Appendix: the Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization1

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Appendix: the Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization1 Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization1 In the following, we will assume that investment returns are completely described by the two moments of mean and variance. To think in terms of asset allocation, we will refer to the elements in the portfolio as “assets” rather than “securities”. We will begin this review with the Markowitz model2 and round off with the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Throughout, risk will be understood to mean the standard deviation of the return, or volatility. We will begin with a portfolio consisting of two risky assets and later generalize to n assets. Two Risky Assets Notation Ra: Return on asset a Rb: Return on asset b Ra : Expected (mean) return on asset a Rb : Expected (mean) return on asset b Rp : Expected (mean) return on portfolio wa: Weight in the portfolio of asset a wb: Weight in the portfolio of asset b (=1 − wa) 2 σ a : The variance of the return on asset 1 1 This Appendix is meant as a quick refresher. For a more complete coverage, see, for example, Elton et al. (2014) or Bodie et al. (2014). 2 Markowitz (1952, 1959). © The Author(s) 2018 211 H. Lumholdt, Strategic and Tactical Asset Allocation, https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-89554-3 212 Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization 2 σ b : The variance of the return on asset 2 σab: The covariance between the returns on assets a and b 2 σ p : The variance of the return on the portfolio All wealth is invested in the two assets, implying that wa + wb = 1. The expected return of the portfolio is a linear combination of the expected return on each asset: Rw=+Rw1− R (A.1) paaa()b The variance of the returns on the portfolio is given by: 2 σ 2 =−ER R pp p Expanding this expression, we get: 2 σ 2 =+Ew Rw11− Rw−+Rw− R pa aa()ba()aa()b 2 =−Ew RR+−1 wR− R aa()aa()()bbb 2 2 2 2 =−Ewaa()RRaa+−()12wR()bb− Rw+−a ()1 wRaaa()− R ()RRRbb− 2 2 Note that ER()aa− R and ER()bb− R are the variances of the returns ER − RR( − R on assets a and b, respectively, while ()aa()ab is their covari- ance. We can therefore write: 2 σσ22=+ww2 12− σσ2 +−ww1 (A.2) paaa()ba()aab and 12/ 22 2 2 σσpa=+wwaa()12− σσba+−ww()1 aab (A.3) The covariance can be expressed as the product of the standard deviation of each asset and the correlation coefficient between the assets (ρab) i.e. σab = σaσbρab. We can therefore write (A.2) as Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization 213 2 σσ22=+ww2 12− σσ2 +−ww1 σρ (A.4) paaa()ba()aabab and 12/ 22 2 2 σσpa=+wwaa()12− σσba+−ww()1 aaσρbab (A.5) We see that portfolio risk depends both on the risk of the individual assets and on the correlation of their returns. This is what gives rise to a diversifica- tion effect. To examine this more closely, we begin with the case of perfect posi- tive correlation. Substitute ρab = 1 into (A.4) to get: 2 σσ22=+ww2 12− σσ2 +−ww1 σ (A.6) paaa()ba()aab which corresponds to 2 σσ2 =+ww()1− σ pa aab hence σσ=+ww1− σ (A.7) paaa()b The standard deviation of the portfolio is now a simple weighted average of the standard deviation of each asset, and there is no diversification effect. However, only in this extreme case of a perfect positive correlation does that apply. We see this from the fact that any ρab < 1 would make the right hand side of Eq. (A.4) smaller than (A.6). Consider now a zero correlation between the two assets (ρab = 0 ). Equation (A.4) reduces to 2 σσ22=+ww2 1− σ 2 (A.8) paaa()b and 12/ 22 2 2 σσpa=+wwaa()1− σ b (A.9) 214 Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization σp is now smaller than waσa + (1 − wa)σb unless wa = 1 or 0, in which case the portfolio would be concentrated in either asset a or asset b, which would obviously exclude any diversification effect. Finally, let’s consider the case of a perfect negative correlation (ρab = − 1). As discussed previously, negative correlations between any two assets are hard to find over long time horizons, but frequently occur over shorter periods of time (e.g. in “flight to quality” situations). Substituting ρab = − 1 into Eq. (A.4) we get 2 σσ22=+ww2 12− σσ2 −−ww1 σ paaa()ba()aab which corresponds to 2 σσ2 =−ww()1− σ (A.10) pa aab or to 2 σσ2 =− ww+−()1 σ (A.11) pa aab hence σσ=−ww1− σ (A.12) paaa()b or σσ=−ww+−1 σ (A.13) paaa()b Either (A.12) or (A.13) is valid depending on which of the two is positive. In this case, it is (in principle) possible to entirely eliminate the risk of the portfolio. To find the wa (and, by implication, wb ) necessary for this, set (A.13) equal to zero and solve for wa to get σ w = b (A.14) a σσ+ ab The effect of diversification in the two assets case is illustrated in Fig. A.1, in stylized form. We saw that with a perfect positive correlation, both the risk and the return of the portfolio become linear combinations of the two assets in the portfolio. Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization 215 r = -1 = 0 = 0.5 = 1 r r r Fig. A.1 Correlation and diversification For correlations lower than one, however, the diversification effect is repre- sented by the non-linear combinations of assets a and b in Fig. A.1 and, in the extreme case of ρab = − 1, by the straight lines to the vertical axis. Comparing the linear combination of ρab = 1 with all the others, we see that diversification reduces the level of risk of the portfolio for a given level of return or, which is the equivalent, increases the level of return for a given level of risk. To find the minimum variance portfolio in the two-asset case, we differen- 222 2 2 tiate (A.4), that is, σσpa=+wwaa()12− σσba+−ww()1 aaσρbab , with respect to wa and set it equal to zero: ∂σ 2 p =−22wwσσ22++22σσ2 σρ −=40w σσρ ∂w aa babababaabab a Solving for wa, we get: σσ2 − σρ w = babab (A.15) a σσ22+−2σσρ ab abab σ b This is the general formula which, as we saw, becomes when ρab = − 1. σσab+ We see directly that for uncorrelated assets (ρab = 0), (A.15) is reduced to σ 2 w = b (A.16) a σσ22+ ab 216 Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization A Numerical Example A portfolio consists of an equity fund (asset a) and a high-yielding fixed income fund (asset b). The expected return of the equity fund is 12.5%, while that of the bond fund is 7.5%. The standard deviations of their returns are 18.0% and 12.5%, respectively. Table A.1 below shows the expected return and standard deviation of the portfolio in decimal form, using formulas (A.7), (A.9) and (A.15). As can be seen, the standard deviation of the portfolio falls the lower is the correlation, but this has no cost in terms of the return of the portfolio, which depends exclusively on the weighting of the two assets. Figure A.2 gives a graphical illustration. To calculate the weighting of each asset class required to minimize the stan- dard deviation of the portfolio we use formulas (A.14) and (A.15) to get the results set out in Table A.2. Table A.1 Standard deviation of portfolio returns with different levels of correlation Standard deviation of portfolio return wa wb Rp ρ = 1 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0 ρ = −0.5 0.0 1.0 0.0750 0.1250 0.1250 0.1250 0.1250 0.1 0.9 0.0800 0.1305 0.1225 0.1139 0.1047 0.2 0.8 0.0850 0.1360 0.1220 0.1063 0.0878 0.3 0.7 0.0900 0.1415 0.1237 0.1028 0.0765 0.4 0.6 0.0950 0.1470 0.1273 0.1040 0.0735 0.5 0.5 0.1000 0.1525 0.1328 0.1096 0.0799 0.6 0.4 0.1050 0.1580 0.1399 0.1190 0.0936 0.7 0.3 0.1100 0.1635 0.1483 0.1315 0.1121 0.8 0.2 0.1150 0.1690 0.1580 0.1462 0.1333 0.9 0.1 0.1200 0.1745 0.1686 0.1625 0.1561 1.0 0.0 0.1250 0.1800 0.1800 0.1800 0.1800 0.2000 0.1800 ρ = 1 ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0 ρ = -0.5 0.1600 . 0.1400 0.1200 0.1000 folio St.D 0.0800 Port 0.0600 0.0400 0.0200 0.0000 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 Weight in asset 1 Fig. A.2 Portfolio volatility and asset correlation Appendix: The Mechanics of Mean-Variance Optimization 217 Table A.2 Minimum standard deviation portfolio Minimum St.D portfolio ρ = 0.5 ρ = 0 ρ = −0.5 wa 0.1714 0.3254 0.3811 wb 0.8286 0.6746 0.6189 Rp 0.0836 0.1028 0.1098 σp 0.122 0.1027 0.0734 Portfolios of n Risky Assets Generalizing to n assets, we can express the expected return on the portfolio as: n (A.17) Rwp = ∑ iiR i=1 n which is a simple weighted average of the return on each asset with ∑wi = 1.
Recommended publications
  • (12) United States Patent T531
    US008620789B2 (12) United States Patent (10) Patent N0.: US 8,620,789 B2 Arnott et a1. (45) Date of Patent: Dec. 31, 2013 (54) USING ACCOUNTING DATA BASED (56) References Cited INDEXING TO CREATE A LOW VOLATILITY PORTFOLIO OF FINANCIAL OBJECTS U.S. PATENT DOCUMENTS 4,334,270 A 6/1982 Towers (75) Inventors: Robert D. Arnott, Newport Beach, CA 4,751,640 A 6/1988 Lucas et a1. (US); Paul Christopher Wood, Waltham (GB); Feifei Li, Irvine, CA (US) (Continued) FOREIGN PATENT DOCUMENTS (73) Assignee: Research Af?liates, LLC, Newport Beach, CA (U S) EP 1351179 A1 10/2003 GB 2393532 3/2004 Notice: Subject to any disclaimer, the term of this (Continued) patent is extended or adjusted under 35 OTHER PUBLICATIONS U.S.C. 154(b) by 0 days. Fundamental Indexation, Robert Arnott, 2004; 36-pages. (21) Appl. No.: 13/593,415 (Continued) Primary Examiner * Gregory Johnson (22) Filed: Aug. 23, 2012 (74) Attorney, Agent, or Firm * Ralph P. Albrecht; ATFirm, PLLC (65) Prior Publication Data (57) ABSTRACT US 2013/0117199 A1 May 9, 2013 A system, method and computer program product creates an index based on accounting data, or a portfolio of ?nancial objects based on the index where the portfolio is weighted Related US. Application Data according to accounting data. Indexes may be built with met rics other than market capitalization weighting, price weight (63) Continuation-in-part of application No. 13/216,238, ing or equal weighting. Financial and non-?nancial metrics ?led onAug. 23, 201 1, which is a continuation-in-part may be used to build indexes to create passive investment of application No.
    [Show full text]
  • Seeing Through the Smoke Screen of Fundamental Indexers: What Are the Issues with Alternative Equity Index Strategies?
    Seeing through the Smoke Screen of Fundamental Indexers: What are the Issues with Alternative Equity Index Strategies? June 2012 Noël Amenc Professor of Finance, EDHEC Business School and Director, EDHEC-Risk Institute Felix Goltz Head of Applied Research, EDHEC-Risk Institute Shuyang Ye Quantitative Equity Analyst, EDHEC-Risk Institute EDHEC is one of the top five business schools in France. Its reputation is built on the high quality of its faculty and the privileged relationship with professionals that the school has cultivated since its establishment in 1906. EDHEC Business School has decided to draw on its extensive knowledge of the professional environment and has therefore focused its research on themes that satisfy the needs of professionals. EDHEC pursues an active research policy in the field of finance. EDHEC-Risk Institute carries out numerous research programmes in the areas of asset allocation and risk management in both the 2 traditional and alternative investment universes. Copyright © 2012 EDHEC Introduction With an ever-growing number of alternative index construction methods on offer, investors should, in principle, be thankful for comparative analysis. Such comparison has recently been provided in several articles written by promoters of fundamentally-based equity indices. In particular, Arnott (2011) and Chow et al. (2011) offer a back-test of several alternative weighting strategies and come to the conclusion that there are no differences in performance and risk factor exposures of alternative weighting schemes; but when it comes to implementation, fundamental weighting schemes are superior. While the conclusions of these articles may not come as a surprise, it is important to mention that the results reported in these articles are based on a flawed methodology which has the potential to lead to misleading conclusions on the relative merits and the properties of various indices.
    [Show full text]
  • Making Smart Money - an Evaluation of Fundamental Smart
    Making Smart Money - An Evaluation of Fundamental Smart Beta Investment Strategies Department of Economics Uppsala University Bachelor’s Thesis, 15 credits Authors: Amelie Dahlgren & Oliver Eliassen Supervisor: Lars Forsberg Spring Semester of 2017 Date of Submission: 2017-06-02 Abstract In recent decades, many investors have abandoned hopes of achieving above market returns through active management, and consigned themselves to passive investing in the form of market capitalization based portfolios. Using Swedish stock exchange data from 2002-2016, this thesis investigates if there is a way to harmonize the strengths of active management, yielding potential above market returns, and passive index investing, implying lower fees and transparency. Based on observations from 275 companies, analysed through market model regressions, the results suggest that fundamentally invested value and quality portfolios create an alpha of 1-2 percent quarterly relative the market capitalization benchmark portfolio. Moreover, the results constitute basis for performing real investments, as they take into consideration the transaction costs implied by portfolio turnover. Furthermore, the findings of greater risk-adjusted returns through fundamentally weighted portfolios stand in opposition to the efficient market hypothesis. Keywords: Alpha, Abnormal Returns, Smart Beta, Fundamental Indexation, Market Model, Value Investing, Swedish Stock Exchange Table of Contents 1. Introduction ...........................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • The Law of One Price Lagen Om Ett Pris
    LIU-IEI-FIL-A—09/00489—SE Linköping University, Sweden Department of Management and Engineering Master’s Thesis in Finance 15hp The International Business Program Spring 2009 The Law of One Price Evidence from Three European Stock Exchanges Lagen om ett pris Bevis från tre europeiska börsmarknader Author: – Sanna Olkkonen – Supervisor: Göran Hägg The Law of One Price – Evidence from Three European Stock Exchanges Abstract For the last decades the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) has had a vital role in the financial theory. According to the theory assets, independent of geographic location, always are correctly priced due to the notion of information efficiency across financial markets. A consequence of EMH is the Law of One Price, hereafter simply the Law, which is the main concept of this thesis. The Law extends the analysis by stating that in a perfectly integrated and competitive market cross- traded assets should trade for the same common-currency price in every country. This becomes a fact due to the presence of arbitrageurs’ continuous vigilance in the financial markets, where any case of mispricing is acted upon in a matter of seconds by buying the cheaper asset and selling it where the price is higher in order to make a profit from the price gap. Past research reveals that mispricing on cross-traded assets does exist, indicating that there exists evidence of violations of the Law on financial markets. However, in the real world most likely only a few cases of mispricing equal arbitrage opportunities due to the fact that worldwide financial markets are not characterized by the perfect conditions required by Law.
    [Show full text]
  • The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964)
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 18, Number 3—Summer 2004—Pages 25–46 The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence Eugene F. Fama and Kenneth R. French he capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of William Sharpe (1964) and John Lintner (1965) marks the birth of asset pricing theory (resulting in a T Nobel Prize for Sharpe in 1990). Four decades later, the CAPM is still widely used in applications, such as estimating the cost of capital for firms and evaluating the performance of managed portfolios. It is the centerpiece of MBA investment courses. Indeed, it is often the only asset pricing model taught in these courses.1 The attraction of the CAPM is that it offers powerful and intuitively pleasing predictions about how to measure risk and the relation between expected return and risk. Unfortunately, the empirical record of the model is poor—poor enough to invalidate the way it is used in applications. The CAPM’s empirical problems may reflect theoretical failings, the result of many simplifying assumptions. But they may also be caused by difficulties in implementing valid tests of the model. For example, the CAPM says that the risk of a stock should be measured relative to a compre- hensive “market portfolio” that in principle can include not just traded financial assets, but also consumer durables, real estate and human capital. Even if we take a narrow view of the model and limit its purview to traded financial assets, is it 1 Although every asset pricing model is a capital asset pricing model, the finance profession reserves the acronym CAPM for the specific model of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965) and Black (1972) discussed here.
    [Show full text]
  • “Mean Variance Optimization Via Factor Models in the Emerging Markets: Evidence on the Istanbul Stock Exchange”
    “Mean variance optimization via factor models in the emerging markets: evidence on the Istanbul Stock Exchange” AUTHORS Fazıl Gökgöz Fazıl Gökgöz (2009). Mean variance optimization via factor models in the ARTICLE INFO emerging markets: evidence on the Istanbul Stock Exchange. Investment Management and Financial Innovations, 6(3) RELEASED ON Friday, 21 August 2009 JOURNAL "Investment Management and Financial Innovations" FOUNDER LLC “Consulting Publishing Company “Business Perspectives” NUMBER OF REFERENCES NUMBER OF FIGURES NUMBER OF TABLES 0 0 0 © The author(s) 2021. This publication is an open access article. businessperspectives.org Investment Management and Financial Innovations, Volume 6, Issue 3, 2009 Fazil Gökgöz (Turkey) Mean variance optimization via factor models in the emerging markets: evidence on the Istanbul Stock Exchange Abstract Markowitz’s mean-variance analysis, a well known financial optimization technique, has a crucial role for the financial decision makers. This quadratic programming method determines the optimal portfolios within the risk-return perspec- tive. Estimation of the expected returns and the covariances for the financial assets has a significant importance in quantitative portfolio management. The famous financial models used in estimating the input parameters are CAPM, Three Factor Model and Characteristic Model. The goal of this study is to investigate the significance of asset pricing models in the Markowitz’s mean-variance optimization technique for the different Turkish benchmark indices. The optimized risky financial assets have demonstrated higher portfolio risks rather than risky portfolios with risk-free assets. Portfolio risk is found lower for CAPM, Three Factor Model and Characteristics Model, however higher for naive returns. The performances of optimized CAPM portfolios are higher than multi-factor models.
    [Show full text]
  • Keynes Meets Markowitz: the Trade-Off Between Familiarity and Diversification
    Keynes Meets Markowitz: The Trade-off Between Familiarity and Diversification January 2011 Phelim Boyle, Wilfrid Laurier University Lorenzo Garlappi, University of British Columbia Raman Uppal, EDHEC Business School Tan Wang, University of British Columbia Abstract We develop a model of portfolio choice that nests the views of Keynes—who advocates concentration in a few familiar assets—and Markowitz—who advocates diversification across assets. We rely on the concepts of ambiguity and ambiguity aversion to formalize the idea of an investor's "familiarity" toward assets. The model shows that when an investor is equally ambiguous about all assets, then the optimal portfolio corresponds to Markowitz's fully-diversied portfolio. In contrast, when an investor exhibits different degrees of familiarity across assets, the optimal portfolio depends on (i) the relative degree of ambiguity across assets, and (ii) the standard deviation of the estimate of expected return on each asset. If the standard deviation of the expected return estimate and the difference between the ambiguity about familiar and unfamiliar assets are low, then the optimal portfolio is composed of a mix of both familiar and unfamiliar assets; moreover, an increase in correlation between assets causes an investor to increase concentration in the assets with which they are familiar (flight to familiarity). Alternatively, if the standard deviation of the expected return estimate and the difference in the ambiguity of familiar and unfamiliar assets are high, then the optimal portfolio contains only the familiar asset(s) as Keynes would have advocated. In the extreme case in which the ambiguity about all assets and the standard deviation of the estimated mean are high, then no risky asset is held (non-participation).
    [Show full text]
  • Generating Passive Alpha in the Core of a Portfolio Analyzing the 10-Year Real-Time Results from Wisdomtree’S U.S
    WisdomTree Research MARKET INSIGHTS [ March 2017 ] Generating Passive Alpha in the Core of a Portfolio Analyzing the 10-Year Real-Time Results from WisdomTree’s U.S. Earnings Indexes BY LUCIANO SIRACUSANO, CHIEF INVESTMENT STRATEGIST, JEREMY SCHWARTZ, CFA®, DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH & CHRISTOPHER GANNATTI, CFA®, ASSOCIATE DIRECTOR OF RESEARCH Ten years is a significant period. In June 2016, WisdomTree reached its first 10-year milestone when its original family of Dividend Indexes obtained a critical juncture of live performance history. In February 2017, the WisdomTree Earnings Index family also reached a 10-year anniversary. In this paper, we will: + Examine the philosophical and fundamental underpinnings for the creation of the WisdomTree fundamentally weighted1 Indexes + Showcase the impressive performance track record generated + Indicate the factors2 that we believe drove this performance + Conclude with how we think these strategies fit into the U.S. equity market context today While many factor or “smart beta3” indexes exist today, we emphasize that few have a full 10 years of live performance upon which to judge the effectiveness of their approaches. The results thus far indicate a capability to generate low-cost and passive alpha4 in the core building blocks of a portfolio. THE “NOISY MARKET HYPOTHESIS” & BUBBLE AVOIDANCE Wharton finance Professor Jeremy Siegel developed a theory—the “Noisy Market Hypothesis”—that provides rationale for why it is possible to develop indexes that can deliver added value over a market cap-weighted5 index. Most of the time, markets are micro-efficient6 at digesting new information. However, widespread evidence exists that markets can become overextended, allowing for bubbles7 to occur.
    [Show full text]
  • A Comparison of Basic and Extended Markowitz Model on Croatian Capital Market
    Croatian Operational Research Review (CRORR), Vol. 3, 2012 A COMPARISON OF BASIC AND EXTENDED MARKOWITZ MODEL ON CROATIAN CAPITAL MARKET Bruna Škarica Faculty of Economics and Business – Zagreb, Croatia Trg J. F. Kennedyja 6, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia E-mail: [email protected] Zrinka Lukač Faculty of Economics and Business - Zagreb Trg J. F. Kennedyja 6, 10000 Zagreb, Croatia E-mail: [email protected] Abstract Markowitz' mean - variance model for portfolio selection, first introduced in H.M. Markowitz' 1952 article, is one of the best known models in finance. However, the Markowitz model is based on many assumptions about financial markets and investors, which do not coincide with the real world. One of these assumptions is that there are no taxes or transaction costs, when in reality all financial products are subject to both taxes and transaction costs – such as brokerage fees. In this paper, we consider an extension of the standard portfolio problem which includes transaction costs that arise when constructing an investment portfolio. Finally, we compare both the extension of the Markowitz' model, including transaction costs, and the basic model on the example of the Croatian capital market. Key words: portfolio optimization, Markowitz model, expected return and risk, transaction costs 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1. Modern portfolio theory Constructing a portfolio of investments is one of the most significant financial decisions facing both individual and institutional investors. Modern portfolio theory has gained widespread acceptance as a practical tool for portfolio construction. It has been used by investors to choose a portfolio which, given the level of investors' risk aversion, offers them an acceptable balance between risk and return.
    [Show full text]
  • Style Influences and JSE Sector Returns: Evidence from the South
    The Journal of Applied Business Research – September/October 2017 Volume 33, Number 5 Style Influences And JSE Sector Returns: Evidence From The South African Stock Market Wayne Small, University of the Western Cape, South Africa Heng-Hsing Hsieh, University of the Western Cape, South Africa ABSTRACT A distinctive phenomenon on the Johannesburg Stock Exchange (JSE) is the market segmentation between the resource sector and the financial and industrial sectors documented in empirical literature. The dominance of the resource sector in the cap-weighted FTSE/JSE All-Share index (ALSI) implies that the ALSI index might not be mean-variance efficient due to the potential lack of diversification. We estimate and compare the historical sector exposures of the ALSI index to its hypothetically optimal sector exposures over the examination period from 2003 through 2013. It is found that to achieve mean-variance efficiency on the JSE over the examination period, one should maintain substantial investments in the industrial sector and tactically allocate the remainder of the investments to the financial sector and/or the resource sector. It is also observed that the sector exposures of the ALSI index have shifted significantly from the resource sector to the industrial sector. To gain a better understanding of the investment style influences on the JSE sector returns, we further investigate the exposures of the prominent JSE sector returns to the style risks using the Carhart (1997) four-factor model. It is found that investments in financial stocks are exposed to significant value risk and, to some degree, influenced by the performance of large caps on the JSE.
    [Show full text]
  • Portfolio Theory & Financial Analyses: Exercises
    Robert Alan Hill Portfolio Theory & Financial Analyses: Exercises Download free ebooks at bookboon.com 2 Portfolio Theory & Financial Analyses: Exercises © 2010 Robert Alan Hill & Ventus Publishing ApS ISBN 978-87-7681-616-2 Download free ebooks at bookboon.com 3 Portfolio Theory & Financial Analyses: Exercises Contents Contents Part I: An Introduction 7 1. An Overview 7 Introduction 7 Exercise 1.1: The Mean-Variance Paradox 8 Exercise 1.2: The Concept of Investor Utility 10 Summary and Conclusions 10 Selected References (From PTFA) 11 Part II: The Portfolio Decision 13 2. Risk and Portfolio Analysis 13 Introduction 13 Exercise 2.1: A Guide to Further Study 13 Exercise 2.2: The Correlation Coefficient and Risk 14 Exercise 2.3: Correlation and Risk Reduction 16 Summary and Conclusions 18 Selected References 19 3. The Optimum Portfolio 20 Introduction 20 Exercise 3.1: Two-Asset Portfolio Risk Minimisation 21 Exercise 3.2: Two-Asset Portfolio Minimum Variance (I) 24 e Graduate Programme I joined MITAS because for Engineers and Geoscientists I wanted real responsibili Maersk.com/Mitas Month 16 I wwasas a construction supervisor in Please click the advert the North Sea advising and Real work hhelpinge foremen InternationalInternationaal opportunities reeree workworo placements ssolve problems Download free ebooks at bookboon.com 4 Portfolio Theory & Financial Analyses: Exercises Contents Exercise 3.3: Two-Asset Portfolio Minimum Variance (II) 27 Exercise 3.4: The Multi-Asset Portfolio 29 Summary and Conclusions 30 Selected References 30 4. The Market Portfolio 31 Introduction 31 Exercise 4.1: Tobin and Perfect Capital Markets 32 Exercise 4.2: The Market Portfolio and Tobin’s Theorem 34 Summary and Conclusions 39 Selected References 40 Part III: Models of Capital Asset Pricing 41 5.
    [Show full text]
  • An Application of the Markowitz's Mean-Variance Framework in Constructing Optimal Portfolios Using the Johannesburg Securities
    Journal of Accounting and Management ISSN: 2284 – 9459 J A M v o l . 1 0 , n o . 2 ( 2 0 2 0 ) An Application of The Markowitz’s Mean-Variance Framework in Constructing Optimal Portfolios using the Johannesburg Securities Exchange Tradeable Indices Sally Huni1, Athenia Bongani Sibindi2 Abstract: The aim of this study was to assess the feasibility of constructing optimal portfolios using the Johannesburg Securities Exchange (JSE) tradable sector indices. Three indices were employed, namely Financials, Industrials and Resources and these were benchmarked against the JSE All Share Index for the period January 2007 to December 2017. The period was split into three, namely before the 2007-2009 global financial crises, during the global financial crises and after the global financial crises. The Markowitz’s mean- variance optimisation framework was employed for the construction of global mean variance portfolios. The results of this study demonstrated that it was feasible to construct mean-variance efficient portfolios using the tradable sector indices from the JSE. It was also established that, on the other hand, global mean variance portfolios constructed in this study, outperformed the benchmark index in a bullish market in terms of the risk-return combinations. On the other hand, in bear markets, the global mean variance portfolios were observed to perform better than the benchmark index in terms of risk. Further, the results of the study showed that portfolios constructed from the three tradable indices yielded diversification benefits despite their positive correlation with each other. The results of the study corroborate the findings by other scholars that the mean-variance optimisation framework is effective in the construction of optimal portfolios using the Johannesburg Securities Exchange.
    [Show full text]