” autocratic the 1930s. It has returned armed with new and governments were devoid of grand theories about hitherto unimaginable tools of social control and society and, for the most part, left their people disruption that are shoring up authoritarian rule at alone.
    [Show full text]
  • East Asian Democratization and Value Change
    Noises and A Comparative Survey of DEMOCRACY, GOVERNANCE AND DEVELOPMENT Working Paper Series: No. 11 Noises and Interruptions – The Road to Democracy Wai-man Lam Hsin-Chi Kuan Chinese University of Hong Kong Issued by Asian Barometer Project Office National Taiwan University and Academia Sinica 2003 Taipei 1 Asian Barometer A Comparative Survey of Democracy, Governance and Development Working Paper Series The Asian Barometer (ABS) is an applied research program on public opinion on political values, democracy, and governance around the region. The regional network encompasses research teams from twelve East Asian political systems (Japan, Mongolia, South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, China, the Philippines, Thailand, Vietnam, Cambodia, Singapore, and Indonesia), and five South Asian countries (India, Pakistan, Bangladesh, Sri Lanka, and Nepal). Together, this regional survey network covers virtually all major political systems in the region, systems that have experienced different trajectories of regime evolution and are currently at different stages of political transition. The ABS Working Paper Series is intended to make research result within the ABS network available to the academic community and other interested readers in preliminary form to encourage discussion and suggestions for revision before final publication. Scholars in the ABS network also devote their work to the Series with the hope that a timely dissemination of the findings of their surveys to the general public as well as the policy makers would help illuminate the public discourse on democratic reform and good governance. The topics covered in the Series range from country-specific assessment of values change and democratic development, region-wide comparative analysis of citizen participation, popular orientation toward democracy and evaluation of quality of governance, and discussion of survey methodology and data analysis strategies.
    [Show full text]
  • Military Neoliberalism: Endless War and Humanitarian Crisis in the Twenty-First Century Michael Schwartz Stony Brook State University
    Societies Without Borders Volume 6 | Issue 3 Article 3 2011 Military Neoliberalism: Endless War and Humanitarian Crisis in the Twenty-First Century Michael Schwartz Stony Brook State University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/swb Part of the Human Rights Law Commons, and the Social and Behavioral Sciences Commons Recommended Citation Schwartz, Michael. 2011. "Military Neoliberalism: Endless War and Humanitarian Crisis in the Twenty-First Century." Societies Without Borders 6 (3): 190-303. Available at: https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/swb/vol6/iss3/3 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Cross Disciplinary Publications at Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Societies Without Borders by an authorized administrator of Case Western Reserve University School of Law Scholarly Commons. Schwartz: Military Neoliberalism: Endless War and Humanitarian Crisis in th M. Schwartz/Societies Without Borders 6:3 (2011) 190-303 Military Neoliberalism: Endless War and Humanitarian Crisis in the Twenty-First Century Michael Schwartz Stony Brook State University Received January 2011; Accepted August 2011 ______________________________________________________ Abstract This article seeks to understand the dynamics of twenty-first century military intervention by the United States and its allies. Based on an analysis of Bush and Obama administration policy documents, we note that these wars are new departures from previous interventions, calling on the military to undertake post-conflict reconstruction in ways that was previously left to indigenous government or to the civilian aspects of the occupation. This military-primary reconstruction is harnessed to ambitious neoliberal economics aimed at transforming the host country’s political economy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Liberal Democracy*
    THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY* Sharun Mukand Dani Rodrik Department of Economics John F. Kennedy School of Government University of Warwick Harvard University Coventry CV4 7AL Cambridge, MA 02138 United Kingdom U.S.A. Revised January 2016 * The first draft of this paper was written at the Institute for Advanced Study, to which we are grateful for support. We also thank members of the IAS School of Social Science lunch table for useful discussions, as well as Carles Boix, William Ferguson, Sumon Majumdar, Jan-Werner Müller, Ira Katznelson, and commentators at presentations at Northwestern, London School of Economics, the NBER, Brown, and WINIR-Rio for helpful suggestions. -2- THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY ABSTRACT We distinguish between three sets of rights – property rights, political rights, and civil rights – and provide a taxonomy of political regimes. The distinctive nature of liberal democracy is that it protects civil rights (equality before the law for minorities) in addition to the other two. When democratic transitions are the product of a settlement between the elite (who care mostly about property rights) and the majority (who care mostly about political rights), they generically fail to produce liberal democracy. This is because the minority has neither the resources nor the numbers to make a contribution to the settlement. We develop a formal model to sharpen the contrast between electoral and liberal democracies and highlight circumstances under which liberal democracy can emerge. We discuss informally the difference between social mobilizations sparked by industrialization and decolonization. Since the latter revolve around identity cleavages rather than class cleavages, they are less conducive to liberal politics.
    [Show full text]
  • LUCA KRISTÓF* Cultural Policy in an Illiberal State. a Case Study Of
    LUCA KRISTÓF Intersections. EEJSP Cultural Policy in an Illiberal State. A Case Study of 3(3): 126-147. DOI: 10.17356/ieejsp.v3i3.328 Hungary after 2010 http://intersections.tk.mta.hu [[email protected]] (Institute for Sociology, Centre for Social Sciences, Hungarian Academy of Sciences) This work was supported by the Bolyai scholarship of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences. Abstract In social sciences literature, numerous attempts have been made to capture the political essence and features of Hungary’s ‘illiberal’ regime but few were aimed at analyzing specific public policy fields in the illiberal democracy. This paper analyses the cultural policy of the Orbán regime, focusing on the role of ideology. A qualitative case study based on document analysis looks at the legitimizing function of post-communist traditionalism in a managed illiberal democracy (Csillag and Szelényi, 2015). Governmental policy making in the field of culture is analyzed on two interrelated levels: (1) attempts to rewrite the cultural canon, and (2) institutional and financial changes. The results show that post-communist traditionalism serves as a discursive framework for the partial replacement of the cultural elite as well as the redistribution of cultural positions and resources, thus contributing to the creation of a new, loyal elite for the managed illiberal political system. Keywords: Cultural Policy; Cultural Elite; Illiberalism; Post-communist Traditionalism; Hungary. INTERSECTIONS. EAST EUROPEAN JOURNAL OF SOCIETY AND POLITICS, 3 (3): 126-147. CULTURAL POLICY IN AN ILLIBERAL STATE 127 1. Introduction: illiberal democracy in Hungary? Fared Zakaria in his famous article noted noticed already in the 1990s that, in contrast with Francis Fukuyama’s popular democratic teleology, countries that had recently undergone the process of democratization, did not turn into western type liberal democracies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Liberal Democracy
    The Economic Journal, 130 (April), 765–792 DOI: 10.1093/ej/ueaa004 C 2020 Royal Economic Society. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved. For permissions please contact [email protected]. Advance Access Publication Date: 15 January 2020 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY∗ Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/ej/article-abstract/130/627/765/5706839 by Harvard Law School Library user on 15 May 2020 Sharun W. Mukand and Dani Rodrik This paper develops a taxonomy of political regimes that distinguishes between three sets of rights—property rights, political rights and civil rights. The truly distinctive nature of liberal democracy is the protection of civil rights (equal treatment by the state for all groups) in addition to the other two. The paper shows how democratic transitions that are the product of a settlement between the elite (who care mostly about property rights) and the majority (who care about political rights), generically fail to produce liberal democracy. Instead, the emergence of liberal democracy requires low levels of inequality and weak identity cleavages. Democratic rule has never been so prevalent. Since the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989, the number of democracies has risen rapidly and cross-national tabulations suggest that, for the first time in history, more countries now qualify as democracies than as non-democracies (Figure 1). While the spread of democracy is something to cheer about, it is clear that this democratisation has not been accompanied by the spread of the full panoply of rights that we associate with the established democracies in the West.
    [Show full text]
  • Schumpeter's Leadership Democracy
    Schumpeter’s Leadership Democracy Forthcoming, Political Theory Gerry Mackie, Assistant Professor Department of Political Science University of California, San Diego 9500 Gilman Dr., MC 0521 [email protected] Social Sciences Bldg. 301 La Jolla, CA, 92093-0521, USA Biography: Gerry Mackie is Assistant Professor of Political Science at University of California, San Diego. His interests include contemporary democratic theory, deliberation, and conceptual and normative understandings of voting. His Democracy Defended (2003) reinterpreted the applicability of social choice theory to democratic theory. Abstract: Schumpeter’s redefinition of representative democracy as merely leadership competition was canonical in postwar political science. Schumpeter denies that individual will, common will, or common good are essential to democracy, but he, and anyone, I contend, is forced to assume these conditions in the course of denying them. Democracy is only a method, of no intrinsic value, its sole function to select leaders, according to Schumpeter. Leaders impose their views, and are not controlled by voters, and this is as it should be, he says. I respond that his leadership democracy is implausible, both descriptively and prescriptively. Competitive election is a necessary, but not a sufficient condition of democracy, not sufficient even for the limited empirical purpose of regime classification. Any adequate definition of democracy must make reference to the common will, the common good, and other values, I submit. Keywords: Joseph Schumpeter, democracy, elections, common good, common will. Author’s Note: The essay is better for comments by participants at: the 2004 annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, especially Ann Davies, discussant; the Montreal Political Theory Workshop, Matthias Risse, discussant; the University of Chicago Political Theory Workshop, Zachary Callen, discussant.
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series the Political Economy of Liberal Democracy
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY Sharun Mukand Dani Rodrik Working Paper 21540 http://www.nber.org/papers/w21540 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 September 2015 This paper was written at the Institute for Advanced Study, to which we are grateful for support. We also thank Carles Boix, William Ferguson, Sumon Majumdar , Jan-Werner Müller, and Ira Katznelson for helpful suggestions and members of the School of Social Science lunch table for useful discussions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2015 by Sharun Mukand and Dani Rodrik. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. The Political Economy of Liberal Democracy Sharun Mukand and Dani Rodrik NBER Working Paper No. 21540 September 2015 JEL No. P48 ABSTRACT We distinguish between three sets of rights – property rights, political rights, and civil rights – and provide a taxonomy of political regimes. The distinctive nature of liberal democracy is that it protects civil rights (equality before the law for minorities) in addition to the other two. Democratic transitions are typically the product of a settlement between the elite (who care mostly about property rights) and the majority (who care mostly about political rights).
    [Show full text]
  • Confucian - Confusion?: Hong Kong Between Virtual State and Torn Country
    CONFUCIAN - CONFUSION?: HONG KONG BETWEEN VIRTUAL STATE AND TORN COUNTRY Eric H. Honda [email protected] Paper Prepared for Delivery at the 74th Annual Meeting of the Western Political Science Association, Seattle, WA, Apr 1-3, 2021 Abstract Hong Kong between The Virtual State and Torn-Country conceptualizes constant double-movement historically evident by recent protest that resembles rebellions from the Mid-Nineteenth Century onward in which local residents mobilized against external intrusion. Intrusion—imparting imperialist imperatives—incessantly institutes indoctrination inherent in ideological identity. Identity, objectively subjected to constant change, stages the development of Hong Kong whether Crown Colony or Special Administrative Region amid The Asian Tiger that describes postwar prosperity. Prosperity, though, comes at the ultimate price that goes to mere cost of opportunity through tradeoff transposing more autocratic rule amid less autarkic regulation as the iron-fist from the state dialectically synthesizes the invisible-hand of the market so trapped in some Max Weber Cage that imprisons The Marxist Zeitgeist to haunt hellish History. History, in this way, both begins and ends embedded by liberalism from Keynesian conception to The Reaganomics reaction. Reaction, in turn, radicalizes residential resistance reconciling the constant conflict over economic openness under political oppression that now asks then answers the question of Hong Kong with Confucian-Confusion? 1 CONFUCIAN-CONFUSION?: HONG KONG BETWEEN THE VIRTUAL STATE AND TORN- COUNTRY Hong Kong between The Virtual State and Torn-Country incidentally inscribes much recent history of current events replete with mass protests against questionable extraditions to The Mainland among other police powers however abusive or autocratic either way.
    [Show full text]
  • Liberal Democracy: the Threat of Counter-Narratives
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Springer - Publisher Connector EUROPeAN VIew (2015) 14:145–154 DOI 10.1007/s12290-015-0369-z ARTICLE Liberal democracy: the threat of counter‑narratives Ingrid Habets Published online: 23 November 2015 © The Author(s) 2015. This article is published with open access at Springerlink.com Abstract The universalism of liberal democracy is under attack. While the number of democracies in the world has increased, the level of freedom in them has declined. Electoral or illiberal democracies only provide the minimum standard of democracy, where individual liberties remain unprotected. Furthermore, these illiberal democracies have developed counter-narratives that attack the liberal international order, and with it, liberal democracy. These counter-narratives, supported by Russia, China and other undemocratic regimes, confront liberal democracy in three ways: first, they trivialise the violation of individual liberties for the sake of increasing state security; second, the claim of civilisational diversity is used to reject democratic values as incompatible with their culture; and third, they accuse the West of the moral decay of ‘traditional’ values. Moreover, these authoritarian narratives play to the West’s weaknesses. The West needs to defend its hard-won liberties, rights and values by confronting these counter- narratives. Furthermore, citizens have a moral duty to participate politically in order to ensure that democracy continues to work. The transatlantic
    [Show full text]
  • Populism and Liberal Democracy: Three Case Studies
    Populism and Liberal Democracy: Three Case Studies By Werner Vollgraaff Thesis presented in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Political Science at the Faculty of Arts and Social Sciences, Stellenbosch University Supervisor: Prof Pieter Fourie Co-supervisor: Dr Cindy Steenekamp December 2018 Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za Declaration: By submitting this thesis/dissertation electronically, I declare that the entirety of the work contained therein is my own, original work, that I am the sole author thereof (save to the extent explicitly otherwise stated), that reproduction and publication thereof by Stellenbosch University will not infringe any third party rights and that I have not previously in its entirety or in part submitted it for obtaining any qualification. December 2018 Copyright © 2018 Stellenbosch University All rights reserved i Stellenbosch University https://scholar.sun.ac.za Abstract: This study used an exploratory case study design to examine the wave of populism that occurred in 2016. During 2016, numerous notable populist events in Liberal Democracies occurred. These include Rodrigo Duterte becoming the president of the Philippines; the Brexit vote in Britain and Donald Trump winning the presidency in the U.S. This series of populist events sparked a concern that internal failings within the Liberal Democratic system were the cause of the populism. Understanding the underlying causes of these incidents is of utmost importance considering that Liberal Democracy is globally the current dominant political system. The primary goal of this study is to uncover how and why populism has occurred in these Liberal Democracies, and more specifically, whether it is due to internal failings with the Liberal Democratic system.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Liberal Democracy
    Warwick Economics Research Paper Series The Political Economy of Liberal Democracy Sharun Mukand and Dani Rodrik September, 2015 Series Number: 1074 ISSN 2059-4283 (online) ISSN 0083-7350 (print) This paper also appears as CAGE Working Paper 240 THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY* Sharun Mukand Dani Rodrik Department of Economics John F. Kennedy School of Government University of Warwick Harvard University Coventry CV4 7AL Cambridge, MA 02138 United Kingdom U.S.A. Revised September 2015 * This paper was written at the Institute for Advanced Study, to which we are grateful for support. We also thank Carles Boix, William Ferguson, Sumon Majumdar, Jan-Werner Müller, and Ira Katznelson for helpful suggestions and members of the School of Social Science lunch table for useful discussions. -2- THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF LIBERAL DEMOCRACY ABSTRACT We distinguish between three sets of rights – property rights, political rights, and civil rights – and provide a taxonomy of political regimes. The distinctive nature of liberal democracy is that it protects civil rights (equality before the law for minorities) in addition to the other two. Democratic transitions are typically the product of a settlement between the elite (who care mostly about property rights) and the majority (who care mostly about political rights). Such settlements rarely produce liberal democracy, as the minority has neither the resources nor the numbers to make a contribution at the bargaining table. We develop a formal model to sharpen the contrast between electoral and liberal democracies and highlight circumstances under which liberal democracy can emerge. We discuss informally the difference between social mobilizations sparked by industrialization and decolonization.
    [Show full text]